UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND...

53
UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN JOHN M. OLIN CENTER FOR LAW & E CONOMICS THE ELUSIVE B OUNDARY B ETWEEN COST -B ASED AND B ENEFIT-B ASED L IABILITY IN P RIVATE L AW OMRI BEN-SHAHAR ROBERT MIKOS WORKING PAPER #01-004 THIS PAPER CAN BE DOWNLOADED WITHOUT CHARGE AT : MICHIGAN J OHN M. OLIN CENTER WEBSITE HTTP :// WWW.LAW .UMICH. EDU/ CENTERSANDPROGRAMS / OLIN/ PAPERS .HTM

Transcript of UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND...

Page 1: UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University

UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN

JOHN M. OLIN CENTER FOR LAW & ECONOMICS

THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW

OMRI BEN-SHAHAR

ROBERT MIKOS

WORKING PAPER #01-004

THIS PAPER CAN BE DOWNLOADED WITHOUT CHARGE AT :

MICHIGAN JOHN M. OLIN CENTER WEBSITE HTTP://WWW.LAW .UMICH.EDU/CENTERSANDPROGRAMS/OLIN/PAPERS.HTM

Page 2: UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University

March 2003

THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW

Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University of Michigan Law School

Ann Arbor, MI 48109 (734) 763-4608

__________________________________________________________ ∗ Ben-Shahar is a Professor of Law and Economics, University of Michigan Law School ([email protected]); Mikos is the John M. Olin Faculty Fellow in Law and Economics, University of Michigan Law School ([email protected]). We would like to thank Hanoch Dagan, Tomotaka Fujita, Alon Harel, Jim Krier, Andrew Kull, Ariel Porat and workshop participants at Michigan, Stanford, Yale, and the ALEA 2001 Meeting in Georgetown for helpful comments. Financial support from the John M. Olin Center for Law and Economics at the University of Michigan Law School is gratefully acknowledged.

Page 3: UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University

THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW

ABSTRACT

Private law is replete with instances in which an investing party can recover from the investment’s beneficiaries, even in the absence of a contract. In some contexts, recovery is measured by the benefit from the investment, while in other contexts recovery is measured by the investment’s cost. Previous scholarship has shown that either benefit-based or cost-based recovery can provide optimal incentives to invest. However, this article demonstrates that, in practice, the law often awards recovery that is neither purely benefit-based nor purely cost-based. Under one “hybrid” approach, an investing party can recover the greater of the benefit enjoyed by the beneficiary or the cost of the investment. Under a second hybrid approach, the investing party can recover only the lesser of these two measures. Both hybrid approaches distort incentives to invest. After examining some important legal doctrines that employ the hybrid approaches, the article considers seve ral economic and non-economic purposes motivating their use, but argues that the hybrid approaches are at best poorly suited for these purposes. Even more troubling, the Article suggests that the hybrid approaches are sometimes employed inadvertently, due to an inability or unwillingness to conceptually distinguish between cost-based and benefit-based measures of recovery.

Page 4: UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University

COST-BASED VERSUS BENEFIT-BASED

1

INTRODUCTION

Private parties often make investments that benefit others. Such investments are usually made under contract with the beneficiaries. The contract determines the investing party’s right to recover and the measure of that recovery. Sometimes, however, a party considering making an investment is unable to contract with its potential beneficiaries. In these situations, the investing party must rely upon the law to create an obligation on the part of others to pay for the service.

Indeed, private law is replete with doctrines enabling an investing party to recover in the absence of contract. For example, a co-owner may recoup the costs of repairs she makes to co-owned property, and a doctor may recover a fee for treating an unconscious accident victim. In measuring the recovery, the law normally utilizes one of two approaches. In some instances, recovery is measured by the benefit from the investment: the obligor has to pay in accordance with the actual benefit she enjoyed. In other instances, recovery is measured by the investment’s cost. A great deal of legal order has been created along this cost versus benefit distinction. 1 For example, the law of torts defines obligations that are cost-based, whereas the law of restitution defines obligations that are benefit-based.

The allowance for recovery in the absence of contract has been rationalized from an economic (that is, incentive-oriented) perspective.2 In particular, the right to recover has been defended on the grounds that it encourages parties to make desirable investments that are otherwise difficult to contract over. This paper does not directly take issue with the economic literature demonstrating the desirability of imposing liability in such circumstances. Rather, it explores a systematic and puzzling inconsistency in the law that determines the magnitude of liability. It exposes common scenarios in which a conceptual confusion arises concerning the measure of recovery—cost versus benefit—and the resulting distortion in the magnitude of liability. __________________________________________________________ 1 P.S. ATIYAH, THE RISE AND FALL OF FREEDOM OF CONTRACT 149-152, 184-189 (1979).

2 William Landes and Richard Posner, Salvors, Good Samaritans, and Other Rescuers: An Economic Study of Law and Altruism, 7 J. LEG. STUD. 83 (1978); see also Saul Levmore, Explaining Restitution , 71 VA . L. REV. 65 (1985).

Page 5: UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University

COST-BASED VERSUS BENEFIT-BASED

2

The common situation in which this inconsistency arises when one party makes a costly investment that is expected to yield an uncertain benefit to another party. This is an investment that confers a chance, or probabilistic value, as opposed to certain benefit. Examples are abundant: owners of land make investments to repair or improve co-owned property that might, but are not certain to, increase the market value of the property; insured parties take precautions that might, but are not certain to, reduce the losses that their insurers have to cover; attorneys pursue legal actions that might result in favorable judgments or settlements for their clients. By the time the law has to determine the recovery ex-post, the actual benefit—or lack thereof—becomes known and (usually) can be verified by the court.

If the investing party is entitled to recover, it might be expected that courts would measure the recovery either on the basis of the recipient’s benefit, or on the basis of the investor’s costs. The benefit-based measure would depend on (and is potentially equal to) the benefit that in fact materialized. This is an ex-post recovery regime: the investing party will enjoy a high recovery when the court observes that the benefit is high, and a low recovery when the court observes a low benefit. The cost-based measure, alternatively, would not depend on any ex-post realization of benefit. Instead, and irrespective of whether the actual benefit is high or low, this measure would award a recovery that is fixed, equal to the average benefit, usually approximated by the reasonable cost of the investment. Under either the benefit-based or the cost-based regimes, appropriately tuned, the investment would be taken if and only if it is cost-justified.

It turns out, however, that in many circumstances, the law takes neither a pure benefit-based nor a pure cost-based approach to measuring recovery. Instead, it often uses one of two “hybrid” recovery approaches. Under one approach, the investing party can recover either the ex-post benefit enjoyed by the beneficiary, or the cost of the investment, and can elect the greater of the two. This approach, which we label the “greater-of” regime, permits the investing party to recover the full benefit when it is high, or recover the cost of the investment when the benefit is low (or zero). The expected recovery under this approach is greater—potentially far greater—than the expected benefit of the investment, creating excessive incentives to invest.

Under a second hybrid approach, which we label the “lesser-of”

Page 6: UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University

COST-BASED VERSUS BENEFIT-BASED

3

regime, the investing party can again recover either the ex-post benefit enjoyed by the beneficiary, or the cost of the investment, but this time she is limited to the lesser of the two. The investing party can effectively recover the full benefit only when it is low; when the benefit turns out to be high, recovery is capped at the cost of the investment. The expected recovery under this approach is lower than the expected benefit of the investment, creating insufficient incentives to invest.

For example, consider a party who invests in a project potentially adding value to a neighbor’s land, in a setting that gives rise to a restitutionary right of recovery. A benefit-based regime would set the recovery equal to the actual enhancement value enjoyed by the neighbor. A cost-based regime would set the recovery equal to the cost of the investment, if it is adjudged reasonable. A greater-of regime would permit the investing party to recover the full benefit when the enhancement value is high, and recover her costs when the enhancement value is low. Section II.E of the paper will demonstrate that this is a recovery strategy available to investing co-owners under the repairs and improvements doctrine in property law. Lastly, a lesser-of regime would limit the investing party to recovering the full benefit when this benefit is low and only her costs when the benefit is high. Section II.F of the paper will demonstrate that this is the recovery schedule available to mistaken improvers under the Restatement of Restitution.

The distortion this article attributes to the hybrid recovery regimes can be further illustrated with a lottery metaphor. Suppose party A owns a lottery ticket which provides a 1% chance of winning $1000, and a 99% chance of winning 0. The ex-ante value of such a ticket—its actuarial cost—is $10. Party A mistakenly loses her lottery ticket at party B’s home and discovers the loss after the lottery draw was announced. Under the pure benefit-based recovery regime, party A can recover from party B either 0 or $1000, depending on the ticket’s actual draw. Under the pure cost-based recovery regime, party A can recover the ex-ante value, or the cost of the ticket, $10, independent of the actual draw. The expected recovery under both regimes is $10, correctly reflecting the value of the ticket at the time it was lost. Consider, in contrast, the two hybrid approaches described above. Under the greater-of approach, party A can recover $1000 if the ticket wins, and can recover $10 if the ticket’s draw is 0. The expected recovery is approximately $20, twice the ex-ante expected value of the ticket (the ticket is worth more if lost;

Page 7: UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University

COST-BASED VERSUS BENEFIT-BASED

4

party A would have an incentive to lose it!). Under the lesser-of approach, party A can recover only $10 if the ticket wins, and recover 0 when the ticket’s draw is 0. The expected recovery is 10 cents, well below the ex-ante expected value of the ticket.

The theoretical argument advanced by this article is straightforward. Regimes that set the recovery to equal the greater of the ex-post and the ex-ante values of the investment provide excessive recovery, thereby creating excessive incentives to invest; regimes that limit the recovery to the lesser of the ex-post and the ex-ante values of the investment provide too little recovery and create insufficient incentives to invest. This is an argument about a distortion arising from internal inconsistency within a recovery regime. A rule that shifts from a cost-based to a benefit-based measure of recovery according to the magnitude of the benefit that randomly materializes distorts the expected recovery. Whichever recovery criterion is applied, it should be applied consistently, across the different possible realizations of the benefit.3 Put differently, the analysis in this article identifies a problem of boundaries in the law of obligations. It demonstrates that the distinction between benefit-based and cost-based obligations—a fundamental distinction in private law—is more elusive than previously recognized. On the interface between these two types of obligations, systematic confusion arises, giving rise to hybrid and distortive rules of liability.

After developing this theoretical argument in Section I of the article, the analysis turns to a more interesting and challenging two-fold task. First, we hope to demonstrate that hybrid regimes are not merely an esoteric phenomenon. Accordingly, Section II of the paper surveys prominent recovery doctrines in the law of contracts, property, __________________________________________________________ 3 By now, there is a substantial literature analyzing the optimal recovery when uncertainty over some value (of, say, the harm or the benefit) exis ts at the time of trial . For example, a prominent branch of this literature examines whether courts should resolve this uncertainty by accurately verifying the random value, or restrict their attention to “averages” based on the ex-ante distribution of the value. See, e.g., Louis Kaplow and Steven Shavell, Accuracy in the Assessment of Damages, 39 J. L. & ECON. 191 (1996). This paper, in contrast, focuses on uncertainty that existed at the time when the costly action was taken, but that is (usually) fully resolved by the time of trial. As we hope to show, the initial randomness—when unrecognized by courts ex-post—leads them to apply recovery criteria that are inconsistent across the various possible realizations of value.

Page 8: UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University

COST-BASED VERSUS BENEFIT-BASED

5

restitution, litigation, and taxation, demonstrating that in many instances in which investments yield probabilistic benefits, the law in fact employ variants of the greater-of or lesser-of approaches to recovery.

Once the prevalence of hybrid regimes is established, and the contexts in which they arise is understood, the analysis turns to the second part of the task, which is to explain why the hybrid approaches are used so frequently in the law, despite the obvious distortions they create. This inquiry is developed in Section III. It begins by reviewing the economic and non-economic purposes commonly cited for the use of hybrid approaches in practice. It demonstrates that the adjustment in recovery embodied in the hybrid approaches cannot readily serve these purposes. Further, this Section suggests that courts occasionally employ hybrid rules inadvertently, due to problems of information and of drawing boundaries between related causes of action. The paper concludes by offering a possible interpretation of the analysis.

I. A SIMPLE MODEL OF RECOVERY FOR PROBABILISTIC BENEFIT

A. The Framework of Analysis

Suppose that party A can spend a cost C that would yield a random benefit to party B (and 0 benefit to party A). For simplicity and without loss of generality, assume that the benefit to party B might be either high or low, with the high benefit denoted by V and the low benefit fixed at 0. The exogenous probabilities of V and 0 are p and 1−p, respectively. Assume also that the parties are both risk-neutral and are unable to form a contract governing this investment. (Some of these assumptions are relaxed in the discussions of various legal doctrines below.)

From a social point of view, it is desirable for A to spend C if and only if:

C ≤ pV. Party A’s private decision whether to incur C would depend, however, on the legal regime governing her right to recover for her efforts. B. The Pure Benefit-Based and Cost-Based Regimes

Under the benefit-based recovery regime, party A can recover the

Page 9: UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University

COST-BASED VERSUS BENEFIT-BASED

6

full benefit conferred upon party B. Thus, party A can recover V with probability p and 0 otherwise, for an expected recovery of pV. Party A will invest if and only if C ≤ pV, which is socially optimal. 4

Under the cost-based regime, party A’s recovery is independent of the realization of benefit, and equals the ex-ante value of her investment. We consider two versions of an ex-ante regime. In theory, a “pure” ex-ante regime is one in which the measure of recovery is the average, or expected benefit pV. If party A is entitled to recover pV regardless of the realization of benefit, she will invest if and only if C ≤ pV, which guarantees socially optimal investment. The more practically significant version of the ex-ante regime is the pure cost-based regime, in which the recovery is equal to party A’s cost of investment, C. To guarantee that party A will invest C only when socially optimal, recovery should be conditional on C ≤ pV, namely, on the cost being “reasonable.” Like the benefit-based regime, the cost-based regime generates optimal incentives to exert effort.5 C. The Hybrid Regimes

1. The greater-of regime Under one type of hybrid regime, the greater-of regime, party A

receives the ex-post benefit measure when the realization of benefit is high, and receives her cost when the realization of benefit is low. Thus, __________________________________________________________ 4 Other hypothetical “ex-post”, or benefit-based recovery rules which make recovery dependent on—but not exactly equal to—the actual benefit, still provide optimal incentives, as long as the expected recovery equals the expected benefit. For example, in the dichotomous benefit distribution of {V,0}, optimal incentives are provided under an entire family of “m-recovery rules”, under which, for all m = 1, party A can recover mV from a fraction 1/m of the V-type beneficiaries, and 0 otherwise. The expected recovery under such rules is again pV. The m multiplier can represent, for example, a recovery enhancement in situations where the likelihood of successful suit is only 1/m. See, e.g., A. Mitchell Polinsky and Steven Shavell, Punitive Damages: An Economic Analysis, 111 HARV. L. REV. 869 (1998).

5 Whether benefit-based approach is superior to the cost-based approach (e.g., for reasons of fairness, information and administration costs, or risk) is beyond the scope of this analysis. See, e.g., A. Mitchell Polinsky and Steven Shavell, Should Liability Be Based on the Harm to the Victim or the Gain to the Injurer? , 10 J. L. ECON. & ORG. 427 (1994); Louis Kaplow, The Value of Accuracy in Adjudication: An Economic Analysis, 23 J. LEG. STUD. 307 (1994).

Page 10: UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University

COST-BASED VERSUS BENEFIT-BASED

7

party A receives a recovery of V when the benefit is V and receives a recovery of C when the benefit is 0. Party A’s net expected recovery is:

pV + (1 − p) C - C = p(V − C),

which is greater than pV – C, the net social gain from investment, for all p < 1. Party A will over invest: whenever pV < C ≤ V, party A will invest although it is too costly from a social point of view. Intuitively, the distortion in this case arises from the fact that, with some likelihood, the investing party will externalize her cost. If a high benefit occurs, the investing party internalizes both the cost and the benefit; but if the benefit is low, the cost of the investment is externalized.6

Another way to view the valuation distortion occurring under the greater-of regime is to recognize the option value incorporated in this recovery scheme. The greater-of regime is equivalent to a benefit-based regime compounded by a put option for party A – an option to “sell” the benefit for C. If the ex-post value arising from the investment falls below C, party A will exercise the option and receive C; and if the ex-post value realizes above C, party A will not exercise the option and will receive instead the full ex-post value, V. This option perspective suggests that the value of the greater-of approach to party A depends on factors similar to those that affect option prices. For example, the greater the variance of the distribution of benefits, the more valuable is the option;7 and the longer the time period that party A can wait before exercising the __________________________________________________________ 6 A similar distortion arises when the ex-ante measure of recovery equals pV, rather than C. In this case, a greater-of regime entitles party A to recover the actual benefit or the expected benefit whichever is higher. Accordingly, party A’s expected recovery under this hybrid rule is pV + (1 − p )pV = pV (2 − p), which exceeds the expected social benefit, pV, whenever p < 1.

7 For example, consider a perturbation of the benefit values to {a, V-b} for some small a,b, such that the mean of the distribution remains unchanged, pV (namely, if the probability of the high value V-b remains p, b = a[p/(1-p)]. For this reduced-variance distribution, the expected net recovery under the greater-of regime is p(V-a )+(1-p)C – C = p(V-C) – pa, which is smaller (by an amount pa) than the expected recovery under the higher-variance distribution. The smaller the variance (a higher a), the lower the expected net recovery.

Page 11: UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University

COST-BASED VERSUS BENEFIT-BASED

8

option (namely, until filing a suit), the more valuable is the option. 8

2. The lesser-of regime Under the lesser-of hybrid regime, party A receives the ex-post

benefit when the realization of benefit is low, but receives only her cost when the realization of benefit is high. Thus, party A receives a recovery of 0 when the benefit is 0 and a recovery of C when the benefit is V. Under the lesser-of regime, party A’s expected net recovery is:

pC + (1 – p)0 – C = –(1 – p)C,

which is less than pV – C, the social gain from investment, for all p > 0. The lesser-of regime generates insufficient incentives to invest: whenever 0 ≤ C ≤ pV, party A will not invest although the investment is socially desirable. Intuitively, the under- investment arises from the fact that the investing party internalizes the entire cost but does not get to enjoy the entire benefit.9 Here, as in the greater-of regime, the magnitude of the distortion is equal to the value of an option, this time a call option given to party B, to “buy” the benefit at a price of C. If the ex-post benefit realizes above C, party B will exercise the option and pay only C; and if the ex-post benefit realizes below C, party B will not exercise the option and instead will pay the benefit. The value of this option is the amount by which party A is under-compensated. D. Extension: Probabilistic Costs

The analysis thus far has focused on investments with probabilistic benefits and certain costs. We now consider the opposite __________________________________________________________ 8 This effect of the timing of the suit on the expected value of recovery is recognized in a similar context in Thomas Jackson, Anticipatory Repudiation and the Temporal Element of Contract Law: An Economic Inquiry into Contract Damages in Cases of Prospective Nonperformance, 31 STAN. L. REV. 69 (1978).

9 As in the discussion of the greater-of regime, a similar distortion occurs when the cost-based measure of recovery is pV instead of C. In such case, a lesser-of regime entitles party A to either the expected or the actual benefit, whichever is lower. Accordingly, party A’s expected recovery under this hybrid rule is p(pV) = p2V, which is less than the social value of the investment, pV, for all p>0.

Page 12: UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University

COST-BASED VERSUS BENEFIT-BASED

9

case: investments with certain benefits and probabilistic costs. For some investments, the benefits—e.g., measured as the increase or decrease in market value of the property—may be certain, more or less. For example, an investor may know in advance the benefit of making a common improvement to a house; among other things, she could compare the sale price of similar houses with and without the improvement. But for some investments with certain benefits, the costs will be random. In this example, suppose the improvement to the house involves excavating land. The investor may not know the precise condition of the subsurface soil, making the cost of the investment probabilistic.

To see how the analysis above extends to the case of probabilistic costs, note that the critical feature in both cases is the randomness of the net benefit. This randomness may arise from either probabilistic benefit or probabilistic cost (or both). When the benefit is probabilistic and can take values of either V or 0, the net benefit is either V-C or –C. When, instead, the cost is probabilistic and can take values of, say, either 0 or c, with probabilities p and 1-p, and the benefit is fixed at v, the net benefit is either v or v-c. Both sources of randomness would generate the same distribution of net benefit if v = V-C and c = V. The net benefit in the case of probabilistic cost is either V-C or –C, which is identical to the distribution of net benefit in the case of probabilistic benefit.

Thus, under an ex-post benefit-based recovery rule the investor recovers the actual benefit and bears the actual cost, either of which could be random, and thus the actual net benefit is internalized. Under an ex-ante cost-based rule, the investor recovers the expected benefit and bears the expected cost, and the expected net benefit is again internalized.

A greater-of regime in the case of probabilistic cost awards party A either the benefit or the actual cost, whichever is greater. The expected net recovery equals pv + (1– p)c – (1– p)c = pv . Thus, whenever (1– p)c > v party A will invest although the investment is too costly from a social point of view. As in the case of probabilistic bene fit, the distortion in this case arises from the fact that the investing party does not effectively internalize the entire cost.

A lesser-of regime awards party A either the benefit or the actual cost, whichever is lower. Party A’s expected net recovery equals (1– p)v – (1– p)c = (1– p)(v – c). Party A will invest only when v > c. Thus,

Page 13: UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University

COST-BASED VERSUS BENEFIT-BASED

10

whenever (1– p)c < v < c, party A will not invest although the investment is socially desirable. As in the case of probabilistic benefit, the distortion arises because the investing party bears the entire cost, but does not enjoy the entire benefit.

II. DOCTRINAL APPLICATIONS OF THE HYBRID APPROACHES

This Section identifies and explores a broad range of legal

doctrines that employ the hybrid approaches to measuring recovery. It discusses the unique features of each doctrine in some detail to demonstrate the different ways hybrid regimes function in practice. It also briefly addresses the economic and non-economic purposes each hybrid is intended to serve. However, we postpone till Section III a more thematic discussion of the reasons hybrids are used with such frequency.

A. Implied Contracts

In drafting the provisions of their contract, parties are free to determine whether the obligation to pay on the part of a beneficiary depends on the success of the service rendered by the other party. While most service contracts guarantee payment on a per-service or per-effort basis (think of a visit to the doctor’s office), parties are free to design a payment scheme contingent on success (think of hiring an attorney to litigate a personal injury claim). In the absence of an explicit contract between the parties, however, it is up to the law to determine the obligation to pay for the services rendered.

A typical situation in which one party performs a service before executing an explicit contract with the beneficiary arises during the negotiation stage of their relationship. The party providing the service may do so in anticipation of striking a deal, at the encouragement of the other party, or in an attempt to convince the other party that a deal is desirable. For example, an advertising agency might develop an idea for an advertising campaign and, in bidding for the client’s account, share it with the client. If negotiations eventually break down, the investing party might seek to recover its costs or the value it created for the other party. In the absence of an explicit contract or a preliminary agreement over reimbursement of these pre-contractual services, the law must determine whether a right of recovery exists, and if so, its measure.

The law of implied contracts deals with these situations.

Page 14: UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University

COST-BASED VERSUS BENEFIT-BASED

11

Doctrinally, courts distinguish between two types of obligations that might be imputed, labeled implied-in-fact and implied- in- law contracts. An implied- in-fact contract may be found where circumstances and actions other than an express promise indicate that the parties intended to be bound without the exchange of express promises. Here, as in many other areas of contract law, the parties’ expectation is determined not merely from the text of their agreement (or lack thereof), but from the context as well. An implied- in- law contract, in contrast, arises even in the absence of any reliable indication of the parties’ intentions. It is based, ins tead, on the conferral of a benefit, and is intended to strip the beneficiary of this gain if the acquisition is deemed unjust under the established principles of the law of restitution. 10

The two types of implied contracts also lead to different measures of recovery for their breach. An implied- in-fact contract, once inferred, is supplemented by courts to include a provision mimicking the fee that an express contract would have stipulated, which is usually (though not necessarily) calculated on a per-effort basis. In the advertising contract example above, the implied-in-fact obligation would require the client to pay the advertising firm’s fee, normally calculated by the number of billable hours it spent on the project. In contrast, an implied- in- law obligation, once constructed, often leads to restitution of the full benefit enjoyed by the other party. 11 The client would have to pay, under the implied- in-law obligation, the value it actually derived from the advertising campaign, which can potentially differ from the contract fee. If no benefit was actually enjoyed but the service was nevertheless costly to perform, the implied- in-fact contract would lead to a greater recovery; if, instead, the benefit was substantial and exceeded the hypothetical fee, the implied- in- law contract would lead to a greater recovery.

Put in terms of the analysis in Section I, the implied-in-fact __________________________________________________________ 10 E.A. FARNSWORTH, CONTRACTS 499-501 (3d ed., 1999).

11 In rewarding the value the benefit conferred, courts use one of two possible measures, equal either to the “net enrichment”, namely, the increase in total wealth to the beneficiary, or to the “cost avoided”, namely, the saving to the beneficiary in obtaining the service. See, FARNSWORTH, supra note 10, at 107; see also RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF CONTRACTS, §371[hereinafter REST . 2D CONTRACTS]. It is only when a “net enrichment” measure is applied that the recovery under an implied-in-law claim differs from the recovery under an implied-in-fact claim.

Page 15: UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University

COST-BASED VERSUS BENEFIT-BASED

12

doctrine often embodies a cost-based (or fee-based) recovery approach, whereas the implied- in- law doctrine often embodies a benefit-based recovery approach. As argued in Section I, either regime, if applied consistently and in the appropriate situations, can lead to optimal pre-contractual investment.

A distortion arises, however, when the plaintiff can elect the greater of the two recovery measures. In particular, when courts allow a party who conferred a high benefit to seek the restitutionary implied-in-law recovery for the entire benefit, and allow a party who conferred a low (or zero) benefit to seek the implied-in-fact recovery for the per-effort fee, excessive recovery results. The investing party will get the full benefit when the benefit is high, and more than the full benefit when the benefit is low, a recovery schedule that exceeds the expected benefit from the investment.

The implied-contracts doctrine falls occasionally into this greater-of trap. Whenever a court is willing to recognize an implied contract, the plaintiff would often be able to satisfy the elements of both types of implied-contract claims.12 Although courts regularly recognize that a difference exists in the way recovery is measured under the two types of claims, they often accord plaintiffs the power to choose between them. In the casebook favorite Hill v. Waxberg, for example, a contractor who was negotiating a building project invested in “plans, ideas, and efforts” that benefited the landowner after negotiations broke down. In allowing a recovery, the court didactically distinguished between the two types of implied contracts and their associated recovery measures, and noted that “the elements of either theory could be satisfied, but since counsel has declined to choose between them, we are not prepared to make the choice for him.”13 __________________________________________________________ 12 Indeed, contracts are implied under either doctrine only when courts identify reasons why the parties did not enter into explicit contracts. These reasons often have to do with high transactions costs. See, e.g., RICHARD POSNER, ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF LAW 151-2 (5th Ed. 1998) (an implied contract arises when “the costs of a voluntary transaction would be prohibitive”).

13 237 F. 2d 936, 939 (9th Cir. 1956) (emphasis added). See also Bastian v. Gafford, 563 P.2d 48 (Idaho 1977) (holding that when an implied-in-law action fails due to the absence of actual enrichment, the conferring party may recover on the basis of an implied-in-fact claim the standard fee that the conferring party charges).

Page 16: UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University

COST-BASED VERSUS BENEFIT-BASED

13

In that case, the court awarded the contractor the implied-in-fact measure based on the contractor’s expenditures, rather than the potentially higher recovery based on the implied- in-law measure of benefit, only because that measure was not expressly claimed by the contractor plaintiff. Commentators have approved of this greater-of approach and have suggested that, even when no actual benefit materializes, an implied- in-fact claim for the services should lie.14 Thus, when the benefit conferred upon the other party is low, the investing party is generally encouraged to seek a recovery of her cost or hypothetical fee, based on an implied-in-fact contract claim.15 And when the benefit is high, the investing party is not precluded from making an implied- in-law contract claim for the full benefit.16

This greater-of approach is further facilitated by procedural rules permitting plaintiffs to delay their commitment to any particular litigation strategy until the stage of trial at which it will become clear which recovery measure is higher, and to amend the complaint if they originally stated only the lower theory of recovery. 17 Indeed, modern pleading rules encourage plaintiffs to offer several alternative theories of recovery. 18 As long as courts are unwilling or unable to clearly distinguish the circumstances that give rise to implied- in- law, as opposed to implied- in-fact, claims, parties may plead for the higher between the two measures, potentially leading to excessive compensation and investment. __________________________________________________________ 14 E. Allan Farnsworth, Precontractual Liability and Preliminary Agreements: Fair Dealings and Failed Negotiations, 87 COLUM. L. REV. 217, 232-233 (1987).

15 Earhart v. William Low Company, 600 P.2d 1344 (Cal. 1979) (rejecting the lower court’s holding that when the benefit enjoyed by the defendant is low, there could be no recovery even for plaintiff’s costs; holding that in the absence of actual benefit, the recovery of expenses incurred at the request of the other party is allowed).

16 Robertus v. Candee, 670 P.2d 540 (Mont. 1983).

17 Matarese v. Moore-McCormack Lines, Inc., 158 F.2d 631 (2nd Cir. 1947) (permitting amendment of the complaint from a suit based on express contract to one based on the theory of unjust enrichment).

18 See, e.g., Frontier Management Co. v. Balboa Ins. Co. 658 F. Supp. 987, 994 (D. Mass. 1986) (holding that plaintiff may plead unjust enrichment merely on the possibility that its contractual claims will prove inadequate at trial).

Page 17: UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University

COST-BASED VERSUS BENEFIT-BASED

14

B. Remedies for Breach of Contract

A similar greater-of approach is embodied in the choice of remedies available for breach of an explicit contract. This Part addresses two typical situations in which this election-of-remedy issue arises.19 The first situation involves total breach or repudiation of a contract after one party has partially performed. In these circumstances, the aggrieved party may seek either expectation damages or restitution. That is, the aggrieved party can either enforce the bargain and sue for “make whole” damages, calculated in accordance with the contract price,20 or disaffirm the materially breached bargain—employ a legal fiction that the contract ceased to exist—and recover damages equal to the benefit conferred on the breaching party. 21

A greater-of approach is created when these alternative remedies differ in a non-systematic fashion. When the benefit the breaching party enjoys from partial performance is low, the aggrieved party would indeed seek the standard expectation remedy, that being greater than the ex-post benefit (assuming, of course, that the contract price was not also tied to the benefit). But when the benefit to the breaching party from the partial performance is high, the aggrieved party can receive more than the adjusted contract price by recovering the ex-post value of the partial performance.22 Again, procedural rules enable the aggrieved party to join __________________________________________________________ 19 For a helpful treatment of restitution damages in contract actions, see Andrew Kull, Restitution as a Remedy for Breach of Contract, 67 S. CAL L. REV. 1465 (1994).

20 Expectation, or “make whole” damages would entitle the aggrieved party to recover the full contractual price, less costs she saved by not having to complete her performance. Another way to reach this same measure is to award the aggrieved party the costs she incurred plus the profit she expected to enjoy had the contract been performed. See, e.g., FARNSWORTH, CONTRACTS §12.9.

21 REST . 2D CONTRACTS § 373; see also §241 for a list of factors determining whether breach is material; Kull, supra note 19, at 1513-16.

22 See GEORGE E. PALMER, 1 THE LAW OF RESTITUTION §4.4 (“[T]he overwhelming weight of authority grants restitution in his favor of the reasonable market value of his part performance not limited by the contract price.”); Boomer v. Muir, 24 P.2d 570, 577 (Cal. App. 1933) (“[U]pon prevention of performance the injured plaintiff may treat the contract as rescinded and recover upon a quantum meruit without regard to the contract price.”); see also Kull, supra note 19, at 1477, 1498 (recognizing that the rule of the

Page 18: UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University

COST-BASED VERSUS BENEFIT-BASED

15

in the complaint a claim for restitution recovery (in quantum meruit) and a claim for expectation damages, thus postponing the election of the remedy until it becomes clear, at trial, which of the two measures is greater.23

This greater-of regime for total breach is reinforced by the way the restitution (benefit-based) remedy is calculated. Under the Restatement of Contracts, the benefit to the breaching party may be measured by either the market price for furnishing a service, or the extent to which the beneficiary’s property has been enhanced in value by the service, as justice requires.24 When the enhancement- in-value measure of benefit is low, the aggrieved party is encouraged to seek the more generous market-price measure of restitution, 25 and when the enhancement- in-value measure is high, the aggrieved party is entitled to seek this larger sum. As one court summarizes:

“The rule has evolved that the proper measure of damages in unjust enrichment should be the greater of the two measures.”26

The availability of an option to elect the higher of the these two

measures of recovery is puzzling in light of the more strict reluctance of courts to allow the aggrieved party to elect reliance damages in losing Restatement grants the aggrieved party “a choice of monetary remedies: either damages measured by expectancy, or restitution for the amount of the benefit conferred”).

23 United States v. Algernon Blair, Inc. 479 F.2d 638 (4th Cir. 1973).

24 REST . 2D CONTRACTS § 371 (1981). See also Robertus, 670 P.2d, at 542 (“The measure of this equitable restitution interest is either the quantum meruit value of plaintiff’s labor and materials or the value of the enhancement to the defendant’s property.”).

25 REST . 2D CONTRACTS §371 cmt. b (“[T]he reasonable value to the party from whom restitution is sought is usually greater than the addition to his wealth. If this is so, a party seeking restitution for part performance is commonly allowed the more generous measure of reasonable value. . .”).

26 Robertus, 670 P.2d at 543 (citing WILLISTON, CONTRACTS § 1480).

Page 19: UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University

COST-BASED VERSUS BENEFIT-BASED

16

contracts, namely when they exceed the expectation damages.27 By exposing a party considering breach to liability that exceeds standard contract damages, this greater-of rule may deter efficient breach of contract.

A second typical situation in which the greater-of damage measure applies is in an action for breach of warranty of title. A buyer who purchases an asset from a seller who is not the true owner and later has to surrender the purchased asset to its true owner, can recover from the seller either the purchase price or the ex-post value of the asset at the time it was surrendered, whichever is greater. Thus, when the asset depreciates in value below the price paid, the buyer can recover the price.28 And when the asset value increases, the buyer can recover the full value, uncapped by the contract price.29 As Williston summarizes:

[A rule limiting damages to the purchase price] virtually confines the buyer to rescission and restitution, a remedy to which the injured buyer is undoubtedly entitled if he so elects, but it is a violation of general principles of contracts to deny him in an action on the contract such damages as will put him in as good a position as he would have occupied had

__________________________________________________________ 27 See L. Albert & Son v. Armstrong Rubber, 178 F.2d 182 (2d Cir. 1949); REST . 2D CONTRACTS § 349.

28 Armstrong v. Percy, 5 Wend. 535 (N.Y.).

29 Menzel v. List, 246 N.E. 2d 742 (1969) (buyer who purchased a painting for $4000, which was not owned by the (good faith) seller and had to be returned to its rightful owner seven years later, recovered from the seller the market value of the painting at the time of dispossession, $22,500). Other courts, calculating the aggrieved buyer’s remedy of breach of warranty under § 2-714(2) of the Uniform Commercial Code, adhere to a pure ex-post regime. For example , a buyer who purchased a stolen car from a dealer cannot recover the full purchase price but only the depreciated value of the car at the time it was repossessed. See, e.g., Itoh v. Kimi Sales, Ltd. , 345 N.Y.S.2d 416 (N.Y.City Civ.Ct. 1973); Metalcraft, Inc. v. Pratt, 500 A.2d 329, 337 (Md. App, 1985) (“the proper measure of damages is indeed the value of the goods at the date of dispossession whether that value be larger or smaller than the value of the goods at acceptance.”). However, the principal way in which depreciation in fair market value of used goods can be assessed is by deducting the value of the buyer’s use. Many courts still refuse to make such deduction and effectively apply a greater-of regime. See, e.g., Curran v. Ciaramelli, 1998 WL 1095080 (N.Y. Dist. Ct. Aug. 19, 1998).

Page 20: UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University

COST-BASED VERSUS BENEFIT-BASED

17

the contract been kept.30

One purpose the added liability might serve in this context is to give sellers an incentive to verify title in their goods before putting them up for sale. But it is unclear why a greater-of regime is necessary for this purpose; as long as the disgruntled buyer is able to recover the expected value of its purchase from the seller, the seller should have efficient incentives to verify title. In any event, the seller can simply avoid the greater-of regime by executing a waiver of the implied warranty with the buyer. The rule may thus be better suited to forcing a seller to divulge information concerning potential defects in title when making a sale, a necessary precondition to executing a valid waiver.31 C. Attorney Fees

Recovery of attorney fees is commonly governed by a hybrid regime. This Part considers three prominent examples: the right of a trial attorney who is discharged without cause prior to the conclusion of litigation to recover from her client; the right of a defendant to indemnification of litigation expenses that run to the benefit of third parties; and lastly, the right of a plaintiff to reimbursement of litigation costs from a defendant.

1. Discharge of an attorney-client contract

Trial attorneys are typically compensated using one of two possible formulae. Under one approach—the billable hours contract—the attorney is paid the same fee regardless of the outcome of the litigation. This fee is calculated by multiplying the number of hours the attorney worked on the case by a pre-agreed hourly rate. The alternative approach is the contingency-fee contract, under which the attorney is paid a portion of the client’s award. If the client’s claim is denied, the attorney recovers nothing, but if the client’s claim prevails, the attorney receives a substantial premium vis a vis the billable hours contract.

For reasons concerning the fiduciary nature of the relationship, courts have held that a client has an unfettered right to discharge an __________________________________________________________ 30 WILLISTON ON CONTRACTS § 1395A (3d ed. 1960) (emphasis added).

31 Menzel, 246 N.E.2d at 745.

Page 21: UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University

COST-BASED VERSUS BENEFIT-BASED

18

attorney working under contract.32 Accordingly, the courts have established special rules governing attorneys’ remedies upon discharge—rules that cannot be altered by the parties and which usually differ from the simple contract remedies discussed above. When the client exercises this right before the conclusion of litigation and dismisses her attorney without cause, the question arises as to how the dismissed attorney is to be compensated for the services she has already provided the client. This situation fits well into the framework of this paper, since the benefit to the client at the time the lawyer rendered the services—before the client’s case is resolved—is still probabilistic.

Consider first the rules governing discharge of the attorney working under a contingency-fee contract. Strikingly, the rules that have emerged across the states mirror the four approaches described in Section I of this paper.33 Some jurisdictions apply a pure benefit-based recovery approach that simply enforces the contingency-fee agreement. As soon as the underlying litigation concludes or settles—that is, as soon as the “benefit” to the client, if any, becomes known—the dismissed attorney recovers her full contingency fee, minus any expenses not incurred by the attorney in performing the balance of the contract.34 Thus, the attorney recovers in proportion to the actual benefit conferred upon the client: if the suit is ultimately successful, recovery is high; and if the suit is ultimately unsuccessful, the attorney recovers nothing. 35 __________________________________________________________ 32 E.g., Fracasse v. Brent, 494 P.2d 9, 12-13 (Cal. 1972).

33 For a general overview of the case law, see Attorneys at Law, 7 Am. Jur. 2d §301 and Limitation to Quantum Meruit Recovery, Where Attorney Employed Under Contingent-Fee Contract is Discharged Without Cause, 56 A.L.R.5th 1.

34 See Tonn v. Reuter, 95 N.W.2d 261 (Wis. 1959).

35 The recovery may not be in proportion to the exp ected benefit conferred by the attorney, however, if the attorney’s work on the client’s case is squandered. For example, where the client hires a relatively less talented replacement attorney, the probability of success in the litigation, p, may be lower than it would have been had the dismissed attorney prosecuted the case to completion, and thus, the dismissed attorney’s expected recovery is lower than optimal. See Fracasse, 494 P.2d at 23 (dissent) (recognizing that an attorney working under a contingency-fee contract “bargains for a limited risk—the risk that the personal injury action may be unsuccessful under his management. He does not expect to hazard compensation for

Page 22: UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University

COST-BASED VERSUS BENEFIT-BASED

19

Other courts apply a variant of a pure cost-based approach, which permits the dismissed attorney to recover, in a quantum meruit claim, the reasonable value of her services, but not the contingency fee. That is, neither the attorney’s right to recover, nor the amount of that recovery, are affected by the outcome of the litigation. 36 In theory, a lesser-of regime might still emerge in these jurisdictions if the client is permitted to dismiss the attorney after the client obtains new information on the likelihood of success of her suit. Under such a scenario, when the client learns that the suit is about to succeed (or to reach a favorable settlement), the client would dismiss the original attorney and pay the attorney her costs, and when the client learns that the suit is about to fail, the client would retain the attorney and pay her the contractual contingency fee – nothing. 37 However, courts recognize the danger of such manipulation, 38 and thus the risk that clients can strategically create his services on the client’s choice of a substitute attorney when the client may have made an arbitrary and ill-considered decision to change counsel.”).

36 To maintain a pure cost-based regime, a court must allow the discharged attorney to recover more than the contract damages in some cases, e.g., where the client’s suit is ultimately unsuccessful. See, e.g., Lai Ling Cheng v. Modansky Leasing Co., Inc., 539 N.E.2d 570 (N.Y. 1989) (holding that a discharged attorney “is entitled to recover compensation [in quantum meruit]. . . whether that be more or less than the amount provided in the contract”); Hoddick, Reinwald, O’Connor & Marrack v. Lotsof, 719 P.2d 1107, 1112 (Haw. Ct. App. 1986) (acknowledging that the quantum meruit measure may exceed 100% of the client’s recovery in some cases). But courts must also be willing to award attorneys less than the full contract fee in other cases, e.g., when the client’s suit turns out to be a resounding success or when the attorney bore substantial risk in taking the case. See Boyette v. Martha White Foods, Inc., 528 So.2d 539 (Fla. App. 1988) (reversing award of $15,900 to dismissed attorney because the time based value of the services was only $5,300; the district court had trebled that amount due to the contingency risk in the case).

37 Of course, if the client dismisses her original attorney she will need to hire a replacement. Even so, the client may gain by paying the replacement attorney a lower fee than was offered the original attorney, given the new information indicating the suit has a higher probability of success than was contemplated under the original contingency contract, and the fact that the original attorney had already performed some work on the case.

38 See, e.g., Fracasse, 494 P.2d at 14 (holding that an attorney discharged without cause under a contingency-fee contract is normally limited to recovering the reasonable value

Page 23: UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University

COST-BASED VERSUS BENEFIT-BASED

20

a lesser-of regime appears relatively small. A third set of courts applies a greater-of approach by permitting

the dismissed attorney to elect her remedy. The attorney may collect either the reasonable value of her services or her contingency fee minus any expense saved because of the termination. 39 Therefore, if the award the client eventually collects is high, the attorney may elect the benefit-based measure of recovery, namely, a fraction of the client’s award; and if the award to the client is low, the attorney may elect the ex-ante measure of recovery, namely, her cost. As discussed above in Part II.B, the greater-of approach may discourage a client from discharging her attorney, even when it would otherwise make sense for her to do so.

Lastly, some jurisdictions, including California, apply a lesser-of approach by limiting the attorney’s recovery to the reasonable value of the services and then, only if the suit is ultimately successful.40 Thus, if the client receives a high award, the attorney gets the cost-based measure of recovery (her hourly fee), whereas if the client receives a low award, the attorney gets the benefit-based measure of recovery (a fraction of the award). Regardless of whether the client’s motives for dismissing the attorney are opportunistic or not, the client who dismisses an attorney without cause in these jurisdictions ensures that the attorney will receive of his services, but may recover the full contingency fee when discharge occurs “on the courthouse steps”).

39 E.g., Lockley v. Easley, 78 S.W.2d 573 (Ark. 1990) (holding that dismissed attorney could elect to recover his one-third contingency fee, even though he had already collected the quantum meruit value of services from client, since attorney did not discover that client had settled the case when he sought the quantum meruit measure of recovery); In re Downs, 363 S.W.2d 679, 686 (Mo. 1963) (holding that a lawyer working under a contingency fee contract who is dismissed by his client without cause “has the election to claim a reasonable fee for the work done . . . or to wait until the claim is liquidated by judgment or settlement and then sue . . . for his contract fee”).

40 E.g., Fracasse, 494 P.2d at 14; see also Rosenberg v. Levin, 409 So.2d 1016, 1021-22 (Fl. 1982); Chambliss, Bahner & Crawford v. Luther, 531 S.W.2d 108, 113 (Tenn. Ct. App. 1975) (holding that “fees . . . should be limited to the value of the services rendered or the contract price, whichever is less”). A similar lesser-o f approach may also arise under the pure ex-ante regime, whenever the client has limited financial resources. In that case, if the client loses her suit, the attorney will not get paid, and if the client wins her suit, the attorney will recover only the quantum meruit hourly fee figure.

Page 24: UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University

COST-BASED VERSUS BENEFIT-BASED

21

a lower expected recovery than under the contract arrangement, or under either pure recovery regime.

Jurisdictions following the lesser-of approach have cited several reasons to reject either pure approach. The pure cost-based regime, according to some courts, is unfa ir to poor clients who cannot afford to pay the attorney’s fees unless the client recovers in the suit. At the same time, the pure benefit-based regime, according to these courts, would place an undue burden on the client’s right to dismiss her attorney, because the client might end up having to pay two attorneys a full contingency fee.41 What these courts fail to recognize is that giving clients unbridled freedom to terminate an existing contingency relationship with an attorney may deter attorneys from agreeing to represent some clients in the first instance. In the alternative, attorneys may charge some clients higher rates (to reflect the risk of dismissal) or switch to billable-hours contracts, which are governed by different rules.42

A similar issue concerning recovery by contingency fee attorneys has come to the fore in the settlement of state lawsuits against tobacco companies. The contractual arrangements between the states and their outside (i.e., private) attorneys usually entitled the attorneys to a pure benefit-based recovery measure, anywhere between 2% and 25% of the settlements. When the tobacco industry agreed to settlements involving enormous sums, the attorneys’ combined fees reached billions of dollars. Ex-post, this translated to hourly fees reaching, in some cases, tens of thousands of dollars per hour. At that stage, lawmakers were ready to __________________________________________________________ 41 Fracasse, 494 P.2d at 12-14. A related concern is that a client may not know ex-ante whether cause exists to dismiss her attorney (in which case the attorney would be denied any recovery). Id. The lesser-of rule is apparently intended to reduce the cost of making an erroneous assessment.

42 Interestingly, every jurisdiction permits an attorney working under a non-contingent contract to recover regardless of the outcome of the litigation. The measure of recovery varies across jurisdictions, but is typically calculated on the basis of the contract price. See Measure or Basis of Attorney’s Recovery on Express Contract Fixing Noncontingent Fees, Where He is Discharged Without Cause or Fault on His Part, 54 A.L.R.2d 604, 616.

Page 25: UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University

COST-BASED VERSUS BENEFIT-BASED

22

discharge the contingency fee arrangements and override the contracts.43 Recognizing that these fees overwhelmingly exceed standard legal hourly rates, commentators, judges, the Press, and many lawmakers called these fees excessive, exorbitant, and even unconscionable.44

Critics of the fees are effectively advocating a lesser-of recovery regime. If the suits had been unsuccessful—as were most tobacco suits prior to the settlement—the plaintiffs’ attorneys would have recovered no fees. But now that the states have prevailed against the tobacco companies, the attorney fees have been scrutinized relative to hourly fees, and—as many critics endorse—capped not to exceed standard (i.e., guaranteed) hourly rates. What critics overlook is the enormous risk that many of these attorneys (albeit not all) had taken at the outset of the litigation. Ex-ante, in light of the slim chance of victory against the tobacco indus try and the projected out-of-pocket cost to be incurred by the attorneys,45 the negotiated contingency fees seem less excessive. Measuring in hindsight the per-hour fee that the attorneys in fact recovered overlooks this risk factor. It is equivalent to the view that the holder of a winning lottery ticket is unjustly enriched by collecting the award and that he should recover no more than the price paid for the ticket. In this lesser-of regime, attorneys would be less willing to undertake risky projects under contingency fee arrangements.

2. Indemnification of litigation costs

Another regime applying a hybrid approach to the recovery of attorney fees involves indemnification of litigation costs. A party __________________________________________________________ 43 See, e.g., 144 Cong. Rec. S6373-01, S6374 (remarks by Rep. Sessions) (“How can we violate contracts? We violate contracts all the time in this body. […] Everything about the tobacco business is being changed by this legislation. […] One of those aspects ought to be how much these fees should count for.”); see also Geoffrey C. Hazard and W. William Hodes, THE LAW OF LAWYERING (2000) (“The requirement that a fee be reasonable in amount overrides the terms of the contract, so that an unreasonable fee cannot be recovered even if agreed to by the client.”).

44 See, e.g., Lester Brinkman, Will Legal Ethics Go Up in Smoke?, WALL ST . J. A18 (June 16, 1998).

45 See generally, DAN ZEGART , CIVIL WARRIORS: THE LEGAL SIEGE ON THE TOBACCO INDUSTRY (Delacorte 2000).

Page 26: UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University

COST-BASED VERSUS BENEFIT-BASED

23

expending litigation costs to the benefit of others may seek reimbursement from the beneficiaries, even in the absence of an express indemnification agreement. The most common situation in which such an indemnity right is recognized occurs in products liability litigation over a defective product, where a seller who has defended a suit against the buyer seeks indemnity from the product’s manufacturer for any damages awarded or legal expenditures. Recovery by the seller is based on quasi-contractual principles; the manufacturer is considered the primary wrongdoer and any defense asserted by the seller against the buyer flows to the benefit of the manufacturer.46

There are different approaches across jurisdictions regarding sellers’ rights to recover legal expenses. Some jurisdictions allow a seller to recover reasonable legal expenses regardless of the outcome of the litigation with the buyer.47 These jurisdictions take a distinctly cost-based approach to indemnification. If the seller expends a reasonable sum defending against the buyer’s suit, the seller may recover its costs whether the benefit to the manufacturer is “low” (because the buyer prevailed) or “high” (because the seller prevailed).

Other jurisdictions allow a seller to recover its legal expenses from the manufacturer, but only—and surprisingly—when the seller __________________________________________________________ 46 If the seller’s defense is successful, the manufacturer may use that judgment to bar the buyer from re -asserting the same product liability claim against the manufacturer. See Booker v. Sears Roebuck & Co., 785 P.2d 297, 303 (Okla. 1989) (“A distributor’s successful defense of a claim for which the manufacturer would be ultimately liable but for said successful defense, saves the manufacturer an expense and confers a benefit upon him.”). For the seller to recover, the manufacturer must be the principle wrongdoer responsible for the buyer’s damages. For example, the damages must stem from a product defect caused by the manufacturer and not by an alteration or modification by the seller. Further, the seller must not have taken a position adverse to that of the manufacturer in the litigation. That is, the seller cannot attempt to shift all blame to the manufacturer and then seek to recover its legal costs from the manufacturer. The seller must also give the manufacturer notice of the suit and provide the manufacturer an opportunity to partake in the defense. See Products Liability—Counsel Fees, 53 A.L.R.4th 414.

47 E.g., Booker, 785 P.2d at 299; Pullman Standard, Inc. v. Abex Corp., 693 S.W.2d 336, 338 (Tenn. 1985) (citing cases); Heritage v. Pioneer Brokerage & Sales, Inc., 604 P.2d 1059, 1067 (Alaska 1979).

Page 27: UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University

COST-BASED VERSUS BENEFIT-BASED

24

loses in its defense against the buyer.48 These jurisdictions follow an inverted lesser-of approach to indemnification. If the seller expends a reasonable sum defending against the buyer’s suit, the seller may recover its costs only if the seller, and hence the manufacturer, is liable, that is, when the ex-post benefit of the defense to the manufacturer is low. If the ex-post benefit to the manufacturer is high, that is, if the seller prevails and the manufacturer thereby avoids liability for damages, the seller cannot recover its legal expenses.

This lesser-of approach distorts sellers’ incentives to defend against product liability suits brought by buyers. The less-than-full indemnity induces sellers to act as less-than-perfect defense agents of manufacturers. By declining to assert a defense, the seller not only avoids incurring any legal expenses but also can collect from the manufacturer any damages secured by buyer.49

3. Reimbursement of fees under statute

The third application of the hybrid approach arises with respect to a plaintiff’s right to recover attorney fees from a defendant. The general rule of American law is that each party must bear its own litigation costs. But exceptions to the rule are found in a variety of state and federal statutes that establish a right to recover litigation expenses from a defendant.50 From an economic perspective, these statutes are intended to give individuals an added incentive to prosecute violations of the law, __________________________________________________________ 48 This doctrine is based on a provision in the RESTATEMENT (FIRST ) OF RESTITUTION (1937) § 93(1), which declares that the right to indemnification arises “[w]here a person has supplied to another a chattel which because of the supplier’s negligence . . . is dangerously defective . . . and both have become liable . . . to a third person injured by its use.” Accordingly, the burden of indemnification lies only on a liable manufacturer. By succeeding in its defense against the buyer (thereby establishing also the absence of manufacturer’s liability), the seller eliminates the basis for indemnification. See, e.g., Automatic Time and Control Co., Inc., 600 A.2d 220, 222 (Pa. Super. 1991); Merck & Co., Inc. v. Knox Glass, Inc., 328 F.Supp. 374, 376 (E.D. Pa. 1971) (noting that “[i]ndemnity arises where one is legally required to pay an obligation for which another is primarily liable”).

49 To be sure, sellers can circumvent the lesser-of regime by joining the manufacturer as a party. See Merck & Co., Inc., 328 F.Supp. at 378.

50 See ALBA CONTE, ATTORNEY FEE AWARDS (1993) for a list of examples.

Page 28: UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University

COST-BASED VERSUS BENEFIT-BASED

25

by reducing the expected cost of pursuing cla ims, and to persuade attorneys to represent indigent clients, by enhancing the prospects of getting paid for their services. Since most lawsuits involve a sure cost but confer only a chance of victory and recovery, these statutes and their incentive effects are well captured by the recovery-for-chance model, even though a plaintiff clearly does not undertake litigation for the benefit of a defendant.

To recover under most fee-shifting statutes, the plaintiff must first have prevailed in the underlying litigation. 51 The recovery is then measured using the “lodestar” approach. To calculate the lodestar, the court simply multiplies the number of hours the plaintiff’s attorney worked on the successful portions of the case by a reasonable hourly rate. Importantly, this hourly rate is usually the rate the attorney would charge for non-contingent work.52 The court may then adjust the lodestar to take into account other factors such as the plaintiff’s degree of success in the litigation. However, while the court may adjust the lodestar figure downward to account for poor results obtained in litigation, it may not adjust the figure upward to account for such factors as the risk involved in the litigation. 53 This statutory approach to recovery resembles a lesser-of hybrid regime. The regime takes an element of the ex-post approach by requiring that a party prevail in order to recover anything at all. However, the regime takes a distinct element of the cost-based approach by measuring recovery on the basis of the reasonable cost of services. Accordingly, where the value of the suit turns out to be high, the __________________________________________________________ 51 Id. at § 1.02 (stating that “fees are authorized by statute and by common fund and substantial benefits principles only to those who demonstrate some level of success in obtaining the litigation benefits sought”). A party prevails where it recovers monetary damages from its opponent or where it vindicates significant non-monetary interests in the litigation. See Hensley v. Eckerhart, 461 U.S. 424, 433 (1983).

52 CONTE, supra note 50, at § 4.06.

53 See, e.g., City of Burlington v. Dague, 112 S. Ct. 2638 (1992); United States Football League v. Nat’l Football League, 887 F.2d 408 (2d Cir. 1989) (holding that party which prevailed in litigation but received only $1 in damages was still entitled to attorney’s fees of over $5 million, though that amount had been reduced by twenty percent from the full fee figure). Similarly, some statutes cap the amount that may be recovered for fees. See CONTE, supra note 50, at § 4.11.

Page 29: UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University

COST-BASED VERSUS BENEFIT-BASED

26

prevailing party may recover only the cost of the attorney’s services. Where the value of the suit turns out to be low or nominal, however, the party recovers the ex-post assessment of the suit’s value—nothing or a reduced cost-based figure. The statutory scheme provides less-than-optimal recovery:54 Whenever the probability of prevailing in the suit is less than 1, the party and her attorney will be under-compensated by this regime and may thus under- invest in litigation. 55

To be sure, information constraints may hamper application of a pure regime in this context. Courts attempting to apply a pure cost-based approach have to know whether the cost expended was reasonable. If courts do not know the probability of success for some types of litigation, they may not be able to accurately determine the reasonableness of the expenditures. Likewise, courts attempting to apply a pure benefit-based approach may not be able to accurately measure the non-monetary value of the victory to some prevailing plaintiffs. Where information constraints seriously hamper a court’s ability to apply a pure regime accurately, it might inadvertently be transformed into a hybrid regime. This effect will be explored more generally in Section III below.

D. Recovery for Precautions

Another setting in which one party might invest to the benefit of another involves accidental loss. A party who takes actions aimed at preventing a harm that might be suffered by another, or at preventing a harm for which another party might be liable, may have a claim to __________________________________________________________ 54 See, e.g., Dague, 112 S. Ct. at 2648 (Blackmun, J., dissenting); The Supreme Court – Leading Cases, 106 HARV. L. REV. 338 (1992); see also Charles Silver, A Restitutionary Theory of Attorneys’ Fees in Class Actions, 76 CORNELL L. REV. 656, 703 (1991) (asserting that courts should award fees that comport with terms that attorneys would accept in negotiations prior to litigation, but basing his argument on restitution principles and not on incentives).

55 The pernicious effects of the lesser-of regime may be limited. Relatively wealthy plaintiffs will hire attorneys regardless of the statutory approach as long as the expected benefits of their suits outweigh the costs, and relatively poor plaintiffs who seek substantial monetary damages will be able to hire attorneys on a contingency fee basis. Thus, the effects of the lesser-of regime are most pronounced when a plaintiff does not have independent wealth and is not seeking substantial monetary damages. Moreover, expanding recovery by adopting a pure regime may have its own detrimental economic consequences, studied extensively in the economic literature on litigation.

Page 30: UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University

COST-BASED VERSUS BENEFIT-BASED

27

recovery, even in the absence of a contract with the other party, on the basis of restitutionary principles. Recovery may be measured by either the benefit conferred, or the reasonable cost of the precautions. If the precautions eliminated an imminent risk, the benefit to the party-at-risk (or the party who is liable for the risk) is readily apparent ex-post. Often, however, these precautions only reduce the risk and do not eliminate it, and thus situations arise in which precautions that are cost-justified ex-ante provide zero measurable benefit in hindsight. This might be the case if, even after the precautions are taken, the harm—which due to the precautions has become less likely to occur—nevertheless occurs. Or, it might turn out that the harm—which, without the precautions, was more likely to occur—would nevertheless not have materialized. In either case, the ex-post benefit from the precautions is zero.

In some situations, where the investing party is a professional performing a service that is within her occupation, the law provides recovery that is equal to the service provider’s standard contractual fee. For instance, a doctor who treats an unconscious accident victim may recover her costs, irrespective of the actual benefit to the patient, which could be either higher (if the risk was eliminated) or lower (if the precautions failed).56 This is one of the purest doctrinal examples of the cost-based measure of recovery. In contrast, a salvor who comes to the aid of a sinking ship may recover a portion of the value of the salvaged cargo and vessel, but only if the efforts prove successful; this recovery schedule mirrors the “no cure, no pay” condition commonly found in salvage contracts.57 This is a doctrinal example of the benefit-based measure of recovery.

In other situations, however, a lesser-of approach applies. One sub-set of cases, which was identified by Saul Levmore and others,58 involves an insured party who takes precautions to reduce loss for which __________________________________________________________ 56 REST . RESTITUTION § 114 Illus. 3 (permitting recovery for physician’s expenses in reaching accident victim, even though the victim had died by the time the physician arrived).

57 Thomas J. Schoenbaum, ADMIRALTY AND MARITIME LAW, § 16-5 (2001).

58 Saul Levmore, Obligation or Restitution for Best Efforts, 67 S. CAL. L. REV. 1411 (1994); Note, Allocation of the Costs of Preventing an Insured Loss, 71 COLUM. L. REV. 1309 (1971).

Page 31: UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University

COST-BASED VERSUS BENEFIT-BASED

28

she is insured. Whenever the precautions go beyond the preventive steps required under the insurance agreement and reduce the likelihood of the insured-against harm, the insured party is conferring a probabilistic benefit upon the insurer. If the precaution is determined ex-post to have been successful in fully eliminating the harm, the insured may be able—although this is still controversial—to recover from the insurer the costs of the precaution, even if the insurance contract does not contain a “sue-and- labor” clause requiring the insurer to cover these charges.59 If, however, the reasonable precaution fails to eliminate the harm which eventually materializes (and which becomes part of the insured’s claim), the insured is less likely to be able to recover the cost of the precaution, as this precaution cannot be proven to have benefited the insurer.60 Unless there is a provision in the insurance contract covering the insured’s prevention expenses, in which case recovery is independent of the success of the prevention effort,61 a quasi-contractual claim to __________________________________________________________ 59 See Leebov v. U.S. Fidelity & Guaranty Co., 165 A.2d 82 (Pa. 1960) (“It would be a strange kind of argument and an equivocal type of justice which would hold that the defendant would be compelled to pay out, let us say, the sum of $100,000 if the plaintiff had not prevented what would have been inevitable, and yet not be called upon to pay the smaller sum which the plaintiff actually expended to avoid a foreseeable disaster.”). But some courts deny the insured recovery of prevention costs. See, e.g., Farmers Mutual Fire Ins. Co. v. McMillan, 395 S.W.2d 798 (Tenn. 1965) (holding that the coverage provision in the policy, viz., “all direct loss by fire,” did not include prevention costs); Schlosser Co., Inc. v. Ins. Co. of North America, 600 A.2d, 836 (Md. 1992) (rejecting Leebov and holding that in the absence of explicit stipulation in the policy, coverage of harm does not include the cost of preventive measures taken by the insured).

60 See Recoverability, Under Property Insurance or Insurance Against Liability for Property Damage, of Insured’s Expenses to Prevent or Mitigate Damages, 33 A.L.R. 3d 1262 (1970) (surveying “the requirement that expenditures incurred by the insured result in some benefit to the insurer”). One way in which courts limit the recovery to situations where an ex-post benefit exists is through the requirement that a loss must first occur before the insured may incur recoverable costs. See Thornewell v. Indiana Lumbermens Mut. Ins. Co., 147 N.W.2d 317 (Wis. 1967). But see Insurance Co. of North America, Inc. v. U.S. Gypsum Co., 870 F.2d 148 (4th Cir. 1989) for the opposite view, that an insured could also recover damages for expenditures which were reasonably incurred in attempting to reduce losses, whether or not those attempts were successful.

61 See Home Ins. Co. v. Ciconett, 179 F.2d 892, 896 (6th Cir., 1950) (holding that, under a sue and labor clause, the insured can recover all reasonable prevention expenses

Page 32: UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University

COST-BASED VERSUS BENEFIT-BASED

29

recover costs would fail in the absence of an ex-post benefit.62 Thus, when the ex-post value of the precaution turns out to be high, the insured recovers only its costs—that is, less than the ex-post value. Otherwise, when the ex-post value of the precaution is zero, the insured recovers nothing. This “half-step” remedy, as Levmore calls it, or lesser-of approach as we call it, provides inefficiently low incentives to take precaution. 63

This approach governing harm-reduction investments in the context of accidental harms can be contrasted with the pure cost-based approach governing a situation that is analytically identical, namely loss-reduction investments in the context of contractual breach. Under the contract law doctrine of mitigation, a breached-against party who takes reasonable steps to reduce damages (and thus to reduce the liability of the breaching party) can recover its costs even if this effort proved unsuccessful.64 E. Repairs and Improvements by Co-tenants

Property law also governs several types of investment having incurred, “without regard to the amount of the loss or whether there has been a loss or whether there is salvage”); GILMORE & BLACK, THE LAW OF ADMIRALTY 68 (1957) (supporting a broader view of benefits by suggesting that a benefit is bestowed on an insurer simply by the attempt to save, even though the loss is not reduced).

62 Note, supra note 58, at 1319.

63 Levmore, supra note 58, at 1436 (concluding that “precaution-taking is insufficiently encouraged with this restitutionary strategy”). It might be conjectured that a lesser-of regime provides incentives for the insured (or salvor) who already spent some initial cost not to abandon the effort and to spend additional subsequent cost to increase the likelihood of success. By making payoff in the event of success higher, the insured will be motivated to succeed. This argument is mistaken for two reasons. Even if the lesser-of regime generates incentives for subsequent effort, it reduces the incentives to spend any effort in the first place. Second, better incentives to both spend the initial and the additional effort are provided by the pure ex-post regime, which equates the private and social return to both the initial and any additional effort.

64 REST . 2D CONTRACTS § 350(2) (an injured party can recover even if “he has made reasonable but unsuccessful efforts to avoid the loss”). See UNIDROIT Principles 7.4.8(2) (allowing recovery of “expenses reasonably incurred in attempting to reduce the harm”).

Page 33: UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University

COST-BASED VERSUS BENEFIT-BASED

30

probabilistic benefits, including repairs and improvements made on co-owned property. While repairs and improvements are not always easily distinguished, the courts tend to treat them quite differently, potentially creating a hybrid regime to govern these investments.

Consider first the rule governing repairs. In many jurisdictions, a co-tenant who repairs property without the consent of her co-tenants may recover a portion of the cost of those repairs from her non-contributing co-tenants in an action for a partition or an accounting. 65 These jurisdictions apply a cost-based recovery approach; if repairs are reasonable, the investing tenant recovers the cost of the repairs (the portion commensurate with the other tenant’s stake in the property) regardless of whether the repairs in fact benefit her fellow tenants. For example, a mining company was able to recover one-half of the cost of repairs to a railroad track it jointly owned with another mining company, even though the passive tenant used the rail far less than the investing tenant and thus derived relatively little benefit from it.66 In other words, regardless of the ex-post value derived by the beneficiary—which in this case turned out to be low—the court awards the investing co-tenant the ex-ante costs of reasonable repairs.

By contrast, the tenant who improves property without the consent of her co-tenants may recover the increase in value of the property attributable to those improvements, but not their cost, in an action for a partition, or, in some jurisdictions, in an accounting. 67 This rule resembles a pure benefit-based recovery regime; the investing tenant recovers the full benefit, if any, of the improvements she makes. For __________________________________________________________ 65 The inves ting co-tenant may not, however, recover directly from her co-tenants in an action for contribution. JESSE DUKEMINIER & JAMES E. KRIER, PROPERTY 358-59 (4th ed. 1998).

66 Wagner Coal Co. v. Roth Coal Co., 267 S.W. 1096 (Ky. App. 1925) (noting that the investing tenant shipped five-times more coal on the rail than did the passive tenant).

67 In an action for partition, the improved portion of the property is awarded to the investing tenant, so long as such a partition does not damage the interests of the other tenants. If the property cannot be so partitioned, and the property is sold, the proceeds are distributed to award the investing tenant the added value resulting from the improvements. Under such a system, the “improver bears [the] full ‘downside’ risk [but also] enjoy[s] the full ‘upside’ of the improvements.” DUKEMINIER & KRIER, supra note 65, at 360.

Page 34: UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University

COST-BASED VERSUS BENEFIT-BASED

31

example, a co-tenant who invested roughly $1,000 in clearing and draining land to use as pasture and crop acreage, and in installing fences, was allowed to recover a portion of the enhancement value of such improvements, potentially totaling more than $29,000.68 The improving co-tenant may not, however, recover her costs where the improvements do not increase the value of the property. One type of distortion arises under the improvements doctrine when courts limit the investing party to recovering the lesser-of the improvement value or its cost. As one court explained, in limiting the recovery for improvement:

When a co-tenant is allowed [to recover] for improvements, he should not . . . be allowed to recover more than the cost; and not that, if the added value of the land, arising from such improvements, is less than the cost.69

According to this approach, when the improvement value is low, the investing tenant can recover no more than the value added, which might be less than her cost;70 and when the improvement value is high, the tenant can recover no more than her cost, which is less than the value added.71 A similar lesser-of approach is sometimes applied under the repairs doctrine as well. Some courts will allow a co-tenant to recover __________________________________________________________ 68 Buschmeyer v. Eikermann, 378 S.W.2d 468 (Mo. 1964) (remanding for a determination of the value of the imp rovements).

69 Eighmey v. Thayer, 98 N.W. 734 (Mich. 1904). See also WILLIAM B. STOEBUCK AND DALE A. WHITMAN, THE LAW OF PROPERTY 208 (3d ed. 2000) (“Generally the amount of contribution will be limited to the lesser of the cost of the improvements or the value they add to the land.”).

70 Buschmeyer, 378 S.W.2d at 479 (noting the general rule that “a cotenant be limited to recovery of the cost of the improvements, limited always to a maximum recovery of the amount by which the value of the property was enhanced solely by reason of the improvements made”, but making an exception for that case).

71 Madrid v. Spears, 250 F.2d 51, 54 (10th Cir. 1957) (“The owner is not unjustly enriched more than the improver’s cost. In short, where enhancement exceeds cost, unjust enrichment equal cost.”).

Page 35: UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University

COST-BASED VERSUS BENEFIT-BASED

32

for making repairs only if, in hindsight, the repairs actually increased the value of the land.72 For example, courts may find a repair to be unreasonable, and hence, not reimbursable, when the repair turns out not to affect the value of the property, even though ex-ante the repair seemed like a good idea. As one commentator noted, “the necessity of a repair has been determined in some instances by judging the results of the mending process rather than by the nature of the repairing act.”73

It should be highlighted that in the context of co-tenancy, even a pure cost-based or benefit-based regime might not provide sufficient incentives to invest unilaterally, due to the procedural difficulty of collecting from co-owners. In this already restrictive environment for the investing tenant, the lesser-of regime effectively applied by some courts exacerbates the under- investment problem. Investing tenants bear the full downside that the repair or improvement they make will prove valueless, yet they enjoy only part of the upside if the repair or improvement increases the value of the property significantly.

Even more interestingly, the lack of a clear practical distinction between acts that constitute “repairs” and acts that constitute “improvements” may permit an investing tenant to create a greater-of regime for expenditures lying on the interface between the two categories of investments. That is, some co-tenant investments may qualify as either repairs or improvements. When courts cannot easily distinguish repairs and improvements (or simply refuse to do so) a __________________________________________________________ 72 Clifton v. Clifton, 810 S.W.2d 51, 54 (Ark. Ct. App. 1991) (re-characterizing repairs as improvements and denying recovery on basis of evidence that joint tenant’s expenditures had not enhanced value of the property); Womach v. Sandygren, 180 P. 922, 924 (Wash. 1919) (disallowing recovery for repairs where investing tenant failed to show that the repairs enhanced the value of the property). In at least one reported case, a greater-of approach has also emerged with regards to repairs. See Storms v. Bergsieker, 835 P.2d 738 (Mont. 1992) (allowing landowner who replaced dilapidated bridge, over which neighbors had easements, to elect between recovering the resulting increased value of neighboring properties or the cost of the repairs; court reversed lower court’s dismissal of landowner’s suit because, although owner had failed to show any increase in the value of the adjoining properties, he should have been allowed instead to seek his costs).

73 Note, Right of Cotenant to Contribution from other Cotenants for Unauthorized Repairs and Improvements Made to the Common Property, 32 NOTRE DAME L. R. 493, 498 (1957).

Page 36: UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University

COST-BASED VERSUS BENEFIT-BASED

33

plaintiff is effectively accorded the power to choose the higher of the two measures of recovery. The tenant who invests to repair or to improve a property can, under these circumstances, recover the greater of the cost of the investment or the value it adds to the property. If the value is low, the tenant would sue to recover under the repairs doctrine; and if the value is high, the tenant would sue to recover under the improvements doctrine.

It is easy to imagine how such a hybrid approach might arise in practice.74 Courts struggle to classify some investments as either “improvements” or “repairs” across many areas of property law, oftentimes using the two terms interchangeably despite the differing legal treatment accorded each. For example, after taking pains to define the term “repair” as “to mend . . . to make good an existing thing; restoration after destruction” and “improvement” as a “valuable and useful addition, something more than a mere repair,” one court adjudicating a landlord-tenant case went on to hold that the term repair must be applied flexibly. 75 Accordingly, the court permitted a tenant to __________________________________________________________ 74 To illustrate how a combination of the repair and improvement regimes may create a hybrid regime, imagine that a tenant makes an investment in a house she owns in equal shares with one other co-tenant. In this hypothetical, the investor replaces a broken gas furnace in the house with a new, comparably priced electric furnace. Assume that the cost of the furnace is $60. Now imagine two possible scenarios and how they might affect the investor’s recovery and incentives. In the first scenario, assume that the price of gas skyrockets following the investment. Demand for homes heated by electricity, rather than expensive gas, also skyrockets, increasing the value of the home by $100. Under this scenario, the investor cares about which recovery regime applies; she will receive more if the court considers her furnace purchase an improvement. In the second scenario, assume that the furnace does not change the value of the property. Once again, the investing party cares which recovery regime a court applies; she will receive more if the court considers her investment a repair rather than an improvement. If both scenarios are equally likely, the tenant expects a gross recovery of ½*$50 + ½*$30 = $40. Her net payoff will be ½*$50 + $40 – $60=$5, which means that she will invest in the furnace, even though the investment is not beneficial from a social point of view, yielding a net value of ½*$100 – $60 = –$10.

75 Dougherty v. Taylor & Norton Co, 63 S.E. 928, 930 (Ga. Ct. App. 1909). See also Measure and Items of Recovery for Improvements Mistakenly Placed or Made on Land of Another, 24 A.L.R. 2d 11, 17 (cautioning that “definitions of the term ‘improvements’ as laid down in the law of real property in general cannot be safely followed, for the term is used loosely, to cover whatever beneficial changes in the property, as it is relinquished to the true owner, the [true owner] should equitably be

Page 37: UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University

COST-BASED VERSUS BENEFIT-BASED

34

recover from his landlord the full costs of replacing a storefront window in the leased building, even though the replacement window was an “improvement” over the original one because it was more expensive and of higher quality.76 The court’s choice of language was not merely semantic; had the court deemed the replacement window an improvement the tenant would not have been able to recover at all because the landlord was under no contractual obligation to reimburse the tenant for improvements to the building, only repairs.77 Indeed, in a variety of cases, courts have (wittingly or unwittingly) allowed the parties to manipulate the distinction between repair and improvement to their advantage.78 Given the lack of a technological distinction between the two types of investment and the incentive of some parties to muddle required to pay for”). Some investments which courts potentially could have treated as repairs but instead treated as improvements include reconstruction of an old building, spraying of a house for termites, and fixing a roof and painting a cabin. Id. at 20.

76 Dougherty, 63 S.E. at 930.

77 Id. Although it seems harsh to deny all recovery, the court could have ordered the landlord to reimburse the tenant for the replacement cost of the window, but not for the surplus associated with an improved window.

78 See e.g., Clifton, 810 S.W.2d at 54 (noting that plaintiff had not alleged that the investment actually increased the value of the property but the lower court had allowed the plaintiff to recover her costs anyway by calling the investment a repair; appeals court found the investment to be an improvement and thus denied recovery); Smith v. Sulzby, 87 So. 823 (Ala. 1921) (giving the term “permanent improvements” an expansive interpretation in order to provide recovery to a mistaken improver for repairing a roof and chimney and painting and plastering the inside of a house, even though such “repairs” admittedly only restored the property after some decay); Brown v. Cooper, 67 N.W. 378 (Iowa 1896); Compare Gilpin v. Brooks, 115 N.E. 421 (Mass. 1917) (holding that, although mortgagee is not allowed to make permanent improvements on the property, he may finish a building if necessary to preserve its value, and the work will be found to be repairs), with Warwik v. Harvey, 148 A. 592 (Md. 1930) (holding that a similar completion of a building is an improvement in the context of the mistaken improver doctrine). Indeed, one commentary surmised that, in the context of the mistaken improver doctrine, “[a]llowances for repairs are made . . . in many, if not most, of the cases in which they are claimed,” even though normally a mistaken improver is not entitled to compensation for mere repairs. 24 A.L.R. 2d, supra note 75 at 21 (citing, e.g., Duckett v. Duckett, 21 A. 323 (Md. 1891) (“substantial repairs” held to be “improvements”)).

Page 38: UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University

COST-BASED VERSUS BENEFIT-BASED

35

them, the hybrid regime may emerge in borderline cases.79

F. Mistaken Improvements A related doctrine concerns recovery for mistaken improvement

of real property. An investor might mistakenly improve property she does not own when she unknowingly holds land under an invalid title, mistakes the nature of her interest, or mistakes the location of her land.80 When the improver discovers her mistake, an interesting question arises as to whether and how much she may recover from the true owner of the land for the improvements, given their probabilistic value.

In most jurisdictions, the mistaken improver who meets certain criteria, such as acting in good faith and under the color of title, may recover from the true owner of the property. 81 Recovery, however, is capped at the cost of the investment. For example, under the Restatement of Restitution, the improver may recover “to the extent that the land has been increased in value by [the] improvements, or for the value of the labor and materials employed in making such improvements, whichever __________________________________________________________ 79 It might be argued that if the courts are just as likely to confuse either type of investment with the other type, the potential for a greater-of regime is balanced off by the potential for a lesser-of regime. If this were the case, the effects of the two distortions cancel out and incentives to invest are therefore not distorted. However, if it is up to the plaintiff to elect the action upon which she is claiming the recovery, the likelihood of a greater-of distortion that is not balanced off by an equally likely lesser-of regime is more substantial.

80 Kelvin H. Dickinson, Mistaken Improvers of Real Estate, 64 N.C. L. REV. 37, 37-38 (1985).

81 Recovery is provided under statute or under the judicially crafted principles of unjust enrichment. See, e.g., Improvements, 41 Am. Jur. 2d §§ 11, 18 (citing cases holding that, in order to recover, improver must have acted in good faith and must have held the land under color of title when making the improvements); Dickinson, supra note 71, at 43 (noting that betterment statutes usually require improver to show that he acted in good faith and under color of title). See also REST . RESTITUTION § 42(1) (urging that mistaken improver may recover so long as mistake was “reasonable”). The improver cannot usually recover damages directly from the true owner. Rather, she may only raise her claim defensively in response to certain actions taken by the true owner, such as a suit by the owner to eject the improver, to collect rents for the occupation, or to clear the title to the land. See DUKEMINIER & KRIER, supra note 65 at 358-59.

Page 39: UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University

COST-BASED VERSUS BENEFIT-BASED

36

is least.”82 Many courts have followed the Restatement regime.83 Furthermore, many states have enacted betterment acts that accomplish the same result by allowing the true owner to elect the remedy for the improver.84

The mistaken improver doctrine takes a lesser-of approach to recovery. When the improvement turns out to be valuable, the improver recovers only her costs, but when the improvement turns out to be of little or no value, the improver recovers only that nominal sum. The lesser-of approach could potentially distort incentives to make investments. By reducing the recovery from that which the parties would have agreed upon had they contracted (namely, a recovery equal to either the cost of the investment or a portion of the benefit it creates), the Restatement’s scheme dilutes incentives to invest and induces excessive caution prior to the unilateral investment in improvements.85 __________________________________________________________ 82 REST . RESTITUTION § 42 (1937) (emphasis added).

83 E.g., Madrid v. Spears, 250 F.2d 51, 52-54 (10th Cir. 1957) (citing REST. RESTITUTION § 42) (awarding mistaken improver $14,214 in costs, rather than $39,150 the improvements added to the value of the property). For cases predating the Restatement, see Rzeppa v. Seymour, 203 N.W. 62, 63 (Mich. 1925) (applying lesser-of rule) and Sires v. Clark, 112 S.W. 526, (Kan. 1908) (holding that recovery for mistaken improvements is measured by “the addition in value the improvements have made to the land” not, however, to exceed the cost of the improvements).

84 Usually the true owner can choose to pay for the cost of the improvements or to sell the land at its pre-improved price to the improver. Where the value of the improvement exceeds its cost, the owner will choose to pay the improver the cost of the improvement, but where the improvement did not create such value, the owner will opt instead to convey the land to the improver. See Dickinson, supra note 80 at 44.

85 Whether this hybrid regime actually distorts incentives to invest or take care depends in part on the state of mind of the improver. The distortion will be muted in any individual case, since, by definition, a mistaken improver does not think the lesser-of approach will apply to her investment. Still, the improver may harbor some doubt about her claim to the property while still meeting the requirements of acting in good faith and under color of title; the greater is this doubt, the more likely is the lesser-of approach to weigh on the improver’s decision-making (she may, for instance, take additional measures to verify title). Further, the distortion may affect a large number of investments—not just mistaken improvements—because many improvers harbor doubts about property that they do, in fact, rightfully own.

Page 40: UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University

COST-BASED VERSUS BENEFIT-BASED

37

This lesser-of approach has been defended on grounds other than investment incentives. Some courts simply rest on the misguided conclusion that the mistaken improver suffers no loss under the lesser-of approach. The Restatement rests on the notion that requiring an owner to pay the full value of the improvement would be unduly harsh, particularly for an illiquid owner. The Restatement’s approach, however, does not require the court to inquire into the equities of any particular transaction, at least when both parties appear blameless.86 Finally, some commentators have argued that the lesser-of approach gives improvers an incentive to verify that they actually own the property. However, as discussed in Section III below, the mistaken improver’s right to recovery is already conditional on her proving that she acted with care, e.g., with good faith under color of title, thus it is not clear why additional incentives are required.87 It is also somewhat puzzling that the Restatement does not adopt a greater-of hybrid approach to give true owners a similar incentive to prevent mistakes, even when it is obvious they could do so, namely, when they have notice of the mistake or defraud the improver. To illustrate, suppose there are 100 potential improvers, each of whom could invest $100 for a ½ chance of enhancing the value of a piece of property by $210, and $0 otherwise. Each improver believes with 90% certainty that she owns the property on which she intends to invest. Put in terms of Section I, there is a 90% chance that the investment will be governed by a pure ex-post regime, and a 10% chance that the lesser-of regime will apply. Although the investment appears efficient, under these facts, none of the parties will make it, since the expected recovery ($99.5) is less than the cost of the improvement ($100).

86 If the true owner causes the improvements to be made upon his land by misrepresentations or has notice of the error and the work being done, but does not prevent the mistaken improver from continuing his work, “he is subject to liability for the reasonable value of the services, irrespective of the value to him.” REST . RESTITUTION. at § 42 cmt. a. Thus, the Restatement appears to adopt a pure ex-ante approach where the true owner seems somewhat blameworthy.

87 For the first justification, see Madrid v. Spears, 250 F.2d 51, 54 (10th Cir. 1957) (“[T]he owner is not unjustly enriched more than the improver’s cost.”). For the Restatement’s view, see REST . RESTITUTION § 42 cmt. a (1937) and RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF RESTITUTION AND UNJUST ENRICHMENT (March 2000 Draft) §9 cmt a. For the third justification, see Dickinson, supra note 80 at 43 (arguing that the lesser-of approach “also provides a disincentive to careless or knowing improvers by denying them the profit from their improvements”).

Page 41: UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University

COST-BASED VERSUS BENEFIT-BASED

38

G. Recovery for Probabilistic Costs: The Law of Special Assessment

Finally, we address the law of special assessment, a doctrine demonstrating the use of a hybrid lesser-of approach in the context of probabilistic costs. Special assessments are a species of tax imposed by local governments to fund the costs of various improvements that benefit specific landowners. These improvements typically involve structural investments by cities, such as the paving of roads or the renovation of sewer lines. A special assessment is levied on the landowners adjacent to the improvement.

The special assessment is based on the cost of the improvement. Applying one of several possible formulae, such as the footage abutting a newly paved road, the cost is divided among the neighboring beneficiaries. However, the assessment for any landowner may not exceed the actual value of the improvement to that landowner. This is a lesser-of regime: if an improvement generated benefits in excess of its costs, the city can only recover its costs; but if the benefits of the improvement to the specially affected landowners are less than the cost of the investment, the city can only recover the benefit.88 In the latter case, the special assessment fails to cover the entire cost of the project and the difference is covered by general assessments, i.e., taxes paid by all residents.

Note that many types of infrastructure investments that are funded by special assessments have relatively non-random benefits. For example, the benefits of installing a new sewer line or repaving an existing road are relatively certain. What makes such investments risky, however, is the occasional randomness of the cost, due to such variables as weather and soil conditions.89 As demonstrated in Section I.D, the distortion in measuring recovery under a lesser-of regime arises any time the net benefit is probabilistic, regardless of whether the source of the __________________________________________________________ 88 McNally v. Teaneck, 379 A.2d 446 (N.J. 1977); see also Special or Local Assessments, 70C Am. Jur. 2d at § 22 (“When the cost of a local improvement exceeds the benefit, the difference must not be borne by a particular property, but instead by the municipality as a whole.”) (citing cases).

89 Municipalities could avoid this risk by hiring outside contractors for a fixed price. But to the extent municipal governments perform such work in-house or contract on a cost-plus basis, the effective cost remains random.

Page 42: UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University

COST-BASED VERSUS BENEFIT-BASED

39

randomness is the (gross) benefit or the cost. Thus, for example, a city that has to choose between two projects that generate a benefit of 100 each, one that costs a sure 90 and another that costs either 40 or 120 with a 50/50 chance, might select the first project even though the second has a lower expected cost (of 80, rather than 90). Under the first project the city’s cost will be fully recovered (from adjacent landowners), whereas under the second project there is a 50% chance that the cost will be only partially recovered. (When the cost is 120, only 100 of it—the full benefit—can be recovered.) Assuming general taxpayers are unwilling to subsidize costly investments that have the potential to benefit only the few, the more risky is the project, the less likely is the government to pursue it, even if pursuing it makes economic sense. It is true that the special assessments doctrine can induce better choice of projects by municipalities than if investments were funded entirely out of general tax revenues. For one, the doctrine goes a long way to ensure that liquidity constraints will not deter cities from making desirable improvements. However, our analysis suggest that a pure, rather than a lesser-of recovery regime, has the potential of improving project funding decisions even further, to the benefit of the taxed residents.90

III. WHY ARE HYBRID APPROACHES USED IN PRACTICE?

The analysis thus far demonstrated that hybrid regimes underlie a

wide variety of substantive legal doctrines and began to explore several possible justifications for them. This Section explores more systematically why such regimes are used in practice. Does the broad existence of these regimes manifest the confusion of courts in distinguishing between ex-post (benefit-based) and ex-ante (cost-based) conceptions of value, or can they be justified from either an economic or __________________________________________________________ 90 Another justification for the lesser-o f regime focuses on the unfairness of asking the landowner to pay for the entire benefit, as this might force the landowner to sell the property whenever the improvement boosts the property value significantly. Nevertheless, for reasons explained in the previous section on mistaken improvements and further elaborated in section III.A. below, these justifications do not necessarily support a lesser of regime. For one, even under a lesser-of regime, a landowner may be unable to afford the special assessment.

Page 43: UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University

COST-BASED VERSUS BENEFIT-BASED

40

other perspective? In general, hybrid regimes are created in two ways. Some hybrid

regimes, like the mistaken improver doctrine, are created intentionally by courts or legislatures in order to adjust recovery and thus serve purposes that are often unrelated to investment incentives. This Section considers several such purposes. It argues that the adjustment of recovery embodied in the hybrid approaches is often unrelated to and thereby incapable of furthering the intended aims.

Other regimes, like the hybrid that governs co-tenant investments that can be classified as either repairs or improvements, are created inadvertently. In particular, this Section shows that problems of information and of drawing boundaries between similar causes of action transform what were designed as pure recovery regimes into inadvertent hybrid regimes.

A. Deliberate Adjustment of the Recovery: Justifications Given for the Use of Hybrids

Despite the problems associated with the hybrid approaches, courts and legislatures occasionally employ them deliberately, to adjust the expected recovery for the investing party and thus serve other instrumental goals unrelated to investment incentives. This Section considers a variety of such goals.

1. Provide Incentives to Contract or to Avoid Unsolicited Investment

One goal a downward adjustment might serve is to give investors incentives to contract with beneficiaries or to take greater care before investing to someone else’s benefit. For example, a lesser-of regime, by reducing an investor’s expected recovery, may give her incentives to verify title before mistakenly improving her neighbor’s property.

While providing such incentives may be desirable policy, use of the lesser-of hybrid regime is a misguided way to implement it, in several respects. First, if the policy is intended to induce the investing party to contract with the beneficiary rather than make a unilateral investment, or to take more care before making a mistaken improvement, better incentives might arise if no recovery were allowed. Indeed, the doctrines that create restitution liability already incorporate a fault standard: the right to recover is itself conditional on the investor either taking sufficient care or not having reasonable opportunities to contract.

Page 44: UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University

COST-BASED VERSUS BENEFIT-BASED

41

For example, a mistaken improver must show that she acted in good faith and under color of title before making her improvements.91 Such conditions for the incidence of liability appear to provide investors with adequate incentives to take care and to contract, rendering unnecessary additional tinkering with the magnitude of liability. Thus, in those cases where the investor has satisfied the “due care” requirements like the ones embodied in the mistaken improver doctrine, it is unclear what instrumental purpose, if any, a reduction of the damages award serves.

2. Protect “Innocent” Parties

Another stated purpose for the lesser-of approach is to protect “innocent” parties from burdensome liability. For example, comments to the Restatement of Restitution dealing with recovery for mistaken improvement assert that forcing an “innocent” owner to pay the full value of improvements mistakenly placed on her land is harsh. 92 An innocent beneficiary of an illiquid benefit should not be forced to liquidate her property to be able to pay for the improvements, proponents of the lesser-of approach assert.93 Thus, the owner should not have to pay for the full enhancement value. At the same time, it seems unfair, from an ex-post perspective, to require an owner who received no enhancement value to compensate a mistaken investor for the costs of the failed improvement effort. The lesser-of regime seems to perfectly serve this dual protective goal.

Upon careful examination, however, the lesser-of rule of the Restatement is more difficult to justify. In the absence of any apparent wrongdoing, it is unclear why fairness necessarily favors one innocent party over another, that is, why the owner, but not the equally “innocent” and unaware mistaken improver, should be protected. An owner may be wealthy and a mistaken improver poor, yet the rule of the Restatement, on its face, still denies this improver full recovery even of her costs. __________________________________________________________ 91 See, e.g., Improvements, supra note 81.

92 REST . RESTITUTION § 42 cmt a (acknowledging that, while the rule is “harsh to the one making the improvements by mistake . . . in many cases it would be still more harsh to require the one receiving the benefits to pay therefor”).

93 REST ATEMENT (SECOND) OF RESTITUTION AND UNJUST ENRICHMENT §9 cmt a (March 2000 Draft).

Page 45: UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University

COST-BASED VERSUS BENEFIT-BASED

42

Further, the liquidity rationale cannot justify a reduction of recovery when the owner contemplates a voluntary sale of the improved property, yet the lesser-of rule is maintained even in these circumstances.

More fundamentally, even if some sort of reduction in liability is desirable, to protect the “autonomy” of the owner who did not solicit the improvement, the reduction achieved through the lesser-of regime is still ill-suited to this purpose. As the analysis in Section I demonstrated, the lesser-of regime achieves a reduction in liability equal to the option value embodied in election between the cost-based and the benefit-based values. The magnitude of this reduction depends primarily on the variance, or the riskiness of the investment, a factor that is independent of the reasons this reduction was deemed desirable in the first place.94 Thus, when the investment yields a certain—instead of a probabilistic—benefit, there is no reduction in liability although the same hardships confront the innocent landowner. Recognizing the probabilistic nature of the benefit demonstrates, therefore, that the reduction in liability attained by the lesser-of rule is arbitrary: it is not tailored to serve the goal motivating the reduction, and would often fail to achieve it.

Another area in which the lesser-of reduction of liability is intended to ease the compensatory burden placed on the beneficiary involves recovery for breach of a contingency fee agreement. Here, courts applying the lesser-of approach intend to give the client greater freedom to dissolve the relationship with his current attorney and enter into a better match with a different attorney. 95 It is less often recognized, however, that while the reduced recovery accords greater freedom to the __________________________________________________________ 94 As explained in Section I, the more risky the investment (i.e., the more dispersed the distribution of benefits), the more valuable is the option to the beneficiary and the greater is the effective reduction in the investor’s recovery. Compare two possible cases. In the first case, an investment of 50 creates a certain benefit of 100. In the second case, an investment of 50 creates a probabilistic benefit of either 0 or 200, equally likely. The two investments are identical from a net expected value perspective, and would be deemed equivalent by risk-neutral parties. However, in the first case recovery under the lesser-of regime would equal 50, and in the second case the expected recovery is only 25 (a recovery of 50 but only with 50% chance, namely when the benefit is 200).

95 See, e.g., Rosenberg v. Levin, 409 So.2d 1016 (Fla. 1982) (reasoning that “there is an overriding need to allow clients freedom to substitute attorneys without economic penalty”).

Page 46: UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University

COST-BASED VERSUS BENEFIT-BASED

43

client, the added risk it places on the attorney might diminish the attorney’s willingness to take on the client’s case or cause the attorney to raise her rates to absorb the risk, to the client’s detriment.96

3. Deter wrongdoing

Finally, a hybrid approach may also be deliberately tailored to serve deterrent concerns. For example, fiduciary and agency doctrines entitle a principal to a greater-of recovery against a fiduciary or an agent who violates her duties to the principal. If the agent receives a large benefit by violating her duty of loyalty (say, if the agent expropriates funds and invests them in her own account successfully), the principal is entitled to recover the entire ex-post benefit.97 And if the agent receives little or no benefit from the violation (say, if the agent’s investment failed), the principal can alternatively recover damages equal to the value taken from the principal’s account.98

This greater-of rule can be rationalized on the basis of deterrence theory. Since many violations of fiduciary and agency relationships go undetected, the risk of over-recovery, which normally arises under the greater-of regime, is not much of a factor. By applying the greater of the ex-post and the ex-ante recovery values, an increase in deterrence is achieved, potentially offsetting the otherwise diluted deterrence resulting from imperfect detection. That is, while the expected recovery under the hybrid rule exceeds the expected value of the funds that were taken, this premium hardly measures up to the “discount” enjoyed by the wrongdoer who goes undetected.

B. Overlap of Pure Regimes

The hybrid approaches are not always adopted deliberately. A __________________________________________________________ 96 Fracasse, 494 P.2d at 23 (dissent).

97 RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF AGENCY § 407.

98 Id. at §§ 399-401; id. at § 407 cmt a (“for a violation of duty by the agent which results in loss to the principal, the principal has a cause of action for damages […]. If the agent receives a benefit as a result of such misuse, the principal, instead of taking the value of the misused thing, can recover from the agent anything which the agent has receive in exchange therefor.”). See also Fawcett v. Heimbach, 591 N.W.2d 516, 521 (Minn. Ct. App. 1999).

Page 47: UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University

COST-BASED VERSUS BENEFIT-BASED

44

hybrid regime might also arise where two different “pure” recovery regimes overlap. When a particular investment can lead to recovery under two different causes of action, one employing a pure cost-based recovery approach and the other employing a pure benefit-based recovery approach, a hybrid regime might de facto govern this investment, for two reasons. First, courts may openly defer to the investing party to elect which of the two causes of action to apply to her investment; not surprisingly, she will elect the one that gives her the greater measure of recovery. This was shown to be the case, for example, in the choice of remedies regime governing total breach of partially performed contract.

More interestingly, courts may not be able to prevent a party from opportunistically pursuing one cause of action over another, as when the boundaries between two related causes of action are imprecise. For example, the co-tenant repairs and improvements doctrines overlap in some cases where an investment can be categorized as both a repair and an improvement. The use of a cost-based approach in recovery for repairs and a benefit-based approach in recovery for improvements may become a hybrid greater-of approach if the investing party can elect which of the two doctrines to apply. To the extent that courts cannot draw a bright line between what constitutes a repair versus an improvement, the investing party can effectively elect the greater of the cost-based and the benefit-based recovery measures. Likewise, a problem of imprecise boundaries exists within the implied contracts doctrine. To the extent that courts cannot draw a bright line between the grounds for implied- in-fact and implied- in- law claims—and, at least in the context of precontractual investment, such a line is difficult to draw—the investing party can claim the greater recovery measure.

Note that in the repair/improvement case, and to some extent in the implied contracts case as well, courts do not openly permit the investing party to characterize her investment so as to secure the higher recovery measure. In fact, if courts were aware of the problem, they might be driven to draw more precise boundaries between existing amorphous causes of action. Unfortunately, the type of sorting of claims that creates these greater-of regimes occurs “pre-trial”, distant from the judge’s scrutiny, when potential plaintiffs privately design their pleading strategies. In the usual case, a plaintiff pleads only one cause of action, either a pure ex-post or a pure ex-ante recovery claim. It is only across

Page 48: UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University

COST-BASED VERSUS BENEFIT-BASED

45

cases that a greater-of pattern emerges. In the end, eliminating such inadvertently created hybrid regimes

may prove difficult. To begin, courts simply may not be able to police the boundaries of overlapping regimes any more rigorously. For example, in some cases, courts may not be able to distinguish between repairs and improvements, even if they were to understand the consequences of failing to do so. Alternatively, the law may adopt a common approach for regimes that overlap. True, for reasons outside the scope of this article, it might seem optimal to maintain a dual regime: a cost-based rule for some investments and a benefit-based rule for others. But if a clear boundary cannot be drawn between the activities governed by the two rules, the distortion associated with the hybrid regime that is likely to emerge might offset the benefit from the dual regime. C. Information Problems

Finally, and perhaps most interestingly, hybrid approaches might also emerge inadvertently when courts lack the information necessary to apply a “pure” regime consistently across a class of cases. In order to apply a pure benefit-based regime, courts must be able to verify the actual benefit received. In order to apply a pure cost-based regime, courts do not need to know the actual benefit, but they do need to know the cost of the investment and the ex-ante distribution of benefits associated with the investment (to guarantee that the cost is reimbursed only if it was reasonable). The discussion below demonstrates that when some of this information is not readily verifiable in court, pure recovery regimes might be transformed into hybrid regimes. Formally, the doctrine employs a pure approach to measuring recovery; in practice, given information problems, it operates like a hybrid.

1. Information Regarding the Distribution of Benefits

To apply a cost-based recovery regime, courts need to calculate the ex-ante distribution of benefits. In contrast to the benefit-based regime, in which courts need only measure the actual realization of the benefit, under the cost-based regime courts need to assess whether the investment was reasonable in light of its projected benefits. In order to do that, courts have to consider the range of possible benefits that were associated with the investment and their associated likelihoods. That is, courts need to be able to measure not only the actual benefit that

Page 49: UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University

COST-BASED VERSUS BENEFIT-BASED

46

materialized, but also hypothetical (or counter- factual) ones. When the difficulty in estimating the prior distribution of benefits is accounted for, a pure cost-based recovery regime can be transformed inadvertently into a lesser-of regime.

One of the factors that could—and we believe, in fact does—interfere with a court’s ability to accurately assess the distribution of benefits at the time when the costly action was taken is the hindsight bias. When a court knows the ex-post value of an investment, but does not have enough information to determine its ex-ante expected value, it may draw an inference about expected value from the value that was realized. If the actual benefit from the investment turns out to be high, it is likely to appear cost-justified, and recovery of the cost would be allowed. If, instead, the actual benefit from the investment turns out to be low or zero, the investment as a whole might seem unreasonable, and recovery of the cost would be denied. Under these conditions, a cost-based recovery regime, in which the investing party recovers her costs only if they are reasonable, may turn into a lesser-of regime.99

This hindsight bias can explain the emergence of the lesser-of regime in several of the areas surveyed in Section II. For example, it can explain the lesser-of rule that sometimes governs restitution for repairs made by co-tenants and the quasi-contractual recovery for precautions. Some courts, when evaluating the reasonableness of certain repairs, condition the right to recover repair costs on whether the repairs appear, in hindsight, to be justified. Thus, the mere fact that the repairs did not add value ex-post is used to justify a conclusion that they were not reasonable ex-ante and thereby to deny recovery of their costs.100 Courts fail to see, in this context, that even repairs that “fa iled” to generate value could have been reasonable when made. Similarly, in assessing the desirability of precautions taken by an insured, courts already know whether the precautions succeeded in preventing or reducing the loss, __________________________________________________________ 99 Another possibility is that a court might mistakenly award recovery for an investment that was “unreasonable” ex-ante, because, by chance, it proved valuable ex-post.

100 See, e.g., Clifton v. Clifton, 810 S.W.2d 51, 54 (Ark. 1991) (no recovery of cost of repair when it added no value to the property).

Page 50: UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University

COST-BASED VERSUS BENEFIT-BASED

47

and are susceptible to a well-documented hindsight bias.101 One of the effects of this bias is that when a precaution fails to reduce the loss, courts draw an inference that it was not cost-justified in the first place and refuse to award even the ex-ante measure of recovery. Another potential effect of this bias might occur when, in hindsight, it is clear that the loss was avoided independently of the precaution, which again might lead courts to wrongly conclude the that the precaution was unjustified ex-ante and deny the recovery of its cost.

This “hindsight” problem is also illustrated in the debate over the plaintiff attorneys’ fees stemming from the tobacco settlement. Either an hourly fee that is not contingent or a contingency fee that is not truncated could adequately compensate the attorneys representing the states. However, conditioning the recovery on success and then limiting it to the (guaranteed) hourly fee creates a lesser-of regime. The rhetoric utilized by advocates of this regime suggests that they fail to consider the substantial ex-ante likelihood that the contingency fee attorneys could have received no recovery at all.

In theory, courts can avoid or mitigate the problems created by gaps in information by adopting the “pure” regime for which the best information is available. If it is consistently difficult for courts to assess the ex-ante value of any given type of investment, the courts could instead apply an ex-post approach to govern those investments, assuming, of course, that information about the actual benefit is relatively more obtainable.

2. Verifiability of the Actual Benefit

A different type of information problem might arise if courts cannot easily verify the actual benefit. Because it is the defendant/beneficiary who usually possess the best information regarding the benefit enjoyed, the defendant might manipulate the type of information he reveals to the court. Recognizing the plaintiff’s difficulty in proving the magnitude of the benefit she conferred upon the defendant, courts might allow a plaintiff who cannot prove the magnitude of the benefit to at least recover her costs, whenever these costs appear reasonable. Namely, in asymmetric information __________________________________________________________ 101 See, e.g., Jeffrey J. Rachlinsky, A Positive Psychological Theory of Judging in Hindsight, 65 U. CHI. L. REV. 571 (1998).

Page 51: UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University

COST-BASED VERSUS BENEFIT-BASED

48

environments, courts might be willing to award recovery based on the full ex-post benefit enjoyed by the defendant whenever reliable information about the actual benefit is provided, but award only some ex-ante measure (either cost or expected benefit) otherwise. This adjudication regime quickly transforms into a lesser-of regime if the defendant can selectively disclose information. The defendant would hide information about his actual benefit whenever this benefit is high, thereby limiting the plaintiff to the more moderate cost-based measure of recovery. And conversely, the defendant would reveal information about his actual benefit whenever this benefit is low, to limit the magnitude of the plaintiff’s recovery to the (low) actual benefit. To the extent that discovery procedures enable the defendant to manipulate information in this way, the plaintiff’s recovery is effectively governed by a lesser-of regime.

The limited ability of courts to verify actual benefits might also translate into a greater-of regime, when it is the plaintiff who can manipulate the information provided to the court. One way the plaintiff can control the informational-basis of the recovery is by affecting the timing of the suit. A plaintiff who, on the basis of private information, knows that the ex-post benefit will be low, can time her suit prior to the verifiable realization of the benefit, expecting the court, which cannot verify the actual benefit, to employ instead a cost-based recovery measure. Conversely, a plaintiff who knows that the ex-post benefit will be high can await the verifiable realization of the benefit and recover the full ex-post value.

3. Information about the Cost of the Investment

Another type of information problem arises when courts cannot verify the cost of the investment. Because of the stochastic nature of the benefit, any given observable ex-post realization of benefit can be associated with any number of different costs of investment. This problem might be particularly acute in the context of pre-accident precautions taken by an insured party. As many of the precaution measures that the insured can take are both non-verifiable in court and non-observable to the insurer, it is less puzzling why the parties to the insurance arrangement do not contract over them and why the courts cannot apply the pure cost-based recovery rule to them. Courts must look to the verifiable benefit to ascertain, not only whether the precaution was

Page 52: UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University

COST-BASED VERSUS BENEFIT-BASED

49

desirable, but also whether the alleged precaution was ever taken. Thus, when the realization of the benefit is high, the inference that some unobservable precaution had been taken is more plausible than when the benefit is low. When a ship sinks, courts are less likely to believe that the insured ship-owner took the necessary, yet subsequently futile, precautions. A cost-based recovery regime might, in the presence of this Bayesian inference strategy, transform into a lesser-of regime.

However, the lesser-of regime applied in practice to precautions taken by insured parties cannot be fully explained as a by-product of this information problem. If the non-verifiability of the precaution investments were the reason for the transformation of a cost-based rule into a lesser-of rule, one would expect that in cases where precautions are observable and verifiable a pure cost-based regime would survive. This, however, is not the case. While many pre-accident precautions are indeed non-verifiable, most post-accident harm-reducing mitigation actions taken by the insured—which are another category of precautions—are more easily observable and verifiable, and yet are subject to the same lesser-of rule. For example, the actions taken by a ship’s crew to avoid maritime hazards prior to an accident (e.g., safer routes, maintenance of machinery) might be non-verifiable, whereas actions taken by the crew to reduce the harm after an accident (e.g., raise a sinking vessel) are more readily verifiable. Case law, however, can hardly be partitioned according to this verifiability property of precautions; the adherence to the lesser-of rule and the denial of recovery for failed precautions are more robust than this conjecture would imply.

CONCLUSION

This article has identified a distortion in the structure of legal rules that deal with chance. Although the type of uncertainty examined here—uncertainty over the value of the investment—is (usually) resolved by the time the law steps in to determine the recovery, the confusion between the ex-ante (cost-based) and the ex-post (benefit-based) measures of value leads to hybrid recovery practices with their associated distortions. By identifying the generality of the problem—potentially arising any time the net external benefit of an investment is probabilistic—the analysis can be applied to any situation that exhibits this structure. The article explored some half-dozen applications of the

Page 53: UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN · 2007. 9. 28. · March 2003 THE ELUSIVE BOUNDARY BETWEEN COST-BASED AND BENEFIT-BASED LIABILITY IN PRIVATE LAW Omri Ben-Shahar and Robert A. Mikos∗ University

COST-BASED VERSUS BENEFIT-BASED

50

hybrid approaches, all from seemingly unrelated areas of law, but all sharing the same analytical structure. The list is, of course, far from exhaustive. Accordingly, the usefulness of the analysis would prove greater to the extent that the trans-substantive tool offered here is found applicable within other areas of the law as well. This paper can be read “narrowly”, as a remark on the benefit principle within the law of quasi-contract. Under this principle, the liable party has to pay only when an actual benefit is conferred upon him. The analysis in this paper provides an argument for expanding the definition of benefit to include, not only actual benefits, but also potential benefits. Receiving a chance for enrichment is valuable to the beneficiary in similar fashion that receiving a lottery ticket is beneficial. If the beneficiary pays only for the ex-ante value of the chance when the chance materializes ex-post into a substantial benefit, he should also pay for the value of the chance when a benefit does not materialize ex-post. Lastly, this paper can be read more broadly, as a comment on the appropriate interface between cost-based and benefit-based liability in private law. Costly actions that are identical from an ex-ante, cost-based perspective, can appear dissimilar ex-post, once the stochastic benefit materializes. This appearance can lead—and as we showed, it has often led—courts to apply an inconsistent treatment of the right to recovery, bouncing in an arbitrary fashion between cost-based and benefit-based liability. While the paper does not take a position concerning the choice between the two pure methods of measuring liability, it highlights the distortion that an inconsistent choice creates.