“Estimating the New Keynesian Philips Curve for the UK” … · 2018. 9. 13. · The New...

8
“Estimating the New Keynesian Philips Curve for the UK” Submitted to: Dr. Stephen Millard Advanced Macroeconomics (L14010) Authors: Mohammad Alali (4295448) Moosa Yousuf (4297530) Ziya Ekrem Bayrak (4311388) 10 th May 2018

Transcript of “Estimating the New Keynesian Philips Curve for the UK” … · 2018. 9. 13. · The New...

  • “Estimating the New Keynesian Philips Curve for the UK”

    Submitted to:

    Dr. Stephen Millard

    Advanced Macroeconomics (L14010)

    Authors:

    Mohammad Alali (4295448)

    Moosa Yousuf (4297530)

    Ziya Ekrem Bayrak (4311388)

    10th May 2018

  • Introduction

    The New Keynesian Phillips curve (NKPC) delivers a simple relationship between

    inflation and output by taking into consideration the expected inflation and real

    marginal cost of private agents. It has been beneficial for its simplicity when

    conducting theoretical policy analysis. Gali and Gertler (1999) were one of the first

    researchers who estimated the NKPC. They used quarterly US data from 1960 to

    1977 and found that their model was a good fit. In particular, the real marginal cost

    was quantitatively important and statistically significant. On the contrary, Roberts

    (2001) argued that the NKPC did not fit the US Data very well, and for it to fit the

    data, rational expectations needed to be augmented by additional lags of inflation.

    Hence, he argued that the backward-looking component of the NKPC was the most

    important determinant indicating that most of the population just uses a univariate

    rule to forecast inflation. Vašíček (2014) in a relatively recent study on a panel of four

    central European countries (Poland, Hungary, Czech and Slovakia) argued that the

    NKPC vaguely fits the data. He finds that inflation is driven by external factors and

    its past values both. Furthermore, he disputed the NKPC claims that the real marginal

    cost is the main inflation forcing variable. In contrast, Scheufele (2010) tested the

    NKPC and its hybrid variant on German data and found a purely forward-looking

    behavior. Despite the large amount of research devoted to the validity of the NKPC,

    the issue is still subject to debate.

    NKPC in the UK

    As for the UK, Batini et al (2005) use an open-economy NKPC and find that external

    factors such as real oil prices; competitive pressure and relative prices of imported

    inputs are all significant determinants of future inflation, as they make modifications

    to the baseline NKPC model. Furthermore, they adjust for price stickiness in their

    model using a framework based on Rotemberg (1982). A study aimed at considering

    inflation uncertainty by Groth et al (2006) tests the validity of the NKPC by

    examining the fit between fundamental and actual inflation series for UK and US

    data. Their findings for the UK data had narrower confidence bounds than the US,

    which allowed for identification of factors that may have contributed towards the

    inability of the NKPC to fit actual data for certain periods. Initially, there was a shift

    in the monetary policy around 1979, which was followed by a drastic fall in inflation.

  • Next, the NKPC failed to predict a rise in inflation during the second-half of the

    1980s. However, since the adoption of inflation targeting set at two percent in 1992, a

    relatively stable economic environment has accompanied low inflation and a low

    level of uncertainty regarding it. Since then, it could be fairly said that the

    fundamental inflation predicted by the NKPC has tracked actual inflation reasonably

    well. Our goal for this paper will be to extend previous studies on the verification of

    the NKPC, by examining if it fits the relatively recent UK data. We shall be studying

    a hybrid version of the NKPC that studies both backward and forward-looking

    components of inflation.

    Data and Methodology

    𝝅𝒕 − 𝝅 =  𝜷𝟏𝑴𝑪+ 𝜷𝟐(𝝅𝒆 − 𝝅)+ 𝜷𝟑(𝝅𝒕!𝟏 − 𝝅) (1) 𝝅𝒕 − 𝝅 =  𝜸𝟏(𝝅𝒕!𝟏 − 𝝅)+ 𝜸𝟐(𝝅𝒕!𝟐 − 𝝅)+ 𝜸𝟑(𝝅𝒕!𝟑 − 𝝅)+ 𝜸𝟒(𝝅𝒕!𝟒 − 𝝅) (2) 𝝅𝒕 − 𝝅 =  𝜽𝟏(𝝅𝒕!𝟏 − 𝝅)+ 𝜽𝟐(𝝅𝒕!𝟐 − 𝝅)+ 𝜽𝟑(𝝅𝒕!𝟒 − 𝝅) (3)

    The empirical estimations in the following section are based on quarterly data from

    1955 Q1 until 2016 Q3, gathered from the Bank of England database. We have

    constructed the real marginal cost (RMC) based on the log deviation of labor share

    from its mean, and specified instrumental variables for the generalized method of

    moments (GMM) estimation based on Gali et al (2005). Accordingly, we specify four

    lags for inflation and two lags each, for de-trended real GDP, nominal wage inflation

    and RMC. In order to estimate the NKPC (given in Equation 1), we construct three

    models based on different forms of expected inflation:

    1. We use an AR process to forecast future inflation using the 1st, 2nd and 4th

    lags. The AR (4) model is depicted in Equations 2, which we estimated and

    found an insignificant coefficient for the 3rd lag, hence used its reduced form

    illustrated in Equation 3.

    2. Assuming rational expectations, we could expect inflation in the next period to

    be the actual inflation plus a random expectational error. Doing so, we use πt+1

    as the expected inflation.

  • 3. Expected inflation is also available from survey forecasters at the Bank of

    England. We use these values in our third model, however, since these values

    start from 1996, leaving us with relatively fewer observations than the first

    two models.

    We calculate inflation as !"#!!"#!!!

    − 1 ∗ 400. The steady state inflation rate used in

    our framework is 2% for the post 1992 period, based on inflation target set by the

    central bank, and 6.5% prior to 1992 based on the mean inflation for 1955 Q1 to 1991

    Q4. Labor share is computed as !!!!!"#$  !"#!

    , where Wt and Nt correspond to real wages

    and the number of people employed respectively.

    Figure 1 depicts the expected inflation differential from its steady state based on the

    AR (4) reduced model, plotted against actual values. The expected inflation seems to

    fit well with the actual values, though it has a lower variation as the series takes more

    balanced values based on the 1st, 2nd and 4th lags. On the other hand, the values for

    expected inflation based on survey forecasts minus the steady state value of 2%

    appears to be very close to zero throughout 1996 – 2016 period and doesn’t fit well

    with actual inflation differential series from its steady state. Perhaps, this is since

    forecasts on average, expect that the central bank would commit to the target, which

    is observed to be the case in the long run where average inflation based on CPI over

    the inflation targeting period starting from 1992 is found to be very close to 2%.

    -‐15  

    -‐10  

    -‐5  

    0  

    5  

    10  

    15  

    20  

    25  

    30  

    1955  

    1958  

    1961  

    1964  

    1967  

    1970  

    1973  

    1976  

    1979  

    1982  

    1985  

    1988  

    1991  

    1994  

    1997  

    2000  

    2003  

    2006  

    2009  

    2012  

    2015  

    Figure 1 Actual inflation differential from its steady state and its expectation

    based on AR process

    Actual  

    AR  expected  

  • Empirical Results

    Table 1: Summary of regression outputs

    Dependent Variable: CPI Inflation Linear estimation with 1 weight update

    Choice of Expected Inflation

    Independent Variables Rational

    Expectations (Model 1)

    AR Process (Model 2)

    Survey Forecasts (Model 3)

    Real Marginal Cost 0.017 (1.33) 0.002 (0.12)

    0.017 (0.74)

    Expected Inflation 0.517*** (6.41) 1.045***

    (9.42) -0.651 (0.26)

    Lagged inflation 0.125* (1.95) -0.123**

    (2.35) -0.252**

    (2.33) R-squared 0.22 0.48 0.00

    J-statistic 26.2 9.8 15.8 Cragg-Donald F-statistic 1659.7 13.8 5.6 Number of observations 241 242 82 Instrument rank 10 10 10

    Instrument specification: Constant; 4 lags of CPI Inflation; 2 lags of Real Marginal

    Cost; 2 lags of De-trended Real GDP; 2 lags of Nominal Wage Inflation. Estimation weighting matrix: HAC (Bartlett kernel, Newey-West fixed bandwidth = 5.00 for Models 1 and 2, and 4.00 for Model 3). Standard errors and covariance are computed using estimation weighting matrix. Numbers in parentheses are the absolute (Newey West) t-statistics that have been corrected for heteroscedasticity and serial auto-correlation. Significant coefficients are indicated by *p

  • There are different methods that contribute to the estimation of NKPC like the Non-

    Linear Least Squares, Maximum Likelihood Estimation, Limited Information

    Maximum Likelihood Estimation and the Generalized Method of Moments (GMM).

    However, we have used GMM since it is among the best estimators able to deal with

    potential endogeneity issues. Doing so, we have introduced a set of 10 instruments

    based on different number of lags of 4 variables, as suggested by Gali et al (2005).

    Results for each of the three models are presented in Table 1.

    It is essential that we test for the strength of these instruments for robustness. We do

    this by comparing the Cragg-Donald F-statistic with the Stock-Yogo critical values.

    Based on the results, we reject the “null hypothesis of weak instruments” at the 5%

    level for Model 1, and 10% level for Model 2. However, we fail to reject the “null

    hypothesis of weak instruments” for Model 3. Furthermore, Model 3 has an r-squared

    of zero, indicating that it lacks predictive power. We therefore disregard it from our

    analysis and examine the NKPC under expected inflation based on rational

    expectations and the AR process. Next, we test for over-specification based on the J-

    statistic given by our GMM estimation. Using a significance threshold of 1%, our

    results indicate that none of the models severely suffer from the over-specification

    problem.

    Inferences on the expected inflation and the backward looking component:

    The coefficients of expected inflation for Models 1 and 2 are both positive and

    statistically significant, underlying a strong forward-looking component. In Model 1,

    we assume rational expectations, suggesting that current inflation heavily depends on

    the actual one period ahead inflation with an expectational error. There is also a

    significantly positive backward looking component implying inflation tends to be

    higher in periods that follow high inflation in the most immediate period.

    Surprisingly, the opposite is true for lagged inflation in Model 2, in which case

    consumers expect inflation to be lower at times succeeding periods of high inflation.

    Nonetheless, the backward looking component is of a lower magnitude than the

    forward looking component in both Models 1 and 2, suggesting that the NKPC is

    predominantly forward looking. Additionally, our coefficient for expected inflation in

    Model 2 (which uses an AR process to estimate expected inflation) is highly

  • significant and closer to one. This supports the general claim in Roberts (2001) that

    most people just use a univariate rule when estimating inflation.

    Comments on the real marginal cost:

    In theory, the RMC forms a major component of the NKPC as it is expected to

    positively influence inflation. Accordingly, the signs of coefficients for RMC are

    theoretically correct in each of the three models we have estimated, however, neither

    are statistically significant. This could be due to the inherent limitations for measuring

    RMC or using labor share to proximate it. Mazumder (2010) mentions two main

    reasons why labor share used by Gali et al (2005) is an unsuitable proxy for RMC.

    Firstly, he argues that while marginal cost should be pro-cyclical (in theory), labor

    share tends to be countercyclical. Secondly, he criticizes the assumption that labor

    input is freely adjusted at a fixed real wage, since in reality, due to labor contracts,

    hiring and training costs, labor is not fully flexible in the short-run.

    Conclusion and further recommendations In conclusion, we found expected inflation to be the most valuable contributor in the NKPC, since the coefficients of expected inflation in both Models 1 and 2 are statistically significant and quantitatively important. As for the lagged inflation, although it is statistically significant in both models, it carries a relatively lower magnitude than its forward-looking counterpart. This conclusion is also found in Gali and Gertler (1999) who suggested the forward-looking component has a dominant role in the NKPC. Furthermore, the RMC is statistically insignificant across all three models; partially due to the limitation of using labor share to proximate RMC. Finally, we would like to suggest alternatives to studying inflation dynamics. We recommend using financial and money market variables such as interest and forward rates as they are closely linked with inflation. For countries that actively participate in international trade, introducing variables such as average inflation rates in trading partner countries and exchange rates could help in identifying any potential spillovers. Cottarelli et al (1998) suggest a number of non-monetary determinants of inflation such as the central bank independence, exchange rate regimes, degree of price liberalization and fiscal policy variables that they find significant. Furthermore, it may be a good idea to revisit the classical Philips curve to study interactions between inflation and unemployment, though this relation could only last in the short run as unemployment is determined by real factors in the long run when markets adjust their expectations over time (Friedman, 1977).

  • References

    Batini, N., Jackson, B. and Nickell, S., 2005. An open-economy new Keynesian Phillips curve for the UK. Journal of Monetary Economics, 52(6), pp.1061-1071. Cottarelli, M.C., 1998. The Nonmonetary determinants of inflation: A panel data study. International Monetary Fund. Friedman, M., 1977. Nobel lecture: inflation and unemployment. Journal of political economy, 85(3), pp.451-472. Gali, J. and Gertler, M., 1999. Inflation dynamics: A structural econometric analysis. Journal of monetary Economics, 44(2), pp.195-222. Gali, J., Gertler, M. and Lopez-Salido, J.D., 2005. Robustness of the estimates of the hybrid New Keynesian Phillips curve. Journal of Monetary Economics, 52(6), pp.1107-1118. Groth, C., Jääskelä, J.P. and Surico, P., 2006. Fundamental inflation uncertainty. Mazumder, S., 2010. The new Keynesian Phillips curve and the cyclicality of marginal cost. Journal of Macroeconomics, 32(3), pp.747-765. Roberts, J., 2001. How Well does the new Keynesian Sticky Price Model Fit the Data?. Rotemberg, J.J., 1982. Sticky prices in the United States. Journal of Political Economy, 90(6), pp.1187-1211. Scheufele, R., 2010. Evaluating the german (new keynesian) phillips curve. The North American Journal of Economics and Finance, 21(2), pp.145-164. Vašíček, B., 2011. Inflation dynamics and the new Keynesian Phillips curve in four Central European Countries. Emerging Markets Finance and Trade, 47(5), pp.71-100.