Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

91
Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets Hugo Molina KU Leuven Bergen Competition Policy Conference, BECCLE April 2019 Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 1 / 35

Transcript of Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Page 1: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Hugo Molina

KU Leuven

Bergen Competition Policy Conference, BECCLE

April 2019

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 1 / 35

Page 2: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

Definition

Figure 1: Buyer alliance in a vertical market

U1 U2. . .

UF

D1 D2 . . . DR

Consumers

U1 U2. . .

UF

D1 D2 . . . DR

Consumers

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 2 / 35

Page 3: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

Definition

Figure 1: Buyer alliance in a vertical market

U1 U2. . .

UF

D1 D2 . . . DR

Consumers

U1 U2. . .

UF

D1 D2 . . . DR

Consumers

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 2 / 35

Page 4: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

Buyer alliances in practice

Alliances formed by buyers to deal with their suppliers is awidespread

phenomenon in many industries:I Pharmaceutical industries: e.g., Numark in the UK, Giphar in France;I Health care sector: group purchasing organizations (GPOs);I Retail food industries.

Antitrust concerns of buyer alliances: strong presumption of le-

gality (Carstensen, 2010, Wm. & Mary Bus. L. Rev.).

Galbraith (1952, 1954): Countervailing buyer power.No market power effect unlike downstream concentration.

Do final consumers benefit from buyer alliances?How do they affect manufacturers and industry profits?

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 3 / 35

Page 5: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

Buyer alliances in practice

Alliances formed by buyers to deal with their suppliers is awidespread

phenomenon in many industries:I Pharmaceutical industries: e.g., Numark in the UK, Giphar in France;I Health care sector: group purchasing organizations (GPOs);I Retail food industries.

Antitrust concerns of buyer alliances: strong presumption of le-

gality (Carstensen, 2010, Wm. & Mary Bus. L. Rev.).

Galbraith (1952, 1954): Countervailing buyer power.No market power effect unlike downstream concentration.

Do final consumers benefit from buyer alliances?How do they affect manufacturers and industry profits?

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 3 / 35

Page 6: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

Buyer alliances in practice

Alliances formed by buyers to deal with their suppliers is awidespread

phenomenon in many industries:I Pharmaceutical industries: e.g., Numark in the UK, Giphar in France;I Health care sector: group purchasing organizations (GPOs);I Retail food industries.

Antitrust concerns of buyer alliances: strong presumption of le-

gality (Carstensen, 2010, Wm. & Mary Bus. L. Rev.).

Galbraith (1952, 1954): Countervailing buyer power.No market power effect unlike downstream concentration.

Do final consumers benefit from buyer alliances?How do they affect manufacturers and industry profits?

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 3 / 35

Page 7: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

Buyer alliances in practice

Alliances formed by buyers to deal with their suppliers is awidespread

phenomenon in many industries:I Pharmaceutical industries: e.g., Numark in the UK, Giphar in France;I Health care sector: group purchasing organizations (GPOs);I Retail food industries.

Antitrust concerns of buyer alliances: strong presumption of le-

gality (Carstensen, 2010, Wm. & Mary Bus. L. Rev.).

Galbraith (1952, 1954): Countervailing buyer power.No market power effect unlike downstream concentration.

Do final consumers benefit from buyer alliances?How do they affect manufacturers and industry profits?

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 3 / 35

Page 8: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

ContributionsFigure 2: Without Alliance

U1 U2. . . UF

D1 D2 . . . DR

Consumers

Figure 3: With Alliance

U1 U2. . . UF

D1 D2 . . . DR

ConsumersShed light on 3 economic forces generated by buyer alliances:

I Status quo effect (Caprice and Rey, 2015, EJ):Deteriorate manufacturers’ status quo payoffs in negotiations.

I Nondiscrimination effect (O’Brien, 2014, RAND):Impact concessions costs of firms to the detriment of retailers.

Harsanyi (1977)’s joint-bargaining paradox?I Bargaining ability effect: Grennan (2013, AER; 2014, MS), Lewis and

Pflum (2015, AEJ: Econ. Policy), Grennan and Swanson (2019, JPE).

The global effect of buyer alliances is an empirical question!Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 4 / 35

Page 9: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

ContributionsFigure 2: Without Alliance

U1 U2. . . UF

D1 D2 . . . DR

Consumers

Figure 3: With Alliance

U1 U2. . . UF

D1 D2 . . . DR

ConsumersShed light on 3 economic forces generated by buyer alliances:

I Status quo effect (Caprice and Rey, 2015, EJ):Deteriorate manufacturers’ status quo payoffs in negotiations.

I Nondiscrimination effect (O’Brien, 2014, RAND):Impact concessions costs of firms to the detriment of retailers.

Harsanyi (1977)’s joint-bargaining paradox?I Bargaining ability effect: Grennan (2013, AER; 2014, MS), Lewis and

Pflum (2015, AEJ: Econ. Policy), Grennan and Swanson (2019, JPE).

The global effect of buyer alliances is an empirical question!Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 4 / 35

Page 10: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

ContributionsFigure 2: Without Alliance

U1 U2. . . UF

D1 D2 . . . DR

Consumers

Figure 3: With Alliance

U1 U2. . . UF

D1 D2 . . . DR

ConsumersShed light on 3 economic forces generated by buyer alliances:

I Status quo effect (Caprice and Rey, 2015, EJ):Deteriorate manufacturers’ status quo payoffs in negotiations.

I Nondiscrimination effect (O’Brien, 2014, RAND):Impact concessions costs of firms to the detriment of retailers.

Harsanyi (1977)’s joint-bargaining paradox?I Bargaining ability effect: Grennan (2013, AER; 2014, MS), Lewis and

Pflum (2015, AEJ: Econ. Policy), Grennan and Swanson (2019, JPE).

The global effect of buyer alliances is an empirical question!Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 4 / 35

Page 11: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

ContributionsFigure 2: Without Alliance

U1 U2. . . UF

D1 D2 . . . DR

Consumers

Figure 3: With Alliance

U1 U2. . . UF

D1 D2 . . . DR

ConsumersShed light on 3 economic forces generated by buyer alliances:

I Status quo effect (Caprice and Rey, 2015, EJ):Deteriorate manufacturers’ status quo payoffs in negotiations.

I Nondiscrimination effect (O’Brien, 2014, RAND):Impact concessions costs of firms to the detriment of retailers.

Harsanyi (1977)’s joint-bargaining paradox?I Bargaining ability effect: Grennan (2013, AER; 2014, MS), Lewis and

Pflum (2015, AEJ: Econ. Policy), Grennan and Swanson (2019, JPE).

The global effect of buyer alliances is an empirical question!Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 4 / 35

Page 12: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

ContributionsFigure 2: Without Alliance

U1 U2. . . UF

D1 D2 . . . DR

Consumers

Figure 3: With Alliance

U1 U2. . . UF

D1 D2 . . . DR

ConsumersShed light on 3 economic forces generated by buyer alliances:

I Status quo effect (Caprice and Rey, 2015, EJ):Deteriorate manufacturers’ status quo payoffs in negotiations.

I Nondiscrimination effect (O’Brien, 2014, RAND):Impact concessions costs of firms to the detriment of retailers.

Harsanyi (1977)’s joint-bargaining paradox?I Bargaining ability effect: Grennan (2013, AER; 2014, MS), Lewis and

Pflum (2015, AEJ: Econ. Policy), Grennan and Swanson (2019, JPE).

The global effect of buyer alliances is an empirical question!Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 4 / 35

Page 13: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

ContributionsFigure 2: Without Alliance

U1 U2. . . UF

D1 D2 . . . DR

Consumers

Figure 3: With Alliance

U1 U2. . . UF

D1 D2 . . . DR

ConsumersShed light on 3 economic forces generated by buyer alliances:

I Status quo effect (Caprice and Rey, 2015, EJ):Deteriorate manufacturers’ status quo payoffs in negotiations.

I Nondiscrimination effect (O’Brien, 2014, RAND):Impact concessions costs of firms to the detriment of retailers.

Harsanyi (1977)’s joint-bargaining paradox?I Bargaining ability effect: Grennan (2013, AER; 2014, MS), Lewis and

Pflum (2015, AEJ: Econ. Policy), Grennan and Swanson (2019, JPE).

The global effect of buyer alliances is an empirical question!Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 4 / 35

Page 14: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

Contributions

Use a structural model of demand and supply to estimate the bar-gaining power of firms before and after the formation of 3 buyer

alliances that occured on the French bottled water industry in 2014.

Perform counterfactual scenarios to gain further insights on theeconomic forces generated by buyer alliances.

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 5 / 35

Page 15: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

Contributions

Use a structural model of demand and supply to estimate the bar-gaining power of firms before and after the formation of 3 buyer

alliances that occured on the French bottled water industry in 2014.

Perform counterfactual scenarios to gain further insights on theeconomic forces generated by buyer alliances.

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 5 / 35

Page 16: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

Relation to literature

Buyer power in vertically related markets.

I Retail concentration: Dobson and Waterson (1997, EJ), Iozzi and Val-letti (2014, AEJ: micro), Gaudin (2017, EJ).

I Buyer Alliances: Sorensen (2003, J Ind Econ), Inderst and Shaffer(2007, EJ), Ellison and Snyder (2010, J Ind Econ), Dana (2012, GEB),Caprice and Rey (2015, EJ).

Structural models of buyer-seller bargaining (in a given network).

Crawford and Yurukoglu (2012, AER), Grennan (2013, AER), Lewisand Pflum (2015, AEJ: Econ Policy), Gowrisankaran, Nevo and Town(2015, AER), Ho and Lee (2017, ECMTA).

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 6 / 35

Page 17: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

Outline

1 Buyer alliances background & Data

2 Demand modelMultinomial logit modelIdentification and estimation of consumer demandDemand results

3 Supply modelStage 2: Downstream price competitionStage 1: Manufacturer-retailer bargainingIdentification and estimation of bargaining stageSupply results

4 Counterfactuals

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 7 / 35

Page 18: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

Buyer alliances in the French food retail sector

Producers

Carrefour

(21.8%)

Cora

(3.3%)

Auchan

(11.3%)

SystemeU

(10.3%)

ITM

(14.4%)

Casino

(11.5%)

Leclerc

(19.9%)

HD

(6.9%)

ConsumersMarket shares in parenthesis (source: Autorite de la concurrence, 2015).

In 2014, three buyer alliances have been formed to negotiate wholesaleprices of national brands (excluding fresh products and private labels)Details

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 8 / 35

Page 19: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

French bottled water market: Micro data

I use household-level scanner data on bottled water purchases

(550,059 purchases) in France collected by KANTAR WorldPanel overthe year 2013 and 2015 (from March to December).

I consider purchases of bottled water at8 retailers: Carrefour, Leclerc,ITM, Auchan, Systeme U, Casino, Cora, and an aggregate of harddiscounters.

I select the 11 biggest national brands according to the number ofpurchases in the sample plus all private labels (store brands).

Market definition: All purchases of bottled water for home con-sumption in France within a month (20 markets).

I define a product as a brand-retailer combination: 111 differenti-ated products.

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 9 / 35

Page 20: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

French bottled water market: Micro data

I use household-level scanner data on bottled water purchases

(550,059 purchases) in France collected by KANTAR WorldPanel overthe year 2013 and 2015 (from March to December).

I consider purchases of bottled water at8 retailers: Carrefour, Leclerc,ITM, Auchan, Systeme U, Casino, Cora, and an aggregate of harddiscounters.

I select the 11 biggest national brands according to the number ofpurchases in the sample plus all private labels (store brands).

Market definition: All purchases of bottled water for home con-sumption in France within a month (20 markets).

I define a product as a brand-retailer combination: 111 differenti-ated products.

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 9 / 35

Page 21: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

French bottled water market: Micro data

I use household-level scanner data on bottled water purchases

(550,059 purchases) in France collected by KANTAR WorldPanel overthe year 2013 and 2015 (from March to December).

I consider purchases of bottled water at8 retailers: Carrefour, Leclerc,ITM, Auchan, Systeme U, Casino, Cora, and an aggregate of harddiscounters.

I select the 11 biggest national brands according to the number ofpurchases in the sample plus all private labels (store brands).

Market definition: All purchases of bottled water for home con-sumption in France within a month (20 markets).

I define a product as a brand-retailer combination: 111 differenti-ated products.

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 9 / 35

Page 22: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

French bottled water market: Micro data

I use household-level scanner data on bottled water purchases

(550,059 purchases) in France collected by KANTAR WorldPanel overthe year 2013 and 2015 (from March to December).

I consider purchases of bottled water at8 retailers: Carrefour, Leclerc,ITM, Auchan, Systeme U, Casino, Cora, and an aggregate of harddiscounters.

I select the 11 biggest national brands according to the number ofpurchases in the sample plus all private labels (store brands).

Market definition: All purchases of bottled water for home con-sumption in France within a month (20 markets).

I define a product as a brand-retailer combination: 111 differenti-ated products.

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 9 / 35

Page 23: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

French bottled water market: Micro data

I use household-level scanner data on bottled water purchases

(550,059 purchases) in France collected by KANTAR WorldPanel overthe year 2013 and 2015 (from March to December).

I consider purchases of bottled water at8 retailers: Carrefour, Leclerc,ITM, Auchan, Systeme U, Casino, Cora, and an aggregate of harddiscounters.

I select the 11 biggest national brands according to the number ofpurchases in the sample plus all private labels (store brands).

Market definition: All purchases of bottled water for home con-sumption in France within a month (20 markets).

I define a product as a brand-retailer combination: 111 differenti-ated products.

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 9 / 35

Page 24: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

French bottled water market: Micro data

Table 1: Descriptive statistics by firms (pre-alliances)

Market shares (%) Retail prices (e/liter)mean s.d. mean s.d.

ManufacturersManufacturer 1 15.74 1.07 0.52 0.02Manufacturer 2 10.87 0.42 0.45 0.02Manufacturer 3 13.08 0.76 0.15 0.00Private labels 23.41 0.53 0.22 0.00

RetailersRetailer 1 14.84 0.37 0.34 0.01Retailer 2 1.79 0.16 0.33 0.02Retailer 3 7.32 0.42 0.33 0.01Retailer 4 4.95 0.21 0.37 0.01Retailer 5 9.04 0.81 0.33 0.01Retailer 6 4.61 0.19 0.36 0.01Retailer 7 14.46 0.65 0.30 0.01Retailer 8 6.10 0.09 0.19 0.01

Outside good 37.09 1.41

Notes: Standard deviation refers to variation across markets for the year 2013 (pre-alliances).

Brands

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 10 / 35

Page 25: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

Market structure in 2013 (pre-alliances)

Manuf.1

(15.74%)

Manuf.2

(10.87%)

Manuf.3

(13.08%)

PrivateLabels

(23.41%)

Retailer1

(14.84%)

Retailer2

(1.79%)

Retailer3

(7.32%)

Retailer4

(4.95%)

Retailer5

(9.04%)

Retailer6

(4.61%)

Retailer7

(14.46%)

Retailer8

(6.10%)

Consumers

Notes: Market shares in parenthesis.

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 11 / 35

Page 26: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

Market structure in 2015 (post-alliances)

Manuf.1

(16.75%)

Manuf.2

(10.56%)

Manuf.3

(14.68%)

PrivateLabels

(21.34%)

Retailer1

(14.22%)

Retailer2

(1.88%)

Retailer3

(7.21%)

Retailer4

(5.99%)

Retailer5

(8.97%)

Retailer6

(4.77%)

Retailer7

(15.17%)

Retailer8

(6.19%)

Consumers

Notes: Market shares in parenthesis.

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 12 / 35

Page 27: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

Descriptive retail price analysis

Figure 4: Average retail price trend

Weighted Log Alternative

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 13 / 35

Page 28: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

Descriptive retail price analysis

In line with the literature on retrospective merger analysis (e.g.,Ashenfelter and Hosken, 2010, JLawEcon):

log(pj ,t ) = β11{post-alliances}t ×1{national brand}j ,t ×1{alliance}j ,t+ β21{post-alliances}t + βj + βmonth(t)+uj ,t

Table 2: Changes in retail prices

Parameters Value S.E. ∆ retail price CI

β1 −0.056∗ 0.008 -5.40% [-6.88% ; -3.92%]β2 −0.026∗ 0.006βj (not shown)βmonth(t) (not shown)

R2 adjust. 0.994Nb. of observations 2,192

Notes: OLS estimates. ∗ indicates significance at the 5% level. Heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors. 95%confidence intervals computed using the delta method.

Price Common trend Weight

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 14 / 35

Page 29: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

Outline

1 Buyer alliances background & Data

2 Demand modelMultinomial logit modelIdentification and estimation of consumer demandDemand results

3 Supply modelStage 2: Downstream price competitionStage 1: Manufacturer-retailer bargainingIdentification and estimation of bargaining stageSupply results

4 Counterfactuals

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 15 / 35

Page 30: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

Multinomial logit model

Each consumer in the sample chooses among Jt + 1 alternativesindexed from j ∈ {0, . . . ,Jt }= Jt at each shopping trip.

The utility that consumer i obtains from purchasing product j ∈ Jt\{0}in market t is specified as follows:

Ui ,j ,t = β0+βb(j)+βr(j)+βt +φxspark(j) +ψixminer(j) −αipj ,t +ξj ,t +ei ,j ,t

where ψi = ψ+ψg(agei ) and αi = α+αg(yi ) .

Outside good: Ui ,0,t = ei ,0,t .

ei ,j ,t is i.i.d. from the standard Gumbel distribution. The probabilitythat consumer i selects product j ∈ Jt in market t is:

si ,j ,t =exp(β0 + βb(j)+ βr(j)+ βt +φxspark(j) +ψi xminer(j) −αipj ,t + ξj ,t )

1+Jt∑

k=1exp(β0 + βb(k)+ βr(k)+ βt +φxspark(k) +ψi xminer(k) −αipk ,t + ξk ,t )

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 16 / 35

Page 31: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

Multinomial logit model

Each consumer in the sample chooses among Jt + 1 alternativesindexed from j ∈ {0, . . . ,Jt }= Jt at each shopping trip.

The utility that consumer i obtains from purchasing product j ∈ Jt\{0}in market t is specified as follows:

Ui ,j ,t = β0+βb(j)+βr(j)+βt +φxspark(j) +ψixminer(j) −αipj ,t +ξj ,t +ei ,j ,t

where ψi = ψ+ψg(agei ) and αi = α+αg(yi ) .

Outside good: Ui ,0,t = ei ,0,t .

ei ,j ,t is i.i.d. from the standard Gumbel distribution. The probabilitythat consumer i selects product j ∈ Jt in market t is:

si ,j ,t =exp(β0 + βb(j)+ βr(j)+ βt +φxspark(j) +ψi xminer(j) −αipj ,t + ξj ,t )

1+Jt∑

k=1exp(β0 + βb(k)+ βr(k)+ βt +φxspark(k) +ψi xminer(k) −αipk ,t + ξk ,t )

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 16 / 35

Page 32: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

Multinomial logit model

Each consumer in the sample chooses among Jt + 1 alternativesindexed from j ∈ {0, . . . ,Jt }= Jt at each shopping trip.

The utility that consumer i obtains from purchasing product j ∈ Jt\{0}in market t is specified as follows:

Ui ,j ,t = β0+βb(j)+βr(j)+βt +φxspark(j) +ψixminer(j) −αipj ,t +ξj ,t +ei ,j ,t

where ψi = ψ+ψg(agei ) and αi = α+αg(yi ) .

Outside good: Ui ,0,t = ei ,0,t .

ei ,j ,t is i.i.d. from the standard Gumbel distribution. The probabilitythat consumer i selects product j ∈ Jt in market t is:

si ,j ,t =exp(β0 + βb(j)+ βr(j)+ βt +φxspark(j) +ψi xminer(j) −αipj ,t + ξj ,t )

1+Jt∑

k=1exp(β0 + βb(k)+ βr(k)+ βt +φxspark(k) +ψi xminer(k) −αipk ,t + ξk ,t )

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 16 / 35

Page 33: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

Identification and estimation of consumer demand

Retail price endogeneity: 2-step procedure of Berry, Levinsohn andPakes (2004, JPE), also called BLP-micro.

1 GMM with a nested fixed point algorithm: Moments

Define δj ,t = β0 + βb(j)+ βr(j)+ βt +φxspark(j) +ψxminer(j) −αpj ,t + ξj ,t .Estimate δ= (δ1,1, . . . ,δJ ,T )

> and θd2 = (ψ2,ψ3,α2,α3,α4)> by GMM:

minθd

2

gd (δ(θd2),θ

d2)>A−1gd (δ(θd2),θ

d2)

where gd ,(l) = 1I

T∑t=1

It∑i=1

Jt∑j=1

(1i ,j ,t − si ,j ,t (δt ,θd2)

)X (l)j ,tDi and δ is ”concentrated

out” of the objective function (Berry, Levinsohn and Pakes, 1995, ECMTA).

2 TSLS: δj ,t(θd2) = β0+βb(j)+βr(j)+βt+φxspark(j)+ψxminer(j) −αpj ,t+ξj ,t

2 instrumental variables Zd that shift supply but not demand for bottled water:I BLP-type: number of products sold by rival retailers (shift markup).I Exogenous shifter of the competitive environment (Berry and Haile, 2014,

ECMTA): 1{post-alliances}t ×1{national brand}j ,t ×1{alliance}j ,t(see also Miller and Weinberg, 2017, ECMTA).

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 17 / 35

Page 34: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

Identification and estimation of consumer demand

Retail price endogeneity: 2-step procedure of Berry, Levinsohn andPakes (2004, JPE), also called BLP-micro.

1 GMM with a nested fixed point algorithm: Moments

Define δj ,t = β0 + βb(j)+ βr(j)+ βt +φxspark(j) +ψxminer(j) −αpj ,t + ξj ,t .Estimate δ= (δ1,1, . . . ,δJ ,T )

> and θd2 = (ψ2,ψ3,α2,α3,α4)> by GMM:

minθd

2

gd (δ(θd2),θ

d2)>A−1gd (δ(θd2),θ

d2)

where gd ,(l) = 1I

T∑t=1

It∑i=1

Jt∑j=1

(1i ,j ,t − si ,j ,t (δt ,θd2)

)X (l)j ,tDi and δ is ”concentrated

out” of the objective function (Berry, Levinsohn and Pakes, 1995, ECMTA).

2 TSLS: δj ,t(θd2) = β0+βb(j)+βr(j)+βt+φxspark(j)+ψxminer(j) −αpj ,t+ξj ,t

2 instrumental variables Zd that shift supply but not demand for bottled water:I BLP-type: number of products sold by rival retailers (shift markup).I Exogenous shifter of the competitive environment (Berry and Haile, 2014,

ECMTA): 1{post-alliances}t ×1{national brand}j ,t ×1{alliance}j ,t(see also Miller and Weinberg, 2017, ECMTA).

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 17 / 35

Page 35: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

Identification and estimation of consumer demand

Retail price endogeneity: 2-step procedure of Berry, Levinsohn andPakes (2004, JPE), also called BLP-micro.

1 GMM with a nested fixed point algorithm: Moments

Define δj ,t = β0 + βb(j)+ βr(j)+ βt +φxspark(j) +ψxminer(j) −αpj ,t + ξj ,t .Estimate δ= (δ1,1, . . . ,δJ ,T )

> and θd2 = (ψ2,ψ3,α2,α3,α4)> by GMM:

minθd

2

gd (δ(θd2),θ

d2)>A−1gd (δ(θd2),θ

d2)

where gd ,(l) = 1I

T∑t=1

It∑i=1

Jt∑j=1

(1i ,j ,t − si ,j ,t (δt ,θd2)

)X (l)j ,tDi and δ is ”concentrated

out” of the objective function (Berry, Levinsohn and Pakes, 1995, ECMTA).

2 TSLS: δj ,t(θd2) = β0+βb(j)+βr(j)+βt+φxspark(j)+ψxminer(j) −αpj ,t+ξj ,t

2 instrumental variables Zd that shift supply but not demand for bottled water:I BLP-type: number of products sold by rival retailers (shift markup).I Exogenous shifter of the competitive environment (Berry and Haile, 2014,

ECMTA): 1{post-alliances}t ×1{national brand}j ,t ×1{alliance}j ,t(see also Miller and Weinberg, 2017, ECMTA).

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 17 / 35

Page 36: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

Demand results

Table 3: Estimates of consumer demand

(a) Preference heterogeneity

Parameters (θd2 ) Value S.E.

α2: yi ∈ [900;1,899[ −0.09∗ 0.02α3: yi ∈ [1,900;4,449[ −0.21∗ 0.01α4: yi > 4,449 −0.26∗ 0.02

ψ2: agei ∈ [40;60] 0.39∗ 0.01ψ3: agei > 60 0.70∗ 0.01

Nb. of observations 550,059

Notes: GMM estimates. ∗ indicates significance at the5% level. Heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors.

(b) Mean preferences

Parameters (θd1 ) Value S.E.

β0 −2.48∗ 0.50α (retail price) 15.37∗ 3.12ψ (mineral) 0.64∗ 0.23φ (sparkling) −0.23 0.20

βb(j) (not shown)

βr(j) (not shown)

βt (not shown)

Feff 20.73Nb. of observations 2,192

Notes: TSLS estimates. ∗ indicates significance at the5% level. Heteroskedasticity-robust standard errorsuncorrected for the sampling error in market sharesto estimate δ. Feff indicates the robust F-stat of Mon-tiel Olea and Pflueger (2013, JBES).

1st stage

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 18 / 35

Page 37: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

Elasticity of demand

Table 4: Estimates of own-price elasticity of demand

Types of water Value

Total -4.66

Still spring water -2.24Sparkling spring water -3.73Still mineral water -5.34Sparkling mineral water -7.72

Notes: Average own-price elasticity of products arecalculated using quantity weights.

Results for spring water products and mineral water products are inline with Bonnet and Dubois (2015) who find respectively -3.09 and-6.70. Density

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 19 / 35

Page 38: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

Outline

1 Buyer alliances background & Data

2 Demand modelMultinomial logit modelIdentification and estimation of consumer demandDemand results

3 Supply modelStage 2: Downstream price competitionStage 1: Manufacturer-retailer bargainingIdentification and estimation of bargaining stageSupply results

4 Counterfactuals

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 20 / 35

Page 39: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

Bilateral oligopoly setting

Timing and information:I Stage 1: Manufacturers and retailers engage simultaneously andsecretly in bilateral bargains to determine wholesale prices of eachproduct j ∈ Jt\{0}.

I Stage 2: Retailers compete in prices on the downstream market withinterim unobservability (Rey and Verge, 2004, RAND).

I assume complete information about the cost of production anddistribution of each product j ∈ Jt\{0}.

Bargaining protocol: I use the ”Nash-in-Nash” bargaining solution(Horn and Wolinsky, 1988, RAND) to determine the division of sur-plus between up- and downstream firms. Details

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 21 / 35

Page 40: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

Stage 2: Downstream price competition

In each market t , retail prices are determined in a pure-strategy

Nash equilibrium. Retailer r solves the following maximization prob-lem

max{pj ,t }j∈Jr ,t

πr ,t ≡∑j∈Jr ,t

(pj ,t −wj ,t − cj ,t

)Mt sj ,t(pr ,t ,p

∗−r ,t ;δt ,θ

d2)

The first-order condition w.r.t k ∈ Jr ,t

sk ,t (pr ,t ,p∗−r ,t ;δt ,θ

d2)+

∑j∈Jr ,t

(pj ,t −wj ,t − cj ,t

) ∂sj ,t∂pk ,t

(pr ,t ,p∗−r ,t ;δt ,θ

d2) = 0

∀k ∈ Jr ,t , I obtain the vector of price-cost margins of retailer r inmarket t

γ∗r ,t ≡ p∗r ,t −w∗r ,t − cr ,t = −

(IrSpt

Ir

)+Ir sss t

and retailer r’s marginal costs: w∗r ,t + cr ,t = p∗r ,t −γ∗r ,t .Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 22 / 35

Page 41: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

Stage 1: Manufacturer-retailer bargaining

Pre-alliances:

Negotiation between manufacturer f and retailer r over wj ,t :

maxwj ,t

(πf ,t −d

−jf ,t

)λpref ,r

(πr ,t −d

−jr ,t

)1−λpref ,r Details

First-order condition and sources of bargaining power:(1−λpre

f ,r

)︸ ︷︷ ︸r’s bargaining

weight

(πf ,t −d

−jf ,t

)︸ ︷︷ ︸

f ’s gainsfrom trade

∂πr ,t∂wj ,t︸︷︷︸

r’s concessioncost︸ ︷︷ ︸

r’s bargaining power

+ λpref ,r︸︷︷︸

f ’s bargainingweight

(πr ,t −d

−jr ,t

)︸ ︷︷ ︸

r’s gainsfrom trade

∂πf ,t∂wj ,t︸︷︷︸

f ’s concessioncost︸ ︷︷ ︸

f ’s bargaining power

= 0

Post-alliances:

Negotiation between manufacturer f and retailers’ alliance a(j) over

wa(j),b(j),t : maxwa(j),b(j),t

(πf ,t −d

−a(j),b(j)f ,t

)1−λpostf ,a(j)

(πa(j),t −d

−a(j),b(j)a(j),t

)λpostf ,a(j) Details

First-order condition:(1−λpost

f ,a(j)

)(πf ,t −d

−a(j),b(j)f ,t

) ∂πa(j),t∂wa(j),b(j),t

+λpostf ,a(j)

(πa(j),t −d

−a(j),b(j)a(j),t

) ∂πf ,t∂wa(j),b(j),t

= 0

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 23 / 35

Page 42: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

Stage 1: Manufacturer-retailer bargaining

Pre-alliances:

Negotiation between manufacturer f and retailer r over wj ,t :

maxwj ,t

(πf ,t −d

−jf ,t

)λpref ,r

(πr ,t −d

−jr ,t

)1−λpref ,r Details

First-order condition and sources of bargaining power:(1−λpre

f ,r

)︸ ︷︷ ︸r’s bargaining

weight

(πf ,t −d

−jf ,t

)︸ ︷︷ ︸

f ’s gainsfrom trade

∂πr ,t∂wj ,t︸︷︷︸

r’s concessioncost︸ ︷︷ ︸

r’s bargaining power

+ λpref ,r︸︷︷︸

f ’s bargainingweight

(πr ,t −d

−jr ,t

)︸ ︷︷ ︸

r’s gainsfrom trade

∂πf ,t∂wj ,t︸︷︷︸

f ’s concessioncost︸ ︷︷ ︸

f ’s bargaining power

= 0

Post-alliances:

Negotiation between manufacturer f and retailers’ alliance a(j) over

wa(j),b(j),t : maxwa(j),b(j),t

(πf ,t −d

−a(j),b(j)f ,t

)1−λpostf ,a(j)

(πa(j),t −d

−a(j),b(j)a(j),t

)λpostf ,a(j) Details

First-order condition:(1−λpost

f ,a(j)

)(πf ,t −d

−a(j),b(j)f ,t

) ∂πa(j),t∂wa(j),b(j),t

+λpostf ,a(j)

(πa(j),t −d

−a(j),b(j)a(j),t

) ∂πf ,t∂wa(j),b(j),t

= 0

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 23 / 35

Page 43: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

Stage 1: Manufacturer-retailer bargaining

Pre-alliances:

Negotiation between manufacturer f and retailer r over wj ,t :

maxwj ,t

(πf ,t −d

−jf ,t

)λpref ,r

(πr ,t −d

−jr ,t

)1−λpref ,r Details

First-order condition and sources of bargaining power:(1−λpre

f ,r

)︸ ︷︷ ︸r’s bargaining

weight

(πf ,t −d

−jf ,t

)︸ ︷︷ ︸

f ’s gainsfrom trade

∂πr ,t∂wj ,t︸︷︷︸

r’s concessioncost︸ ︷︷ ︸

r’s bargaining power

+ λpref ,r︸︷︷︸

f ’s bargainingweight

(πr ,t −d

−jr ,t

)︸ ︷︷ ︸

r’s gainsfrom trade

∂πf ,t∂wj ,t︸︷︷︸

f ’s concessioncost︸ ︷︷ ︸

f ’s bargaining power

= 0

Post-alliances:

Negotiation between manufacturer f and retailers’ alliance a(j) over

wa(j),b(j),t : maxwa(j),b(j),t

(πf ,t −d

−a(j),b(j)f ,t

)1−λpostf ,a(j)

(πa(j),t −d

−a(j),b(j)a(j),t

)λpostf ,a(j) Details

First-order condition:(1−λpost

f ,a(j)

)(πf ,t −d

−a(j),b(j)f ,t

) ∂πa(j),t∂wa(j),b(j),t

+λpostf ,a(j)

(πa(j),t −d

−a(j),b(j)a(j),t

) ∂πf ,t∂wa(j),b(j),t

= 0

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 23 / 35

Page 44: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

Stage 1: Manufacturer-retailer bargaining

From the first-order conditions of each Nash bargaining problem in-volving manufacturer f , it is possible to formulate its price-cost mar-

gins in vector-matrix form Details

w∗f ,t −µf ,t = Γ

pref ,t (sss t ;λ

pre)×1{pre-alliance}t+ Γ

postf ,t (sss t ;λ

post)×1{post-alliance}t

where λpre and λpost are two Jt -dimensional vectors withλpre[j ,1] = λpre

f ,r if j ∈ Jf ,t ∩Jr ,t and λpost[j ,1] = λpostf ,a(j) if j ∈ Jf ,t ∩Ja(j),t .

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 24 / 35

Page 45: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

Identification and estimation of bargaining stage

To estimate λpre and λpost, exploit the variation in retailers’ marginal

costs for each product recovered in stage 2 (wj ,t + cj ,t = pjt −γj ,t ).Decompose retailers’ marginal costs as follows

wj ,t + cj ,t = (wj ,t −µj ,t)︸ ︷︷ ︸upstream market power

+ (cj ,t +µj ,t)︸ ︷︷ ︸operational costs

wj ,t − µj ,t has an expression implied by the FOC of the ”Nash-in-

Nash” bargaining model (pre- and post-alliances).

Total marginal cost specification:cjt +µj ,t = κ0 +κb(j)+κt +κmxminer(j) +κsxspark(j) +ωj ,t

(e.g., Gowrisankaran, Nevo and Town, 2015, AER)

Supply-side equation:

wt + ct = Γ pre(sss t ;λpre)×1{pre-al.}t + Γ post(sss t ;λ

post)×1{post-al.}t+ vtκ+ωt

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 25 / 35

Page 46: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

Identification and estimation of bargaining stage

To estimate λpre and λpost, exploit the variation in retailers’ marginal

costs for each product recovered in stage 2 (wj ,t + cj ,t = pjt −γj ,t ).Decompose retailers’ marginal costs as follows

wj ,t + cj ,t = (wj ,t −µj ,t)︸ ︷︷ ︸upstream market power

+ (cj ,t +µj ,t)︸ ︷︷ ︸operational costs

wj ,t − µj ,t has an expression implied by the FOC of the ”Nash-in-

Nash” bargaining model (pre- and post-alliances).

Total marginal cost specification:cjt +µj ,t = κ0 +κb(j)+κt +κmxminer(j) +κsxspark(j) +ωj ,t

(e.g., Gowrisankaran, Nevo and Town, 2015, AER)

Supply-side equation:

wt + ct = Γ pre(sss t ;λpre)×1{pre-al.}t + Γ post(sss t ;λ

post)×1{post-al.}t+ vtκ+ωt

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 25 / 35

Page 47: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

Identification and estimation of bargaining stage

To estimate λpre and λpost, exploit the variation in retailers’ marginal

costs for each product recovered in stage 2 (wj ,t + cj ,t = pjt −γj ,t ).Decompose retailers’ marginal costs as follows

wj ,t + cj ,t = (wj ,t −µj ,t)︸ ︷︷ ︸upstream market power

+ (cj ,t +µj ,t)︸ ︷︷ ︸operational costs

wj ,t − µj ,t has an expression implied by the FOC of the ”Nash-in-

Nash” bargaining model (pre- and post-alliances).

Total marginal cost specification:cjt +µj ,t = κ0 +κb(j)+κt +κmxminer(j) +κsxspark(j) +ωj ,t

(e.g., Gowrisankaran, Nevo and Town, 2015, AER)

Supply-side equation:

wt + ct = Γ pre(sss t ;λpre)×1{pre-al.}t + Γ post(sss t ;λ

post)×1{post-al.}t+ vtκ+ωt

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 25 / 35

Page 48: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

Identification and estimation of bargaining stage

To estimate λpre and λpost, exploit the variation in retailers’ marginal

costs for each product recovered in stage 2 (wj ,t + cj ,t = pjt −γj ,t ).Decompose retailers’ marginal costs as follows

wj ,t + cj ,t = (wj ,t −µj ,t)︸ ︷︷ ︸upstream market power

+ (cj ,t +µj ,t)︸ ︷︷ ︸operational costs

wj ,t − µj ,t has an expression implied by the FOC of the ”Nash-in-

Nash” bargaining model (pre- and post-alliances).

Total marginal cost specification:cjt +µj ,t = κ0 +κb(j)+κt +κmxminer(j) +κsxspark(j) +ωj ,t

(e.g., Gowrisankaran, Nevo and Town, 2015, AER)

Supply-side equation:

wt + ct = Γ pre(sss t ;λpre)×1{pre-al.}t + Γ post(sss t ;λ

post)×1{post-al.}t+ vtκ+ωt

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 25 / 35

Page 49: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

Identification and estimation of bargaining stage

wt + ct = Γ pre(sss t ;λpre)×1{pre-al.}t + Γ post(sss t ;λ

post)×1{post-al.}t︸ ︷︷ ︸upstream market power

+ vtκ+ωt︸ ︷︷ ︸operational costs

Endogeneity problem: correlation of sj ,t with ωj ,t .

Reduce the number of bargaining parameters to 6 instead of 24.Retailers not in any alliance: λpre

na = λpostna = λna (R7, R8).

Retailers in an alliance:I with high market shares and low retail costs: λpre

1 (R1, R3, R5),I with low market shares and high retail costs: λpre

2 (R2, R4, R6),I λpost

a for each alliance a (R1-R2, R3-R4, R4-R6).

8 instrumental variables for the endogenous market shares sj ,t :I 1{post-alliances}t×1{national brand}j ,t×1{alliance}j ,t (Miller and Wein-

berg, 2017, ECMTA),I 1{post-alliances}t ×1{national brand}j ,t ×1{no alliance}j ,t ,I nb. of rival products in each bottled water segment (mineral, sparkling),

interacted with a dummy for each type of retailers list .Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 26 / 35

Page 50: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

Identification and estimation of bargaining stage

wt + ct = Γ pre(sss t ;λpre)×1{pre-al.}t + Γ post(sss t ;λ

post)×1{post-al.}t︸ ︷︷ ︸upstream market power

+ vtκ+ωt︸ ︷︷ ︸operational costs

Endogeneity problem: correlation of sj ,t with ωj ,t .

Reduce the number of bargaining parameters to 6 instead of 24.Retailers not in any alliance: λpre

na = λpostna = λna (R7, R8).

Retailers in an alliance:I with high market shares and low retail costs: λpre

1 (R1, R3, R5),I with low market shares and high retail costs: λpre

2 (R2, R4, R6),I λpost

a for each alliance a (R1-R2, R3-R4, R4-R6).

8 instrumental variables for the endogenous market shares sj ,t :I 1{post-alliances}t×1{national brand}j ,t×1{alliance}j ,t (Miller and Wein-

berg, 2017, ECMTA),I 1{post-alliances}t ×1{national brand}j ,t ×1{no alliance}j ,t ,I nb. of rival products in each bottled water segment (mineral, sparkling),

interacted with a dummy for each type of retailers list .Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 26 / 35

Page 51: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

Identification and estimation of bargaining stage

wt + ct = Γ pre(sss t ;λpre)×1{pre-al.}t + Γ post(sss t ;λ

post)×1{post-al.}t︸ ︷︷ ︸upstream market power

+ vtκ+ωt︸ ︷︷ ︸operational costs

Endogeneity problem: correlation of sj ,t with ωj ,t .

Reduce the number of bargaining parameters to 6 instead of 24.Retailers not in any alliance: λpre

na = λpostna = λna (R7, R8).

Retailers in an alliance:I with high market shares and low retail costs: λpre

1 (R1, R3, R5),I with low market shares and high retail costs: λpre

2 (R2, R4, R6),I λpost

a for each alliance a (R1-R2, R3-R4, R4-R6).

8 instrumental variables for the endogenous market shares sj ,t :I 1{post-alliances}t×1{national brand}j ,t×1{alliance}j ,t (Miller and Wein-

berg, 2017, ECMTA),I 1{post-alliances}t ×1{national brand}j ,t ×1{no alliance}j ,t ,I nb. of rival products in each bottled water segment (mineral, sparkling),

interacted with a dummy for each type of retailers list .Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 26 / 35

Page 52: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

Supply results

Table 5: Bargaining Estimates

Parameter Value S.E. CI

Bargaining parametersManufacturers vs. Retailers 1, 3, 5: λpre

1 0.541 0.058 [0.428 ; 0.651]

Manufacturers vs. Retailers 2, 4, 6: λpre2 0.731 0.061 [0.598 ; 0.833]

Manufacturers vs. Retailers 1, 2: λpost1 0.242 0.127 [0.076 ; 0.555]

Manufacturers vs. Retailers 3, 4: λpost2 0.380 0.067 [0.260 ; 0.517]

Manufacturers vs. Retailers 5, 6: λpost3 0.268 0.067 [0.158 ; 0.417]

Manufacturers vs. Retailers 7, 8: λna 0.000 0.003 [0 ; 1]

Cost parametersκ0 0.139 0.007κm (mineral) 0.066 0.005κs (sparkling) 0.048 0.005Brand fixed effect (not shown)Market fixed effect (not shown)

GMM objective function value 14.452Nb. of observations 2,192

Notes: Continuously updated GMM estimates. Heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors uncorrected for the

demand estimates. 95% confidence intervals. Weak instru.

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 27 / 35

Page 53: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

Supply results

Table 6: Margins, marginal costs, and surplus division

Alliance No Alliance Total

Pre Post Pre Post Pre Post

Price-cost margins:Retail margins: γ 29.40 30.51 39.28 40.80 32.62 33.81

Upstream margins: Γ 16.87 9.15 0.85 0.53 12.88 7.10

Marginal cost:Retail mc: w+ c 0.28 0.25 0.20 0.18 0.25 0.23

Total mc: c+µ 0.24 0.23 0.19 0.18 0.22 0.21

Division of surplus:Retailers’ share 62.48 76.74 97.27 98.43 68.86 81.18

Notes: Average price-cost margins in percentage of retail prices and average marginal costs are calculatedusing quantity weights. Average share captured by retailers in bilateral contracts.

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 28 / 35

Page 54: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

Outline

1 Buyer alliances background & Data

2 Demand modelMultinomial logit modelIdentification and estimation of consumer demandDemand results

3 Supply modelStage 2: Downstream price competitionStage 1: Manufacturer-retailer bargainingIdentification and estimation of bargaining stageSupply results

4 Counterfactuals

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 29 / 35

Page 55: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

Counterfactuals

I consider 4 counterfactual scenarios to further analyze the effects ofbuyer alliances:

I No buyer alliances: go

I Joint-bargaining paradox: go (nondiscrimination vs status quo)

I Status quo effect: go

I Bargaining ability effect: go

Conclusion

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 30 / 35

Page 56: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

Counterfactual 1: No buyer alliances

Figure 5: ”No buyer alliances” scenario

Notes: Counterfactual retail prices calculated using quantity weights. DiD Menu

Table 7: Results of the ”no buyer alliances” scenario

∆ Margins ∆ Profit

∆ Retail price Retailers Manuf. Retailers Manuf. Industry

Total 4.37% -0.39% 99.10% -5.46% 57.47% 2.96%

Notes: Percentage changes in retail prices and margins are calculated using quantity weights.

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 31 / 35

Page 57: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

Counterfactual 2: Joint-bargaining paradox (Harsanyi, 1977)Figure 6: Joint-bargaining paradox

Notes: Counterfactual retail prices calculated using quantity weights. Alliance Menu

Table 8: Joint-bargaining paradox

∆ Margins ∆ Profit

∆ Retail price Retailers Manuf. Retailers Manuf. Industry

Total 0.23% 0.05% 0.86% -0.04% -0.47% -0.13%

Notes: Percentage changes in retail prices and margins with respect to the ”no buyer alliance” sce-nario are calculated using quantity weights.

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 32 / 35

Page 58: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

Counterfactual 3: Status quo effectsFigure 7: Status quo effects

Notes: Counterfactual retail prices calculated using quantity weights Alliance Menu

Table 9: Status quo effects∆ Margins ∆ Profit

∆ Retail price Retailers Manuf. Retailers Manuf. Industry

Total -0.76% -0.06% -5.90% 0.96% -9.22% -1.12%

Notes: Percentage changes in retail prices and margins with respect to the ”no buyer alliance” scenarioare calculated using quantity weights.

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 33 / 35

Page 59: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

Counterfactual 4: Bargaining ability effectsFigure 8: Bargaining ability effect

Notes: Counterfactual retail prices calculated using quantity weights. Details Menu

Table 10: Bargaining ability effect∆ Margins ∆ Profit

∆ Retail price Retailers Manuf. Retailers Manuf. Industry

Total -4.25% -0.04% -34.41% 6.45% -60.75% -4.55%

Notes: Percentage changes in retail prices and margins with respect to the ”no buyer alliance” scenario arecalculated using quantity weights.

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 34 / 35

Page 60: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

Concluding remarks

I study the economic effects of buyer alliances formed by retailersto negotiate wholesale prices with manufacturers.

Using data on the French bottled water market, I find evidence thatbuyer alliances formed in 2014 generate a price decrease of:

I [−6.88%;−3.92%] for the concerned products using a diff-in-diff.I −7.97% for the concerned products using a structural model of bar-

gaining.

The bargaining ability effect plays an important role in this pricedecrease.

Although buyer alliances benefit retailers (+5.46%), they generatea drop in manufacturers’ profit by more than 50%, thereby destroy-

ing the total industry profit by 3%.

Welfare effect: TO BE COMPLETED.

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 35 / 35

Page 61: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

Concluding remarks

I study the economic effects of buyer alliances formed by retailersto negotiate wholesale prices with manufacturers.

Using data on the French bottled water market, I find evidence thatbuyer alliances formed in 2014 generate a price decrease of:

I [−6.88%;−3.92%] for the concerned products using a diff-in-diff.I −7.97% for the concerned products using a structural model of bar-

gaining.

The bargaining ability effect plays an important role in this pricedecrease.

Although buyer alliances benefit retailers (+5.46%), they generatea drop in manufacturers’ profit by more than 50%, thereby destroy-

ing the total industry profit by 3%.

Welfare effect: TO BE COMPLETED.

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 35 / 35

Page 62: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

Concluding remarks

I study the economic effects of buyer alliances formed by retailersto negotiate wholesale prices with manufacturers.

Using data on the French bottled water market, I find evidence thatbuyer alliances formed in 2014 generate a price decrease of:

I [−6.88%;−3.92%] for the concerned products using a diff-in-diff.I −7.97% for the concerned products using a structural model of bar-

gaining.

The bargaining ability effect plays an important role in this pricedecrease.

Although buyer alliances benefit retailers (+5.46%), they generatea drop in manufacturers’ profit by more than 50%, thereby destroy-

ing the total industry profit by 3%.

Welfare effect: TO BE COMPLETED.

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 35 / 35

Page 63: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

Concluding remarks

I study the economic effects of buyer alliances formed by retailersto negotiate wholesale prices with manufacturers.

Using data on the French bottled water market, I find evidence thatbuyer alliances formed in 2014 generate a price decrease of:

I [−6.88%;−3.92%] for the concerned products using a diff-in-diff.I −7.97% for the concerned products using a structural model of bar-

gaining.

The bargaining ability effect plays an important role in this pricedecrease.

Although buyer alliances benefit retailers (+5.46%), they generatea drop in manufacturers’ profit by more than 50%, thereby destroy-

ing the total industry profit by 3%.

Welfare effect: TO BE COMPLETED.

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 35 / 35

Page 64: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Introduction Buyer alliances background & Data Demand model Supply model Counterfactuals

Concluding remarks

I study the economic effects of buyer alliances formed by retailersto negotiate wholesale prices with manufacturers.

Using data on the French bottled water market, I find evidence thatbuyer alliances formed in 2014 generate a price decrease of:

I [−6.88%;−3.92%] for the concerned products using a diff-in-diff.I −7.97% for the concerned products using a structural model of bar-

gaining.

The bargaining ability effect plays an important role in this pricedecrease.

Although buyer alliances benefit retailers (+5.46%), they generatea drop in manufacturers’ profit by more than 50%, thereby destroy-

ing the total industry profit by 3%.

Welfare effect: TO BE COMPLETED.

Molina (2019) Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets 35 / 35

Page 65: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Autorite de la concurrence (2015):

”On 10 September 2014, Systeme U gave Auchan a mandate to nego-

tiate the purchase of products sold under national brands common tothe two retailers (around 300), excluding small enterprises and companiesproviding traditional fresh products (e.g., fruit and vegetables)”.

”On 7 November 2014, Intermarche and Casino entered into a coop-

eration agreement aimed at negotiating the purchase of some goods

under national brands (excluding retailers’ branded products and tradi-tional fresh products). [...] The two distributors set up a joint undertak-ing (INCAA) that negotiates exclusively with the suppliers covered by theagreement.”

”On 22 December 2014, Carrefour and Cora in turn entered into a part-

nership agreement, providing Cora with access to Carrefour’s listing of-fices. The cooperation agreement expressly excludes products from theagricultural sector, traditional fresh products and private label products.”

back

Page 66: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Table 11: Statistics by brands (before buyer alliances)

Market shares (%) Retail prices (e/liter)Mineral Sparkling mean s.d. mean s.d.

Types of waterType 1 No No 25.47 0.92 0.15 0.00Type 2 No Yes 0.67 0.06 0.26 0.01Type 3 Yes No 20.89 1.13 0.36 0.01Type 4 Yes Yes 16.10 1.06 0.52 0.01National brandsBrand 1 Yes Yes 4.49 0.65 0.71 0.03Brand 2 Yes No 3.47 0.28 0.36 0.02Brand 3 Yes No 3.22 0.30 0.53 0.02Brand 4 Yes No 3.36 0.33 0.31 0.02Brand 5 Yes Yes 1.50 0.36 0.73 0.04Brand 6 Yes No 3.47 0.24 0.41 0.01Brand 7 Yes No 2.56 0.35 0.32 0.01Brand 8 Yes Yes 2.53 0.18 0.41 0.01Brand 9 Yes Yes 2.40 0.28 0.70 0.03Brand 10 No No 11.61 0.66 0.13 0.00Brand 11 Yes No 1.48 0.15 0.31 0.01Private labelsPL 1 No No 13.88 0.51 0.18 0.00PL 2 No Yes 0.67 0.06 0.26 0.01PL 3 Yes No 3.54 0.19 0.27 0.01PL 4 Yes Yes 5.35 0.26 0.29 0.00

Notes: Standard deviation depicts variation across markets.

back

Page 67: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Figure 9: Average retail price trend

Notes: Average retail price weighted by the number of household purchases in the sample.back

Page 68: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Figure 10: Average (log) retail price trend

back

Page 69: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Figure 11: Average retail price trend

back

Page 70: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

The retail price of product j in market t is constructed as follows:

pj ,t =

∑i1i ,j ,tpi ,j ,tqi ,j ,t∑i1i ,j ,tqi ,j ,t

where 1i ,j ,t is an indicator equal to 1 if consumer i buys product j inmarket t and qi ,j ,t stands for the volume bought (in liter).

back

Page 71: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

log(pj ,t ) = βamonth(t) ×1{national brand}j ,t ×1{alliance}j ,t + βj + βmonth(t)+uj ,t

Table 12: Testing for retail price common trend (pre-alliances)

Variable Value S.E. p-value

βa1 −0.013 0.024 0.58

βa2 −0.010 0.025 0.68

βa3 −0.008 0.024 0.75

βa4 −0.012 0.022 0.59

βa5 −0.001 0.022 0.96

βa6 −0.019 0.023 0.41

βa7 −0.010 0.023 0.66

βa8 −0.022 0.025 0.37

βa9 −0.009 0.022 0.69

βj (not shown)βmonth(t) (not shown)

R2 adjusted 0.995Nb. of observations 1,097

Notes: OLS estimates. ∗ indicates significance at the 5%level. Heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors.

back

Page 72: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Table 13: Changes in retail prices

Parameters Value S.E. ∆ retail price CI

β1 −0.038∗ 0.000 -3.68% [-3.77% ; -3.59%]β2 −0.019∗ 0.000βj (not shown)βmonth(t) (not shown)

R2 adjust. 0.997Nb. of observations 2,192

Notes: OLS estimates with observations weighted by the number of household purchases. ∗ indicates significanceat the 5% level. Heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors. 95% confidence intervals computed using the deltamethod.

back

Page 73: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

First set of moments: system of market shares

Match the observed aggregated market shares of products with thosepredicted by the demand model

sj ,t − sj ,t(δt ,θd2) = 0 (1)

where δt = (δ1,t , . . . ,δJ ,t)> is a Jt -dimensional vector. Use the con-

traction procedure of Berry, Levinsohn and Pakes (1995, ECMTA) torecover δt .

Second set of moments: micro-moments

Defined L moments as follows

1I

T∑t=1

It∑i=1

Jt∑j=1

(1i ,j ,t − si ,j ,t(δt ,θd2)

)Xd ,(l)i ,j ,t = 0

back

Page 74: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Table 14: First-stage regression (TSLS)

Variable Value S.E.

Nb. products of rival retailers −0.004 0.0041{post-alliances}t ×1{national brand}j ,t×1{alliance}j ,t −0.025∗ 0.004

βb(j) (not shown)βr(j) (not shown)βt (not shown)

Feff 20.73R2 adjusted 0.986Nb. of observations 2,192

Notes: ∗ indicates significance at the 5% level. Feff is the robust F-stat ofMontiel Olea and Pflueger (2013, JBES). The critical value for testing thatthe TSLS bias exceeds 10% of the OLS bias is 6.363.

back

Page 75: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Figure 12: Own-price Elasticity of Demand

back

Page 76: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

”Nash-in-Nash” bargaining solution (Horn and Wolinsky, 1988, RAND;Collard-Wexler, Gowrisankaran and Lee, 2019, JPE).

Figure 13: Delegated agents model

R1

M1

R2

M2

w1 w2 w3 w4

back

Page 77: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Bilateral bargaining between manufacturer f and retailer r

over wj ,t (pre-alliances).

Agreement payoffs (pre-alliances).

πf ,t =(wj ,t −µj ,t

)Mt sj ,t (pr ,t (wj ,t ,w

∗−j ,t ),p

∗−r ,t ;δt ,θ

d2 )

+∑

k∈Jf ,t \{j }

(w∗k ,t −µk ,t

)Mt sk ,t (pr ,t (wj ,t ,w

∗−j ,t ),p

∗−r ,t ;δt ,θ

d2 )

πr ,t =(pj ,t (wj ,t ,w

∗−j ,t )−wj ,t − cj ,t

)Mt sj ,t (pr ,t (wj ,t ,w

∗−j ,t ),p

∗−r ,t ;δt ,θ

d2 )

+∑

k∈Jr ,t \{j }

(pk ,t (wj ,t ,w

∗−j ,t )−w

∗k ,t − ck ,t

)Mt sk ,t (pr ,t (wj ,t ,w

∗−j ,t ),p

∗−r ,t ;δt ,θ

d2 )

Status quo payoffs (pre-alliances).

d−jf ,t =∑

k∈Jf ,t \{j }

(w∗k ,t −µk ,t

)Mt s

−jk ,t (p

−jt ;δt ,θ

d2 )

d−jr ,t =∑

k∈Jr ,t \{j }

(p−jk ,t (w

∗−j ,t )−w

∗k ,t − ck ,t

)Mt s

−jk ,t (p

−jt ;δt ,θ

d2 )

with p−jt [k ,1] =

+∞ if k = j

p−jk ,t if j , k and j ,k ∈ Jr ,tp∗k ,t otherwise

back

Page 78: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Bilateral bargaining between manufacturer f and alliance a(j)

over wa(j),b(j),t (post-alliances).

Agreement payoffs (post-alliances).

πf ,t =∑

h∈Ja(j)∩Jb(j)

(wa(j),b(j),t −µh ,t

)Mt sh ,t (pa(j),t (wa(j),b(j),t,w

∗−a(j),b(j),t),p

∗−a(j),t) . . .

+∑

k∈Jf \Ja(j)∩Jb(j)

(w∗a(k),b(k),t −µk ,t

)Mt sk ,t (pa(j),t (wa(j),b(j),t,w

∗−a(j),b(j),t),p

∗−a(j),t)

πa(j),t =∑

h∈Ja(j)∩Jb(j)

(ph ,t (wa(j),b(j),t ,w

∗−a(j),b(j),t)−wa(j),b(j),t − ch ,t

)Mt sh ,t (pa(j),t (wa(j),b(j),t ,w

∗−a(j),b(j),t),p

∗−a(j),t ) . . .

+∑

k∈Ja(j)\Jb(j)

(pk ,t (wa(j),b(j),t ,w

∗−a(j),b(j),t)−w

∗a(j),b(k),t − ck ,t

)Mt sk ,t (pa(j),t (wa(j),b(j),t,w

∗−a(j),b(j),t),p

∗−a(j),t )

Status quo payoffs (post-alliances).

d−a(j),b(j)f ,t =

∑k∈Jf∩Ja(j)\Jb(j)

(w∗a(k),b(k),t −µk ,t

)Mt s−a(j),b(j)k ,t (p

−a(j),b(j)t )

d−a(j),b(j)a(j),t =

∑k∈Ja(j)\Jb(j)

(p−a(j),b(j)k ,t −w∗a(j),b(k),t − ck ,t

)Mt s−a(j),b(j)k ,t (p

−a(j),b(j)t )

with p−a(j),b(j)t [k ,1] =

+∞ if k ∈ Ja(j) ∩Jb(j)p−a(j),b(j)k ,t if k ∈ Ja(j)\Jb(j)

p∗k ,t otherwise

. back

Page 79: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

FOC of the ”Nash-in-Nash” (pre-alliances):

λpref ,r

(πf ,t −d

−jf ,t

)( ∂πr ,t∂wj ,t

)+

(1−λpre

f ,r

)(πr ,t −d

−jr ,t

)( ∂πf ,t∂wj ,t

)= 0

Γj ,t sj ,t + ∑k∈Jf \{j }

Γk ,t

(sk ,t − s

−jk ,t (p

−jt ;δt ,θ

d2 )

)( ∑k∈Jr ,t

∂pk ,t∂wj ,t

sk ,t − sj ,t +∑

k∈Jr ,tγk ,t

∑l∈Jr ,t

∂sk ,t∂pl ,t

∂pl ,t∂wj ,t

). . .

pref ,r

1−λpref ,r

γj ,t sj ,t +∑

k∈Jr ,t \{j }γk ,t sk ,t − γkt (p

−jt )s−jk ,t (p

−jt ;δt ,θ

d2 )

sj ,t +

∑k∈Jf ,t

Γk ,t

∑l∈Jr ,t

∂sk ,t∂pl ,t

∂pl ,t∂wj ,t

= 0

where Γj ,t ≡ wj ,t −µjt ; γj ,t ≡ pj ,t −wj ,t − cj ,t ; γk ,t ≡ p−jk ,t −wk ,t − ck ,t .

FOC of the ”Nash-in-Nash” (post-alliances):

λpostf ,a(j)

(πf ,t −d

−a(j),b(j)f ,t

) ∂πa(j),t∂wa(j),b(j),t

+(1−λpost

f ,a(j)

)(πa(j),t −d

−a(j),b(j)a(j),t

) ∂πf ,t∂wa(j),b(j),t

= 0

⇔( ∑h∈Ja(j)∩Jb(j)

Γa(j),b(j),t sh ,t +∑

k∈Jf \Ja(j)∩Jb(j)

Γa(k),b(k),t

(sk ,t − s

−a(j),b(j)k ,t (p

−a(j),b(j)t ;δt ,θ

d2 )

)). . .

( ∑h∈Ja(j)

∂ph ,t∂wa(j),b(j),t

sh ,t −∑

k∈Ja(j)∩Jb(j)

sk ,t +∑

k∈Ja(j)

γk ,t

∑l∈Ja(j)

∂sk ,t∂pl ,t

∂pl ,t∂wa(j),b(j),t

). . .

+1−λpost

f ,a(j)

λpostf ,a(j)

( ∑h∈Ja(j)∩Jb(j)

γh ,t sh ,t +∑

k∈Ja(j)\Jb(j)

γk ,t sk ,t − γ−a(j),b(j)k ,t s

−a(j),b(j)k ,t (p

−a(j),b(j)t ;δt ,θ

d2 )

). . .

( ∑h∈Ja(j)∩Jb(j)

sh ,t +∑k∈Jf

Γa(k),b(k),t

∑l∈Ja(j)

∂sk ,t∂pl ,t

∂pl ,t∂wa(j),b(j),t

)= 0

back

Page 80: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

8 supply-side instruments.

nb. of rival products in each bottled water segment (mineral, sparkling)× 1{pre-alliances}r(j)={1,3,5}× 1{pre-alliances}r(j)={2,4,6}× 1r(j)={7,8}

1{post-alliances}t ×1{national brand}j ,t ×1{alliance}j ,t× 1a(j)={1}× 1a(j)={2}× 1a(j)={3}

1{post-alliances}t ×1{national brand}j ,t ×1{no alliance}j ,t× 1r(j)={7}× 1r(j)={8}

back

Page 81: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Gandhi and Houde (2017) test. (Gauss-Newton regression)From a first-order Taylor expansion of ω(θs) around the true parameters θs0, we

can linearize the structural bargaining model as follows: ω(θs) =

∂ω(θs)

∂θs θGN + u.

Because we have a linear model with multiple endogenous variables (i.e., ∂ω(θs)

∂λ),

we can estimate the model by TSLS in which first-stage equations correspond to∂ω(θ

s)

∂λ= Zsβ+e.

Table 15: First-stage diagnostics for the bargaining model

Test ∂ω∂λpre

1

∂ω∂λpre

2

∂ω∂λpost

1

∂ω∂λpost

2

∂ω∂λpost

3

∂ω∂λna

Feff 1,835.96 1,872.96 253.19 3,976.30 1,707.16 6.82SW-F 211.91 30.91 174.09 705.10 83.21 1.21

Notes: Feff is the robust F-stat of Montiel Olea and Pflueger (2013, JBES). The critical valuefor testing that the TSLS bias exceeds 10% of the OLS bias is around 20.

back

Page 82: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Figure 14: ”No buyer alliances” scenario

Notes: Counterfactual retail prices for national brands of alliances’ members. Average retailprices calculated using quantity weights.

Table 16: Retail price effect of buyer alliances

Diff-in-Diff Simulation

Alliances’ members (treatment) [-6.88% ; -3.92%] -7.97%No Alliances (control) 0% -0.15%

back

Page 83: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Figure 15: Status quo effect

Notes: Counterfactual retail prices for national brands of alliances’ members. Average retailprices using quantity weights.

∆ retail prices: -1.43% with respect to the ”no buyer alliance” scenario.

back

Page 84: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Figure 16: Bargaining ability effect

Notes: Counterfactual retail prices for national brands of alliances’ members. Average retailprices using quantity weights.

∆ retail prices: -8.00% with respect to the ”no buyer alliance” scenario.

back

Page 85: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Figure 17: Joint-bargaining paradoc

Notes: Counterfactual retail prices for national brands of alliances’ members. Average retailprices using quantity weights.

∆ retail prices: 0.45% with respect to the ”no buyer alliance” scenario.

back

Page 86: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Ashenfelter, Orley, and Daniel Hosken. 2010. “The Effect ofMergers on Consumer Prices: Evidence from Five Mergers on theEnforcement Margin.” Journal of Law & Economics,53(3): 417–466.

Berry, Steven T., and Philip Haile. 2014. “Identification inDifferentiated Products Markets Using Market Level Data.”Econometrica, 82(5): 1749–1797.

Berry, Steven T., James Levinsohn, and Ariel Pakes. 1995.“Automobile Prices in Market Equilibrium.” Econometrica,63(4): 841–890.

Berry, Steven T., James Levinsohn, and Ariel Pakes. 2004.“Differentiated Products Demand Systems from a Combination ofMicro and Macro Data: The New Car Market.” Journal of PoliticalEconomy, 112(1): 68–105.

Bonnet, Celine, and Pierre Dubois. 2015. “Non Linear Contractingand Endogenous Buyer Power between Manufacturers and

Page 87: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Retailers: Empirical Evidence on Food Retailing in France.”Unpublished.

Caprice, Stephane, and Patrick Rey. 2015. “Buyer Power from JointListing Decision.” Economic Journal, 125(589): 1677–1704.

Carstensen, Peter C. 2010. “Buyer Cartels Versus Buying Groups:Legal Distinctions, Competitve Realities, and Antitrust Policy.”William & Mary Business Law Review, 1(1).

Collard-Wexler, Allan, Gautam Gowrisankaran, and Robin S. Lee.

2019. “”Nash-in-Nash” Bargaining: A Microfoundation for AppliedWork.” Journal of Political Economy, 127(1): 163–195.

Crawford, Gregory S., and Ali Yurukoglu. 2012. “The WelfareEffects of Bundling in Multichannel Television Markets.” AmericanEconomic Review, 102: 643–685.

Dana, James D. 2012. “Buyer groups as strategic commitments.”Games and Economic Behavior, 74(2): 470–485.

Page 88: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Dobson, Paul W., and Michael Waterson. 1997. “CountervallingPower and Consumer Prices.” Economic Journal,107(441): 418–430.

Ellison, Sara Fisher, and Christopher M. Snyder. 2010.“Countervailing Power in Wholesale Pharmaceuticals.” Journal ofIndustrial Economics, 58(1): 32–53.

Galbraith, John Kenneth. 1952. American Capitalism: The Conceptof Countervailing Power. Houghton Mifflin.

Galbraith, John Kenneth. 1954. “Countervailing Power.” AmericanEconomic Review: Papers and Proceedings, 44(2): 1–6.

Gandhi, Amit, and Jean-Francois Houde. 2016. “MeasuringSubstitution Patterns in Differentiated Products Industries.”Unpublished.

Gaudin, Germain. 2017. “Vertical Bargaining and RetailCompetition: What Drives Countervailing Power?” forthcoming atEconomic Journal.

Page 89: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Gowrisankaran, Gautam, Aviv Nevo, and Robert Town. 2015.“Mergers When Prices Are Negotiated: Evidence from the HospitalIndustry.” American Economic Review, 105(1): 172–203.

Grennan, Matthew. 2013. “Price Discrimination and Bargaining:Empirical Evidence from Medical Devices.” American EconomicReview, 103(1): 145–177.

Grennan, Matthew, and Ashley Swanson. 2019. “Transparency andNegotiated Prices: The Value of Information in Hospital-SupplierBargaining.” Forthcoming at Journal of Political Economy.

Harsanyi, John C. 1977. Rational Behaviour and BargainingEquilibrium in Games and Social Situations. Cambridge UniversityPress.

Ho, Katherine, and Robin S. Lee. 2017. “Insurer Competition inHealth Care Markets.” Econometrica, 85(2): 379–417.

Page 90: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Horn, Henrik, and Asher Wolinsky. 1988. “Bilateral Monopolies andIncentives for Merger.” RAND Journal of Economics,19(3): 408–419.

Inderst, Roman, and Greg Shaffer. 2007. “Retail Mergers, BuyerPower and Product Variety.” Economic Journal, 117(516): 45–67.

Iozzi, Alberto, and Tommaso Valletti. 2014. “Vertical Bargainingand Countervailing Power.” American Economic Journal:Microeconomics, 6(3): 106–135.

Lewis, Matthew S., and Kevin E. Pflum. 2015. “Diagnosing HospitalSystem Bargaining Power in Managed Care Networks.” AmericanEconomic Journal: Economic Policy, 7(1): 243–274.

Miller, Nathan H., and Matthew C. Weinberg. 2017. “Understandingthe Price Effects of the Millercoors Joint Venture.” Econometrica,85(6): 1763–1791.

Page 91: Buyer Alliances in Vertically Related Markets

Montiel Olea, Jose, and Carolin Pflueger. 2013. “A Robust Test forWeak Instruments.” Journal of Business & Economic Statistics,31(3): 358–369.

O’Brien, Daniel P. 2014. “The welfare effects of third-degree pricediscrimination in intermediate good markets: the case ofbargaining.” RAND Journal of Economics, 45(1): 92–115.

Rey, Patrick, and Thibaud Verge. 2004. “Bilateral control withvertical contracts.” RAND Journal of Economics, 35(4): 728–746.

Sorensen, Alan T. 2003. “Insurer-Hospital Bargaining: NegotiatedDiscounts in Post-Deregulation Connecticut.” Journal of IndustrialEconomics, 51(4): 469–490.