The waterbed effect and the EU ETS - Ecofys Consultancy waterbed effect and the EU ETS An...

21
The waterbed effect and the EU ETS An explanation of a possible phasing out of Dutch coal fired power plants as an example

Transcript of The waterbed effect and the EU ETS - Ecofys Consultancy waterbed effect and the EU ETS An...

The waterbed effect and the EU ETS

An explanation of a possible phasing out

of Dutch coal fired power plants as an example

ECOFYS Netherlands B.V. | Kanaalweg 15G | 3526 KL Utrecht| T +31 (0)30 662-3300 | F +31 (0)30 662-3301 | E [email protected] | I www.ecofys.com

Chamber of Commerce 30161191

The waterbed effect and the EU ETS

An explanation of a possible phasing out of Dutch coal fired power plants as

an example

By: Eline Begemann, Long Lam, Maarten Neelis

Date: 22 February 2016

Project number: CSPNL16521

Reviewer:

Bram Borkent

© Ecofys 2016 commissioned by: ENECO

The original report was published in Dutch language. This English translation has been made possible

by the European Climate Fund.

ECOFYS Netherlands B.V. | Kanaalweg 15G | 3526 KL Utrecht| T +31 (0)30 662-3300 | F +31 (0)30 662-3301 | E [email protected] | I www.ecofys.com

Chamber of Commerce 30161191

Abstract

In proposals for supplementary policy measures for the reduction of CO2 in sectors falling under the

EU ETS, it has often been said that these are not effective owing to the waterbed effect that occurs

under the existing CO2 ceiling of the EU ETS. CO2 emissions that you reduce by an additional policy

instrument may lead to additional CO2 emissions elsewhere in the European economy, because the

ceiling has not changed. The discussion regarding the waterbed effect is current in the Netherlands

and it appears in debates concerning a possible early phasing out of all coal fired power plants in the

Netherlands. ECN has calculated that this would result in a decrease of Dutch emissions by at least

15 Mt CO2 per year. Approximately half of this reduction is due to the substitution of coal by gas, the

other half would come from an increase in imported electricity.

In this study we present how the alleged waterbed effect precisely works and the impact that the

Market Stability Reserve (MSR), introduced by the European Commission, has on the waterbed effect.

In doing so, we will use the example of a possible phasing out of coal fired power plants in the

Netherlands. We make the following distinctions here:

1. The direct waterbed effect on emissions from the decrease of emissions in the Netherlands is

directly offset by an increase of emissions elsewhere as a result of the relocation of activities.

This impact only occurs gradually, i.e by the aforementioned increase in net imported

electricity. Should the emission factor of the additional net imported electricity be identical to

that of the disused coal fired power plants in the Netherlands, 7.5 Mt CO2 will be immediately

transferred abroad based on the figure mentioned in the ECN study. In the case of the

imported electricity being generated from CO2-free sources such as wind energy, then this

type of waterbed effect fails to occur and all 15 Mt emission allowances per year are then

added to the existing surplus of emission allowances.

2. The indirect waterbed effect through a reducing effect on the CO2 price. In practice, this will

only exercise a very limited impact and will barely lead to an increase in emissions in the

short term. The maximum of 15 million emission allowances that are made available annually

due to the early closure, amount to less than 1% of the annual emissions in the EU ETS.

Therefore, this will have only a small impact on the CO2 price and thus, via the price, barely

lead to immediate higher emissions elsewhere.

3. The indirect waterbed effect through the banking channel, where emission allowances that

are currently not used will be banked for potential future use. This effect occurs but is muted

by the MSR over time. On the basis of cumulative avoided emissions of at least 83 Mt CO2

and a maximum of 165 Mt CO2, approximately 40% of the unused emission allowances (i.e.

33 to 67 million) will be absorbed by the MSR in the period between 2020 – 2030 and thus

only become available again after 2030. We assume here that the MSR will be stocked by

2030.

Should the MSR continue to absorb emission allowances from the market after 2030, the dampening

effect of the MSR on the waterbed effect will intensify in time. However, if the MSR can no longer be

ECOFYS Netherlands B.V. | Kanaalweg 15G | 3526 KL Utrecht| T +31 (0)30 662-3300 | F +31 (0)30 662-3301 | E [email protected] | I www.ecofys.com

Chamber of Commerce 30161191

filled by 2030 because the surplus has reduced below the MSR threshold, then the dampening effect

will reduce. Hereby it is important to remember that ultimately all the allowances absorbed by the

MSR will become available again in future years, i.e. when the MSR is drained in the period after

2030. This may change in the future if alternative political choices are made regarding the surplus of

emission allowances in the EU ETS.

We have recapitulated a few things in the following figure:

This study indicates that the direct waterbed effect under the EU ETS where emissions avoided in the

Netherlands automatically lead to more emissions elsewhere only partially takes place at the most.

The waterbed effect through the banking channel, in the sense that these emission allowances

remain to be used at a later stage, does indeed occur but the MSR exercises a dampening effect over

time and this effect also becomes subject to possible future political decisions regarding the surplus

in the EU ETS.

We hope that this exploratory study contributes to a better insight into the effect of supplementary

policy measures on the net CO2 reduction in sectors under the EU ETS, given the current surplus of

emission allowances, and the impact of the MSR on the additional surplus that is created.

Cumulative

emission

reduction

165 MtCO2e

Phasing out coal

fired power plants

165 MtCO2e

cumulatively over

2020-2030

Additional CO2

from imported

electricity

0-82.5 MtCO2e

40% of

additional

surplus taken up

by MSR

Additional

surplus of

allowances

82.5-165 MtCO2e

60% of

additional

surplus stays in

circulation

To be used in

future

CO2 price

Increased CO2

emissions

Emission

allowances in

MSR are

released

1

2

3b

To be used in

future

3a

1 Waterbed effect through direct displacement of activities

Waterbed effect through CO2 price channel

Waterbed effect through banking channel

2

3

ECOFYS Netherlands B.V. | Kanaalweg 15G | 3526 KL Utrecht| T +31 (0)30 662-3300 | F +31 (0)30 662-3301 | E [email protected] | I www.ecofys.com

Chamber of Commerce 30161191

Table of contents

1 Introduction and guide 1

1.1 Background 1

1.2 This study 2

2 The waterbed effect under the EU ETS and the role of the MSR 3

2.1 Operation of the EU ETS and the MSR 3

2.2 The MSR impact on additional surplus through phasing out 5

2.2.1 The waterbed effect in the EU ETS 5

2.2.2 Dampening of the waterbed effect through the MSR 6

3 Conclusions 12

4 References 14

CSPNL16521 1

1 Introduction and guide

1.1 Background

The European Emissions Trading System (EU ETS) is seen as the cornerstone of European climate

policy. Recently this has been reaffirmed in the Energy Report that was submitted by the Cabinet to

the Lower House in February. The cardinal feature of the EU ETS is that a common CO2 emissions

ceiling1 applies at the European level for all sources of emissions and sectors covered by the EU ETS,

such as the steel and chemicals sector as well as the electricity sector.

In proposals for supplementary policy measures for the reduction of CO2 in sectors falling under the

EU ETS, it has often been said that these are not effective owing to the waterbed effect that occurs

under the existing CO2 ceiling of the EU ETS. CO2 emissions that you reduce by an additional policy

instrument may lead to additional CO2 emissions elsewhere in the European economy. After all, CO2

emission allowances that cannot be used by the additional measure can be used to emit CO2 in other

sectors.

In principle, the waterbed effect can occur in all additional climate and energy measures designed to

reduce CO2 emissions in sectors covered by the EU ETS. A number of these measures account for the

calculation of the European CO2 ceiling, i.e. by also defining explicit European targets regarding

sustainable energy and energy efficiency alongside CO2 reduction targets. Measures, however, that

Member States have taken in order to achieve these targets could be partial or also truly additional,

i.e. more extensive than what had been accounted for in the calculation of the CO2 ceiling. Debate on

the waterbed effect is being held in several Member States where additional policy is currently being

considered. Among these are the promotion of nuclear energy in the United Kingdom and ambitious

measures for promoting renewable energy in Germany.

In the Netherlands, in response to motions passed in the Lower House, the current question being

asked is whether early phasing out of all coal fired power plants in the Netherlands is contributing to

the reduction of CO2 emissions (EZ, 2015). Nobody doubts that this is physically the case in the

Netherlands. What happens then to the remaining emission allowances left over? Does this lead to

direct or indirect additional CO2 emissions elsewhere in the European economy? In short, is the

waterbed effect at play here?

ECN published a study in October 2015, commissioned by DELTA NV, on the impact of early closure

of five Dutch coal fired power plants2 in 2017 or 2020 (ECN, 2015). The ECN study only dealt with the

impact of closure of the coal fired power plants on the EU Emissions Trading System (EU ETS) to a

1 A number of non-CO2 emissions also fall under the EU ETS. Hereafter, we refer to the CO2 ceiling and CO2 emissions for the sake of the

readability of the report. 2 Hemweg 9, Boiler 9 Amer Power Station, Maasvlakte, Maasvlakte 3 and Eemshaven

CSPNL16521 2

limited extent. What is remarkable is that the report did not address the impact that a closure would

have on the recently introduced Market Stability Reserve (MSR) within the EU ETS, that would enter

into force in 2019.

In this context, Eneco commissioned Ecofys to examine the precise workings of the alleged waterbed

effect. Important questions therefore are:

Does the waterbed effect actually occur and does it also occur when a large surplus of CO2

emission allowances exists? After all, according to current estimates, there are approximately

2 billion unused emission allowances at the moment. This raises the question whether

additional CO2 emissions would indeed directly arise elsewhere if the coal fired power plants

in the Netherlands would close? If this is the case, then why is the surplus not used up

immediately?

What is the impact on the MSR recently introduced by the European Union on the EU ETS and

the waterbed effect? The MSR enters into force in 2019 and is specifically intended to reduce

surplus emission allowances in the EU ETS and make them more scarce. If an additional

policy instrument is introduced, such as a sustainable energy subsidy or closure of coal fired

power plants, this leads to an increase in the surplus of CO2 emission allowances. To what

degree does the MSR dampen or delay the potential waterbed effect as a result of these

additional measures?

1.2 This study

By addressing the aforementioned questions, this report serves as an expansion of and an addition to

the ECN report. Only in chapter 2.1 does the study first provide a factual insight into the working of

the EU ETS and the MSR. The effects of an additional surplus of emission allowances on the MSR

under the EU ETS through closure of Dutch coal fired power plants are described in chapter 2.2.

Finally, chapter 3 recapitulates the main conclusions of the study.

CSPNL16521 3

2 The waterbed effect under the EU ETS and the

role of the MSR

2.1 Operation of the EU ETS and the MSR

The EU ETS is the largest international system for trading in allowances for greenhouse gas emissions

and creates a financial incentive to lower greenhouse gas emissions. Geographically, it covers the

countries in the European Union and additionally Iceland, Liechtenstein and Norway. It limits the

emissions of more than 11,000 energy-intensive installations in power generation and the

manufacturing industry, and activities undertaken by aviation enterprises in these countries (EC,

2015a).

The EU ETS operates by setting a limit on the total amount of greenhouse gases that are emitted

from installations governed by the system. Permissible emissions under the limit will be divided into

emission allowances that are partly auctioned and partly distributed for free annually. The total

amount of available emission allowances is reduced by the passage of time. As a result, companies

falling under the EU ETS reduce their overall emissions.

Companies falling under the EU ETS must monitor their emissions and submit an amount of emission

allowances at the end of the year that correspond to the amount of emissions that they emitted. One

emission right equates to one ton of CO2 emissions. If this is not done, the company is then fined

heavily and the obligation to submit emission allowances does not expire. Whenever a company is in

danger of having too few emission allowances to cover the period in question, it has two options

available in order to avoid this fine: either the limiting of emissions or the purchase of emission

allowances through auctions or from other companies. Whenever a company has more emission

allowances than actual emissions, the emission allowances may either be retained for future use or

sold to other companies. The fact that a limited amount of emission allowances are available and this

amount progressively declines (the CO2 ceiling), ensures that these maintain their value. An

emissions trading system, in principle, ensures that emissions are reduced where it costs the least,

while the achievement of the target is guaranteed. This makes emissions trading an attractive policy

instrument.

Under the EU ETS, a surplus of emission allowances has been built up since 2009, partly due to lower

emissions during the crisis where the emissions decreased but the ceiling was not adjusted. This

surplus led to a lower CO2 price, which brings the risk that the emission trading system does not

result in emission reduction in the short term. In the long term, it has a negative impact on the

ability of the EU ETS to comply with stricter requirements in the area of emission reduction (EC,

2015b). The European Commission addresses this with the help of, inter alia, the Market Stability

Reserve (MSR). This reserve shall enter force on 1 January 2019 and will tackle both the current

surplus of emission allowances as well as allow the EU ETS to withstand future fluctuations better by

adapting the size of the surplus to the availability of auctioned emission allowances.

CSPNL16521 4

The MSR adapts the number of auctioned emission allowances to the overall amount of emission

allowances in circulation:

If more than the upper limit 833 Mt emission allowances are in circulation, the surplus is

decreased by auctioning fewer emission allowances and adding the non-auctioned emission

allowances to the MSR. The number of emission allowances added to the MSR is 12%

annually of the overall number of emission allowances in circulation.

If fewer than the lower limit of 400 Mt of emission allowances are in circulation, an additional

100 Mt of emission allowances will be auctioned per year extracted from the MSR. If fewer

than 100 Mt of emission allowances remain in the reserve, all these emission allowances are

to be auctioned.

The current surplus in the EU ETS is over 2 billion emission allowances (2000 Mt). This corresponds

to more than a year of EU ETS emissions. The MSR ensures that this surplus gradually decreases

from 2019 to 1.4 - 2.4 billion emission allowances in 2020 and to below the limit of 833 Mt between

2025 and 2032. The surplus will decrease a few years later to below the limit of 400 Mt. This is borne

out from several studies (European Environment Agency, 2015a) (PBL & NEa, 2014) (DEHSt, 2014)

(Thomson Reuters Point Carbon, 2014) (Sandbag, 2015)3. Most studies indicate that the MSR shall

only bring 100 Mt of emission allowances onto the market per year after 2030. Without the MSR the

current surplus would change minimally in coming years. The studies indicate negligible differences in

the quantity of allowances coming into the MSR and the surplus over time. This is mainly due to the

differences in emission forecasts, assumptions over the behaviour of the EU ETS market participants

and the costs of emission reduction.4

Market analyses and other studies indicate that owing to the decrease of the surplus due to the MSR,

the price of emission allowances, and thus the incentive to reduce emissions, will increase. Studies

that use the model based on marginal costs and cost optimisation of the EU ETS participants estimate

that the price with the MSR will be €10-13 /tCO2 in 2020, an increase of € 3-5/tCO2 compared with

the situation without an MSR. In 2030 the price is estimated at € 20-40/tCO2 (PBL, 2015) (DIW

Berlin, 2015). At the moment that the MSR will be drained again, the effect is reversed. The

additional allowances that then come onto the market lead to a lower CO2 price compared the

situation without the MSR being drained.

3 This is a selection of studies on the MSR and must not be considered as an exhaustive list. 4 Most studies were conducted before the MSR was adopted, with the EC proposal of January 2014 (MSR from 2021) and variants on the EC

proposal as the starting point, as a result of which the calculated scenarios differ somewhat from today’s form of the MSR. For the

comparison, we have taken the scenarios that most reflect the similarities with the final draft, i.e. a starting date of 2017/2018 and the 900

million emission allowances issued from the auctions for 2014-2016 (backloading) directly into the MSR. The difference in the starting date

ensures a difference in surplus on the market primarily in the initial years after entering force, but the difference decreases over the years.

CSPNL16521 5

2.2 The MSR impact on additional surplus through phasing out

2.2.1 The waterbed effect in the EU ETS

Additional policy instruments, as introduced earlier in this report, that result in a decrease in

emissions under the EU ETS can lead to a waterbed effect. This effect can occur in three different

ways that are related to one another:

1. The direct waterbed effect by direct relocation of activities, where emissions from one

location decrease, while they increase at another location

2. The indirect waterbed effect through a negative effect on the price of emission allowances,

that indirectly results in an increase in emissions from other installations under the EU ETS

3. The waterbed effect via the room for emissions, where room for emissions that are currently

unused may be used at a later stage.

Relocation of activities can occur when a country takes individual measures and thus emissions are

relocated to another country. This is the direct waterbed effect. In the event of phasing out of the

coal fired power plants in the Netherlands, for instance due to the loss of capacity in the Netherlands

being (partly) offset by increased importation of electricity from surrounding countries or by lower

exports and thus increased production abroad. In this manner, the closure of the coal fired power

plants indeed ensures reduction of emissions in the Netherlands, but it also ensures a relocation of a

part of the emissions abroad if the net imported electricity did not come from CO2-free sources.

Additionally, the waterbed effect can occur via the prices of emission allowances. This occurs when

emission reducing measures, for example closure of coal fired power plants, leads to a lower demand

for emission allowances. This decrease in demand results in a decrease of the price of emission

allowances. As a result, other measures that possibly would have been cost-effective at a higher price

may no longer be adopted. This is the indirect waterbed effect. The question is to what extent this

effect actually occurs in practice. The additional availability of emission allowances as a result of the

diminished demand must be large enough to exercise an impact on the price. Furthermore, many

companies use long-term price expectations in decisions concerning emission reduction measures.

It may also be the case that the additional policy measures actually lower the emissions under the EU

ETS, which simply increases the surplus in demand for emission allowances in the market. However,

because the overall emission ceiling under the EU ETS does not change, the room for emissions in

principle (unless politics decide otherwise) remains available for future emissions. The additional

measure thus ensures that emissions shift over time. This is the waterbed effect via the room for

emissions. As set out above, the MSR dampens the waterbed effect over time by (temporarily)

decreasing the room for emissions, where it also exercises an impact on the CO2 price through lower

availability. The extent of the impact and its duration is dependent on future decision-making on the

surplus.

The three aforementioned waterbed effects are inextricably linked. A small direct waterbed effect on

the emissions will lower the demand for emissions and depress the CO2 price further, and the surplus

CSPNL16521 6

of emission allowances will increase. A small waterbed effect of the first type thus results in a larger

waterbed effect of the second and third types.

It is important to realise that the aforementioned effects occur in a phasing-out of coal fired power

plants in the Netherlands, but also to a greater or lesser extent to all additional policy instruments

related to energy consumption and the emissions under the EU ETS. Examples include the Multiyear

Energy Efficiency (MEE) agreement, the stimulation of sustainable energy by the Stimulation of

Sustainable Energy production (SDE+) and the subsidising of CO2 capture and storage (CCS). In a

number of these measures, the determining of the European CO2 ceiling is already taken into

account, namely by also defining the CO2 reduction target and explicit European targets on

sustainable energy and energy efficiency that are to be realised by Member States partly by policy

measures.

2.2.2 Dampening of the waterbed effect through the MSR

The various aforementioned effects can also be well illustrated quantitatively using emission

reductions in the Netherlands by a mandatory closure of all coal fired power plants, such as those

calculated by ECN. These calculations (ECN, 2015) indicate that Dutch emissions from the early

closure of all coal fired power plants from 2020 decrease by at least 15 Mt CO2 per year. This is in

addition to the substitution of approximately half of the coal by gas in the generation of electricity.

The other half of the CO2 decrease comes from the increase of net imports of electricity.

The ECN study makes no further mention of either the source or generation methods of the increased

net imports of electricity. Assume that the emission factor of these net imports is identical to those of

the discontinued capacity in the Netherlands, then 7.5 Mt CO2 would be immediately relocated abroad

(waterbed effect 1, Figure 1). In the event that the increased net imports are achieved from CO2-free

sources, then this relocation does not occur. The 15 Mt CO2 can then be regarded as a maximum

room for emissions that are unused annually through phasing out. This surplus will partly result

through a lower CO2 price in higher emissions within the EU ETS (waterbed effect 2, Figure 1), partly

simultaneously and partly available for the future.

The additional room for emissions would then be partly filled directly and remain partly available for

the future. The MSR exercises an effect on this relocation both over time and also on the CO2 price.

This is schematically depicted in Figure 2. On account of the percentage of the surplus of the future

auctioning withheld by the MSR, the number of emission allowances halted in the MSR will also

increase. This does not allow the use of the entire amount of emission allowances released by other

EU ETS participants, until the surplus sinks to the lower limit and these allowances are brought back

into circulation from the MSR in the (distant) future. This allows the MSR to spread the waterbed

effect over time, though it does not essentially disappear: the emission allowances do not disappear

and remain available for future emissions, unless other political choices on the surplus of emission

allowances in the EU ETS are made in the future.

CSPNL16521 7

Figure 1: Schematic depiction of the waterbed effect through direct relocation of emissions abroad (1) and through a

decrease of the CO2 price through lower demand (2)

Figure 2: Schematic depiction of the effect of the phasing out of coal fired power plants in combination with the MSR

on the surplus of emission allowances

Total emissions

Otheremissions

Emissions coalfired power plants

in NL

Additionalemissionsgas-fired

power plants in

NL

Reducedemissions

from coal-to-gas switch in

NL

Reducedemissions in NL through

importation of electricity

Otheremissions

Emissions coal fired power plants

before closure

After closure these emissions can

partially occur in other countries

through increased imports (1)…

Illustration of the potential waterbed effect through two channels:1) replacement of activities and 2) lower CO2-price

1

… and lead to lower CO2 prices

through new supply-demand

balance (2)

CO2-price

Supply and demand of

emission allowances

Fixed

supply

through

fixed

ceiling

Reduced demand

through coal-to-

gas switch in NL

Lower

CO2-

price

7.5Mton

7.5Mton

2

CSPNL16521 8

Given that the annual emissions in the EU ETS of approximately 1,800 Mt CO2e per year (European

Environment Agency, 2015b) and the surplus of over 2 billion emission allowances, the closure of the

Dutch coal fired power plants alone will only exercise a limited impact on the functioning of the EU

ETS and the MSR. The maximum of 15 million emission allowances that are made available annually

due to the early closure, amount to less than 1% of the annual emissions in the EU ETS. Compared to

the fluctuations in the annual EU ETS emissions by, inter alia, economic circumstances and the

weather, the early closure of the Dutch coal fired power plants falls within the typical margin of

uncertainty for future emissions. This means that the additional surplus of emission allowances will

exercise a fairly small impact on the CO2 price, and the CO2 price will decrease to a very limited

extent by the additional surplus. The second waterbed effect described (increase of emissions

through a lower CO2 price) will therefore be small.

A total of 83-165 Mt of emission allowances will be released over the period 2020-2030 by the early

closure of the coal fired power plants and added to the surplus, depending on the corresponding

emissions of the imported electricity. As a simplification, we assume that the replacement by gas in

the Netherlands and net imports yields a constant reduction per year for the period 2020-20305. In

the expectation of a CO2 price of between € 20 and 40/tCO2 in 2030 and a further increase in the CO2

price thereafter through the falling emission ceiling, all coal fired power plants will become

unprofitable regardless of new measures6. If this already is the case in 2030, then the waterbed

effect is no longer an issue because the emission allowances released by the closure of the coal fired

power plants are the result of the market forces through the CO2 price. Therefore, we limit the

analysis of the impact of the MSR on the waterbed effect until 2030.

From the various studies mentioned in chapter 2.1, it appears that the MSR will withdraw emission

allowances from circulation every year until a certain year between 2025–2032. In the event that the

MSR will absorb emission allowances at least until 2030, the MSR will have absorbed 33-67 Mt of

additional emission allowances surplus through early closure in 2030. In this manner, the MSR

spreads excess surplus over time, depending on whether imported electricity is generated from coal

fired power plants (see Table 1) or comes from CO2-free sources (see Table 2).

5 The lower level of 83 million rights assumes that net imported electricity is generated with an emission factor equal to the electricity

replaced in the Netherlands. The upper limit of 165 million rights corresponds to imported electricity from CO2 emission-free sources. The

ECN study indicates a slowly incremental reduction of 15 Mt CO2 in the Netherlands in 2020 to 17 Mt CO2 in 2030. For the readability of the

report, we maintain a reduction of 15 Mt CO2 for the entire period of the study. Furthermore, within this study no examination is undertaken

regarding the plausibility of the reduction and distribution of net imports and the domestic replacement of coal by gas mentioned by ECN. 6 The CO2 price required to make coal fired power plants unprofitable is influenced by various factors, such as the prices of coal and gas and

electricity demand, and varies over time. At the moment, a CO2 price of approximately € 35/tCO2 is required to switch the electricity supply

from coal over to gas (I4CE, 2015).

CSPNL16521 9

Table 1: Emission allowances surplus when imported electricity is generated from coal fired power plants

Surplus with imported coal

fired sourced electricity

[MtCO2]

2020 2021 2022 2023 2024 2025 2026 2027 2028 2029 2030 2020-

2030

a)

Annual CO2 decrease in

emissions from early

closure of NL coal fired

power plants

15 15 15 15 15 15 15 15 15 15 15 165

b) Annual CO2 emissions from

imported electricity 7.5 7.5 7.5 7.5 7.5 7.5 7.5 7.5 7.5 7.5 7.5 82.5

c)

Annual released

emission allowances

added to the surplus (b-

a)

7.5 7.5 7.5 7.5 7.5 7.5 7.5 7.5 7.5 7.5 7.5 82.5

d)

Cumulative additional

emission surplus in

circulation due to early

closure of coal fired power

plants (c – e cumulative)

7.5 14.7 21.0 26.5 31.3 35.4 39.0 42.1 44.8 47.1 49.2

e)

Annual surplus withdrawn

from circulation by the MSR

(12% x d)7

0 0.3 1.2 2.0 2.7 3.4 3.9 4.4 4.8 5.2 5.5 33.4

Table 2: Emission allowances surplus when imported electricity comes from CO2-free sources

Surplus with imported

electricity from CO2-free

sources [Mt CO2]

2020 2021 2022 2023 2024 2025 2026 2027 2028 2029 2030 2020-

2030

a)

Annual CO2 decrease in

emissions from early

closure of NL coal fired

power plants

15 15 15 15 15 15 15 15 15 15 15 165

b) Annual CO2 emissions from

imported electricity 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 82.5

c)

Annual released

emission allowances

added to the surplus (b-

a)

15 15 15 15 15 15 15 15 15 15 15 165

d)

Cumulative additional

emission surplus in

circulation due to early

closure of coal fired power

plants (c – e cumulative)

15.0 29.4 42.0 53.0 62.5 70.8 77.9 84.2 89.6 94.2 98.3

e)

Annual surplus withdrawn

from circulation by the MSR

(12% x d)7

0 0.6 2.4 4.0 5.5 6.7 7.8 8.8 9.6 10.3 10.9 66.7

Since the portion not absorbed in the MSR every year is added to the surplus and 12% goes to the

MSR, the total amount of emission allowances grows every year, such as those depicted in row d) in

Table 1 and Table 2. The results of the tables are graphically depicted in Figure 3. The figure on the

left depicts the situation where imported electricity from coal fired power plants, where of the 15

million emission allowances that remain each year from early closure, one half are directly used by

7 The calculation accounts for the fact that the MSR absorbs emission allowances from September determined on the basis of the surplus of

the previous year, spread over 12 months.

CSPNL16521 10

the coal fired power plants abroad and the other half appear as additional emission allowances on the

market. The figure on the right depicts the situation where 15 million allowances are added as

surplus to the emission allowances market each year. Both figures show that the MSR absorbs

approximately 40% of de 83-165 Mt of additional allowances that are released by early closure. If

this analysis were to be extended after 2030 and the MSR continues to absorb emission allowances

from the market after 2030, the dampening effect of the MSR on the waterbed effect will be stronger.

Figure 3: Impact of de MSR on the additional emission allowances surplus resulting from early closure of Dutch coal

fired power plants

A schematic overview of aforementioned calculations is depicted in Figure 4.

Figure 4: Schematic overview of the effect of phasing out coal fired power plants on the EU ETS

0

20

40

60

80

100

120

140

160

2020 2021 2022 2023 2024 2025 2026 2027 2028 2029 2030

Additio

nal

surp

lus of

allo

wances

[MtC

O2e]

Year

Flow of surplus into MSR

until 2030

Imported electricity from coal fired power plants

0

20

40

60

80

100

120

140

160

2020 2021 2022 2023 2024 2025 2026 2027 2028 2029 2030

Additio

nal

surp

lus of

allo

wances

[MtC

O2e]

Year

Flow of surplus into MSR

until 2030

Imported electricity from CO2-free sources

Year

Annual surplus withdrawn from circulation by the MSR

Cumulative additional emission surplus in circulation due to early closure of coal fired power plants

Emission allowances in the MSR

MSR neemt ten minste t/m 2030 emissierechten

uit omloop

Cumulative

emission

reduction

165 MtCO2e

Phasing out coal

fired power plants

165 MtCO2e

cumulatively over

2020-2030

Additional CO2

from imported

electricity

0-82.5 MtCO2e

40% of

additional

surplus taken up

by MSR

Additional

surplus of

allowances

82.5-165 MtCO2e

60% of

additional

surplus stays in

circulation

To be used in

future

CO2 price

Increased CO2

emissions

Emission

allowances in

MSR are

released

1

2

3b

To be used in

future

3a

1 Waterbed effect through direct displacement of activities

Waterbed effect through CO2 price channel

Waterbed effect through banking channel

2

3

CSPNL16521 11

Should the MSR halt absorbing emission allowances even before 2030 because the surplus in

circulation has decreased below the threshold of 833 Mt of emission allowances, then the picture in

Figure 3 would be different. The amount of additional emission allowances that the MSR would absorb

from circulation would then be lower.

Moreover, at any given moment, the point is reached where the surplus in circulation falls below the

lower limit of 400 Mt allowances, causing the MSR to introduce emission allowances on the market

again and then is slowly drained. The additional allowances that then come onto the market lead to a

lower CO2 price compared the situation without the MSR being drained. The early closure of Dutch

coal fired power plants therefore also influences the CO2 price in the second half of the following

decade and the years thereafter, because it can influence the turning points of flooding and draining

of the MSR.

The impact of only a closure of Dutch coal fired power plants on the EU ETS and the MSR is logically

limited. However, should all coal fired power plants in Europe close because of new measures, it will

probably exercise a major impact upon the EU ETS and the MSR. This is not examined further in this

study.

CSPNL16521 12

3 Conclusions

A phasing out of the five new coal fired power plants from 2020 as a measure in addition to the EU

ETS, results in a decrease of Dutch emissions by at least 15 Mt CO2 per year. This is in addition to the

substitution of approximately half of the coal by gas in the generation of electricity. The other half of

the CO2 decrease in the Netherlands comes from an increase of net imported electricity. This can lead

to various waterbed effects under the EU ETS:

1. The direct waterbed effect on emissions from the decrease of emissions in the Netherlands is

directly offset by an increase of emissions elsewhere as a result of the relocation of activities.

This impact only occurs gradually, i.e by the aforementioned increase in net imported

electricity. Should the emission factor of the additional net imported electricity be identical to

that of the disused coal fired power plants in the Netherlands, 7.5 Mt CO2 will be immediately

transferred abroad based on the figure mentioned in the ECN study. In the case of the

imported electricity being generated from CO2-free sources such as wind energy, then this

type of waterbed effect fails to occur and all 15 Mt emission allowances per year are then

added to the existing surplus of emission allowances.

2. The indirect waterbed effect through a reducing effect on the CO2 price. In practice, this will

only exercise a very limited impact and will barely lead to an increase in emissions in the

short term. The maximum of 15 million emission allowances that are made available annually

due to the early closure, amount to less than 1% of the annual emissions in the EU ETS.

Therefore, this will have only a small impact on the CO2 price and thus, via the price, barely

lead to immediate higher emissions elsewhere.

3. The indirect waterbed effect through the banking channel, where emission allowances that

are currently not used will be banked for potential future use. This effect occurs but is muted

by the MSR over time. On the basis of cumulative avoided emissions of at least 83 Mt CO2

and a maximum of 165 Mt CO2, approximately 40% of the unused emission allowances (i.e.

33 to 67 million) will be absorbed by the MSR in the period between 2020 – 2030 and thus

only become available again after 2030. We assume here that the MSR will be stocked by

2030.

Should the MSR continue to absorb emission allowances from the market after 2030, the dampening

effect of the MSR on the waterbed effect will intensify in time. However, if the MSR can no longer be

filled by 2030 because the surplus has reduced below the MSR threshold, then the dampening effect

will shrink. Hereby it is important to remember that ultimately all the allowances absorbed by the

MSR will become available again in future years, i.e. when the MSR is drained in the period after

2030. This may change in the future if alternative political choices are made regarding the surplus of

emission allowances in the EU ETS.

In this study we thus show that the direct waterbed effect under the EU ETS where avoided emissions

in the Netherlands automatically directly lead to more emissions elsewhere, only occurs partially. The

waterbed effect on the room for emissions through time, in the sense that room for emissions remain

CSPNL16521 13

and can be used at a later stage does indeed occur, but the MSR exercises a dampening effect on this

waterbed effect on the room for emissions in the EU ETS and this effect is subject to possible future

political decisions concerning the surplus in the EU ETS.

We hope that this exploratory study contributes to a better insight into the effect of supplementary

policy measures on the net CO2 reduction in sectors under the EU ETS, given the current surplus of

emission allowances, and the impact of the MSR on the additional surplus that is created.

CSPNL16521 14

4 References

DEHSt (2014), Strengthening Emissions Trading.

DIW Berlin (2015), Modelling a market stability reserve in carbon markets.

EC (2015a), The EU Emissions Trading System (EU ETS). Retrieved from

http://ec.europa.eu/clima/policies/ets/index_en.htm

EC (2015b), Retrieved from Structural reform of the European carbon market:

http://ec.europa.eu/clima/policies/ets/reform/index_en.htm

ECN (2015), Effecten van het vervroegd sluiten van de Nederlandse kolencentrales.

European Environment Agency (2015a), Trends and projections in the EU ETS in 2015.

European Environment Agency (2015b), EU Emissions Trading System (ETS) data viewer.

Retrieved from http://www.eea.europa.eu/data-and-maps/data/data-viewers/emissions-

trading-viewer.

EZ (2015), Brief Minister Kamp aan Tweede Kamer betreffende uitvoering motie over uitfaseren van

kolencentrales.

I4CE (2015), Tendances Carbone No. 107.

PBL & NEa (2014), Marktstabiliteitsreserve in het EU ETS.

PBL (2015), CO2-prijs en veilingsopbrengsten in de nationale energieverkenning 2015.

Sandbag (2015), Sandbag Market Stability Reserve modelling tool. Retrieved from

https://sandbag.org.uk/carbonpricing/data/msr/.

Thomson Reuters Point Carbon (2014), The MSR: Impact on balance and prices. Retrieved from

https://www.ceps.eu/sites/default/files/Ferdinand.pdf.

ECOFYS Netherlands B.V.

Kanaalweg 15G

3526 KL Utrecht

T: +31 (0) 30 662-3300

F: +31 (0) 30 662-3301

E: [email protected]

I: www.ecofys.com