Ws 031220 Huy Nh Paper

49
December 20, 2003 Job Rotation, Corruption, and Tax Administration in the Developing Countries Do Ngoc Huynh Visiting Scholar, Policy Research Institute, Ministry of Finance, Japan Abstract This paper is purposed to make a theoretical model to illustrate the role of job rotation in reducing tax evasion and corruption and consider an appropriate framework to apply the job rotation system in tax administration in the developing countries. For the theoretical model, we consider the role of rob rotation in a simple framework based on the principal-agent and cooperation relations in the theory of tax administration, and find that there would be an optimal time for tax inspectors to work with the same taxpayers that maximizes the expected government revenue. This would play a role of the cornerstone for applying the job rotation system in tax administration. Then, based on the Japanese experience, we discuss the issue of how to apply the job rotation system in tax administration with emphases on difficulties, feasibility, and necessary conditions for the The author would like to thank Hosen Mitsuo, Kashiwagi Shigeo, Mutoh Shizuki, Satoh Masayuki, Kuzumi Masayuki, and other members participating in a workshop on tax policy and administration in developing countries at the Policy Research Institute of the Ministry of Finance, Japan. He is also grateful to Ukai Yukio from the National Personnel Authority and Shimazaki Masao from the Ministry of Finance’ Secretariat for providing useful information on the job rotation scheme in the Japanese administration system. The views expressed in this paper are, however, those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the views of affiliated institutions. 1

description

job rotation artical

Transcript of Ws 031220 Huy Nh Paper

Job Rotation and Tax Administration in the Developing Countries

December 20, 2003

Job Rotation, Corruption, and

Tax Administration in the Developing Countries (Do Ngoc HuynhVisiting Scholar,

Policy Research Institute, Ministry of Finance, JapanAbstract

This paper is purposed to make a theoretical model to illustrate the role of job rotation in reducing tax evasion and corruption and consider an appropriate framework to apply the job rotation system in tax administration in the developing countries. For the theoretical model, we consider the role of rob rotation in a simple framework based on the principal-agent and cooperation relations in the theory of tax administration, and find that there would be an optimal time for tax inspectors to work with the same taxpayers that maximizes the expected government revenue. This would play a role of the cornerstone for applying the job rotation system in tax administration. Then, based on the Japanese experience, we discuss the issue of how to apply the job rotation system in tax administration with emphases on difficulties, feasibility, and necessary conditions for the implementation process under the context of socio-economic conditions in the developing countries.

Keywords: Rotation; Specification; Tax Evasion; Corruption; Tax AdministrationJEL Classification: J53, L22, C70, K42, D73

I. Introduction

The issue of tax evasion and corruption in tax administration has always been one of the most disputed topics for policy-makers and economists in the developing world nowadays. In the developed countries, where the tax system is quite functioned in the condition of high economic development, corruptions in general and corruption in tax administration in particularly are suppressed at relatively low levels. Being different from the situation of corruptions in these countries, it is widely accepted that the phenomenon of corruptions has been appeared everywhere in the developing countries, especially in the process of tax compliance. There are, generally, many reasons for the popularity of tax evasion and corruption in these countries. However, they could be divided in three main groups consisting of the tax policy, the organization and management of tax administration, and the checking system (Das- Guppta et al. (1999)). Regarding to the tax policy, in the condition that the government faces many difficulties and obstacles in the initial stages of economic development, the major measures of reducing tax evasion and corruption, such as reducing tax burden, eliminating preferential treatments, increasing incentives for tax inspectors, and setting a system of heavy penalties on tax evasion and corruption, have certain limits in their real impacts. On the other hand, the checking system might be too expensive and biased in the condition of limited budget resources and asymmetric information in these economies. Therefore, the system of organization and management of tax administration would play an important role in reducing disastrous behaviors in the process of tax compliance, including tax evasion and corruption, in the developing countries.

Regarding to the topic of organizational system in general, as well known in the theory of industrial organization and the practice of the Japanese economy, the introduction of the job rotation system might play an important role in improving the overall efficiency of the whole system. Although job rotation has obvious disadvantages in some important aspects, of which, the two most important ones are the deficiency of breaking down specialization and the difficulty in application, it is noted for its main benefits from positive effects on career development, motivations/renovations, flexibility, and reductions in working stresses, boredom, and monotony, among others (Triggs and King (2000), Cosgel and Miceli (1998)). This also explains why the application of the system has been still limited in certain fields, sectors, or in some countries. When choosing between two organizational schemes of job specialization (specific/assignment jobs) and rotation, there would be usually trade-offs between advantages and disadvantages of these schemes that need to be seriously considered. Generally, job rotation is supposed to be the superior choice in cases of works requiring broad experiences, highly pressured works, or not so high concerned costs in both material and mental aspects.

In this paper, we explore a special advantage of job rotation in reducing tax evasion and corruption and consider the trade-off between the efficiency and the deficiency of job rotation in tax administration in a simple theoretical framework of tax evasion and corruption for developing countries. Based on the fact of these economies, we assume that the tax inspectors probability of finding out tax evasion and the probability of cooperation between the taxpayer and the inspector are increasing functions of the time that the inspector does his job with the same taxpayer. As the time increases, the possibility of finding out tax evasion increases, and therefore, the expected government revenue would be increased. However, the probability of cooperation between the taxpayers and the inspector also increases along with the time. This would reduce the expected government revenue. The solution of this trade-off relation would be the optimal level of the time when its positive revenue effect is offset by its negative cooperation effect. This theoretical model clearly illustrates the superiority of job rotation in tax administration. However, it would be not easy to apply the system in the developing countries, although its advantage in reducing tax evasion and corruption is firmly recognized in the theoretical model. Therefore, we also need to analyze and discuss the framework of job rotation in order to make the job rotation system feasible and efficient in these economies.

The remaining of the paper is then organized as follows. In section II, we make a brief literature survey on job rotation and tax evasion and corruption. The theoretical model illustrating the important role of job rotation in reducing tax evasion and corruption is presented in section III. Then, we will discuss the framework of job rotation in tax administration for developing countries in section IV. Finally, section V makes conclusions.

II. Literature survey

Job rotation and corruption in tax administration are usually considered as two separate topics in the recent economic literature. Job rotation is mostly considered in the context of industrial organization at the firm level. The relation between job rotation and corruption has been rarely discussed. On the other hand, in the literature on tax compliance, most of studies concern the aspects of tax burden, penalties, and incentives. There has been also not much attention on the job rotation system and its effects on reductions in tax evasion and corruption. Therefore, before combining these two issues into an integral framework, it is necessary to make a brief outline of recent studies in these fields.

1. Job rotation

There are many definitions of job rotation; however, there might be divided into two main types: the narrow- and the wide definitions of job rotation, as presented in the following figure.

Figure 1: Job rotation: the narrow and wide definitions

The inside rotation

The outside rotation

Organization A

Organization B

People Works

People Works

A1 X1

B1 Y1

A2 X2

B2

Y2

A3 X3

B3

Y3

Narrow definition

Narrow definition

Wide definition

Regarding to the narrow definition, job rotation is considered as transfers of employees between jobs in an organization. In this case, job rotation is happened only inside the organization, then, it might be called the inside rotation. However, there are also the case of exchanging employees in certain fields/jobs between different organizations, the outside rotation, such as the case of rotations between government agencies and between government agencies and private organizations, as observed in the Japanese economy. Then, the wide definition of job rotation includes both the inside rotation and the outside rotation - the case of crossing transfers of employees between different organizations. Of course, the difference between these definitions is only relative because job rotation between divisions/departments in an organization or between corporations in a holding group is the inside rotation for the whole organization but the outside rotation for smaller units inside the organization.

In organizations applying the system of job rotation, employees are usually not remained in the same jobs/positions permanently but are to be transferred to do other jobs/positions at some frequencies. They usually do not return to former jobs. There are many arguments on the merits and demerits of job rotation. Regarding to the merits of job rotation, most of the studies concern theories of industrial organization and management system in the aspect of relationship between rotation and career development. Studies on career development have recognized the importance of work experiences that the career motivation can be influenced by experiences gained through rotation (London (1983), Morrison and Brantner (1992)). Job rotation is also argued to play important roles to job learning that can be viewed as an environmental strategy for employees career development. The process of employees human capital accumulation is believably dependent on their working experiences: the more they are rotated, the more they learn. Hence, in the corporate management strategy, job rotation is also considered as an important instrument for development (Sonnenfeld and Peiperl (1988)).

For managers who are presumed to perform a variety of different roles, rotation would be very important in the context of developing managers as generalists who can understand and do jobs concerning a vast of issues in the concerned fields. Empirical studies also find that work experiences were related to executives career opportunities, learning, and changes in abilities, attitudes, and motivation (Guthrie and Olian (1991)). Practically, large organizations, such as multi-national corporations, frequently use rotation to develop their networks of managers. There is also another aspect that organizational socialization is considered as a process of information acquisition though rotations, as showed in Ostroff and Kozlowski (1992). Job rotation may enhance career development because of the adjustments and knowledge acquisition that new jobs require. On-the-job factors, such as co-workers, supervisors, and experiences are considered more important than off-the-job factors such as formal training and social activities. Therefore, setting up the organizational framework of varying work experiences through rotation might be considered as one important component for the process of career development.

Studying the cost and benefit of job rotation, there are also discussions concerning the issue of job matching. In the job matching studies (Jovannovic (1979), Miller (1984)), jobs and employees should be matched in the best way possible because of the job specificity of human capital. However, the proficiency of employees in different jobs could be only known if they actually try such jobs. Therefore, job rotation would be an effective instrument for optimally allocating labor forces in case of asymmetric information in the labor market. Looking at each employee performing different jobs, the employer would find the job that is most suitable for him. Concerned the aspect of job specificity of human capital, there are also some striking arguments that job rotation would improve productivities of working more than specialization. Considering job rotation as a learning mechanism in a clear theoretical framework of the job specificity of human capital, Ortega (2001) compared job rotation to an assignment policy, and also showed that job rotation would be a better learning mechanism than specialization when there is little prior information about the relative profitability of different jobs/ works. Relative gains from job rotations are higher than specialization when the initial uncertainties about employees and technologies become larger. Empirical works also support the view that firms using new technologies are likely to use job rotations. Beside the above economic merits, there are also other advantages of job rotation in the social and welfare aspects. They are reductions in boredom and monotony, work stresses, and CDT (cumulative trauma disorders) It is widely believed that a proportion of employees would feel bored and monotonic with the same works for long periods. On the other hand, some of them, especially the young, want to challenge new jobs in new working environments and enjoying new working relations with new people. In many cases, working in the same place and maintaining long relations with the same colleagues would cause stresses and CDT for employees, which are negatively affect their utilities. Therefore, job rotation could be considered as a possible choice to improve employees welfare that might not concern economic incentives.

On the demerits of job rotation, they have been considered in many aspects. The biggest and foremost disadvantage of job rotation concerns specialization. As widely accepted in the economic literature, from classical economists like A. Smith or K. Marx, specialization is one of the major engines for renovations and enhancing working efficiency. Job rotation clearly restrains the degree of specialization. Therefore, cost-benefit analyses of choices between rotation and specialization would be very important. Job rotation should be only applied when it produces benefits that are higher than losses from reductions in specialization (Cosgel and Miceli (1998, 1999)). In the fields requiring specialists with deep knowledge or working skills and experiences in the same jobs, such as some works in high-tech industries and scientific researches, job rotation at relatively frequent levels might be questioned.

Besides, job rotation has close relations with the work structure, workplace relation and culture, and employees behaviors. As usual, experienced employees do not want to do new types of jobs or handover their currently good conditions or share their knowledge and experiences of working to newcomers. It is also very difficult to identify appropriate job for each people in the organization in the process of rotating. On the other hand, there are usually not small costs of rotating, including both material-and non-material costs, such as changes in the living environments, customs and cultures, especially for the employees side (MacLeod and Kennedy (1993), Triggs and King (2000)). This is why the system of job rotation has not been popular in the world economy, and only relatively big organizations with a well-performed management system can apply the system efficiently. Generally, considering the job rotation system to apply, all aspects of cost-benefit analyses, the organizational structure, the system of work evaluation, as well as the period and timing of rotation should be carefully reviewed.

It is also necessary to consider the job rotation system in Japan as a fairly successful and unique example in the economy-wide scale of application. The Japanese economy started to apply and develop the system in the 1950s. There are many studies indicating important roles of the system to the Japanese miracle in the high growth period. The system of lifetime jobs with rotations is one of the most distinguished features of the Japanese economy. Not only the private sector, the system of job rotation has been applying in government agencies, and up to present, it has generally been still rather functioned. Why does the job rotation system go well in Japan but not in somewhere else in the world? As pointed out in Dutton (1987), The strong traditional permanent employment in larger Japanese firms, especially for the managerial group, makes job rotation possible and feasible. Historically, the Japanese economy, especially the labor market, has been different from other economies in many aspects. A typical Japanese employee usually stays in the same organization until their retirements. During his period of staying in the same organization, he experiences many jobs, working positions, and moves towards the top of the pyramid of the management structure in that organization. This is so-called the lifetime job system, and considered as unique in the world. Ouchi (1981) also certified the non-specialized career path as one of the fundamental features of Japanese firms.

Beside the management structure, there are many other factors supporting the job rotation system in Japan. Among others, the wage system in Japan is mainly based on the length of time working at the organization (employees ages), therefore, the system of job rotation would not cause much troubles concerning employees earnings. On the other hand, job rotation has become a custom/culture of business administration, and been widely accepted by the public. In addition, Japanese people are noted for their very diligences at the work. Their attitudes to works and responsibilities for their works are extremely high. The organizational socialization of the Japanese people is also notably respected so that the implementation process is quite smooth and functioned.

Overall, we see that almost studies analyzed the job rotation system in the aspect of industrial organization and management structure. At the firm level, although having disadvantages because of the negative effect on specialization and the difficulty in the implementation process, job rotation is noted for its advantages in career developments/ working experiences, flexibility, reductions of working stresses, boredom, among others. In practice, the Japanese economy has been successfully applying the system due to her special and unique socio-economic conditions at both micro and macro levels. However, looking at the concerned literature, the relation between job rotation and corruption, specifically corruptions in tax administration, has generally still not attracted much attention of studies on the field.

2. Tax evasion and corruption

Tax evasion and corruption in tax administration has been a regular topic in the economic literature, as noted above. Regarding to the theoretical aspect, there are many studies exploring the principal-agent relation in tax administration and cooperative games between taxpayers and inspectors. Historically, the first study on tax evasion might be the seminal paper of Allingham and Sandmo (1972). As showed in this study, it is necessary to audit or investigate the taxpayers reported income in order to deter or reduce evasion. The tax authority (auditor/inspector) is responsible for making justice in tax compliance by finding out the real taxable income and imposes a penalty rate (higher than the tax rate) in case of tax evasions. However, in a hierarchical structure where the principal delegates a task to agents, there would be the cases these agents cooperate with taxpayers to lower their tax liabilities. Then, after the collusion in a hierarchy was formalized by using the principal-agent framework (Tirole (1986), Kaufman and Lawaree (1993)), there have been emerged a bulk of studies on tax evasion and corruption in tax administration.

In these studies, the possibility of cooperation between taxpayers and inspectors would be appeared when the concerned cost is relatively low. The problem of optimal tax scheme is usually regarded in the aspects of tax schedule (burden), penalties and incentives for taxpayers and inspectors, and schemes of auditing and investigations. Besley and McLaren (1993) considered a framework with both honest and dishonest agents, compared three distinct remuneration schemes of reservation, efficient, and capitulation wages that provide different incentives to the inspectors. They characterized the conditions under which each scheme generates the greatest amount of net tax revenues after abstracting administration cost. On the other hand, in Mookherjee and Pngs (1995) paper, they considered corruptible agents with a moral hazard problem that inspectors have to exert costly non-observable efforts to disclose evasions, and found that although bribes encourage the inspector to monitor, it should be better when compensation policies are adjusted to eradicate them. Then, Hindriks et al. (1999) studied a model consisting of all dishonest agent with the distinction of setting flexible tax schemes and allowing extortion that the inspector might overstate the taxpayer income. They also proved that imposing progressive taxes without measures of presenting evasion and corruption would make bribes on high-income reports. Recently, Polinsky and Shavel (2001) analyzed a framework of bribery, distortion, and framing, and found two ways to reduce corruption, consisting of imposing sanctions and rewards for reporting violations with optimal penalties and rewards schemes. Now, we consider the situation of tax compliance and tax administration in the developing countries for looking stylized facts to build the theoretical model in the next section. Tax administrations in the developing countries have arguably been mostly corrupted. As presented above, difficulties and obstacles in the socio-economic conditions in these economies make the picture different from that in the developed economies. In these economies, beside reasons of tax evasion and corruption concerning the tax policy and the checking system, the weak tax administration system itself has been also an important background for developments of tax evasion and corruption. There would be two important issues concerning the tax administration: the organizational structure and management system, and the officers and taxpayers attitudes. Regarding to the organizational structure and management system, shortages of modern management frameworks and modern technologies assistances make the system out-of-date, less flexible and transparent, and inefficient. The reporting system and the information processing system, which play major roles in tax enforcement, are usually weak and inadequate. For the tax administration purposes, both systems of inside relations and outside relations are always questionable in all aspects. Tax inspectors are usually authorized to work with their taxpayers for long periods without a strictly reporting system and frequently investigations. This might be considered as one of the main reasons for cooperation between inspectors and taxpayers that lead to tax evasions and corruptions. Even in the case of investigation by higher-level officials, there are usually further bargaining-cooperation steps in the hierarchical organization. That is why it would be not exaggerated to say that tax evasion and corruption in the developing countries is systematic and serious.

Regarding to the tax officers and taxpayers attitudes, because average levels of per capita income and living standards in the developing countries are relatively low, most of taxpayers and tax officers would have motivations for tax evasion and corruption at some certain levels. Moral hazards and adverse selection might be happened in tax compliance in both sides of taxpayers and tax officers. For taxpayers, under the condition of popularity of tax evasion, they would be forced out of the game if being honest in the competitive market. In the tax officers sides, because of low wage, by touching with opportunities to make money, they would take their chances. The honest officers would be also forced out of their works, partly because of low income, partly because of being strange to their colleagues. Even in the case of initial honest tax officers, after a long time touching with a possibility of making a large amount of money in a relatively safe way in the condition of low salary, they would be engaged in corruptions.

Looking overall, we see that the organization and management aspect would be very important in reducing tax evasion and corruption in the developing countries. The model developed in the next section is then based on the theoretical arguments of job rotation and tax compliance in the recent economic literature and the stylized fact in tax administration in these countries that the structures of tax administration are relatively static in terms of rotating and exchanging their officers. This is considered as one of the major reasons for cooperation between taxpayer and tax officers to engage in tax evasion and corruption in the difficult socio-economic conditions. This model is different with the current literature on job rotation in the aspect that it focuses on analyzing the aspect of cooperation between taxpayers and tax officers. Comparing with the existed theoretical studies on tax evasion and corruption, we concentrate on the aspect of the time (period) that tax officers touch the same taxpayers, which considered as a necessary of cooperation for engaging in tax evasion and corruption.

III. Theoretical Model

1. The framework

Based on the stylized facts of the developing countries, we use a simple framework of studying tax evasion and corruption and integrate the factor of the time required for cooperation between agents into the framework to analyze effects of job rotation on tax evasion and corruption. There are four types of agents in the model: the government, tax inspectors, taxpayers, and auditors. The government announces the tax scheme, consisting of the tax schedule, penalties for the case of reporting income below the real levels for both taxpayers and inspectors, incentives for the inspectors to encourage them to do their jobs. The representative taxpayer is subjective to the tax scheme announced by the government. She is to maximize her payoffs, given the tax scheme. We also assume that she is tax-evasion-driven, as popularly observed in the developing world.

The inspectors are responsible for investigating whether the taxpayers report precisely their real income levels or not. The probability of finding the real income is assumed to be dependent on the time that the representative inspector does his job with the same taxpayer. This reflects the advantage of specialization in tax investigations. On the other hand, the inspectors are corruption-driven, which reflects the popular situation of corruption in tax investigations in the developing countries. The inspectors and taxpayers may negotiate to engage in tax evasion and corruption. However, the process of negotiation is to depend on mutual beliefs between them. This is also a distinguished feature of this study. Besides other factors affecting the process of negotiation, especially the profitability of cooperation, we supposed that the length of the time working with the same partners would be the main reason to strengthen the spirit of cooperation between them, which lead them to negotiate to engage in tax evasion and corruption (evasion for the taxpayer, corruption for the inspector). This is the disadvantage of specialization in tax investigations. We also already noted that even in the case of honest inspectors, to work with the same taxpayers in the long time would make them gradually becoming the dishonest.

Beside the tax inspectors being responsible for investigating the taxable income, an independent auditing agency enters the picture to make the justice of tax compliance. One this agency audits tax reports, they will find the real income. However, the cost of auditing is assumed quite large so that the probability of auditing is rather small. On the other hand, because they do not know which case is tax evaded and corrupted, the choice of auditing tax reports would be incidental.

Looking at the framework, we see that job rotations for inspectors are able to resolve the conflict between the advantage and disadvantage of specialization in tax investigations. Job rotation would significantly affect tax inspectors in many positive and negative aspects, as the recent literature on industrial organization suggested. However, in this paper, we focus on analyzing its effects on reducing tax evasion and corruption under the context of social economic environment in developing countries. As regarded above, tax evasion and corruption is popular in these countries. The tax policy and the systems of penalties and incentives have limits in their real effects under the socio-economic conditions of the developing world. Therefore, besides other policies measures, the government can also apply the system of job rotation to cut off mutually deep relations between taxpayers and inspectors, which are considered as one of the main reasons for tax evasion and corruption. In the model developed in this section, we prove that job rotation would reduce the possibility of cooperation between taxpayers and inspectors, although it would have a natural problem concerning the inspectors working proficiency.

2. The process

Based on the facts of tax administration, the process of tax compliance is assumed to consist of three stages, as follows.

Stage 1: The government announces the tax scheme,

where are the tax rate, real (taxable) income, reported income, penalties on the representative inspector and the representative taxpayer (i = I, T), fixed wage and incentive rate for tax inspector, respectively. This tax scheme, including the functions of penalties and incentive, is popularly applied in the world economy nowadays, especially the developing countries.

With a given level of the real income, the penalty functions are strictly concave on the level of the reported income, as follows,

Because the evasion amount is the gap between the real income and reported income, the fine would be zero when the amount of tax evasion is zero, and strictly increasing with the amount of tax evasion. The fine level is higher than the tax liability for every amount of tax evasion.

Stage 2: Income reporting, investigating, and negotiating

The representative taxpayer reports the level of income r, . This level is set up to maximize her net income, given the tax scheme and the inspectors probability of finding out the real income. The representative inspector investigates to find the reality of the reported income with the probability of finding out the real income as follows,

Of which t is the length of the time that the inspector does his job with the same taxpayer (called the time for short, hereafter). The function (2) means that the inspector needs time to find out the real income. The probability of finding out the real income is an increasing function of t when . When this probability is equal to unit. In other words, is the length of time for surely finding out the real income,.

Now, we consider the process of negotiation between the taxpayer and the inspector. There are two conditions for making negotiation between them successfully. The first is that the cooperation would be profitable for both of them. This means when they agree to report some level of income and accept some level of bribe, both of them are better off in terms of net income. On the other hand, the negotiation process between the inspector and the taxpayer is also supposedly dependent on the time, t. This is because they only cooperate when the relation between them reaches certain levels of closeness, deepness, and mutually believing and understanding. As we noted above, they are all human being; therefore, the more the time to work together, the higher the level of mutual belief and close relation between them. The probability of negotiation is then as follows,

We assume that which means that the limit of time for surely cooperating is shorter than that for surely finding out the real income. Besides, it is supposed that both the taxpayer and the inspector are risk-neutral so that we can concentrate on analyzing the effects of the time in the model. Stage 3: Auditing

The independent auditing agency is responsible for auditing the preciseness of tax compliance. We assume that the probability that the agency audits a tax report is , a given parameter. When auditing, the agency always find out the real income. If the reported income is less than the real income, both the taxpayer and the inspector will be fined according to the announced tax scheme, as presented above. The probability of auditing is assumed rather small because the heavy cost of auditing, as regularly cited in the economic literature and the real world.

3. Analyses

Based on the above process, we can describe the game in the tax administration as that in Figure 1. The left hand is the case of no cooperation with the probability of 1-p(t); meanwhile, the case of cooperation with probability of p(t) is presented in the right hand.

In this figure, we use the following signs: U is the net income of the taxpayer, V is the net income of the inspector. For upper signs, NA is for the case of not being audited; meanwhile A is for the case of being audited. In the lower signs, NN is for the case of no cooperation and the real income not recognized by the inspector, NR is for the case of no cooperation and the real income recognized by the inspector, and C is for the case of cooperation between the taxpayer and the inspector.

Figure 1: The game in tax administration

1-p

p No cooperation

Cooperation

Considering the payoffs for agents in the game, namely, the representative taxpayer, the representative inspector, and the government, as presented in Figure 1, we need to analyzes both two cases: (i) no cooperation between the taxpayer and the inspector, and (ii), cooperation between the taxpayer and the inspector. In the first case, the taxpayer faces the inspectors probability of recognizing the real income,; meanwhile in the second case, they mutually agree on the level of reported income. In each case, the probability of auditing is the same, , as regarded above.

3.1. The case of no cooperation For the inspector, supposing that the taxpayer reports the income r,, as presented above (r is called the taxpayers reported income), in the case of not being audited, because the probability of finding out the real income is , the inspectors expected income would be as follows,

In the case of being audited, his expected income would be,

Therefore, with the probability of auditing , the expected income of the inspector in the case of no cooperation is then,

We can see that this expected income in the equation (4) is dependent on the time t and the reported income r.

Now, we consider the expected income of the taxpayer. Similarly, for the case of not being audited, the expected income would be,

Meanwhile, in the case of being audited, it would become,

With probability of auditing to find out the real income , the taxpayers expected income would be as follows,

We can see in equation (5) that the condition of engaging in tax evasion is,

whereis the expected gain for the taxpayer from tax evasion. In the right hand of (6), the first expression is the expected gain from evasion, and the second expression is the expected loss. Therefore, tax evasion is happened only if the expected gain is larger than the expected loss.

Considering the behavior of the taxpayer, she is to report the income level that maximizes her net income (the after- tax and penalties income). Then, the maximization problem for the taxpayer would be . From (5) and (6), we have,

From the maximization problem of the taxpayer and the characters of the function in (1), we have the optimum choice for the taxpayer as follows,

The optimization level of the taxpayers reported income is determined as described in the following figure.

Figure 2: The optimal level of the reported income

In equation (7), when is rather small. Then we have the rule of 1/2 as stated in the following proposition.

Proposition 1. In case of no cooperation, if the function of penalty for the taxpayer is strictly convex (the penalty is always higher than the tax revenue), when the probability of auditing is rather small, the taxpayer will report the real income when the inspectors probability of finding out the real income is from about 1/2.

Intuitively, because the penalty is always higher than the tax liability, the rational taxpayer would report the real income when she knows that the probability of the real income being recognized by the inspector is from about 1/2. Otherwise, she would face the expected loss from the tax evasion. If the probability is smaller than this level, she will choose to report some level of income less than the real income, as showed in (7).

Now, we consider changes in the optimal level of the reported income with respect to t. From (1) and (7), we have:

where is determined by.Looking at (8), the level of reported income would be increased with t until when t is high enough such that the taxpayer would report the real income (Figure 3).

Figure 3: The dependence of the optimal level of the reported income on t

From (8), at the optimum choice of we have,

of which . Equations (9a) and (9b) mean that whenthe expected income of taxpayer is only negatively affected by the direct effect of t on the inspectors probability of finding out the real income. The indirect of t on the reported income is zero because is at the optimal level of the reported income. On the other hand, whenthe taxpayer would report the real income, and then, the reported income would not be affected by t.Regarding to the trend of changing in the inspectors expected income, we see that it is dependent on the time, t, and the taxpayers reported income, as regarded above. Then, when the reported income is , from (4), (7), and (8), we have,

From equation (10), we see that whenthe inspectors expected income would increase in t. Here, both the direct- and the indirect effects of t on the income are appeared. When t increases, the probability of finding out the real income increases; therefore, the expected incentive income would increase. On the other hand, the expected penalty would be also reduced. Whenthe taxpayer reports the real income, and then, the inspectors expected income would be not affected by t.

The expected (net) government revenue in this case is, therefore, as follows,

The evolution of the expected government revenue is then,

Whenwe assume that,

In (13), the first expression in the right hand is positive, but the second expression is negative. However, because the incentive rate would be not so high and the probability of auditing is rather small, as usual observed, the revenue effect is then higher than the payment effect. Intuitively, increases in the government revenue due to increases in the reported income are to be higher than increases in the net payments to the inspector and the taxpayer. This is also reasonable for the real world of tax administration. The increase in the tax revenue would be not used totally for paying the inspector because it would largely affect the inequality in income distribution in the society.

3.2. The case of cooperation

Supposed that when the taxpayer and the inspector cooperate to report some level of income r and agree on the level of bribe is b, the taxpayers expected income would be dependent on the probability of auditing, as follows,

Similarly, the inspectors expected income would be,

As usual, the maximization problem of cooperation is then to maximize the expected joint income, as follows,

Then we have the optimal value of reported income in case of cooperation,

When the probability of auditing is small and the incentive rate is not so large, there would exit an optimal level of the reported income, as determined in (17). We have the following proposition.

Proposition 2. In case of cooperation, the optimal level of the reported income is unique and not dependent on t.As showed in (16), and (17), at low levels of r the gain from tax evasion would be higher that the loss from penalties. However, because the functions of penalties are convex, the amounts of penalties would increase rapidly when r increases, and after some certain level of r, increases in the gain from tax evasion would be less than losses from increases in penalties. Because both functions of penalties are assumedly not intersected, there would be a uniquely optimal level of r that makes the expected (net) joint income maximized. This level is not dependent on the time, t. Intuitively, when the taxpayer and the inspector cooperate, they would not care about anything else but the expected joint income.

The expected government revenue in the case of cooperation is as follows,

As we can see in the above equation, there would not be the revenue on penalties in the case that the inspector recognizes the real income of the taxpayer because they cooperate to report an optimal level of income that maximizes their expected joint income.

The premium from cooperation would be divided based on bargaining powers of each partner in the cooperative game. Assuming that the bargaining powers are equal, the level of bribe would be as follows,

Generally, the level of bribe is considered as the solution of a Nash bargaining problem between the taxpayer and the inspector. However, for the purpose of studying, we only concentrate on analyzing corruption; therefore, we assume that their bargaining powers are equal so that the premium from cooperation would be equally divided between them.

As noted above, there are two factors deciding the process of cooperation. One is that cooperation is beneficial for both players. The other is the time that the inspector works with the same taxpayer. Because we are dealing with the case of cooperation, we only consider the later. Supposing they cooperate, regarding to the first condition, the expected joint income from cooperation should be higher than that from no cooperation. Therefore, the condition for cooperation would be as follows (P is the expected joint profit),

Otherwise, they would never cooperate. In case of cooperation, because the value of the first parenthesis in (19) doest not depend on t, we have,

Therefore, we can see that there might be two cases depending on the parameters of the model: (i) cooperation is always beneficial; and (ii), cooperation is only beneficial when t is large enough.

For the second case, we assume that at some small level of t, cooperation might not be beneficial (), especially when the inspectors probability of discovering the real income is relatively low at the initial period. When t increases, the inspectors probability of discovering the taxpayers real income increases, and therefore, cooperation will become beneficial (). Then, there might exist some at which . When , the cooperation would not be beneficial; meanwhile when , cooperation becomes beneficial. Therefore, only when , the cooperation between the taxpayer and the inspector is possible. We also assume so that there would always be the possibility of cooperation.

3.3- The expected government revenue

As regarded above, there would be two possible cases of cooperation: cooperation is always beneficial, and cooperation is only beneficial when t is large enough. Then, it is necessary to consider the expected government revenue for both these cases. The expected government revenue should be understood as the (comprehensively) expected government revenue when considering the possibility of cooperation between the taxpayer and the inspector. We suppose that the government pursues the objective of maximizing the expected government revenue. The only way they can do that is to change the time that the inspector does his work with the same taxpayer. This could be implemented through introducing the system of job rotation. Therefore, by considering the evolution of the expected government revenue, and through the results of analyses, we can perceive effects of the rotation system in pursuing the objective of maximizing the expected government revenue.

Case 1: Cooperation is always beneficial

The expected government revenue is determined in the following formula,

Looking at equations (22), when the change of G would depend on the slope of and. Based on the evolution of these functions, we have the following proposition.

Proposition 3. If cooperation is always beneficial, is concave, p(t) is linear or convex, and when ,

There exists a unique value of that maximizes the expected government revenue. This optimal value of t is determined where

Proof. Differentiating G when by t in equation (22), we have

The first term in the right hand of (23) reflects the positive revenue effect of changing in, meanwhile the second term is the negative cooperation effect of changing in p. Because cooperation is always beneficial,

We also have,

When , if , from (26) we see that . This means that increases in t near 0 from the right hand would have positive effects on G.

On the other hand, when , we have,

Therefore, there would be some value such that and changes the sign from positive to negative when t passes across , which is called the optimal time that maximizes the expected government revenue. Because we assume that is concave and p(t) is linear or convex, the first term in the right hand of (23) is decreasing, meanwhile the second term is non decreasing, therefore, the value of is unique (point E in Figure 4).

We can also describe the evolution of the expected government revenue as that in Figure 5. We can see that when the probability of cooperation is between zero and one, , the evolution of G would depend on the evolution of and . Because and have the same sharp of increasing in t, when if the condition in the proposition is satisfied, the slope of would be higher than that of . On the other hand, when , the slope of would be higher than that of . Therefore, there would be some point that the slope of these curves is equal (). Because is concave and p(t) is linear or convex, there would be a unique point E at which the slopes of and are equal. The locus of the expected government revenue would start from , reach the maximum level at E (), and then, reduce to the value of from point F (). When , the government revenue remains constant at because the probability of cooperation is one.

Figure 4: Determination and uniqueness of the optimal time in Proposition 3.

E

In Proposition 3, there would be the cases when the conditions that is concave and p(t) is linear or convex are violated. In these cases, the uniqueness of the optimal level of time would be questioned. There might be several points/regions of t that make and the sign of changes from positive to negative. They called the locally optimal points/regions. In this case, the globally optimal point/region would be chosen between these locally optimal points/regions where the expected government revenue is maximized. Figure 5: The evolution of the expected government revenue in Proposition 3.

0 t* t

When the condition concerning t at near 0 from the right hand in Proposition 3 is not satisfied, i.e., at ,

there might be two following possibilities:

(i) The gap between and is non-increasing in . That means,

In this case, the expected government revenue would be decreased from to when t increases from 0 to . Hence, in this case, the higher the frequency of rotation, the more the government revenue could be collected. Even in this case, it could be possible to find the optimal level of t by two possible methods. The first method is to set up a threshold for p(t), as follows,

where is the threshold level from which there would be a possibility for cooperation. On the other hand, the second method is to add some cost for rotation at the beginning periods for new jobs. It is easy to see that for the first case, is the optimal level of t; meanwhile, in the second case, the optimal time would be determined when the concerned cost of rotation become less than the expected loss in revenue due to the possibility of cooperation.

(ii) The gap between and is increasing in at some ranges in . This case is similar to the case we considered above that the conditions of is concave and p(t) is linear or convex in Proposition 3 are violated. In this case, there might be several points/regions of t that make and changes the sign from positive to negative. They are the locally optimal points/regions. In this case, the globally optimal point/region would be chosen between these locally optimal points/regions where the expected government revenue is maximized.

Case 2: Cooperation is only beneficial when t reaches a certain level ()In this case, the expected government revenue is as follows,

We have the following propositions.

Proposition 4. If cooperation is only beneficial when t is large enough (), is concave, and p(t) is convex or linear, there always exists a unique value of that maximizes the government revenue. This optimal value of t is determined where

Proof. From equation (24), at two polarized point ,

Because when , we have,

On the other hand, we assume that is concave and p(t) is convex or linear. Therefore, similarly to the case stated in Proposition 3, there would be a unique value of t* at which, or,

and changes the sign from positive to negative when t crosses t*.

In this case, the expected government revenue can be presented in Figure 5. Looking at this figure, we see that the curve is always below the curve . Therefore, the expected government revenue would be initially increased and then decreased in the determinant region . Because is concave and p(t) is convex or linear p(t) is convex or linear, the expected government revenue G would be uniquely maximized at point E () where , where the slope of the curve is equal to that of the curve (also equal to the slope of the curve ). When , we have , the locus G is that of . At , it reaches point A, and then, goes to point E () where the expected government revenue is maximized. After that, it is gradually downward to point B (), where the government revenue is . Beyond this point, the expected government revenue remains at because the probability of cooperation becomes unit (the taxpayer and the inspector cooperate surely).

Figure 5: The evolution of the expected government revenue in Proposition 4.

It could be easy to see that the optimal level of t is always existed in this case (cooperation is only beneficial when t is large enough). However, regarding to the uniqueness of the optimal time, there would be several cases. Beside the case in Proposition 4, there would also be the cases at which the conditions that is concave and p(t) is convex or linear are violated. The uniqueness of the optional time is dependent on the sharp of these functions. Similarly to the cases regarded above, there might be several locally optimal points/regions of t that make and the sign of changes from positive to negative. In this case, the globally optimal point/region would be chosen between these locally optimal points/regions where the expected government revenue is maximized.

Looking overall, we can see that, in general, job rotation in tax administration would have a positive effect on the expected government revenue. The optimal time for rotating is dependent on the parameters of the model. Specifically, it would be not difficult to see that it depends on the functions of the probability of cooperation,, and the inspectors probability of finding out the real income, . Regarding to the former, when this function is highly convex, the optimal time for job rotation would be lengthened. By contrast, when it becomes relatively concave, the optimal time would be shortened. By other words, the optimal length of time would be dependent on the slope of this function, the more the flatness of the function at the initial time, the higher the optimal length of time is. For a given sharp of the possibility of finding out the real income of the inspector, if the probability of cooperation is low at the beginning time, the expected government revenue will increase gradually and reach its optimal level at a relatively large t.

On the other hand, the function of probability of finding out the real income is also play an important role in determining the optimal time that the inspector should do his job with the same taxpayer. The higher the slope of the curve at the beginning time, the shorter the optimal time would be. In this case, the inspector would be able to find the real income at the beginning stage at a high probability. Therefore, the expected government revenue would be increased rapidly at the beginning stage but with a decreasing speed, and early reaches its optimal level.

I. Discussions on the framework for developing countries

Before considering the framework for applying the job rotation system in tax administration in the developing countries, we need to consider the job rotation scheme in the Japanese public finances administration system as a unique successful example in the world. Similarly to almost other Japanese government agencies, job rotations in the public finance system, including the tax administration system, have been implemented regularly. The basic time for rotation is about two years. There are usually two times for rotating officials and staffs (the director class and under) in April and July every year. The classes of higher-ranking officials are also subject to this rotation scheme, although there might be different in frequencies. The rotation system has also been designed to ensure the continuousness of works such that there are always newcomers and experienced people at the offices, relatively. The jobs/works before and after rotation might be in the same field, but it is not a rule.

It should be noted that the administrative system in Japan focus on training public servants in their practice works. After several times of rotation, they are believed to perceive a vast of knowledge and experiences concerning the fields of their agencies. There is also a distinguished feature that the rotation system usually makes the rotated people moving following upwardly oscillated orbits, from the bottom to the top of the organizations management system. Although it seems that there is no relation between job rotation and promotion, looking at the whole working-life of a public servant, it would be easy to see the relation between them, not only in positions/ranks, but also the salary levels.

For a public official who passed the Type I of National Examination for public servants and work in government agencies, so-called type I officers, he usually have the working life as follows.

Stage 1: Working at some divisions/department in the agency for around two years, and then, promoted to the section-chief level. In this stage, he is to work at the office from a position as a staff from the beginning to gain various experiences, including the mental aspect, at the lowest level in the administration system. Therefore, it would be easy for him to understand how the works are processed when he promotes to manager positions.

Stage 2: Going to abroad for studying in two years, rotated in the agency, or going to an agencys local branch. In this period, he is usually sent to study in a master course in public administration or concerned fields. In case of going to an agencys local branch, he is supposed to learn comprehensively working experiences in practice at the local level.

Stage 3: Going back to the same agency or going to other government agency, and being promoted to the rank of deputy director. In case of going to other government agency, he would be back to the initial agency after around two years for learning out-side experienced and creating connections between agencies. In this stage, he is rotated every two-year period in different divisions/ departments in the agency and faced various tasks concerning the agencys fields.

Stage 4: Promoted to the rank of director and rotated within the same agency. After around ten years of working as a deputy director in stage 3, he is promoted to the rank of director. He is also subject to rotation between different divisions in the agency at a frequency of around two years.

Stage 5: The period before retirement. As a director, after several times of rotations, he would be promoted to higher positions/ranks, or after some years of working, retired to work at some public/private companies as a member of the board of directors or as a senior advisor to the board. There is also the possibility that he would go a local finance office to resume the position as the general director.

Therefore, the typical public servant in Japan is generally a generalist, not a specialist. In recent years there have been increasing trends in job rotations between government agencies and between public and private sector. The Japanese government intends to make their administration system more flexible and efficient in a close relation with the public. However, with the system of top-down administrative orders, it would be very difficult for creating a flexible system, at least in the near future. There have been recently some issues emerging because of fast changes in the socio-economic conditions in Japan. First, as a culture of working, the system of job rotation seems to be changed little in responding to rapid changes in the environment. Under the new context of socio-economic conditions and the process of globalization, the abortion or revisions of the rotation system, especially in the frequency aspect, might be appropriate in some fields/sectors; meanwhile it is necessary to enhance or introduce in others. It is very difficult to set up a general rule for rotation, as in present system; there should be discretions over the rule. The job rotation system needs to be applied flexibly case-by-case. On the other hand, the currently seniority wage system based on the seniority of ages also needs to be changed towards or mixed with the system of wage based on the working performances/productivities. Therefore, the topic of job rotation for each field/sector should be carefully checked and revised with relevant reforms in the wage system. This is also an important issue for the process of stabilization, liberalization and development of the Japanese labor market.

For tax administration in the developing countries, it is not easy to apply the job rotation system such that the system is immediately well functioned like the Japanese case, although we know that it might play an important role in reducing tax evasion and corruption. As we noted above, one of the major disadvantages of job rotation is the difficulty in application. Based on the socio-economic conditions of developing countries, there would be three main difficulties. First, the job rotation system would face strong oppositions of tax officers and taxpayers and increases in costs of tax compliances. Regarding to tax officers, the job rotation would reduce income from corruption and cut off the deep and preferential relations with the taxpayers. Especially, for the old generation, they would protest the system even stronger because their conservative manners. There would also be social and welfare issues for the tax officers who are rotated into the jobs they do not like or they are not able to do well. For the taxpayers, they might also oppose the system because, beside the possibility of increases in the tax liability, the job rotation also means that the cost of compliance increases relatively because they face new tax officers more often and need to spend time and other concerned costs to meet their requests.

Second, there might be distortions in the management system and organizational aspects. In this aspect, there would be three main problems: (i) the allocation issue: the work of the personnel department in charge of rotating is likely to be biased. The rule of the right person in the right place would be easily violated, especially in the socio-economic conditions of the developing countries where rules seem less affective than discretions; (ii), the job evaluation system and concerning policies such as the wage policy and promotion schemes would be significantly affected; and (iii), the possibility of cooperation between the current officers and the next officers in charge of the same taxpayers. If they cooperate, there would be the issue of new bottle, old wine, and then, the effect of job rotation would be less meaning in the aspect of protecting tax evasion and corruption.

Third, it should be noted that nowhere in the world has such a wonderful socio- economic conditions like Japan so that it would be easy to introduce the system of job rotation. The social aspects concerning the rotation, such as culture of working, customs, routines, and especially, the peoples attitudes to the job rotation system would be rather stiffened. It seems not easy to change these aspects if there are not relevant measures and breakthrough explanations.

Although facing these difficulties, job rotation is believably indispensably necessary in tax administration in the developing countries because tax evasion and corruption has been becoming more and more serious in these countries. The introduction of the job rotation system would be beneficial for the economy as a whole if there is a relevant and feasibility framework in combination with a process of preparing necessary conditions for successfully introducing the system. Regarding to the feasible framework, there would be following issues that should be seriously considered.

(i) Which fields of works/jobs/regions should be rotated? It should be noted that job rotation is usually at the cost of specialization; therefore, at the beginning stage job rotation might be only suitable in the works/jobs where the level of corruption is relatively high or the jobs require less levels of specialization. The decision on the scope and regions for applying the system is also needed to consider carefully because it would be very difficult to send some tax officers living in the urban areas to do some jobs at the remote mountain areas. Rotating people within the local network would be relevant.

(ii) Who is subject to rotations? This is very important because it is impossible to rotate everyone in tax administration at the beginning. It is also very important when regarding to the aspect of the efficiency of rotations in reducing corruption. At the initial stage, it would be advisable to rotate only tax officers who are directly in charge of investigating or determining the reported income of the taxpayers because they are believably the most powerful and corruptible.

(iii) How often to rotate? This is an extremely difficult question at the initial stage of application. The optimal time would be dependent on the jobs characters, objectives, and socio-economic environments. However, the time should not be too short that would cause high costs and make the works of rotated people less effective. The frequency should be also not too long such that the possibility of cooperation between taxpayers and tax officers become relatively high.

It would also be advisable for the government that the rotation system should be applied in some pilot programs with the approach of trying, seeing, and revising. One the system is successful in the level of these pilot programs; it would be easy to multiple these positive effects to expand the application of the job rotation to the whole tax administration system as well as other relevant fields/sectors of the economy.

Regarding to the necessary conditions for applying the job rotation system, it is necessary to prepare all concerned issues carefully, especially the systems of job evaluation, wage, and promotion, the program of training concerned officials, and the attitude of the government in the process of introducing the system. First, regarding to the systems of job evaluation, wage, and promotion, it is necessary to set up new regulations concerning job rotations, especially schemes of penalties and incentives. Without a relevant system of job evaluation, the efficiency of the job rotation system would be not precisely assessed so that necessary revisions and adjustments would not be implemented. On the other hand, the issues of wage and promotion are also very important, which should be considered comprehensively along with the job evaluation system. Second, training officials to meet the requirements of job rotations is also very important. Because the system is rather new for developing countries, the concerned people in tax administration need to know well about the nature of the system and study both work-related knowledge and skills and mental aspects. This also an effective measure to avoid shocks to the rotated people because they used to do their jobs in very narrow fields. With the rotation system, they need to understand broader fields of works, which need a relevant system of training for rotation.

Finally, a strong stance of the government towards the job rotation system is very important. As presented above, the system would be strongly opposed by both the taxpayers and the tax officers, costly, and rather strange to the public at the beginning stage. Therefore, it would be not implemented successfully without a strong leadership of the government. Beside their strong stance, the government also needs to make the system clearly to the public, especially to explain its important effect on reducing corruption. Because in the developing countries, most of the people are alarmed by the popularity of corruption, one they understand the positive effect of the rotation system in reducing corruption, they would support the government to pursue the objective of introducing the job rotation in public administration in general and tax administration in particularly.

Besides, another important condition is to enhance internal control, which is considered as a foundation for enhancing accountability in the administration system. The framework of establishing and maintaining effective internal control would be very important for successfully introducing the system of job rotation. There is also another aspect should be noted. The job rotation system would change the ways of working and thinking of jobs and careers of public servants. It would also affect the working environment, relation and culture. Therefore, it would take time to introduce and adjust. The introduction of the system would be only successful when its advantages and positive effects on the economy finally recognized by a large number of the people. When introducing successfully in the public sector, the prospect for the private sector to apply the job system would be also opened. For the small- and medium enterprises, it might be not necessary to introduce the system. However, for the large firms and organizations, the system of job rotation would be necessary and important due to its noted advantages, especially positive effects on career development, productivity, flexibility, and reductions in working stresses, among others.

II. Conclusion

In the developing world nowadays, preventing and protecting tax evasion and corruption in the tax administration have been become one of the most important tasks for both policy-makers and economists. Based on the stylized facts of these economies, we analyzed the effect of job rotation in reducing corruption in a simple model of tax compliance for developing countries with the assumption that the tax inspectors probability of finding out tax evasion and the probability of cooperation between the taxpayer and the inspector are functions of the time that the inspector works with the same taxpayer. In this framework, the time would have two distinct effects on tax compliance. On the one hand, the time would make the expected government revenue increasing because the possibility of finding out tax evasion increases along with the time. On the other hand, the probability of cooperation between the taxpayer and the inspector also increase as the time increases, which would reduce the expected government revenue. The solution of this trade-off relation would be the optimal level of the time where the positive revenue effect is offset by the negative cooperation effect. This theoretical model clearly illustrates the superiority of job rotation to reduce tax evasion and corruption in tax administration in the developing countries. The idea of considering the job rotation system in the framework of tax evasion and corruption is the distinguished feature of the theoretical model developed in this paper because job rotation and tax evasion corruption have been usually considered as two separate topics in the recent economic literature. Job rotation is usually considered in the context of industrial organization at the firm level; the relation of job rotation and corruption has been rarely discussed. On the other hand, in the literature on tax compliance, most of studies concentrated on analyzing aspects of tax burden, penalties, and incentives.

It should also be noted that the theoretical framework in this paper might be widely extended in the manner that introductions of working efforts of tax inspectors, honest and dishonest taxpayers and inspectors, and changes in assumptions and parameters would have no significant effects on the results and arguments of the model the job rotation system would still have a positive effect in reducing tax evasion and corruption, especially in the condition of much biased and distorted information and difficulties in socio economic conditions in the developing countries. In this paper, we restrained analyses in the case that job rotation would reduce the inspectors probability of finding out the real income. However, when this restraint is lifted, it is even more beneficial for the government to introduce the system in tax administration. In the field of tax investigations, rob rotation might also enhance the working proficiency of the inspectors in some cases. Among others, one of the most possible cases is that there would be heterogeneous taxpayers with different types of income in an economy with asymmetric information. The taxpayers structure of income is changed rapidly such that a rotated inspector with a vast of experiences concerning investigations of these types of income would do his job better than a non-rotated inspector who are specialized in specific taxpayers.

We also discussed the framework for applying the job rotation system in tax administration in the developing countries. It is clear that it would be not easy to apply the system in the developing countries because of difficulties and obstacles in the socio-economic conditions in these countries, although we know its positive effect in reducing tax evasion and corruption. The job rotation system in the Japanese administration is very important for the developing countries when considering the system to introduce because it has been quite successful and stable. However, the socio-economic conditions in the developing countries are much different from that in Japan. Therefore, it is necessary to make careful considerations on possible difficulties in introducing the system, build the feasibly framework, and prepare necessary conditions for the process of implementation in order to make the job rotation system feasible and efficient in tax administration in these countries.

References

Acconcia, A., DAmato,M., and Martina, R., 2003, Tax Evasion and Corruption in Tax Administration, Mimeo, University of Napoli FedericoII, Italy.

Aoki, M., 1990, Toward an Economic Model of the Japanese Firm, Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 28, 1-27.

Allingham, M. , and Sandmo , A., 1972, Income Tax Evasion: A Theoretical Analysis, Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 1, 323-38.

Asher, M., 2001, Design of Tax Systems and Corruption, Conference on Fighting Corruption: Common Challenges and Shared Experiences organized by the Konard Adenauer Stiftung, and the Institute of International Affairs (SIIA) Singapore, 10 ~ 11 May 2001Bardhan, P., 1997, Corruption and development: a review of issues, Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 35, 13201346.Besley, T., and McLaren, J., 1993, Taxes and Bribery: the Role of Wage Incentives, Economic Journal, Vol. 103,119-41.

Buchanan, B., 1974, Building Organizational Commitment: the Socialization of Managers in Work Organizations, Administrative Science Quarterly, Vol. 19, 533-46.Campion, M., and Cheraskin, Lisa, 1994, Career-Related Antecedents and Outcomes of Job Rotation, Academy of Management Journal, Vol. 37, 6, 1518-43.

Chander, P., and Wilde, L., 1992, Corruption in Tax Administration, Journal of Public Economics , 49:333349.

Cho, I., and Kreps, D., 1987, Signaling Games and Stable Equilibria, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. CII, 179221.

Cho, I., and Sobel, J, 1990, Strategic Stability and Uniqueness in Signaling Games. Journal of Economic Theory, Vol. 50, 381-413.

Cosgel, M., and Miceli, T., 1998, On Job Rotation, University of Connecticut, Department of Economics Working Papers, 1998-02.

Cosgel, M., and Miceli, T, 1999, "Job Rotation: Costs, Benefits and Stylized Facts." Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, Vol. 155, pp. 301-20.Das-Guppta, A., Engelschalk, M., Mayville, W., 1999, An Anticorruption Strategy for Revenue Administration, PREM Notes (Worlbanks Poverty Reductions and Economic Management Network), No. 33.

Dutton, R., 1987, The Japanese Manager: the Coordinator of the Network, Business Forum/Spring 1987, 21-24.

Fisman, R., and Svensson, J., 2002, Are Corruption and Taxation Really Harmful to Growth? Firm Level Evidence, Mimeo, Columbia Business School.

Gill, J, 2000, A Dianogstic Framework for Revenue Administration, World Bank Technical Paper 472, the World Bank.

Gittleman, M., Horrigan, M., Joyce,M., 1998, Flexible Workplace Practices: Evidence from a National Representative Survey, Industrial Labor Relation Review, Vol. 52, 1, 99-115.

Guthrie, J, and Olian, J., 1991, Does Context Affect Staffing Decisions? the Case of General Managers, Personnel Psychology, Vol. 44, 263-92.

Hazzard, L., Mautz, J., Wrightsman, D., 1992, Job Rotation Cuts Cumulative Trauma Cases, Personnel Journal, Vol. 71, 29-32Hellman, J., Jones, G., Kaufmamn, D., Schankerman, M., 2000, How Firms and Bureaucrats Shape the Business Environment in Transition Economies, Policy Research Working Paper 2312, the Work Bank.Hindriks, J., Keen, M., and Muthoo, A., 1999, Corruption, Extortion and Evasion, Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 74, 395-430.

Jovannovic, B, 1979, Job Matching and the Theory of Turnover, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 87, 6, 972-990.

Jones, G, 1986, Socialization Tactics, Self-Efficacy, and Newcomers' Adjustments to Organizations, Academy of Management Journal, Vol. 29, 262-79.

Kaufmann, D., 1997, Corruption: The Facts, Foreign Policy, Summer 1997

Kaufman, F., and Lawaree, 1993, Collusion in Hierarchical Agency, Econometrica, Vol. 61, 629-56.

Kreps, D. M., and R. Wilson. (1982). Sequential equilibria. Econometrica, 50:863894.

Koike, K., 1984, Skill Formation Systems in the U. S. and Japan: A Comparative Study in M. Aoki (ed.), The Economic Analysis of the Japanese Firm, North Holland: Amsterdam, 47-75.

Kindra, G., and Stapenhurst, R., 1998, Social Marketing Strategies to Fight Corruption, The Economic Development Institute of the World BankKuroda, A., 2001, The wage-labour system in Japan, the effect of globalization, ERC/METU International Conference 2001Kusunoki, K., and Numagami, T., 1998. "Interfunctional Transfers of Engineers in Japan: Empirical Findings and Implications for Cross Sectional Integration." IEEE Transactions on Engineering Management, Vol. 45, No. 3, 250-62.

Lehtinen, K., and Lehtinen, P., 2001, Job Rotation European Models, JobRotation International AssociationsLondon, M.,1983, Toward a Theory of Career Motivation, Academy of Management Review, Vol. 8, 620-30.

MacLeod, D, Kennedy, E, 1993, Job Rotation System: Report to XYZ Co., Dan MacLeod Ergonomics website, http://www.danmacleod.com/Miller, R., 1984, Job Matching and Occupational Choice, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 92, 6, 1086-1120.

Mookherjee, D., and Png, I., 1995, Corruptible Law Enforcers: How Should They Be Compensated, Economic Journal, Vol. 105, 145-59.

Morrison, R., and Brantner, T., 1992, What Enhances or Inhibits Learning a New Job? A Basic Career Issue, Journal of Applied Psychology, Vol.77, 926-40.

Mourdoukoutas, P., and Roy, U., 1994, Job Rotation and Public Policy: Theory with Applications to Japan and the USA, International Journal of Manpower, Vol. 15, 6, 57-71.

Ortega, J, 2001, Job Rotation as a Learning Mechanism, Management Science, Vol. 47, 10, 1361-70.

Ostroff, C., Kozlowski, S., 1992, Organizational Socialization as a Learning Process: The Role of Information Acquisition, Personnel Psychology, Vol. 45, 849-74.

Ouchi, W., 1981, Theory Z: How American Business Can Meet the Japanese Challenge, Reading, Addison-Wesley, MA.

Polinsky, A., and Shavell, S., 2001, Corruption and Optimal Law Enforcement, Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 81, 1-24.

Rose-Ackerman, S., 1997, High-Level Rent Seeking and Corruption in African Regimes: Theory and Cases, WB Working Paper WPS 1780, the World BankSanchez, I., and Sobel, J., 1993, Hierarchical Design and Enforcement of Income Tax Policies, Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 50, 345-69.

Shleifer, A., and Wishny, R., 1993, Corruption, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 108, 599-617.

Sonnenfeld, J., Peiperl, M., 1988, Staffing Policy as a Strategic Response: A Typology of Career Systems, Academy of Management Review, Vol. 13, 588-600.

Triggs, D., and King, P., 2000, Job Rotation - An Administrative Strategy for Hazard Control, Professional Safety, February 2000.

Tirole, J., 1986, Hierarchies and Bureaucracies: on the Role of Collusion in Organizations, Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, Vol. 2, 181-214.

Transparency International, 2003, Global Corruption Report 2003, the Transparency International

Wane, W., 2002, Tax Evasion, Corruption, and Remuneration of Heterogeneous Inspectors, WB Working Paper WPS 2394, the World Bank.World Bank, 2000, Helping Countries Combat Corruption, Poverty Reduction and Economic Management (PREM) Network, The World Bank. EMBED Equation.3

EMBED Equation.3

EMBED Equation.3

EMBED Equation.3

EMBED Equation.3

EMBED Equation.3

EMBED Equation.3

EMBED Equation.3

EMBED Equation.3

EMBED Equation.3

EMBED Equation.3

EMBED Equation.3

EMBED Equation.3

EMBED Equation.3

EMBED Equation.3

EMBED Equation.3

EMBED Equation.3

EMBED Equation.3

EMBED Equation.3

EMBED Equation.3

EMBED Equation.3

EMBED Equation.3

EMBED Equation.3

EMBED Equation.3

EMBED Equation.3

EMBED Equation.3

EMBED Equation.3

EMBED Equation.3

EMBED Equation.3

EMBED Equation.3

EMBED Equation.3

EMBED Equation.3

EMBED Equation.3

EMBED Equation.3

EMBED Equation.3

EMBED Equation.3

EMBED Equation.3

EMBED Equation.3

EMBED Equation.3

EMBED Equation.3

EMBED Equation.3

EMBED Equation.3

EMBED Equation.3

EMBED Equation.3

EMBED Equation.3

EMBED Equation.3

EMBED Equation.3

EMBED Equation.3

EMBED Equation.3

EMBED Equation.3

EMBED Equation.3

( The author would like to thank Hosen Mitsuo, Kashiwagi Shigeo, Mutoh Shizuki, Satoh Masayuki, Kuzumi Masayuki, and other members participating in a workshop on tax policy and administration in developing countries at the Policy Research Institute of the Ministry of Finance, Japan. He is also grateful to Ukai Yukio from the National Personnel Authority and Shimazaki Masao from the Ministry of Finance Secretariat for providing useful information on the job rotation scheme in the Japanese administration system. The views expressed in this paper are, however, those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the views of affiliated institutions.

See Global Corruption Report 2003 (Transparency International (2003). Also see Bardhan (1997), Rose-Ackerman (1997), Hellman et al. (2000).

Also Campion and Cheraskin (1994).

For theoretical models of tax evasion and corruption, in general, see Besley and McLaren (1993), Hindriks et al. (1999), Polinsky and Shavel (2001), among others.

See Aoki (1990) and Campion and Cheraskin (1994). It is also necessary to recognize the European style of job rotation, which focuses on training employees (off-the-job training) and pre- training for the unemployed to work as substitutes (See Lehtinen and Lehtinen (2001)).

Also see Buchanan (1974) and Jones (1986).

Gittleman et al. (1998) showed the probability of job rotation is 22.3 percent for the firms introducing technology (compared with the average ratio of 9.6 percent) in a sample if over 5,800 US firms in all industries in 1993.

See Hazzard et al. (1992), Triggs and King (2000), among others. It should be noted that Cosgel and Miceli (1998) considered an organization model of analyzing costs and benefits of job rotation and recognized the importance of job satisfaction and attributes.

Also see Koike (1984), Aoki (1990), among others. For recent empirical studies on job rotation in Japan and US, see Kusunoki and Numagami (1998) and Campion and Cheraskin (1994)

It should also be noted that, as showed in the study of Mourdoukoutas and Roy (1994), job rotation is higher in Japan than in the US partly because anticipatory job mobility is higher in Japan than in the US, due to the fact that the culture and labor policy in Japan encourages anticipatory job rotation, meanwhile the US labor policy provides assistances after an employees lost his job.

Also see Shleifer and Wishny (1993), Wane (2002), Acconcia et al. (2003)

The results that the expected government revenues might be reduced when there are increases in the fine rate or the tax rate can be also seen in Graetz et al. (1986), Chander and Wilde (1992), among others.

Regarding to the solution and distribution of premium from engaging in tax corruption, as in most of the literature on corruption, the bribe the taxpayer pays the inspector is the solution of a Nash bargain and they mutually agree to report the income that maximizes their joint profit (Kreps and Wilson (1982), Cho and Sobel (1990)).

Also see Kaufman (1997), Gill (2000), Asher (2001), Fisman, R., and Svensson (2002)

The tax rate might be varied, as a function of income. However, for simplicity, we assume that the tax rate is flat. The case of varied tax rates would have no significant impact on the results of the model. Furthermore, excluding the individual income tax, most types of taxes, such as the corporate income tax, are usually flat-rated taxes.

There would be also the case of considering the inspectors effort; however, we assume that it is given in order to concentrate on analyzing the times effects. The case concerning the inspectors effort can be analyzed by introducing a variable of inspectors effort in this function. However, the results of the model would not be changed significantly.

We can also examine the case when the limit of time for surely finding the real income is shorter than that for surely cooperating ( EMBED Equation.3 ). At some certain level of the gap between these two limits, the results of the model would not be changed.

We also assume that there is no relation betweens the auditing agency and the inspector and taxpayer so that they are well functioned: there would be not further bargaining processes.

Also see Choo and Krep (1987), Hindriks et al. (1999).

From now, we assume that EMBED Equation.3 . The case of EMBED Equation.3 can be similarly described without significant effects on the results.

It should be noted that this possibility happens only when p(t) is relatively concave. In fact, this function is rarely relatively concave. However, we discuss here to ensure the comprehensiveness of the model.

For the case of type II and type III officers who passed the Types II and III of National Examination for public servants, they are also usually rotated to different jobs in the same or different offices in the agency, and also subject to promotion up to the rank of deputy director.

Also see Kuroda (2001).

Also see Das-Guppta et al. (1999), WB (2000), Gill (2000), Asher (2001).

Also see Kindra and Stapenhurst (1998).

PAGE 5

_1132398114.unknown

_1132399627.unknown

_1132399811.unknown

_1132485390.unknown

_1132485584.unknown

_1132759457.unknown

_1132993166.unknown

_1132485601.unknown

_1132485867.unknown

_1132485480.unknown

_1132400968.unknown

_1132401132.unknown

_1132402759.unknown

_1132483521.unknown

_1132400992.unknown

_1132400351.unknown

_1132400817.unknown

_1132400081.unknown

_1132399715.unknown

_1132399750.unknown

_1132399793.unknown

_1132399727.unknown

_1132399738.unknown

_1132399640.unknown

_1132399646.unknown

_1132399633.unknown

_1132399108.unknown

_1132399517.unknown

_1132399571.unknown

_1132399580.unknown

_1132399538.unknown

_1132399160.unknown

_1132399199.unknown

_1132399377.unknown

_1132399130.unknown

_1132399018.unknown

_1132399070.unknown

_1132399088.unknown

_1132399061.unknown

_1132398991.unknown

_1132399005.unknown

_1132398158.unknown

_1131963538.unknown

_1132233139.unknown

_1132318253.unknown

_1132321939.unknown

_1132322749.unknown

_1132323118.unknown

_1132398075.unknown

_1132323131.unknown

_1132322795.unknown

_1132322402.unknown

_1132322576.unknown

_1132322595.unknown

_1132322543.unknown

_1132322383.unknown

_1132321062.unknown

_1132321100.unknown

_1132319843.unknown

_1132320933.unknown

_1132321000.unknown

_1132319894.unknown

_1132319817.unknown

_1132234787.unknown

_1132240731.unknown

_1132317858.unknown

_1132317938.unknown

_1132318012.unknown

_1132242238.unknown

_1132317694.unknown

_1132242221.unknown

_1132235738.unknown

_1132236061.unknown

_1132237977.unknown

_1132236015.unknown

_1132235456.unknown

_1132233309.unknown

_1132233438.unknown

_1132233287.unknown

_1131969583.unknown

_1132042367.unknown

_1132042766.unknown

_1132158580.unknown

_1132042421.unknown

_1131971055.unknown

_1132041803.unknown

_1132041844.unknown

_1132041900.unknown

_1132041517.unknown

_1131970092.unknown

_1131968904.unknown

_1131968922.unknown

_1131964850.unknown

_1131965158.unknown

_1131968842.unknown

_1131964891.unknown

_1131964064.unknown

_1131898644.unknown

_1131957957.unknown

_1131958388.unknown

_1131958459.unknown

_1131958382.unknown

_1131956694.unknown

_1131957401.unknown

_1131957946.unknown

_1131956990.unknown

_1131900857.unknown

_1131900938.unknown

_1131900880.unknown

_1131900802.unknown

_1131900821.unknown

_1131793660.unknown

_1131880510.unknown

_1131886414.unknown

_1131893727.unknown

_1131895076.unknown

_1131895827.unknown

_1131896856.unknown

_1131894542.unknown

_1131894390.unknown

_1131894361.unknown

_1131887783.unknown

_1131888787.unknown

_1131893643.unknown

_1131889258.unknown

_1131888071.unknown

_113188