Structural Change and Productivity Growth in Cities · characterised in terms of the quantitative...

41
Structural Change and Productivity Growth in Cities Ron Martin*, Peter Sunley**, Ben Gardiner*, Emil Evenhuis* and Peter Tyler*** *Department of Geography, University of Cambridge, UK **School of Geography and Environment, University of Southampton, UK *** Department of Land Economy, University of Cambridge, UK Research Paper 2 December 2016 Structural Transformation, Adaptability and City Economic Evolutions An ESRC Urban Transformations Project (ES/N006135/1)

Transcript of Structural Change and Productivity Growth in Cities · characterised in terms of the quantitative...

Page 1: Structural Change and Productivity Growth in Cities · characterised in terms of the quantitative relations between input and output, between the output, employment and productivity

StructuralChangeandProductivityGrowth

inCities

RonMartin*,PeterSunley**,BenGardiner*,EmilEvenhuis*and

PeterTyler***

*DepartmentofGeography,UniversityofCambridge,UK**SchoolofGeographyandEnvironment,UniversityofSouthampton,

UK***DepartmentofLandEconomy,UniversityofCambridge,UK

ResearchPaper2

December2016

Structural Transformation, Adaptability and City Economic Evolutions An ESRC Urban Transformations Project (ES/N006135/1)

Page 2: Structural Change and Productivity Growth in Cities · characterised in terms of the quantitative relations between input and output, between the output, employment and productivity

1

Abstract

Itisnowwidelyacknowledgedthatstructuralchangeisintegraltotheprocessofeconomicgrowthandtheevolutionofcapitalistdevelopment.Giventheveritableexplosionofinterestinrecentyearsincitiesas‘engines’ofwealthcreation,trade,innovation and creativity, the issue of structural change would seem highlyrelevant to understanding the evolving economic performance of cities,particularly given the ongoing debates over structural specialisation versusdiversity. Thispaperexaminesthedifferingproductivitygrowthpathsofsome85Britishcitiessincethebeginningofthe1970s,andexploreshowfarthesepathsreflectdifferencesacrosscitiesinthepaceandnatureofstructuralchange.Wefirst find evidence that while productivity tended to converge across citiesbetween1971-1991, thereafterconvergenceceasedandwasreplacedbyweakdivergence. The paper then analyses the extent and nature of structuraltransformation in the various cities, using particular measures applied to 82sectors of activity, between 1971 and 2014.We find evidence of considerablestructural convergence across cities and a general tendency for the degree ofspecialisationtofall.Thisthenleadstoadecompositionanalysiswhichidentifiesthe relative contribution of within-sector and between-sector (sectoral re-orientation and relocation) effects to city productivity growth. The analysisrevealsthatwithin-sectorproductivitydevelopmentsoutweighstructuralchangeinaccountingfordifferencesinproductivitygrowthacrossmostBritishcities.Assuch, the paper raises questions over the importance often assigned tospecialisation as amotor of city growth, and points to the role of city-specificfactorsthatinfluencethegrowthperformanceacrossmostofacity’ssectors.

Keywords:CitiesStructuralchangeProductivitygrowth

JELClassificationsR10O47R11

Page 3: Structural Change and Productivity Growth in Cities · characterised in terms of the quantitative relations between input and output, between the output, employment and productivity

2

Productivity isn't everything, but in the long run it is almosteverything.(PaulKrugman,1994,p.11)Productivity is the challenge of our time… The gap in labourproductivitybetween theUK’s two largestcityeconomies,LondonandManchester,islargerthaninanyotherG7countryandmorethandoublethatinbothGermanyandJapan.Adynamiceconomyneedsthrivingcities.(HMTreasury,2015,pp.3,68.)

1.IntroductionItisnowwidelyacknowledgedthatstructuralchangeisintegraltotheprocessofeconomicgrowthandtheevolutionofcapitalistdevelopment:asRoncolatoandKucera (2014,p.399)put it, “sustainableeconomicgrowth requires structuraltransformation”.Akeycharacteristicofstructuraltransformationisthechangingsectoral composition of employment and output over time, a stylised fact forwhichthereiscopiousevidence(Kuznets,1957,1971;Pasinetti,1993;FreemanandLouca,2001;CornwallandCornwall,1994;Metcalfe,FosterandRamlogan,2006; Kruger, 2008). Development economists of the structuralist persuasionhave long been concerned with theorising major long-run shifts ortransformationsineconomicstructure,particularlytheprogressiveshiftfromlowproductivity activities to high productivity ones, and the long-run progressionfromprimaryproductiontomanufacturingtotertiaryactivity(see,forexample,Ocampoetal,2009).Partofthisconcern,infactthefocusofearlydebate,focusedon the relative role of sectoral specialisation versus sectorally ‘balanced’developmentas thebasis forachievingproductivityadvance. Incontrast,withrespecttoadvancedeconomies, traditionalgrowththeoryalwayshaddifficultyincorporating structural change. Technical advance, a key driver of economicgrowth,wasintroducedintothattheoryinsuchawayastomakeitcompatiblewiththebasicconceptionofaneconomyinwhichtherewasnostructuralchange,characterised in terms of the quantitative relations between input and output,between theoutput,employmentandproductivityofdifferent sectors,and thepattern of relative prices and incomes. In order to be consistent with thisconception,technicalchangehadtobeassumedastakingplaceatauniformratein all sectors, and demand had to be made to grow at a uniform rate for allproducts,bothassumptionsthatwereclearlyunrealistic.It took the path-breakingwork of authors such as Kaldor (1966, 1967, 1968),Kuznets(1973)andPasinetti(1981,1993)tomovestructuralchangetocentrestageingrowththeory.ThusaccordingtoKuznets

rapid changes in production structure are inevitable – given thedifferentialimpactoftechnologicalinnovationsontheseveralproductionsectors, the differing income elasticity of domestic demand for variousconsumergoods,andthechangingcomparativeadvantageinforeigntrade

Page 4: Structural Change and Productivity Growth in Cities · characterised in terms of the quantitative relations between input and output, between the output, employment and productivity

3

(1973,p.250).Likewise,inPasinetti’sscheme,structuralchangeisconceivedasamulti-sectoraleconomy evolving through time under the influence of technical progress andchangesinfinaldemandconsumption.Technicalchangeoccursunevenlyamongsectors,sothattherateofchangeofproductivitydiffersfromsectortosector(andby implication from region to region).1 Correspondingly, demand changes atdifferentratesamongdifferentproducts.Moreover,technicalchangemaytaketheform of the introduction of new products, and hence the emergence of newactivities and new sectors. In short, structural dynamics are inherent to thegrowth process. In a later contribution, Baumol et al (1989) discuss theconsiderablediversityofproductivitydevelopmentsthatcanbeobservedacrossindustriesandsectors,andemphasisenotonlythefactthatstructuralchangeisan ongoing long-run phenomenon, but also that productivity growth isparticularly relevant in the long run. In Kaldor’s seminalworks on economicgrowththeory,manufacturingwasassignedparticularimportanceasthedriverof economic growth: in his view the more rapid the expansion of themanufacturingsector relative to the restof theeconomy, the faster the rateofgrowthofproductivitynotjustinmanufacturingitself,butintheeconomyasawhole, primarily because of dynamic returns to scale and spillovers to othersectors(Kaldor,opcit;seealsoThirlwall,1983).Yet,asKruger(2008)pointsout,despitethekeyrelevanceofstructuralchangeforgrowththeory,businesscycletheory and labourmarket theory, as well as for economic policy, the topic ofstructural change and its potential relevance for productivity growth, arefrequentlyneglectedtopicsineconomicresearch.On the face of it, these same topics should also be of central relevance forunderstandingtheevolvingeconomicperformanceofcities.Giventheveritableexplosionofinterestinrecentyearsincitiesas‘engines’ofwealthcreation,trade,innovationandcreativity(Jacobs,1984;Glaeser,2011;Moretti,2013),theissueofstructuralchangewouldseemhighlyrelevanttounderstandingcitygrowthanddevelopment. Within the overlapping subfields of urban economics, regionalscienceandthe ‘neweconomicgeography’,avastbodyof literaturenowexiststhatexplores the importanceof theexternaleconomiesand increasingreturnseffectsthatarisefromtheconcentrationofeconomicactivity(firms,workersandconsumers)incities,andthepositiveimpactofthatconcentrationonproductivity,innovationandwages.Thereisalsoagrowingliteratureonhowcityeconomiesevolveovertimeandontheircomparativegrowthpaths(seeforexample,Glaeser,2005;MarkusenandShrock,2006;Moretti,2012;Poweretal,2010;Hobor,2013;Dijkstraetal,2013;Michaelsetal,2013;Cowell,2014,Storperetal,2015;Martin 1 Interestingly,inexplainingthestimulusforhisnewtheory,Pasinettiattributeditinpartto“theextremelyunevendevelopment–fromsectortosector,fromregiontoregion-oftheenvironmentinwhichIlived(post-warEurope)atthetimeIbeganmytrainingineconomics”(Pasinetti,1981;p.xi).

Page 5: Structural Change and Productivity Growth in Cities · characterised in terms of the quantitative relations between input and output, between the output, employment and productivity

4

etal,2016).Oneofthemanyfactstohaveemergedfromthisburgeoningbodyofworkisthatcitiesappeartodifferintheirratesofgrowthofoutput,employmentandproductivity. Inmanyinstancesthegrowthpathsofcitieshavebeenquitedivergent.IntheUnitedStatesforexample,Storperetal(2015)findthatsincethebeginningofthe1970sthetwolargecitiesofSanFranciscoandLosAngeleshavefolloweddistinctlydifferentgrowthpaths,withtheformerpullingprogressivelyahead of the latter in terms of per capita income. The authors attribute thisdivergenceinlargeparttodifferencesinspecialisationbetweenthetwocities.Asimilar pattern of divergence in per capita incomes and employment in facttypifiesnumerousUScities(Moretti,2013;Martin2016).IntheUK,Martinetal,(2016)findasimilarpicture:citygrowthpathsthereovertheperiod1971-2014havebeenhighlydivergent,withmostcitiesinthesouthofthecountrygrowingfasterintermsofbothemploymentandoutputthanthenationalaverageandmostnortherncitiesgrowingslower,withtheresultthatthetwogroupshavepulledprogressively apart over the past four to five decades. Other studies of citiesacrossEuropeandmorewidelyacrosstheOECDnationshavealsofoundmarkeddifferencesingrowthrates(Dijkstraetal,2013).Thereareofcoursenumerouspossiblefactorsthatmightaccountforsuchunevengrowthacrosscities,evenwithinthesamenationalmacro-economy. Citiesaresubject to national-level fiscal, monetary, legal, regulatory and politicalarrangements, all of which influence city growth rates. And most cities areindirectly,ifnotdirectlyaffectedbyglobalforces,eventsandrelationships.Butthespecificsofeachcityalsomatter,andservenotonlytoshapetheparticularimpactofnationalandglobalfactorsandprocessesfromcitytocity,butalsoactas indigenous sources of growth and development in their own right. Severaldeterminants of city prosperity and productivity have been suggested in theliterature, including city and size and density, both being assumed to conferpositive agglomeration economies; human capital, especially skilled, highlyeducated,andcreativeworkers;goodconnectivity,bothinternallyandexternallywith other cities; and supportive and strategic institutions and governancearrangements,tonamebutsome.Inaddition,andthefocusinthispaper,isthequestion of how and to what extent the structural configuration of a city’seconomy(itsensembleofactivities,industriesandfirms),andmoreparticularlyhow changes in that structure over time, contribute to the evolution of cityproductivitytrajectories.Morespecifically,usinganewanddetaileddatasetthepaperinvestigateshowaggregateproductivityhaschangedandevolvedacrosssome85Britishcitiesovertheperiod1971-2014,andhowfarthesepatternsreflectdifferencesacrosscitiesintheimpactofstructuralchange.Thepasthalfcenturyhaswitnessedhistoricshifts and changes in the British economy, most notably intensedeindustrialisation and the rapid growth of services, especially knowledge-intensive business services.How these shifts haveworkedout acrossBritain’s

Page 6: Structural Change and Productivity Growth in Cities · characterised in terms of the quantitative relations between input and output, between the output, employment and productivity

5

citiesisnotonlyofinterestinitsownright,butmayhaveadirectbearingoncityproductivitygrowthpaths.ThenatureofthosepathshasaparticularsalienceintheBritishcontext,giventhatthelacklustreproductivityperformanceofnationaleconomy has itself been a recurring issue of concern. Since 2010, the UKGovernmenthasrepeatedlyvoiceditsdesireto‘spatiallyrebalance’theeconomy,havingacknowledgedthatnationaleconomicgrowthhasbecometoodependentonanarrowrangeofactivities,especiallyfinance,concentratedinonepartofthecountry, namely London and the surrounding South East region. Promotinggrowthandproductivityoutsidetheseareas,andespeciallyincitiesinthenorthofthecountry,hasbecomeakeytopicofnationalpolicydiscourse.Anewmodelof limited fiscal and political devolution has been become part of the policyresponse(Sandford,2016).Yetmorerecently,theGovernmenthasdeclareditsintention to develop an industrial strategy aimed at rebalancing the economysectorally and spatially,with a view to raising the productivity of the nationaleconomy as a whole (HM Treasury, 2015; other refs). Further, the UK’sreferendumvotetoleavetheEuropeanUnion–so-called‘Brexit’-makestheneedtoimprovetheproductivityofthenation’scitiesandregionsallthemoreurgent,giventhattheyarecouldwellfacetariffsontheirexportstoEuropeandwillalsoneedtolooktootheroverseasmarketstoexporttheirgoodsandservices.

Webeginbyfirstreviewingthe literatureonstructuralchangeandhowthis relates to the ongoing debate within economic geography and urbaneconomicsontherelativemeritsofstructuralspecialisationversusdiversityasthebasisforcitysuccess.WethenexaminetheproductivityevolutionsofBritishcitiesoverthepastfortyyearsorso.Thisisfollowedbyananalysisofwhathasbeenhappeningtotheeconomicstructuresofthecitiesinquestion.Akeyissuewithinthiscontextiswhethercityeconomicstructureshavebecomemoreorlessspecialised,andwhethertheyhaveconvergedordiverged.Thepaperthenmovesontoassessthecontributionofstructuralchangetotheevolutionofproductivityacrossthestudycities.2.StructuralChangeandProductivityThereisnogeneralorwidelyacceptedeconomictheoryofstructuralchangeandits effects onproductivity, but instead a variety of theoretical approaches (seeKruger,2008,foranexcellentsurvey).Nevertheless,twotypesofargumenttendtorecur.Inone,itisthetime-evolvingincomeelasticitiesofdemandthatshapethepaceanddirectionofstructuralchange:overtime,thedemandforparticularproductsorservicesapproachessaturation,andthis,togetherwithrisingincomeeffects,stimulatestheemergenceofnewproductsandnewsectorsofactivity.Thegrowthindemandexperiencedbythesesectorsallowsincreasingreturnseffectswhich in their turnpromotehigherproductivity.Other thingsbeingequal, thisincreaseinproductivitywilltendtoreducerelativeprices,whichthenstimulates

Page 7: Structural Change and Productivity Growth in Cities · characterised in terms of the quantitative relations between input and output, between the output, employment and productivity

6

yetfurtherdemandforthenewproducts,sothattheseactivitieswillaccountforlargersharesofemploymentandoutput(thisisessentiallytheargumentbehindthe Kaldorian model of export-led, increasing returns-based, regionaldevelopment). In the other type of argument, it is the differential rates oftechnological advance that drive structural change: sectorswith a high rate oftechnological progress and labour productivity gain in importance over time,whereassectorswithalowrateoftechnologicalprogressandlabourproductivitylose ground and therefore suffer in terms of employment and value added.However,inpracticetheremaybeimportantfeedbackeffectsbetweenchangesinstructureandproductivity.Increasesinproductivityleadtoincreasesinincome,andthecompositionofthelatterwillinfluencethepatternofdemand,andhencestructuralchange.Therelationshipbetweenstructuralchangeandproductivitygrowthisthuslikelytoinvolvecirculardependencies.

Atthesametime,technologicaladvancesassociatedwiththeemergenceof new industries and sectors can spill over to existing activities, raising theirproductivity,thoughthiscanresultinreducedlabourinputs.Indeed,thetechnical,organisationalandproductupgradingwithinexisting(‘old’)sectorsmayleadtomajorproductivityadvancesintheseactivities,thoughpossiblyattheexpenseofemployment.Yetfurther,newsectorsofactivitymayexperiencesustainedgrowthindemand,andhenceinoutput,buthavelimitedscopeforproductivitygrowth,andmayevenhavelowerthanaverageproductivity.Inthiscase,theoutputandemployment shares of these sectors may rise, but the consequence for theaggregateeconomymayactuallybeaslowingofproductivitygrowth.

Therehasinfactbeenconsiderabledebateovertheapparentslowdowninproductivitygrowth inmanyadvancedeconomiesover thepast threedecades.Someattributethisapparentdeclinetomeasurementproblems,tothefactthattechnological advances and shifts simply do not show up in conventionalmeasures of (both labour and total factor) productivity (the so-called ‘SolowProductivity Paradox’ – see Triplett, 1999; Crafts, 2002). Others dispute thisargument, and argue that the slowdown is real (Cowen 2016; Gordon, 2016;Syverson,2016).AccordingtoGordon(2016)andCowen(2016),forexample,innovationhasstalled,andtechnologicalprogressnolongerproducethegainsinGDPthatitoncedid.AsimilarviewisespousedbyCowen(2016),thathigh-techdevelopments have not saved advanced economies from a slowdown inproductivity.Yetanotherexplanationpointstothefallinbusinessdynamismoverthepasttwotothreedecades(EuropeanCentralBank,2016),asreflectedinnewfirm formation rates: new firms are assumed to embody more advancedtechnologyandtobemoreproductivethanoldexistingfirms.WhilemuchofthedebatehascentredontheUnitesStateseconomy,similarconcernanddiscussionhave also surrounded the productivity performances of other OECD countries(OECD,2015),includingtheUK.

Thesecularshifttoservicesthattypifiesalladvancedeconomieshasalso

Page 8: Structural Change and Productivity Growth in Cities · characterised in terms of the quantitative relations between input and output, between the output, employment and productivity

7

provokeddivergentviews,withsomeobserversarguingthatmanyservices(suchasretail,hospitality,personalservices,andevensomeprofessionalandbusinessservices)have limitedpotential forhighproductivitygrowth,andmayevenbe‘stagnant’asfarasproductivityisconcerned(Baumol,1967;Baumoletal,1985;Williamson,1991;Kim,2006).Otherauthors,however,pointtothefactthatmanyservicesfunctionasintermediaryinputstothemanufacturingsector,andmaynotonlyhelptoraisetheproductivityofthelatter,butthemselvesmayhaveasmuchscope for increasing their own productivity (Oulton, 2001). The trend formanufacturing firms to outsource certain routine service activities that werepreviouslycarriedout ‘inhouse’,whileatthesametimeoftendevelopingtheirowncustomer-orientatedserviceactivities(fromfinancetoafter-care),maywellalsohaveimpactedonthemeasurementandallocationofproductivityadvancebetween‘manufacturing’and‘services’incomplexandnotunambiguousways.

What is clear is that the relationship between structural change andproductivitygrowthisnotasimplenorself-evidentone:productivitygrowthcanbeofa‘within-sector’kind,arisingfromtechnologicalandrelatedimprovementsamongstfirmsinthatsector;and‘between-sector’,orstructural-changeinduced,arisingfromtheshiftandreallocationofcapitalandlabourfromlowproductivitygrowthsectorsintohigherproductivitygrowthones(seeTable1). Therehavebeenvariousrecentattemptstoassesstherelativecontributionofsuch‘within’and‘between’effectstoaggregateproductivitygrowth.Someofthesehaveusedsuch a ‘within’ and ‘between’ sectoral decomposition of a particular nation’sproductivity growth, andothers to examinedifferences inproductivity growthbetweencountries(Fagerberg,2000;Pieper,2000;Peneder,2003;Kruger,2006;Ocampoetal,2009;TimmeranddeVries,2009;andKuceraandRoncolato,2012).Althoughtheresultsvaryacrosstimeperiods,datafrequency,whetherstructureis measured by employment shares or output shares, the choice of labourproductivity or total factor productivity, and the particular decompositiontechnique used, the balance of the findings is that the ‘within-sector’ effectdominatesthe‘between-sector’effect(ie.theeffectduetostructuralchange),withthestudybyMcMillanandRodrikalsofindingthisforsome,thoughnotall,ofthecountriesintheirstudy.Haltiwanger(2000)hasarguedthatstructuralchangeismuchmore intensewithin industries (that is among the firmswithindifferentsub-branchesofanindustry)thatbetweenindustries,evenatdetailedlevelsofindustrialdisaggregation.Yet thevarious studies thathaveuseda ‘within’ and‘between’firmdecompositiontoinvestigateproductivitygrowthofagivenbroadsector(Bailyetal,1992,2001;Fosteretal,1998;BartlesmanandDoms,2000;Disneyatel,2003,CantnerandKruger,2006)alsotendtofindthe‘within-firm’effectisgreaterthanthe‘between-firm’effect.Asfarasweareaware,thissortofdecomposition analysis has not been conducted to examine the productivitygrowthpathofcities,whichisouraiminwhatfollows.First,however,usingournovel data set, we explore how British cities have actually fared in terms ofproductivitygrowth.

Page 9: Structural Change and Productivity Growth in Cities · characterised in terms of the quantitative relations between input and output, between the output, employment and productivity

8

Table1:WithinandBetweenSectorSourcesofCityProductivityGrowthWithinsectordevelopments(firmdynamics)

Betweensectordevelopments(crosssectoralstructuralshiftsandreallocations)

Death of low productivity firms and birth of newhigher-productivityfirms

BroadswitchfromPrimaryIndustrytoManufacturingtoServices

Adoption of new organizational and operationalmethodsandtechnologicalinnovations

Declineoflowproductivityactivitiesandbirthanddevelopmentofhighproductivityactivities

Production of new higher-value products andservicesandswitchintonewmarkets

Industryrestructuring–mixingandnewcombinationswithothersectorstoproducehigherproductivityindustries

3.ProductivityGrowthPathsofBritishCitiesAsmentionedabove,theissueofproductivitygrowthintheBritisheconomyhaslongbeenarecurringtopicofacademicandpoliticaldebate.Figure1showshowlabourproductivitygrowthintheUKeconomyhasbeenhighlyvariablefromyearto year since 1950. However, certain features are evident. First, the rate ofproductivitygrowthactuallytrendedupwardsfrom1950to1973,butsincethenthe trend has been on a downward path. In fact,while theUK annual rate ofgrowthover1971-1991averaged2.13percent,over1991-2014theaveragefellto1.46percent.Howfarthe‘turningpoint’intheunderlyingtrendofproductivitygrowtharound1973reflectedtheendofthepost-warexpansionofemploymentin manufacturing, or the impact of the recession of the early-1970s (itselfassociatedwith the firstof theOPECoilpricehikes),are interestingquestions.While all of the major sectors of the economy have experienced productivitygrowth,itisevidentthatsincethebeginningofthe1980s,productivityadvancein manufacturing or production (manufacturing plus construction) has beenfaster than inmarket (private)services,especially if financeand insuranceareexcludedfromthelatter(Figure2).Shiftsintheeconomicstructureofcitiesawayfrommanufacturingtowardsservicesmightbeexpected,therefore,tohavehadpotentiallysignificantimplicationsforcityaggregateproductivity.Figure1:AnnualGrowthRateofLabourProductivityintheUK,1950-2015

Page 10: Structural Change and Productivity Growth in Cities · characterised in terms of the quantitative relations between input and output, between the output, employment and productivity

9

Source:OfficeforNationalStatistics

With regard to British cities, an immediate major issue is the lack of anycomprehensive and consistent official economic time series data. As part of alargerprogrammeofresearchoncityeconomicevolutions,wehaveconstructednewdataseriesonemployment,grossvalueadded(GVA),andlabourproductivity(GVAperemployedworker)forsome85citiesfor82sectorsofactivity,yearlyfrom1971to2014(andon249sectors from1991to2014). Wehavedefinedthese cities spatially on the basis of the 2011 travel-to-work area (TTWA)boundariesasdelineatedbytheUKOfficeforNationalStatistics.Therearesome228TTWAscoveringthewholeoftheUK.ThecriteriafordefiningTTWAsisthatgenerally75percentofanarea’sresidentworkforceworkintheareaandatleast75 percent of those who work in the area also live there. For TTWAs with aworking population of 25,000 or more, self-containment rates as low as 66.7percentareaccepted.OnlythoseareasbasedonanidentifiablecitywithatotalTTWApopulationofat least200,000wereselectedasourfinalsetof85cities.Together these cities, in 2014, accounted for some 83 percent of Britishemployment and85percent of British output (gross value added).2They thusmakeupthebulkofthenationaleconomy.

2 Because of lack of basic data we were unable to include any cities in Northern Ireland.Correspondingly,weuseGreatBritainratherthantheUKasthebaseforsuchcalculations.

!4#

!3#

!2#

!1#

0#

1#

2#

3#

4#

5#

6#

1950#

1953#

1956#

1959#

1962#

1965#

1968#

1971#

1974#

1977#

1980#

1983#

1986#

1989#

1992#

1995#

1998#

2001#

2004#

2007#

2010#

2013#

Annu

al#Growth#in#Labou

r#Produ

c>vity#(G

VA#

per#E

mployed

#Person),#percent#

Trend#Line#is#Best#Fit#Poynomial#(Second#Order)#

Page 11: Structural Change and Productivity Growth in Cities · characterised in terms of the quantitative relations between input and output, between the output, employment and productivity

10

Figure 2: Labour Productivity in Selected Major Sectors of the BritishEconomy (Gross Value Added per Employedworker, 2005 Prices), 1971-2009

Source:OfficeforNationalStatistics(https://www.ons.gov.uk/employmentandlabourmarket/peopleinwork/labourproductivity/datasets/labourproductivity

Thevariationinlabourproductivitylevelsacrossthe85citiesin1971andin2014isshowninFigure3.Thecitieshavebeengroupedinto ‘northern’andsouthern’setsaccordingtotheregionoftheirlocation,usingtheconventionalwayof dividing theUK into these twobroad geographical areas.Also shown is thenational average (Great Britain) productivity level for the two years. What isstrikingisthatallbarthreenortherncities(Crew,ChesterandTelford)areinthebottomleft-handquadrantoftheFigure,havingproductivitylevelslessthanthenationalaveragebothatthebeginningoftheperiodandattheend.However,atthe same time, the correlation between productivity levels in 1971 and 2014,thoughsignificant(R=0.686)isnotparticularlyhigh, indicatingcertainshiftsinrelativepositionovertheperiod;inotherwords,productivitygrowthratesacrosscitieshavenotbeenproportionate.

50

100

150

200

250

300

350

4001971

1973

1975

1977

1979

1981

1983

1985

1987

1989

1991

1993

1995

1997

1999

2001

2003

2005

2007

2009

Labo

urProd

uctiv

ity(G

VAperemployed

worker),1971=100)

Manufacturing

Production

Privateservices

PrivateServicesExcFinanceConstruction

Page 12: Structural Change and Productivity Growth in Cities · characterised in terms of the quantitative relations between input and output, between the output, employment and productivity

11

Figure3:LabourProductivityAcross85BritishCities,1971and2014(GrossValueAddedperemployedworker,2011prices)

Source:Authors’owndataNote:Southerncitiesdefinedasthoseinthefollowingregions:London,SouthEast,EastofEngland,SouthWestandEastMidlands.NortherncitiesdefinedasthoseintheWestMidlands,Yorkshire-Humberside,NorthEast,NorthEast,ScotlandandWales.GreatBritainaveragesshownbyintersectingpeckedlines.

Inthiscontext,an interestingfeatureemerges intherelationshipacrosscitiesbetweentheirinitialproductivitylevelsandtheirsubsequentproductivitygrowthwhenthewholestudyperiodisdividedintothetwosub-periods(Figure4). In the first sub-period, 1971-1991, which corresponds to when nationalproductivity advance was higher, the relationship is negative (R=-0.581). Anegative relationship indicates that cities which had initially low labourproductivitylevelstendedsubsequentlytoexperiencefasterproductivitygrowth,thatisto‘catchup’withcitiesthatinitiallyhadhigherproductivitylevels.Thisisin linewith thepredictionsofstandardneoclassicalgrowththeory.But for thesecondsub-period,1991-2014,therelationshipisnolongernegativebutweaklypositive(R=0.109).ThechangingpatternevidentinFigure4indicatesthatwhileBritish cities converged in terms of productivity in the 1970 and 1980s, thistendencydisappearedover the1990sand2000s. Thedetailed timepathsofproductivityforsomeselectedcitiesillustratethischangeddynamic(seeFigure5,inwhichtheseriesareindexedatGreatBritain=100).

25000

30000

35000

40000

45000

50000

55000

60000

10000 15000 20000 25000 30000 35000

Prod

ucvity(G

VAperemployed

Worker)in

2014

Productivity(GVAperEmployedWorker)in1971

London

Reading

MiltonKeynes

Oxford

Slough

Basingstoke

Sunderland

Blyth

Merthyr TydfilExeter

Derby

Plymouth

Swindon

NorthernCities

SouthernCities

R=0.686

GBAverage

GBAverage

Page 13: Structural Change and Productivity Growth in Cities · characterised in terms of the quantitative relations between input and output, between the output, employment and productivity

12

Figure4:ShiftingPatternsofLabourProductivityGrowthacrossBritishCities,1971-2014(GrossValueaddedperemployedworker,2011prices)

Source:Authors’owndataNote:SoutherncitiesandnortherncitiesdefinedasinFigure2.

Forexample,Oxford,Reading,MedwayandStevenage,initiallyhighproductivitycities, all lost ground against the national average until around 1991, whileSunderland, Doncaster and Merthyr Tydfil, initially low productivity cities, all

0

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5

3

3.5

4

4.5

5

10000 15000 20000 25000 30000 35000

AverageAn

nualGrowthofLab

our

Prod

uctiv

ity(perce

nt)

LabourProductivity,1971

Period1971-1991

Oxford

Reading

MedwayLeamington

HighWycombe

MilfordKeynes

London

Sunderland

BlythMansfield

NorthernCities

York

MerthyrTydfil

SouthernCities

0

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5

3

3.5

4

4.5

5

20000 25000 30000 35000 40000

AverageAn

nualGrowthofLab

our

Prod

uctiv

ity,1991-2014(Percent)

LabourProductivity,1991

Period1991-2014NorthernCitiesSouthernCities

LondonReading

TunbridgeWells

Oxford

GuilfordStevenage

Preston YorkSwansea

Blackpool

Exeter

Cardiff

Page 14: Structural Change and Productivity Growth in Cities · characterised in terms of the quantitative relations between input and output, between the output, employment and productivity

13

gainedground.Thegeneralpatternofmoderateconvergence isclearlyevident(aside from London). From 1991 onwards, however, divergence is apparent.London has continued to pull ahead throughout the period, while Liverpool’sproductivityhasbarelykeptupwiththatnationally.Further,andsignificantly,ifwegroupthe85citiesintothoseinthe‘south’ofBritain,andthoseinthe‘north’,thereisclearevidenceofa‘switch’inrelativeproductivitygrowthbetweenthesetwogroupsbetween1971-1991and1991-2014,withnortherncitiesoutpacingsoutherncitiesinthefirstsub-period,butthelatterout-performingtheformerinthemorerecentsub-period(Table2).

Table2:ProductivityGrowthinNorthernandSouthernCities(AverageannualgrowthinGVAperemployedperson,percentperannum)

1971-1991

1991-2014

SouthernCitiesNorthernCitiesGreatBritain

1.842.28

2.08

2.05

1.511.69

Thekeyquestionof interesthere iswhether,how farand inwhatways, thesechangingpatternsofproductivityacrosstheBritishcitieshavebeeninfluencedstructuraleconomicchangesincethebeginningofthe1970s.Toexplorethisissue,wefirstexaminehowtheeconomicstructuresofthecitiesthemselveshavebeenevolvingoverthisperiod.4.CityEconomicStructureandStructuralChangeThere are numerous indicators which can be used to capture local economicstructureandwithwhichtocomparedifferentareasatanyparticularpointintime.EarlydiscussionsofarangeofalternativemeasurescanbefoundinIsardetal(1960)andBahletal(1971).Morerecently,Palan(2010)reviewednofewerthanninedifferentmeasures. Someof thesewere ‘absolute’measures, inwhich theactualsectoraldistributionofalocalarea’semploymentoroutputiscomparedtoa defined ‘base-line’ metric, usually that of a perfectly equal distribution ofsectoralshares;whileotherswere‘relative’measures,wherethecomparisoniswithsomechosen‘norm’or‘reference’economy,forexamplethenationalsectoralstructure.Palanassessedthevariousmeasuresfortheextent

Page 15: Structural Change and Productivity Growth in Cities · characterised in terms of the quantitative relations between input and output, between the output, employment and productivity

14

Figure5:RelativeTimePathsofLabourProductivityforSelectedCities,1971-2014,IndexedtoGB=100

Source:Authors’owndatatowhichtheysatisfycertaincriteria(orwhatshecalledaxioms)3andthenusedthemtoexamineandcomparetheeconomicstructuresofEuropeancountries.Shefoundthatthedifferentmeasuresdonotyieldconsistentresults,andthatnooneapproach could be said to be superior: to some extent the choice ofmeasuresdependsonthespecificpurposeinmind.

One of themost commonly usedmeasures of city or regional economicstructureisthecoefficientofrelativespecialization(seeIsard,1960;ThirlwallandDixon,1975).ThishasdeployedbyKrugmanonanumberofoccasionstoexaminecity and regional specialization (Krugman, 1991, 1993), and for that reason isoftencalledthe‘KrugmanIndex’.Ittakestheform

𝐶𝑅𝑆$% = |()*+ 𝑠)$% − 𝑠)%∗ | (1)

where,𝑠)$istheshareoftotalemployment(oroutput)incityjaccountedforbysector iattimet,𝑠)∗is thecorrespondingemployment(oroutput)shareofthatsectorinthecomparator‘referenceeconomy’alsoattimet,andNisthenumber

3 Palan lists four such axioms: anonymity, or invariance to ordering of sectors; progressivetransfers, or the principle of rank-preserving equalisation; having defined upper and lowerbounds;anddecomposabilityintowithinandbetweencomponents(suchassectorsorfirms).

50

60

70

80

90

100

110

120

130

140

1501971

1973

1975

1977

1979

1981

1983

1985

1987

1989

1991

1993

1995

1997

1999

2001

2003

2005

2007

2009

2011

2013

RelativeGV

AperW

orker,GB

=100

LondonReading

Oxford

BasingstokeStevenageMedwaySunderlandLiverpoolMerthyrTydfilDoncaster

Page 16: Structural Change and Productivity Growth in Cities · characterised in terms of the quantitative relations between input and output, between the output, employment and productivity

15

of sectors involved in the analysis. The sum is over the absolute differencesbetween the industry shares of a given city’s employment (or output) and thecorresponding industryshares in thereferenceeconomy.Asdefined, the indextakesthevalueofzerowhenacity(orregion)hasexactlythesamestructureasthereferenceeconomy(sinceeachabsolutesectoralsharedifferencein(1)woulditselfbezero).Theindexincreasesthemorethatthecity’s(region’s)economicstructurediffersfromthereferenceeconomy.Ifthecity(region)sharednosectorincommonwiththereferenceeconomy(whichmightbeanothercityorregion),then the maximum value the index would be 2, since each absolute sectoraldifference in (1)wouldbe counted in full.This isnot the case,however, if thenationaleconomyistakenasthereferencenorm,sincebydefinitionthenationaleconomymustshareatleastonesectorincommonwithatleastoneofitscities(regions).Inthiscasetheupperboundoftheindexis2[(N-1)]/N.Alternatively,the ‘national reference economy’ could be calculated individually for each city(region)astheweightedsumofallothercities(regions)minusthecity(region)inquestion.Inthiscaseitispossiblethatthecityand‘adjusted’nationalreferenceeconomydonotshareallofthesamesectors,sothattheupperlimitof2wouldagainbeappropriate.

AccordingtoKrugman,theindexisa“roughwayofquantifyingdifferencesinstructures,andhenceregionalspecialization”(1993,p.250).Strictlyspeaking,however,ittellsusmoreaboutstructuraldissimilaritybetweenregions,orcities,thanaboutregionalorcityspecializationperse,sinceeveniftheindexforacityis close to zero, suggesting little difference from the reference economy, thereferenceeconomyitselfcouldbenarrowlyspecialisedinparticularsectors,sointhiscaseboththecityandthenationwouldbeequallyandsimilarlyspecialized.

Thusanadditionalmeasureisrequiredinordertocapturewhetheracityis absolutely specialisedordiversified economically. Theobvious approach tomeasuring the degree of diversity of a city’s economic structure is to compareactual sectoral (employment or output) shares against an equi-proportiondistributionofshares,thatisastateofcompletediversityorbalancedstructure.Thereareseveralpossiblemeasuresthatcanbeusedforthispurpose(see, forexample,Isardetal,1960;GibbsandPostan,1975;Kruger,2006;Palan,2010).TheseincludeShannon’sEntropyIndex(forexample,AigingerandDavies,2004;AigingerandPfaffermayr,2004),theIndexofInequalityinProductionStructure(see Cuadrado-Roura et al., 1999; Haaland et al., 1999; Landesmann, 2000;Percocoetal.,2005), theTheil Index(BrulhartandTraeger,2005;EzcurraandPascual,2007),and theHirschman-Herfindahl Index(forexample,Sapir,1996;Davis, 1998; Storper et al, 2002; Aiginger and Pfaffermayr, 2004; Beine andCoulombe, 2007). As Palan (2010) shows, although a simple measure, theHirschman-Herfindahlsatisfiesmostofthekeycriteriarequiredforausefuland

Page 17: Structural Change and Productivity Growth in Cities · characterised in terms of the quantitative relations between input and output, between the output, employment and productivity

16

meaningfulindexofdiversity.The Hirchman-Herfindahl index is defined as the sum of the squared sectoralshares, 𝐻𝐻𝐼$% = 𝑠)$%2(

)*+ (2)

where,asinEquation(1),theshares𝑠)$%areexpressedasproportionsofunity.The index ranges from aminimum of 1/N, when all sectoral shares are equal(maximumdiversity)toanupperboundof1,inwhichcaseacitywouldbemono-specialised,that isallof itsactivityis in justoneindustry.Becausethesectoralsharesaresquared,theindexgivesmoreweighttolargesectors.Forthisreason,thesquarerootoftheindexissometimesused(forexample,ChisholmandOeppen,1973).

BoththeCRS(Krugman)IndexandtheHirschman-HerfindahlIndexcanbeusedforidentifyingandtrackingstructuralchangeinindividualcitiesandregionsby comparing values of the indices at different points in time.4 If structure ischanging,thefirstplacetolookisatthepatternsoftheemploymentandoutputsharesandthechangestheyevinceovertime.InthecaseoftheCRS,byusingthenationaleconomyas thereferenceeconomy, the indexcan illuminatewhether,howfarandhowfast,cityeconomicstructuresareconverging(decliningvaluesoftheindex),ordiverging(increasingvaluesoftheindex).NotethattheCRScanbealsousedtochartthechangingeconomicstructureofacityrelativetoitsown‘starting’structure,atsayt=0,bysettingthereference‘norm’𝑠)$%∗ in(1)to𝑠)$3.Inthisinstance,structuralchangewouldbeindicatedbyrisingvaluesoftheindexovertime,asthecityincreasinglydivergedfromitsoriginalmixofsectors.WithrespecttotheHHI, ifthereisproportionalgrowthacrosssectors,andhencenostructural change, the indexwould remain constant over time (Metcalfe et al,2006).Changesintheindexthusindicatestructuralchange:successivevaluesthatmovedtowards1/Novertimewould indicate increasingequality(diversity) ineconomic structure, whereas a trend towards 1 would indicate increasingspecialisation. The rate of change of theHHI is proportional to the covariancebetween employment (or output) shares and employment (or output) growthrates:

dHHI/dt= 2 𝑠)$%(𝑔)$%()*+ − 𝑔$%)𝑠)$% (3)

4Therearemeasuresthatareintendedtocapturethescaleandspeedofstructuralchangeinaregionorcityeconomydirectly,forexampletheLilienIndex(Lilien,1982;Ansarietal,2013),butthesedonotofthemselvestellusmuchaboutwhetherthatchangeisleadingtodiversificationorspecialisationofaregion’sorcity’sstructure

Page 18: Structural Change and Productivity Growth in Cities · characterised in terms of the quantitative relations between input and output, between the output, employment and productivity

17

where𝑔)$%isthegrowthrateofemployment(oroutput)insectoriincityj,and𝑔$%isthecity’saggregateemployment(oroutput)growthrate.

That pronounced ongoing structural changes have transformed the UKeconomyoverthepastfiftyyearsorsoisclearlyevidentfromFigures6and7.Inbroadterms,themostprofoundchangehasbeentheshiftfromaneconomybasedon production industries (manufacturing, construction and utilities) to onedominated by privatemarket services. The decline in production employmentfromitspeakofjustover11million(or41percentoftotaljobs)in1966to5.5million (19 percent) in 2010 represents one of the most rapid rates ofdeindustrialisation inthewesternworld(Ref).Likewise,having increasedoverthetwodecadesaftertheSecondWar,theshareofproductionindustriesintotaloutputsteadilyincreasedtoreachapeakof38percentin1969,andthereafterprogressively declined, falling to 22 percent by 2009. At the same timeemploymentinprivatemarketservicesincreasedfrom8.8million(34percent)in1969 to 14.4 million (50 percent) in 2009. If we add in local and centralgovernment,theserviceeconomyincreaseditsshareoftotalemploymentfrom53percent in1969to80percent in2009,and itsshareof totalnationalGrossValueAddedfrom38percentto55percentoverthesameperiod. Themacro-structureofthenationaleconomyontheeveofthefinancialcrisisin2007lookedverydifferentindeedfromthatin1970.

Figure6:StructuralChangeintheBritishEconomy:EmploymentSharesbyBroadSector,1949-2011

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

1948

1951

1954

1957

1960

1963

1966

1969

1972

1975

1978

1981

1984

1987

1990

1993

1996

1999

2002

2005

2008

2011

Percen

tofTotalEm

ploymen

t MarketServices

Government

Production

Manufacturing

Primary

Page 19: Structural Change and Productivity Growth in Cities · characterised in terms of the quantitative relations between input and output, between the output, employment and productivity

18

Source:OfficeforNationalStatistics,UKNote:Notes:Productionincludesmanufacturing,construction,andutilities(energyandwater).Governmentincludescentralandlocalpublicservicesandadministration.Figure7:StructuralChangeintheBritishEconomy:SharesofGrossValueAdded,byBroadSector,1949-2009

Source:OfficeforNationalStatistics,UKNotes:SectorsdefinedasinFigure5.

Howhave thesestructuralshiftsandchangesworkedoutacrossBritishcities? The calculated CRS (Krugman) indices of structural specialisation byemploymentandbyoutputacross82sectorsforthe85citiesfor1971,1991and2014 are given in Tables 3 and 4 respectively. For each city, the referenceeconomyinEquation(1)wasdefinedasGreatBritainminusthecityinquestion,soastoavoiddoublecounting(whichwouldnotbeinsignificantinthecaseofthelargest cities such as London, Birmingham, Manchester, Sheffield, Liverpool,Glasgow and Edinburgh). Several key features stand out. First, in 1971, citiesdifferedmarkedlyinthedegreeofrelativestructuralspecialisation,whether interms of employment or output. Second, in both instances, the large cities(regional capitals) and Londonwere less specialised thanmost other, smallercities.Third,inthecaseofemploymentstructure,allbutonecity(Slough)haveexperiencedadeclineinrelativespecialisationsince1971.Thetrendsinoutputstructures are broadly similar, although some thirteen cities experienced an

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

1949

1952

1955

1958

1961

1964

1967

1970

1973

1976

1979

1982

1985

1988

1991

1994

1997

2000

2003

2006

2009

Percen

tofG

rossVa

lueA

dded

(2005Price

s)

MarketServices

ProductionGovernment

Manufacturing

Primary

Page 20: Structural Change and Productivity Growth in Cities · characterised in terms of the quantitative relations between input and output, between the output, employment and productivity

19

increaseinrelativespecialisation,ordivergencefromthestructureofthenationaleconomy.Fourth,whethermeasuredbyemploymentsharesoroutputshares,themorespecialisedacitywas in1971, thegreater thereduction inspecialisationovertheensuingperiod(Figures8and9).Thuswhattheanalysisshows,atthelevelofthe82sectorsusedhere,isatendencyforstructuralconvergenceacrosstheBritishcitysystemoverthepastfortyyearsorso.Table3:CRS(Krugman)EmploymentSpecialisationIndicesforBritishCities(82sectors),1971,1991and2014(Citiesrankedindescendingorderofspecialisationfor1971)

1971 1991 2014 1971 1991 2014 Sunderland 0.717 0.417 0.385 Crewe 0.510 0.314 0.242 Mansfield 0.711 0.440 0.296 Stevenage 0.510 0.335 0.292 Halifax 0.686 0.430 0.407 Doncaster 0.504 0.339 0.363 Swansea 0.679 0.321 0.352 Plymouth 0.503 0.382 0.343 MerthyrTydfil 0.677 0.409 0.380 Barnsley 0.502 0.398 0.354 Oxford 0.664 0.325 0.301 Leicester 0.501 0.313 0.280 Kettering&Wellingborough 0.659 0.419 0.349DuDurham&BishopAuckland 0.500 0.417 0.357 Wolverhampton 0.656 0.419 0.269 TunbridgeWells 0.497 0.280 0.280 Blackpool 0.647 0.518 0.399 Bedford 0.493 0.272 0.234 Blackburn 0.634 0.410 0.348 Hull 0.483 0.320 0.316 Dudley 0.621 0.403 0.357 Bristol 0.480 0.325 0.220 Middlesbrough 0.617 0.444 0.305 Peterborough 0.480 0.335 0.289 Trowbridge 0.612 0.346 0.246 Sheffield 0.479 0.252 0.278 Coventry 0.609 0.379 0.296 Warrington&Wigan 0.468 0.296 0.278 Derby 0.606 0.430 0.295 Shrewsbury 0.462 0.259 0.279 Stoke-on-Trent 0.599 0.414 0.325 Medway 0.460 0.276 0.191 Newport 0.597 0.403 0.325 HighWycombe&Aylesbury 0.459 0.297 0.265 Aberdeen 0.592 0.524 0.474 Crawley 0.458 0.362 0.285 Huddersfield 0.589 0.380 0.351 Brighton 0.454 0.300 0.280 Birkenhead 0.584 0.394 0.289 Preston 0.453 0.295 0.286 Colchester 0.581 0.354 0.273 Cambridge 0.452 0.311 0.240 Motherwell&Airdrie 0.577 0.362 0.359 Guildford 0.450 0.285 0.257 Northampton 0.573 0.383 0.332 Liverpool 0.447 0.265 0.234 Bradford 0.568 0.363 0.307 Nottingham 0.445 0.255 0.269 MiltonKeynes 0.551 0.324 0.315 Swindon 0.442 0.282 0.255 FalkirkandStirling 0.550 0.365 0.288 Norwich 0.440 0.269 0.222 Dunfermline&Kirkcaldy 0.550 0.381 0.325 Lincoln 0.439 0.309 0.243 Basingstoke 0.549 0.376 0.366 Ipswich 0.436 0.310 0.251 Blyth&Ashington 0.548 0.398 0.408 Edinburgh 0.434 0.316 0.314 Exeter 0.544 0.338 0.268 Luton 0.434 0.298 0.281 Gloucester 0.540 0.313 0.297 Chelmsford 0.430 0.239 0.164 Bournemouth 0.535 0.329 0.287 Southend 0.423 0.393 0.224 Chester 0.535 0.322 0.261 Worcester&Kidderminster 0.418 0.309 0.264 Chichester 0.530 0.311 0.264 London 0.411 0.387 0.387 Wakefield 0.529 0.382 0.368 Leeds 0.408 0.270 0.227 Chesterfield 0.529 0.446 0.252 Newcastle 0.396 0.258 0.252 Birmingham 0.526 0.308 0.175 Southampton 0.368 0.249 0.184 LeamingtonSpa 0.525 0.322 0.338 Slough&Heathrow 0.352 0.330 0.370 Telford 0.522 0.450 0.376 Cardiff 0.340 0.213 0.233 Portsmouth 0.519 0.311 0.266 Glasgow 0.3280.2090.224 Dundee 0.518 0.345 0.304 Manchester 0.3240.1870.169 Reading 0.513 0.378 0.393 York 0.512 0.357 0.263 Eastbourne 0.511 0.492 0.270

Page 21: Structural Change and Productivity Growth in Cities · characterised in terms of the quantitative relations between input and output, between the output, employment and productivity

20

Table4:CRS(Krugman)OutputSpecialisationIndicesforBritishCities,(82sectors),1971,1991and2014(Citiesrankedindescendingorderofspecialisationfor1971)

197119912014197119912014Oxford 0.723 0.420 0.375 Stoke-on-Trent 0.488 0.466 0.432Kettering&Wellingborough 0.709 0.498 0.513 Leicester 0.488 0.348 0.368Blackpool 0.668 0.488 0.516 Dundee 0.488 0.471 0.432Wolverhampton 0.659 0.450 0.402 Stevenage 0.487 0.418 0.398Basingstoke 0.644 0.433 0.477 Sheffield 0.484 0.345 0.403Swansea 0.634 0.454 0.511 Bournemouth 0.484 0.365 0.313LeamingtonSpa 0.634 0.420 0.539 HighWycombe&Aylesbury 0.481 0.330 0.399Plymouth 0.633 0.509 0.500 Chelmsford 0.481 0.334 0.279Blackburn 0.633 0.508 0.485 Exeter 0.480 0.397 0.408Trowbridge 0.600 0.451 0.281 TunbridgeWells 0.479 0.380 0.332Birkenhead 0.593 0.552 0.400 Bedford 0.479 0.384 0.341Chester 0.590 0.416 0.399 Cambridge 0.479 0.405 0.365Crewe 0.590 0.439 0.412 Peterborough 0.478 0.360 0.323Halifax 0.582 0.443 0.432 Telford 0.478 0.507 0.511MerthyrTydfil 0.580 0.491 0.547 Hull 0.477 0.418 0.500Middlesbrough 0.576 0.517 0.489 Blyth&Ashington 0.476 0.472 0.541Portsmouth 0.567 0.427 0.372 Shrewsbury 0.472 0.405 0.424Coventry 0.559 0.527 0.432 London 0.468 0.548 0.643Sunderland 0.558 0.447 0.525 Dunfermline&Kirkcaldy 0.467 0.439 0.436Derby 0.554 0.503 0.535 Doncaster 0.465 0.483 0.538Medway 0.551 0.361 0.297 York 0.463 0.532 0.419Mansfield 0.551 0.515 0.483 Worcester&Kidderminster 0.457 0.483 0.361Chesterfield 0.551 0.505 0.444 Guildford 0.456 0.443 0.358Reading 0.546 0.446 0.587 Eastbourne 0.453 0.494 0.366Dudley 0.544 0.463 0.454 Brighton 0.446 0.372 0.333Huddersfield 0.542 0.459 0.450 Ipswich 0.438 0.432 0.309Aberdeen 0.542 1.044 0.744 Crawley 0.437 0.490 0.342Barnsley 0.535 0.488 0.487 Norwich 0.432 0.343 0.292MiltonKeynes 0.532 0.359 0.423 Birmingham 0.427 0.374 0.275Preston 0.529 0.502 0.377 Swindon 0.426 0.316 0.435Gloucester 0.522 0.349 0.385 Lincoln 0.418 0.443 0.487Bristol 0.518 0.363 0.255 Nottingham 0.414 0.329 0.409Wakefield 0.515 0.486 0.479 Southampton 0.413 0.350 0.314Newport 0.508 0.455 0.492 Southend 0.386 0.397 0.331Liverpool 0.507 0.328 0.328 Newcastle 0.384 0.302 0.393Falkirkand&Stirling 0.507 0.456 0.430 Edinburgh 0.381 0.389 0.430Colchester 0.504 0.426 0.358 Leeds 0.381 0.288 0.236Motherwell&Airdrie 0.501 0.443 0.475 Luton 0.371 0.386 0.331Bradford 0.501 0.390 0.392 Manchester 0.353 0.332 0.200Warrington&Wigan 0.498 0.388 0.401 Cardiff 0.339 0.330 0.373Durham&BishopAuckland 0.497 0.509 0.526 Glasgow 0.316 0.271 0.271Northampton 0.491 0.442 0.438 Slough&Heathrow 0.294 0.397 0.489Chichester 0.489 0.419 0.340

Page 22: Structural Change and Productivity Growth in Cities · characterised in terms of the quantitative relations between input and output, between the output, employment and productivity

21

Figure 8: Sectoral Convergence in Employment Structures Across Cities,1971-2014

Figure9:SectoralConvergenceinOutputStructuresAcrossCities,1971-2014

-0.500

-0.400

-0.300

-0.200

-0.100

0.000

0.100

0.200 0.300 0.400 0.500 0.600 0.700 0.800

Chan

geinKrugm

anInde

x,1971-2014

KrugmanIndex,1971

R=-0.534

Slough

LondonGlasgow

Manchester

Newcastle

Southampton

Sunderland

Mansfield

Halifax

Wolverhampton

Aberdeen

-0.400

-0.300

-0.200

-0.100

0.000

0.100

0.200

0.300

0.200 0.300 0.400 0.500 0.600 0.700 0.800

Chan

geinKrugm

anInde

x,1971-2014

KrugmanIndex1971

Oxford

Kettering

Wolverhampton

Trowbridge

AberdeenLondon

DoncasterReading

Manchester

Glasgow

CardiffEdinburgh

Bristol

R=-0.379

Page 23: Structural Change and Productivity Growth in Cities · characterised in terms of the quantitative relations between input and output, between the output, employment and productivity

22

ThecorrespondingHHindicesfor1971,1991and2014aregiveninTables5and6,withthedetailedtemporaltrendsforselectedcitiesshowninFigures10and11. Theseshowseveral interesting features. Ingeneral, cities tend tobemorespecializedintermsofoutputstructuresthaninemploymentstructures;thiswasespecially the case in the 1970s and 1980s. With respect to employmentstructures,morethanhalfofthecitiesexperiencedadeclineinspecializationovertheperiod1971-2014.Thosecitiesthatweremorespecializedinitiallyunderwentthelargestdeclines,whilesomeofthecitiesleastspecialisedinitiallyexperiencedan increase inemploymentspecialization.TheHHstructural indices foroutputshares,however, showamoredefinitepattern,withmost citiesbecoming lessspecializedoverthefourdecades.AsinthecaseoftheKrugmanindices,itwouldappearthatthedeclineinspecialisationwasmostevidentinthe1971-1991subperiod,andthatstructuralchangesincethenhasbeenslower.Table 5: Hirschman-Herfindahl Employment Specialisation Indices forBritishCities,(82sectors),1971,1991and2014(Citiesrankedindescendingorderofspecialisationfor1971________________________________________________________________________________________________

1971 1991 2014 1971 1991 2014Oxford 0.081 0.052 0.054 York 0.046 0.045 0.045Sunderland 0.077 0.043 0.045 Edinburgh 0.045 0.043 0.043Huddersfield 0.072 0.041 0.046 Peterborough 0.045 0.039 0.045Stoke-on-Trent 0.071 0.050 0.044 Aberdeen 0.045 0.041 0.042Halifax 0.071 0.037 0.045 Newport 0.045 0.042 0.048Dudley 0.067 0.043 0.045 Luton 0.044 0.043 0.044Trowbridge 0.066 0.050 0.041 Cambridge 0.044 0.044 0.044Bradford 0.060 0.045 0.045 Chesterfield 0.043 0.047 0.042Middlesbrough 0.060 0.045 0.050 Worcester&Kidderminster 0.043 0.048 0.043Reading 0.060 0.043 0.048 Chichester 0.043 0.046 0.044Exeter 0.059 0.044 0.047 LeamingtonSpa 0.043 0.039 0.036Plymouth 0.059 0.056 0.051 Motherwell&Airdrie 0.043 0.045 0.044Mansfield 0.059 0.042 0.042 Preston 0.043 0.041 0.046Gloucester 0.059 0.039 0.043 Nottingham 0.043 0.042 0.050Kettering&Wellingborough 0.059 0.039 0.041 Lincoln 0.042 0.038 0.043Basingstoke 0.058 0.040 0.041 Bedford 0.042 0.042 0.046Swansea 0.056 0.047 0.052 Birmingham 0.042 0.037 0.042Wolverhampton 0.056 0.039 0.043 Crewe 0.042 0.040 0.036Portsmouth 0.056 0.044 0.049 and 0.042 0.041 0.048FalkirkandStirling 0.055 0.048 0.047 Wakefield 0.041 0.046 0.045Colchester 0.054 0.054 0.052 Liverpool 0.041 0.047 0.048Dunfermline&Kirkcaldy 0.054 0.043 0.046 Chester 0.041 0.041 0.038Medway 0.053 0.041 0.044 TunbridgeWells 0.041 0.043 0.041Dundee 0.053 0.047 0.054 Norwich 0.041 0.040 0.044Blackburn 0.052 0.039 0.044 Brighton 0.040 0.044 0.049Coventry 0.051 0.042 0.043 Newcastle 0.040 0.043 0.049Chelmsford 0.050 0.045 0.041 HighWycombe&Aylesbury 0.040 0.039 0.044Sheffield 0.050 0.042 0.048 Guildford 0.039 0.040 0.041Eastbourne 0.049 0.058 0.050 Cardiff 0.039 0.040 0.047Birkenhead 0.049 0.050 0.050 Hull 0.039 0.046 0.043Stevenage 0.049 0.046 0.047 Glasgow 0.039 0.042 0.044Blyth&Ashington 0.048 0.045 0.047 Leicester 0.038 0.037 0.040Swindon 0.048 0.039 0.037 MiltonKeynes 0.038 0.041 0.041Bristol 0.047 0.040 0.042 Shrewsbury 0.038 0.042 0.045Ipswich 0.047 0.046 0.041 Southampton 0.038 0.042 0.045Barnsley 0.047 0.047 0.045 Warrington&Wigan 0.038 0.039 0.039Bournemouth 0.047 0.043 0.045 Leeds 0.038 0.039 0.039Northampton 0.046 0.039 0.038 Manchester 0.037 0.040 0.039Doncaster 0.046 0.049 0.051 London 0.037 0.038 0.039

Page 24: Structural Change and Productivity Growth in Cities · characterised in terms of the quantitative relations between input and output, between the output, employment and productivity

23

Telford 0.046 0.045 0.042 Blackpool 0.037 0.047 0.045Derby 0.046 0.041 0.041 Slough&Heathrow 0.035 0.036 0.037MerthyrTydfil 0.046 0.038 0.049 Crawley 0.034 0.034 0.038Southend 0.046 0.047 0.047

Table 6: Hirschman-Herfindahl Output Specialisation Indices for BritishCities,(82sectors),1971,1991and2014(Citiesrankedindescendingorderofspecialisationfor1971)__________________________________________________________________________________________________ 1971 1991 2014 1971 1991 2014Oxford 0.145 0.057 0.046 Middlesbrough 0.060 0.052 0.047Trowbridge 0.124 0.063 0.037 Southampton 0.059 0.048 0.038Plymouth 0.104 0.078 0.054 Sheffield 0.059 0.045 0.049Gloucester 0.104 0.044 0.037 Doncaster 0.059 0.055 0.053Portsmouth 0.103 0.054 0.045 Chelmsford 0.058 0.044 0.040Basingstoke 0.096 0.043 0.041 Bournemouth 0.058 0.043 0.040Reading 0.092 0.047 0.071 Norwich 0.058 0.043 0.041Exeter 0.086 0.056 0.048 Halifax 0.057 0.040 0.042Swansea 0.084 0.049 0.053 TunbridgeWells 0.057 0.048 0.040FalkirkandStirling 0.084 0.055 0.039 Crewe 0.056 0.034 0.032Medway 0.083 0.045 0.042 Mansfield 0.056 0.042 0.041LeamingtonSpa 0.082 0.041 0.039 Worcester&Kidderminster 0.055 0.050 0.035Swindon 0.074 0.043 0.040 York 0.054 0.045 0.041Durham&BishopAuckland 0.072 0.051 0.048 Huddersfield 0.054 0.042 0.043Colchester 0.072 0.052 0.046 Brighton 0.054 0.048 0.044Kettering&Wellingborough 0.070 0.042 0.042 Bradford 0.053 0.042 0.042Dundee 0.069 0.054 0.045 Motherwell&Airdrie 0.053 0.049 0.040Dunfermline&Kirkcaldy 0.069 0.045 0.040 Derby 0.052 0.044 0.047Bristol 0.069 0.046 0.039 Luton 0.052 0.040 0.039Eastbourne 0.069 0.057 0.045 Birkenhead 0.052 0.047 0.038Wolverhampton 0.066 0.044 0.040 Chester 0.052 0.038 0.032Telford 0.066 0.050 0.040 MiltonKeynes 0.052 0.040 0.044Edinburgh 0.065 0.052 0.047 Preston 0.052 0.040 0.044Dudley 0.065 0.045 0.042 Glasgow 0.051 0.049 0.038Stoke-on-Trent 0.064 0.048 0.040 Wakefield 0.051 0.047 0.044Coventry 0.064 0.054 0.039 Birmingham 0.051 0.041 0.039HighWycombe&Aylesbury 0.064 0.040 0.045 Stevenage 0.050 0.040 0.042Aberdeen 0.063 0.144 0.060 Bedford 0.050 0.043 0.044Lincoln 0.063 0.044 0.047 Shrewsbury 0.050 0.046 0.042Cardiff 0.063 0.044 0.042 London 0.050 0.046 0.045Chichester 0.062 0.049 0.040 Southend 0.049 0.042 0.044Sunderland 0.062 0.043 0.045 Slough&Heathrow 0.048 0.036 0.040BlythandAshington 0.062 0.050 0.044 Warrington&Wigan 0.047 0.036 0.034Peterborough 0.061 0.039 0.039 Crawley 0.047 0.035 0.035Northampton 0.061 0.043 0.040 Leeds 0.046 0.038 0.038MerthyrTydfil 0.061 0.043 0.047 Leicester 0.046 0.040 0.038Barnsley 0.061 0.053 0.046 Liverpool 0.045 0.041 0.039Ipswich 0.061 0.053 0.038 Nottingham 0.045 0.040 0.046Chesterfield 0.061 0.051 0.043 Manchester 0.044 0.043 0.035Newcastle 0.061 0.046 0.049 Blackburn 0.043 0.037 0.038Cambridge 0.060 0.044 0.039 Hull 0.043 0.045 0.039Newport 0.060 0.043 0.046 Blackpool 0.039 0.045 0.043Guildford 0.060 0.042 0.041

Page 25: Structural Change and Productivity Growth in Cities · characterised in terms of the quantitative relations between input and output, between the output, employment and productivity

24

Figure 10: Sectoral Diversification in Selected Cities: The Hirschman-HerfindahlIndexofEmploymentShares,1971-2014.(AsmallervalueofHHindicatesgreatersectoraldiversityorbalance)

Figure11:SectoralDiversificationinSelectedCities:TheHHindexofOutputShares, 1971-2014 (A smaller value of HH indicates greater sectoraldiversityorbalance)

0

0.01

0.02

0.03

0.04

0.05

0.06

0.07

0.08

0.09

0.11971

1973

1975

1977

1979

1981

1983

1985

1987

1989

1991

1993

1995

1997

1999

2001

2003

2005

2007

2009

2011

2013

HHIn

dex

Oxford

Sunderland

Huddersfield

Stoke-on-trent

Halifax

Dudley

Trowbridge

Bradford

Middlesbrough

Reading

0"

0.02"

0.04"

0.06"

0.08"

0.1"

0.12"

0.14"

0.16"

1971"

1973"

1975"

1977"

1979"

1981"

1983"

1985"

1987"

1989"

1991"

1993"

1995"

1997"

1999"

2001"

2003"

2005"

2007"

2009"

2011"

2013"

HH"Inde

x"

Oxford"

Trowbridge"

Plymouth"

Gloucester"

Portsmouth"

Basingstoke"

Reading"

Exeter"

Swansea"

Medway"

Page 26: Structural Change and Productivity Growth in Cities · characterised in terms of the quantitative relations between input and output, between the output, employment and productivity

25

5. Structural Change and Productivity Growth Across BritishCitiesToprovidebackgroundtothecityanalysis,Figure12showsthenational–levelrelationshipbetweenproductivitygrowthandthechangeinemploymentshareforour82sectorsoverthewholeperiod1971-2014.Severalfeaturesareevident.Almostallof themanufacturingsectorshaveexperienceda fall inemploymentshare,consistentwithdeindustrialisationtrenddepictedinFigure6.theinmostcases of between 2-4 percent per annum. But all except ‘coke and refinedpetroleum products’ also experienced productivity growth, in most cases ofbetween2-4percentperannum.Somekeysectors,however,achievedratesmuchhigher than this, of between 4 and 6.5 percent per annum: pharmaceuticals,transportequipment,chemicals,computerequipment,andvehicles.Inthecaseofprivatemarketservices,thesefallintotwomaingroups:oneinwhichannualproductivity growth has averaged around 2.5 percent, but employment shareshavechangedonlymarginally(eg.FinancialServices,Insurance,),andanotherinwhichemploymentshareshavegrownbuttheannualrateofproductivitygrowthhas averaged only around 1.0 percent per annum (eg. Food Services, BuildingServices, Head Offices, Management Consultancies). Information services, airtransport,financeandcomputerprogrammingserviceshaverecordedhighratesofproductivitygrowth,thoughonlythelastofthesesawanysignificantincreasein employment share. What is particularly striking is that, overall, there is anegativerelationshipbetweenproductivitygrowthandemploymentshareacrosssectors(R=-0.201):theemploymentstructureofthenationaleconomyhasbeenawayfromthosesectors–manufacturing,constructionandutilities-whichhaveshownthehighestratesofproductivitygrowthintothosesectors–privateandpublicservices–mostofwhichhaveexperiencedtheslowestratesofproductivitygrowth.HowfarthishelpstoaccountforthedecliningtrendinnationalaggregateproductivitygrowthshowninFigure1isthusaninterestingquestioninitsownright.Ourinteresthere,however,isintherelationshipbetweenstructuralchangeandproductivitygrowthacrossBritain’scities.Asmentionedabove,variousauthorshavesoughttoidentifytherelativecontributionof‘within-sector’and‘between-sector’ (structural change) contributions to country-level and industry-levelproductivity growth. For example, in their study of differences in productivityperformance among developing countries, McMillan and Rodrik (2011) use asimpledecompositionoftheabsolutechangeinproductivity,

Page 27: Structural Change and Productivity Growth in Cities · characterised in terms of the quantitative relations between input and output, between the output, employment and productivity

26

Figure12.ProductivityGrowthandChangeinEmploymentSharebySector,GreatBritain,1971-2014

whichwhenappliedtoourcitiestakestheform:

∆𝑌$% = 𝑠)$%:;<)*+ ∆𝑦)$% + ∆𝑠)$<

)*+ 𝑦)$% (4)where𝑌$%and𝑦)$%refer,inourcase,tototalandsector-specificlabourproductivitylevels(realGVAperemployedworker)incityjattimet.The∆operatordenotesthechange, inproductivityandinemploymentshares,betweent-kandt. Thefirsttermin(4),whatMcMillanandRodrikcallthe‘withinsector’contribution,istheweighted sum of productivity changewithin individual sectors, arising forexample from improvements in production technique or the other factorsidentifiedinTable1,wheretheweights𝑠)$%arethesharesofcityemploymentinthose sectors at the beginning of the time period concerned. The second termcapturestheproductivityeffectofemploymentreallocationsacrossorbetweendifferentsectors.Itisessentiallytheinnerproductofsectoralproductivitylevels(attheendofthetimeperiod)withthechangeinemploymentsharesacrossthosesectors(sincethebeginningoftheperiod).ItisthiscomponentthatMcMillanandRodrikrefertoas ‘structuralchange’.Whenchangesinemploymentsharesarepositively correlated with productivity levels, this term will be positive, andstructuralchangewillhaveoperatedtoincreasethecity-widerateofproductivity

-3

-2

-1

0

1

2

3

4

5

-1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7

ChangeinSectoralEmploymentShare(Absolute

ChangeinPercentShare),1971-2014

AverageAnnualRateofProductivityGrowth(Percent)

Pharmaceuticals

AirTransport

Computer,OpticalandElectronic Products

TransportEquip.

InformationServices

Computer Programming

HealthServices

EducationHeadOffices/Manag. Cons

FoodServices

MetalProducts

Chemicals

EmploymentServices

Textiles

BuildingServices

FinancialServices

SocialWork

Coke Products

ProductionIndustriesPrivateSectorServicesPrimaryIndustriesPublic Sector Services

Page 28: Structural Change and Productivity Growth in Cities · characterised in terms of the quantitative relations between input and output, between the output, employment and productivity

27

changeoverthestudyperiod.Ifitisnegative,itindicatesthatacity’semploymentstructurehasshiftedoverall towardssectorsthathave lowerproductivitythanthesectorsthatarelosingemploymentshare.

AvariantofthisdecompositionapproachisusedbyKruger(2006),inhisstudyofstudyofproductivitygrowthinUSmanufacturing(seealsoDisney,etal,2003;Foster,etal,1998;KuceraandRoncaolato,2012;RoncolatoandKucera,2014). In this version, a city’s aggregateproductivity growth (rather than theabsolutechangeinproductivitystudiedbyMcMillanandRodrik)isdecomposed,usingKruger’snotation,intothreecomponents:∆GHIJKGHI

= LMHI∆NMHIJKOMPQ

GHI+ ∆LMHI(NMHI:GHI)

OMPQ

GHI+ ∆LMHIJK∆NMHIJK

OMPQ

GHI

(5)

where, as in (4), 𝑌)$% and 𝑦)$% refer to total and sector-specific labourproductivity levels in city j, and the∆operator denotes the change inproductivityoremploymentsharesbetweentandt+k.Thefirsttermontheright-hand sideof (5) is interpretedas the ‘within-sector’ effect,which is the share-weightedaverageproductivitygrowthof the individual industries incity j.Thesecondtermrepresentsthe‘between-sector’effect.Itispositiveifsectorsinitiallywith above average productivity levels experience increasing shares betweenperiodtandt+1onaverage,andindustrieswithbelow-averageproductivitylevelsexperiencefallingsharesoftotalcityemployment,onaverage.Thethirdtermisaninteractionor‘covariance-effect’whichispositiveifindustrieswithhighratesofproductivitygrowthtendtogainintermsoftheirshares(ormoregenerally,ifsharechangeandproductivitygrowthtendtohavethesamesign).The‘betweeneffect’ and ‘covariance effect’ together reflect the role of structural change inaggregatecityproductivitygrowth.5

HereweuseKruger’s formula (Equation (5)). The results are shown inFigure 12 and Table 7. Figure 12 plots the three right-hand components ofpercentage productivity change in Equation (5) against the total percentageproductivitychange,forthewholeperiod1971-2017foreachofthe85cities.

5 Itisfurtherworthnotinginpassingthatintheliterature,severalmodificationsandextensionsofthetwodecompositionmeasuresinEquations(4)and(5)havebeenproposed(Bailyetal,1992;GrilichesandRegev,1995;OlleyandPakes,1995;Fosteretal,1998;FagerbergandPeneder,2000;Disneyetal,2003).Forexample,Bailyetal(1992)andFosteretal(1998)deriveversionswithadditional terms that represent the contributions of entering and exiting establishments toaggregateproductivitygrowth.Theseeffectscannotbeinvestigatedhereforthetimeperiodthatisofinterest.

Page 29: Structural Change and Productivity Growth in Cities · characterised in terms of the quantitative relations between input and output, between the output, employment and productivity

28

As is clear, the overwhelming contribution to total productivity change acrossalmost all of the cities was from ‘within-sector’ improvements. The ‘between-sector’contributionwhilstgenerallypositive,ismuchsmallerinvirtuallyeverycase.Thereareonlyfivecitiesinwhichthebetween-sectorcontributionisgreaterthan the within-sector contribution: Birkenhead, Chester, Crawley, HighWycombeandHull.Thecovariancecomponent,bycontrast,isnegativeinmostcities, and is larger (in absolute terms) than the between-sector or structuralcontributioninmorethanhalfofthecities.Thisisconsistentwithadeclineovertimeintheemploymentsharesofthosesectorswithhigherproductivitygrowth–thatis,manufacturingandproduction.Giventhatthisnegativecovarianceeffectgenerally exceeds the small positive between-sector component, the overall‘structuraleffect’onproductivityacrossmostcitieswouldappeartohavebeennegative. Table 7,which shows the detailed decomposition for the top 10 andbottom10 cities in termsof total productivity growth for the two sub-periods1971-1991and1991-2017,confirmsthesefindings.Figure12.DecompositionofCityProductivityGrowth,1971-2014,into

Within-Sector,Between-SectorandCovarianceContributions

-100

-50

0

50

100

150

-20 0 20 40 60 80 100 120 140 160

Percen

tageCha

ngeinProd

uctiv

ity,by

Compo

nent

TotalProductivityChange,1971-2014(Percent)

WithinSector BetweenSector Covariance

Page 30: Structural Change and Productivity Growth in Cities · characterised in terms of the quantitative relations between input and output, between the output, employment and productivity

29

Table7:DecompositionofCityProductivityGrowth,intoWithin-Sector,Between-SectorandCovarianceContributions,fortheTopTenandBottom

TenCities,1971-1991and1991-2014

1971-1991TOPTENBOTTOMTEN

Total Within Between Covar Total Within Between Covar

Aberdeen 138.1 110.51 7.26 20.39 Blackpool 17.86 26.47 -046 -8.32Sunderland 89.80 127.76 25.41 -63.36 Basingstoke 17.12 28.20 -4.75 -6.33Blyth 75.89 104.51 19.77 -48.40 Plymouth 16.59 22.25 -4.10 -1.55Mansfield 69.33 92.42 18.11 -41.19 Colchester 15.43 17.41 1.40 -3.38York 64.93 51.19 6.90 6.83 Eastbourne 13.86 18.37 -8.89 4.39MerthyrTydfil 62.02 101.04 20.05 -59.06 Hull 13.42 19.26 43.02 -48.85Derby 60.52 71.99 13.09 -24.56 Oxford 12.77 25.77 -4.53 -8.46London 59.77 57.21 9.12 -6.54 Medway 10.85 26.53 -8.41 -7.25Halifax 59.62 52.08 14.11 -6.55 HighWycombe 3.7 7.44 9.54 -13.28Middlesborough 59.11 61.29 7.31 -9.50 Leamington

Spa

-7.10 -5.99 7.35 -8.46

1991-2014

TOPTENBOTTOMTEN Total Within Between Covar Total Within Between Covar

Swindon 67.81 61.14 5.40 1.26 Bedford 25.04 41.29 -4.96 -11.29

Reading 59.10 58.27 4.79 -3.97 Cardiff 24.82 27.84 -0.78 -2.24

Basinstoke 56.42 67.97 -2.44 -9.10 Doncaster 23.89 37.66 -5.71 -8.06

Leamington 55.20 54.42 38.66 -37.89 Colchester 23.42 33.72 -2.84 -7.45

Crewe 54.24 58.30 99.25 -103.31 Plymouth 22.63 34.28 8.36 -3.28

Eastbourne 50.40 83.88 2.79 -36.26 Hull 22.54 26.93 35.70 -40.09

Derby 49.95 54.06 1.86 -6.50 Swansea 20.66 28.09 -0.14 -7.29

Bradford 47.56 51.06 15.97 -19.48 Preston 17.51 29.73 18.72 -30.93

MiltonKeynes 46.51 57.65 -3.63 -7.49 York 16.92 39.21 -9.98 -12.31

Tunbridge 45.97 48.04 -1.30 -0.76 Aberdeen 0.12 2.81 3.51 -6.20

These findings are somewhat surprising, in that they suggest that structuralchangehasplayedaminor,andinmostcasesanegativeroleinaccountingforthevariationsinproductivitygrowthacrossBritishcities.However, inthisrespect,theydo tend tobe consistentwith the resultsobtained fromstudies thathavesoughttoassessthesignificanceofdifferentialstructuralchangeinaccountingforthepatternsofproductivitygrowthacrosscountries,asreferredtoinSection2above. And given that our analysis in Section 4 suggests that city economic

Page 31: Structural Change and Productivity Growth in Cities · characterised in terms of the quantitative relations between input and output, between the output, employment and productivity

30

structureshaveconverged,theimplicationisthatcitydifferencesinproductivitygrowth havemainly reflected differential productivity performancewithin thesame sectors: put anotherway, itwould appear that the same sector performsdifferentlyacrossdifferentcities.Amuch finer levelof industrialdisaggregationmight change this conclusion, and give more (possibly positive) weight tobetween-sectorandstructuraleffects.On theotherhand, the finer thegrainofsectoraldisaggregation,thesmallerarethecorrespondingsectoralemploymentweights are likely to be, which may not therefore do much to change theimportanceofwithin-sectorandstructuralchangeeffects.6.ConclusionsThispaperhasidentifiedan‘urbanproductivitypuzzle’toaddtothenumerousotherpuzzlesandproblems thatbeset researchonproductivity.Wehaveseenthat while sectoral structures in British cities have converged since the early1970s,afterconvergingover19971-1991,cityproductivitydifferenceshavesincediverged.Wehavefoundagrowingimbalanceintheproductivityperformanceofcitieswhichundoubtedlyhasserious implications for the long-termseverityofspatialinequalitiesinBritain.Itmightbeexpectedthattheconvergenceofurbaneconomies on service sectors would have led to a convergence in theirproductivity,butthishasnotbeenthecase.Howthencanwestarttoexplainthisconundrum? For a start, productivity variations within service industries aredifficulttomeasurebutappeartobelarge(BailyandSolow,2001).Moreover,theresultsofourdecompositionanalysisofcityproductivitygrowthshowshowsthatgrowth has been dominated by within-industry productivity developments,rather than by the transfer of employment and output across industries, orstructural change. Underlying this are the substantial variations in bothproductivitylevelsandgrowththatexistacrossplantsandindustrieswithinthesameindustryorsector.Inthissense,ourresultsconfirmthefindingsofearlierstudies that emphasise that in mature industrialised economies there arepersistent and large productivity differentialswithin individual industries andsectorswhichtendtodominateproductivitygrowth(BartelsmanandDoms,2000;Haltiwanger,2000;Krüger,2006).Thechallengethisposes ishowcanwebestexplainthesourcesoftheseintra-industryspatialvariationsinproductivity?Thereareseveralpossiblesourcesofthisurbangeographyofproductivitygrowth.The first, of course, is that agglomeration economies and localised increasingreturnsmaybenefit firmstoagreaterdegree insomecitiesthanothers.WhiletherearenosimplerelationshipsbetweencitysizeandproductivitygrowthintheBritish case (see Martin et al, 2014), the possible effects of agglomerationeconomiesandespecially thoseacross related industries,need tobeexamined

Page 32: Structural Change and Productivity Growth in Cities · characterised in terms of the quantitative relations between input and output, between the output, employment and productivity

31

morecarefully(forexample,seeEssletzbichlerandRigby,2002),aswellastheimportanceoftraveltimestoLondon(Webberetal,2009).However,giventhattheweight of economic research shows that agglomeration only has at best amodest or marginal effect on productivity – the bulk of the evidence on thissuggeststhatadoublingofcitysizeseemstobeassociatedwithanincreasesinproductivityofonlybetweenabout4-8percent(seealso,RosenthalandStrange,2003)-wesuspectthatagglomerationeconomiesareatbestasmallcontributoryfactorratherthanamajordriver.6ReturningtoTable1,itisevidentthattherearetwokeycausesofwithin-sectorproductivitychange.Thefirstisa‘recompositionorreallocationeffect’andinvolvestheentryandexitoffirmsandthere-allocationofmarketsharesbetweenincumbentfirms.Ingeneralahigherrateoffirmandplant entry leads to faster productivity growth as new entrants tend to havehigherproductivitythanthosethatexitorareclosed.Iflargeandwell-organizedfirmsandplantsgainmarketsharethiswillalsoofcoursepushupproductivitygrowth.Thusvariedentrepreneurialdynamicsandlargefirminvestmentsinnewplants across cities will strongly shape their productivity growth. The secondmajorsetofprocessescentresontechnologicalandorganizationalchangeamongsurviving firms which includes both the adoption of innovations as well asmanagement,organizationalpracticesandformats.Typicallytheseareshapedbythe intensity of competition faced by firms, and by their regulatory andinstitutionalcontext,andintheUKtheyareoftenproxiedbytheamountofcapitalemployedperworkerandlinkedtoforeignownershipofthefirm(SeeWebberetal,2009).Existingindustryresearchimpliesthatbothofthesetwoprocessesarelikelyresponsiblefortheintra-industryurbanvariationsinproductivitythatwehave found (Disneyetal,2003),although the relative importanceof these twoprocessesmaychangeindifferentperiods(see,forexample,RileyandBondibene,2016).HarrisandMoffat(2015)arguethatfirmentryandclosurehavebeenthemost importantcauseofchange to total factorproductivitydifferentialsacrossLocal Enterprise Partnership areas in the UK, but struggle to link this to theeconomic characteristics of these areas. We clearly need more research todisentangletherelativeimportanceandcausesofthesetwosetsofprocessesindifferentcities.Itishighlylikelythatthetwoarecombinedincitiesinreinforcingwayssothatthosecitieswiththemostcompetitiveandglobalisedmarketsandhighestratesofplantcreationandforeigndirectinvestmentwillseehigherratesoffirmchurnandentry,aswellashigherratesofinnovationandorganisationalimprovement. The strength of these processes in some cities may haveimplicationsforunderstandingourfindingsoncityproductivitygrowth.

6There is also the intriguing issue of whether the effects of agglomeration may increase up to a certain size of city but thereafter either increase at a decreasing rate or even begin to decline. Forexample, PotterandWatts(2011)findthatagglomerationeconomiesmayfirstriseandthenfallovertime.

Page 33: Structural Change and Productivity Growth in Cities · characterised in terms of the quantitative relations between input and output, between the output, employment and productivity

32

Oneofthekeylimitationsofourdecompositionanalysis,ofcourse,isitsrelianceonahistorically-derivedclassificationsoffirmsintodistinctindustries.Whilewehaveusedthemostdetailedsectoralbreakdownpossibleforthelongtimespanstudiedhere, thesecategoriesandrepresentationsnevertheless continue tobebasedontheassumptionthatindustrialcategoriesaremeaningful,andthatfirmswithinindustriessharesomekeycharacteristicsandfeatures.Thereisagrowingrecognition,however,thattheseclassificationsarenotcapturingformsofactivitychange and restructuring that are widening differences within particularindustries.Manyindustriesnowincludefirmsthatarequitedifferentintermsoftheoccupationstheyinvolve,themarketstheyreach,andthetasksandfunctionsthat theyperform(seeBaldwin,2016).Partly,ofcourse, this isduetothenewdivisions of labour emerging from supply chain re-organisation and thespecialisationsofareasandcitiesinspecifictasks,stagesandoccupationsratherthan in complete supply chains. In several ways the uneven diffusion ofglobalisationhaswideneddifferenceswithinindustries.ItalsomaybeduetothewaysinwhichICTanddigitisationareboundupwithfirmentryandexit,andarechangingfirmactivitiesandleadingtotheemergenceofdigitalactivitiesthatareblurring industry boundaries (including, in some instances, between whatconstitutes ‘manufacturing’ and ‘services’), and pulling apart the productivityperformancesof firms. In this context, revisions to industryclassificationsarelaggingwellbehindthegrowthofnewactivities.Whatthismayimplyisthatthegeography of ‘structural change’ is no longer well measured by changes inindustrialclassesandcategoriesbutneedstobeanalysedinamorefinegrainedwaywithin particular industries, for example in terms of occupational or task‘bundles’.Atpresenthowever,theseconclusionsarespeculative,andourfutureresearch will endeavour to examine in more depth some of these processesunderlyingthepuzzleofdivergenceinproductivityacrosscontemporaryurbanBritain.

Page 34: Structural Change and Productivity Growth in Cities · characterised in terms of the quantitative relations between input and output, between the output, employment and productivity

33

ReferencesAiginger,K.andDavies,S.(2004)Industrialspecializationandgeographicconcentration:twosidesofthesamecoin?NotfortheEuropeanUnion,JournalofAppliedEconomics,12,pp.231-248.Aiginger,K.andM.Pfaffermayr(2004)TheSingleMarketandgeographicconcentrationinEurope,ReviewofInternationalEconomics,12,pp.1-11.Altunbas,Y.,Jones,E.andThornton,J.(2012)Knowledgespilloversandthegrowthofcities,AppliedEconomicsLetters,20,pp.162-166.Ansari,M.R.,Mussida,C.andPastore,F.(2013)NoteontheLilienandModifedLilienIndex,DiscussionPaper7198,InstitutefortheStudyofLabour,Bonn,Germany.Arrow,K.(1962)TheEconomicImplicationsofLearningbyDoing,ReviewofEconomicStudies,29(3),pp.155–73.Bahl,R.W.,Firestine,R.andPhares,D.(1971),Industrialdiversityinurbanareas:alternativemeasuresandintermetropolitancomparisons,EconomicGeography,47,pp.414-425.Baily,M.N.,Hulten,C.andCampbell,D.(1992)Productivitydynamicsinmanufacturingplants,BrookingsPapersonEconomicActivity,Microeconomics, pp.187–267.Baily,M.N.,Bartelsman,E.J.andHaltiwanger,J.C.(2001)Laborproductivity:structuralchangeandcyclicaldynamics,ReviewofEconomicsandStatistics83,pp.420–433.Baily,M.N.andSolowR.M.(2011)Internationalproductivitycomparisonsbuiltfromthefirmlevel,TheJournalofEconomicPerspectives15,3,151-172.Baldwin,R.(2016)TheGreatConvergence:InformationTechnologyandtheNewGlobalisation,Cambridge,Mass:BelknapPress.Bartelsman,E.andDoms,M.(2000)Understandingproductivity:Lessonsfromlongitudinalmicrodata,JournalofEconomicLiterature,38,3,pp.569-594.Baumol,W.J.(1967)Macroeconomicsofunbalancedgrowth:theanatomyofurbancrisis,AmericanEconomicReview57,pp.415–426.Baumol,W.J.,Blackman,S.A.B.andWolff,E.N.(1985)Unbalancedgrowthrevisited:asymptoticstagnancyandnewevidence,AmericanEconomicReview75,pp.806–817.Beine,M.andS.Coulombe(2007),Economicintegrationandthediversificationofregionalexports:evidencefromtheCanadian-U.S.FreeTradeAgreement,

Page 35: Structural Change and Productivity Growth in Cities · characterised in terms of the quantitative relations between input and output, between the output, employment and productivity

34

JournalofEconomicGeography,vol.7,pp.93-111.Brulhart,M.andTraeger,R.(2005),AnaccountofgeographicconcentrationpatternsinEurope,RegionalScienceandUrbanEconomics,35,pp.597-624.Cantner,U.andKrüger,J.J.(2006)Micro-heterogeneityandaggregateproductivitydevelopmentintheGermanmanufacturingsector:resultsfromadecompositionexercise,DiscussionPaper02/2006JenaerSchriftenzurWirtschaftswissenschaft,,Friedrich-Schiller-UniversityJena.Chisholm,M.andJ.Oeppen(1973)TheChangingPatternofEmployment.RegionalSpecialisationandIndustrialLocationinBritain,Beckenham:CroomHelmConroy,M.(1975)RegionalEconomicDiversification,NewYork:Praeger.Cornwall,J.andCornwall,W.(1994)Growththeoryandeconomicstructure,Economica,NS61,242,pp.237-251.Cowell,M.(2014)Deindustrialisation:AdaptiveResilienceinAmericanMidwesternRegions,London:Routledge.Cowen,T.(2016)SiliconValleyhasnotsavedusfromaproductivityslowdown,EconomicReview,TheNewYorkTimes,4March(http://www.nytimes.com/2016/03/06/upshot/silicon-valley-has-not-saved-us-from-a-productivity-slowdown.html)Crafts,N.(2002)TheSolowProductivityParadoxinhistoricalperspective,DiscussionPaper3142,CentreforEconomicPolicyResearch,LondonSchoolofEconomics.Cuadrado-Roura,J.R.,Garcia-Greciano,B.and.Raymond,J.L.(1999)Regionalconvergenceinproductivityandproductivestructure:TheSpanishcase,InternationalRegionalScienceReview,22,35-53.Davies,A.andTonts,M.(2010)Economicdiversityandregionalsocio-economicperformance,GeographicalResearch,48,pp.223-234.Davis,D.R.(1998)TheHomeMarket,Trade,andIndustrialStructure,AmericanEconomicReview,vol.88,1264-1276.Dijkstra,L.,Garcilazo,E.andMcCann,P.(2013)TheeconomicperformanceofEuropeancitiesandcity-regions:mythsandrealities,EuropeanPlanningStudies,21,pp.334-354.Disney,R.,Haskel,J.andHeden,Y.(2003),RestructuringandproductivitygrowthinUKManufacturing,EconomicJournal,103,pp.666-694.Dixon,RJ.andThirlwall,A.P.(1975)RegionalGrowthandUnemploymentintheUnitedKingdom,London:MacmillanPress.

Page 36: Structural Change and Productivity Growth in Cities · characterised in terms of the quantitative relations between input and output, between the output, employment and productivity

35

Duranton,G.andPuga,D.(1999)DiversityandSpecialisationinCities:Why,WhereandWhenDoesitMatter?ResearchPapersinEnvironmentalandSpatialAnalysis56,DepartmentofGeographyandEnvironment,LondonSchoolofEconomics.Duranton,G.(2007)Urbanevolutions:Thefast,theslowandthestill,AmericanEconomicReview,97,1,pp.197-221Essletzbichler,J.andRigby,D.(2002)AgglomerationeconomiesandproductivitydifferencesinUScities,JournalofEconomicGeography,2,407-432.EuropeanCentralBank(2016)TheslowdowninUSlabourproductivitygrowth–stylisedfactsandeconomicimplications,ECB(https://www.ecb.europa.eu/pub/pdf/other/eb201602_focus01.en.pdf)Ezcurra,R.andP.Pascual(2007),SpatialDisparitiesinProductivityinCentralandEasternEurope,EasternEuropeanEconomics,45,5-32.Fagerberg,J.(2000)Technologicalprogress,structuralchangeandproductivitygrowth:acomparativestudy,StructuralChangeandEconomicDynamics,11,pp.393–411.Farhauer,O.andKröll,A.(2012)Diversifiedspecialisation:Goingonestepbeyondregionaleconomics’specialisation-diversificationconcept,JahrbuchfürRegionalWissenschaft,32,1,pp.63-84.Findeisen,S.AndSüdekum,J.(2008)Industrychurningandtheevolutionofcities:EvidenceforGermany,JournalofUrbanEconomics,64,pp.326-339.Foster,L.,Haltiwanger,J.andKrizan,C.J.(1998),AggregateProductivityGrowth:LessonsfromMicroeconomicEvidence,NBERWorkingPaper6803.Freeman,C.andLouca,F.(2001)AsTimeGoesBy:FromtheIndustrialRevolutionstotheInformationRevolution,NewYork:OxfordUniversityPress.Frenken,K.,VanOort,F.G.,andVerburg,T.(2007)Relatedvariety,unrelatedvarietyandregionalgrowth,RegionalStudies,41,pp.685-697.Gibbs,J.P.andPostan,D.L.(1975)Thedivisionoflabor:conceptualisationandrelatedmeasures,SocialForces,53,pp.GlaeserE.,KallalH.D.,ScheinkmanJ.A.,andShleifer,A.(1992)Growthofcities.JournalofPoliticalEconomy,100,pp.1126–1152.Glaeser,E.(2005)ReinventingBoston:1640-2003,JournalofEconomicGeography,5,pp.119-153.Glaeser,E.(2011)TriumphoftheCity,London:Macmillan.

Page 37: Structural Change and Productivity Growth in Cities · characterised in terms of the quantitative relations between input and output, between the output, employment and productivity

36

Gordon,R.J.(2016)TheRiseandFallofAmericanGrowth,Princeton:PrincetonUniversityPress.Griliches,Z.andRegev,H.(1995)ProductivityandfirmturnoverinIsraeliindustry,1979–1988,JournalofEconometrics,65,pp.175–203.Haaland,J.I.Kind,H.J.,Midelfart-Knarvik,K.H.andJ.Torstensson(1999)WhatdeterminestheeconomicgeographyofEurope?CEPRDiscussionPaper,No.2072,LondonSchoolofEconomics.Haltiwanger,J.(2000)Aggregategrowth:Whatwehavelearnedfrommicroeconomicevidence,OECDEconomicsDepartmentWorkingPapersNo.267,OECD,ParisHarris,R.andMoffat,J.(2015)TotalfactorproductivitygrowthinLocalEnterprisePartnershipRegionsinBritain,1997-2008,RegionalStudies49,6,1019-1041.Hirschman,A.O.(1964)Thepaternityofanindex,AmericanEconomicReview,54,pp.761-762.Hobor,G.(2013)Survivingtheeraofdeindustrialisation:theneweconomicgeographyoftheurbanrustbelt,JournalofUrbanAffairs,35,pp.417-443H.M.Treasury(2015)FixingtheFoundations:CreatingaMoreProsperousNation,HMTreasury,Cm9098,London.Isard,W.andothers(1960)MethodsofRegionalAnalysis:AnIntroductiontoRegionalScience,Cambridge,Mass:MITPress.Jacobs,J.(1984)CitiesandtheWealthofNations:PrinciplesofEconomiclife,NewYork:RandomHouse

Kaldor,N.(1966)CausesoftheslowrateofeconomicgrowthintheUnitedKingdomCambridge:CambridgeUniversityPress.

Kaldor,N.(1967)Strategicfactorsineconomicdevelopment,Ithaca,NY:CornellUniversityPress.

Kaldor,N.(1968)Productivityandgrowthinmanufacturingindustry:Areply,Economica,35,pp.385–391.

Kim,H-J.(2006)TheShifttotheServiceEconomy:CausesandEffects,ResearchPaper2006.7.7,InstituteforMonetaryandEconomicResearch,TheBankofKorea.(https://faculty.washington.edu/karyiu/confer/seoul06/papers/kim_hj.pdf)Kim,S.(1995)Expansionofmarketsandthegeographicdistributionofeconomicactivities:thetrendsinUSregionalmanufacturingstructure1860-1987,QuarterlyJournalofEconomics,10,pp.881-908.

Page 38: Structural Change and Productivity Growth in Cities · characterised in terms of the quantitative relations between input and output, between the output, employment and productivity

37

Krüger,J.J.(2006)TheSourcesofAggregateProductivityGrowth:USManufacturingIndustries,1958-1996,DiscussionPaper10/2006,JenaerSchriftenzurWirtschaftswissenschaft,Friedich-SchillerUniversity,Jena.Krüger,J.J.(2008)ProductivityandStructuralChange:AReviewoftheLiterature,JournalofEconomicSurveys,22,pp.330-363.Krugman,P.(1994)TheAgeofDiminishedExpectations,Cambridge,Mass:MITPress.Kucera,D.andRoncaolato,L.(2012)StructureMatters:SectoralDriversofGrowthandtheLabourProductivity-EmploymentRelationship,ILOResearchPaper3,Geneva:InternationalLaborOfficeKuznets,S.(1957)Quantitativeaspectsoftheeconomicgrowthofnations:II.Industrialdistributionofnationalproductandlabourforce,EconomicDevelopmentandCulturalChange,5(Supplement),pp.3–111.Kuznets,S.(1973)Moderneconomicgrowth:findingsandreflections,AmericanEconomicReview,63,pp.47–258.Laitner,J.(2000)Structuralchangeandeconomicgrowth,ReviewofEconomicStudies,67,pp.545–561.Landesmann,M.(2000),StructuralchangeintheTransitionEconomies1989-1999,EconomicSurveyofEurope,2,pp.95-123.Lilien,D.M.(1982)SectoralShiftsandCyclicalUnemployment,JournalofPoliticalEconomy,90,pp.777-793.Markusen,A.andShrock,(2006)Thedistinctivecity:divergentpatternsingrowth,hierarchyandspecialisation,UrbanStudies,43,pp.1301-1323.Marshall,A.(1920)PrinciplesofEconomics(8thEdition),London:Macmillan.Martin,R.L.(2016)Divergenturbandevelopment:reflectionsonataleoftwocities,RegionalStudies,50,pp.1623-1627.Martin,R.L.,Gardiner,B.andTyler,P.(2014)TheEvolvingEconomicPerformanceofUKCities:CityGrowthPatterns,1981-2011,ForesightFutureCitiesWorkingPaper,UKGovernmentOfficeforScience,London.Martin,R.L.,Sunley,P.,Tyler,P.andGardiner,B.(2016)Divergentcitiesinpost-industrialBritain,CambridgeJournalofRegions,EconomyandSociety,9,pp.269-299.McMillan,M.S.andRodrik,D.(2011)Structuralchangeandproductivitygrowth,WorkingPaper17143,NationalBureauofEconomicResearch,Cambridge,Mass.

Page 39: Structural Change and Productivity Growth in Cities · characterised in terms of the quantitative relations between input and output, between the output, employment and productivity

38

Metcalfe,J.S.,Foster,J.AndRamlogan,R.(2006)AdaptiveEconomicGrowth,CambridgeJournalofEconomics,30,pp.7-32.Michaels,G.,Rauch,F.andRedding,S.(2013)TaskspecialisationinUScities,WorkingPaper18715,NationalBureauofEconomicResearch,Washington.Moretti,E.(2013)TheNewGeographyofJobs,Boston:MarinerBooks.Ocampo,J.A.,Rada,C.andTaylor,L.(2009).GrowthandPolicyinDevelopingCountries:AStructuralistApproach.NewYork:ColumbiaUniversityPress.OECD(2015)TheFutureofProductivity,Paris:OECD.Olley,G.S.andPakes,A.(1996)Thedynamicsofproductivityinthetelecommunicationsequipmentindustry,Econometrica,64,pp.1263–1297.Oulton,N.(2001)Mustthegrowthratedecline?Baumol’sunbalancedgrowthrevisited,OxfordEconomicPapers,53,pp.605–627.Owen,T.(2011)TheGreatStagnation:HowAmericaAteAlltheLow-HangingFruitofModernHistory,GotSick,andWill(Eventually)FeelBetter,NewYork:Dutton)Palan,N.(2010)MeasurementofSpecialisation:TheChoiceofIndices,WorkingPaper62,ForschungsschwerpunktInternationaleWirtschaft,Vienna.Palan,N.andSchmeideberg,C.(2010)StructuralconvergenceofEuropeancountries,StructuralChangeandEconomicDynamics,21,pp.85-100.Pasinetti,L.(1981)StructuralChangeandEconomicsDynamics,Cambridge:CambridgeUniversityPress.Pasinetti,L.(1993)StructuralEconomicDynamics,Cambridge:CambridgeUniversityPress.Pieper,U.(2000)Deindustrializationandthesocialandeconomicsustainabilitynexusindevelopingcountries:Cross-countryevidenceonproductivityandemployment,JournalofDevelopmentStudies,36,pp.66–99.Peneder,M.(2003)Industrialstructureandaggregategrowth,StructuralChangeandEconomicDynamics14,pp.427–448.Percoco,M.,Dall’erba,S.andHewings,G.(2005),StructuralconvergenceofthenationaleconomiesofEurope,MPRAPaper,No.1380.Potter,A.andWatts,H.D.(2011)Evolutionaryagglomerationtheory:increasingreturns,decreasingreturnsandtheindustrylifecycle,JournalofEconomicGeography,11,pp.417-455.

Page 40: Structural Change and Productivity Growth in Cities · characterised in terms of the quantitative relations between input and output, between the output, employment and productivity

39

Power,A.,Plöger,J.andWinkler,A.(2010)TheFallandRiseofGreatIndustrialCities,Bristol:ThePolityPress.Rhodes,C.(2016)IndustrialStrategy,HouseofCommonsLibraryBriefingPaper07682,www.parliament.uk/commons-library | intranet.parliament.uk/commons-library | [email protected] | @commonslibraryRigby,D.andEssletzbichler,J.(2002)AgglomerationeconomiesandproductivitydifferencesinUScities,JournalofEconomicGeography2,pp.407-432.Riley,R.andBondibene,C.(2016)SourcesoflabourproductivitygrowthatasectorlevelinBritain,after2007,afirmlevelanalysis,NESTAWorkingPaper16/01.Romer,P.(1986)IncreasingReturnsandLongRunGrowth,JournalofPoliticalEconomy,94,pp.1002-1037.Roncolato,L.andKucera,D.(2014)StructuralDriversofProductivityandEmploymentGrowth:ADecompositionAnalysisfor81Countries,CambridgeJournalofEconomics,38,pp.399-424.Rosenthal.S.andStrange,W.(2003)Geography,industrialorganization,andagglomeration,ReviewofEconomicsandStatistics,85,2,pp.377-393.SiegelP.B.,Johnson,T.G.andAlwang,J.(1995)Regionaleconomicdiversityanddiversification,GrowthandChange,26,pp.261-284.Sandford,M.(2016)DevolutiontolocalgovernmentinEngland,HouseofCommons Library Briefing Paper 07029, www.parliament.uk/commons-library | intranet.parliament.uk/commons-library | [email protected] | @commonslibrary Sapir,A.(1996),TheeffectsofEurope’sinternalmarketprogramonproductionandtrade:Afirstassessment,WeltwirtschaftlichesArchiv,132,pp.457-475.Storper,M.,Chen,Y.andDePaolis,F.(2002),TradeandthelocationofindustriesintheOECDandEuropeanUnion,JournalofEconomicGeography,vol.2,pp.73-107.Storper,M.(2013)KeystotheCity:HowEconomics,Institutions,SocialInteraction,andPoliticsShapeDevelopment,Princeton:PrincetonUniversityPress.Storper,M.,Kemeny,T.,Makarem,N.P.andOsman,T.(2015)TheRiseandFallofCities:LessonsfromSanFranciscoandLosAngeles,Stanford:StanfordUniversityPress.

Page 41: Structural Change and Productivity Growth in Cities · characterised in terms of the quantitative relations between input and output, between the output, employment and productivity

40

Syverson,C.(2016)ChallengestomismeasurementexplanationsfortheUSproductivityslowdown,WorkingPaper21974,NationalBureauofEconomicResearch,CambridgeMass.Timmer,M.P.,anddeVries,G.J.(2009)StructuralchangeandgrowthaccelerationsinAsiaandLatinAmerica:anewsectoraldataset,Cliometrica,3,pp.165-190.Triplett,J.E.(1999)TheSolowProductivityParadox:whatdocomputersdotoproductivity,CanadianJournalofEconomics,32,pp.309-334.VanderPanne,G.(2004)Agglomerationexternalities:MarshallversusJacobs,JournalofEvolutionaryEconomics,14,pp.593-604.Webber,D.J.,Hudson,J.,Boddy,M.andPlumridge,A.(2009)RegionalproductivitydifferentialsinEngland:explainingthegap,PapersinRegionalScience,88,pp.609-621.Williamson,J.G.(1991)ProductivityandAmericanleadership:areviewarticle.JournalofEconomicLiterature29,pp.51–68.WorldBank(2008)SectoralPatternsofProductivityGrowth,Ch2inUnleashingProsperity,Washington:WorldBank.(http://siteresources.worldbank.org/ECAEXT/Resources/publications/UnleashingProsperity_2.pdf)