Modeling a Government-Manufacturer-Farmer game … › ~jzhuang › Papers ›...

13
Modeling a Government-Manufacturer-Farmer game for food supply chain risk management Cen Song a , Jun Zhuang b, * a School of Business Administration, China University of Petroleum, Beijing, China b Department of Industrial and Systems Engineering, University at Buffalo, USA article info Article history: Received 29 September 2016 Received in revised form 15 February 2017 Accepted 19 February 2017 Available online 23 February 2017 Keywords: Food supply chain Game theory Decision analysis Risk management Regulation abstract Farmers may add chemical additives to crops to enhance their appearances/tastes or decrease their costs, which may also increase the food demand and sales prots. Manufacturers buy products from farmers and sell them to consumers, where the government benets from tax income based on sales revenues. However, once the contaminated food is consumed, customers could get sick. The government would, thus, be partially responsible for society's health risks from the chemical additives. The punishment policies are set up by the government to regulate and deter farmers' and manufacturers' risky behavior, balancing tax income, punishment income, and society's health risks. Based on the observation of government regula- tions, the farmers strategically choose the optimal level of chemical additives, and manufacturers pay the appropriate price to farmers. To our knowledge, little work has studied the strategic interactions among the regulating government, manufacturers, and farmers with endogenous customer demand. This paper lls this gap by building a Government-Manufacturer-Farmer model with three decentralized and centralized sub-models. The models are validated and illustrated through applying the 2008 Sanlu food contamination data. Our results show that (a) the higher the food price is, the higher the punishment is needed to deter the use of chemicals; (b) the optimal chemical level increases in the payment to the farmer when it is low and decreases in the government punishment; (c) the manufacturer's payment to the farmer decreases in the government punishment; (d) the chemical level is signicantly higher in the centralized model than in the decentralized model especially when the food price and slope for sales amount are high, or the base sales demand, tax rate, and chemical cost are low; and (e) the decentralized model leads to the lowest chemical level at equilibrium. This paper provides some novel policy insights for food supply chain risk management. © 2017 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved. 1. Introduction In the eld of food supply chain research, there is literature focusing on health and safety. The consumers' perception of po- tential (food) risks is analyzed in (Liu, Pieniak, Verbeke, 2013; Liu, Pieniak, Verbeke, 2014; Sparks and Shepherd, 1994). Chemical ad- ditives are normally added in many processes along the food supply chain by farmers and manufacturers. The food additives are used for a number of purposes, generally for preservation, provision of vitamins or minerals, and enhancement of the food texture, appearance, and avor. However, food additives could also be harmful. For example, there were more than 100 pet deaths among nearly 500 cases of kidney failure due to a contaminated food additive, wheat gluten(which was adulterated with melamine to increase the apparent protein level) in animal food in 2007, involving three companies Americas Choice, Preferred Pet and Au- thority)(Associated Press, 2007; U S Food and Drug Administration and U S Department of Health & Human Service, 2008). At least six infants were killed due to kidney stones, and the kidneys of 300,000 infants were damaged by industrial chemical melamine in 2008 after using the milk products from Sanlu company (Branigan, 2008). Some children have experienced growth problems due to the contaminated chemical additive 2-ethylhexyl phthalate (DEHP) in food and drinks from 47 Taiwanese companies in 2011 (Galarpe, 2011). The German company, Harles and Jentzsch, contaminated 150,000 tons of feed for chickens, turkey, and swine with the cancer-causing additive Dioxin in 2011 (Spiegel Online, 2011). There are many other cases that follow the same pattern in China. There has been a longstanding concern about farmers using toxic pesticides on vegetables, rice, and other crops in China, where * Corresponding author. Department of Industrial and Systems Engineering, University at Buffalo, USA. E-mail addresses: [email protected] (C. Song), [email protected] (J. Zhuang). Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Food Control journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/foodcont http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.foodcont.2017.02.047 0956-7135/© 2017 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved. Food Control 78 (2017) 443e455

Transcript of Modeling a Government-Manufacturer-Farmer game … › ~jzhuang › Papers ›...

Page 1: Modeling a Government-Manufacturer-Farmer game … › ~jzhuang › Papers › SZ_FoodControl_2017.pdfModeling a Government-Manufacturer-Farmer game for food supply chain risk management

lable at ScienceDirect

Food Control 78 (2017) 443e455

Contents lists avai

Food Control

journal homepage: www.elsevier .com/locate/ foodcont

Modeling a Government-Manufacturer-Farmer game for food supplychain risk management

Cen Song a, Jun Zhuang b, *

a School of Business Administration, China University of Petroleum, Beijing, Chinab Department of Industrial and Systems Engineering, University at Buffalo, USA

a r t i c l e i n f o

Article history:Received 29 September 2016Received in revised form15 February 2017Accepted 19 February 2017Available online 23 February 2017

Keywords:Food supply chainGame theoryDecision analysisRisk managementRegulation

* Corresponding author. Department of IndustriaUniversity at Buffalo, USA.

E-mail addresses: [email protected] (C.(J. Zhuang).

http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.foodcont.2017.02.0470956-7135/© 2017 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

a b s t r a c t

Farmers may add chemical additives to crops to enhance their appearances/tastes or decrease their costs,whichmay also increase the food demand and sales profits. Manufacturers buy products from farmers andsell themtoconsumers,where the governmentbenefits fromtax incomebasedon sales revenues.However,once the contaminated food is consumed, customers could get sick. The government would, thus, bepartially responsible for society's health risks from the chemical additives. The punishment policies are setup by the government to regulate and deter farmers' and manufacturers' risky behavior, balancing taxincome, punishment income, and society's health risks. Based on the observation of government regula-tions, the farmers strategically choose the optimal level of chemical additives, and manufacturers pay theappropriate price to farmers. To our knowledge, littlework has studied the strategic interactions among theregulating government, manufacturers, and farmers with endogenous customer demand. This paper fillsthis gap by building a Government-Manufacturer-Farmer model with three decentralized and centralizedsub-models. Themodels are validated and illustrated through applying the 2008 Sanlu food contaminationdata. Our results show that (a) the higher the food price is, the higher the punishment is needed to deter theuse of chemicals; (b) the optimal chemical level increases in the payment to the farmer when it is low anddecreases in the government punishment; (c) the manufacturer's payment to the farmer decreases in thegovernment punishment; (d) the chemical level is significantly higher in the centralizedmodel than in thedecentralized model especially when the food price and slope for sales amount are high, or the base salesdemand, tax rate, and chemical cost are low; and (e) the decentralized model leads to the lowest chemicallevel at equilibrium. This paper provides somenovel policy insights for food supply chain riskmanagement.

© 2017 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

1. Introduction

In the field of food supply chain research, there is literaturefocusing on health and safety. The consumers' perception of po-tential (food) risks is analyzed in (Liu, Pieniak, Verbeke, 2013; Liu,Pieniak, Verbeke, 2014; Sparks and Shepherd, 1994). Chemical ad-ditives are normally added inmany processes along the food supplychain by farmers and manufacturers. The food additives are usedfor a number of purposes, generally for preservation, provision ofvitamins or minerals, and enhancement of the food texture,appearance, and flavor. However, food additives could also beharmful. For example, there were more than 100 pet deaths amongnearly 500 cases of kidney failure due to a contaminated food

l and Systems Engineering,

Song), [email protected]

additive, “wheat gluten” (which was adulterated with melamine toincrease the apparent protein level) in animal food in 2007,involving three companies Americas Choice, Preferred Pet and Au-thority) (Associated Press, 2007; U S Food and Drug Administrationand U S Department of Health & Human Service, 2008). At least sixinfants were killed due to kidney stones, and the kidneys of300,000 infants were damaged by industrial chemical melamine in2008 after using the milk products from Sanlu company (Branigan,2008). Some children have experienced growth problems due tothe contaminated chemical additive 2-ethylhexyl phthalate (DEHP)in food and drinks from 47 Taiwanese companies in 2011 (Galarpe,2011). The German company, Harles and Jentzsch, contaminated150,000 tons of feed for chickens, turkey, and swine with thecancer-causing additive Dioxin in 2011 (Spiegel Online, 2011).

There are many other cases that follow the same pattern inChina. There has been a longstanding concern about farmers usingtoxic pesticides on vegetables, rice, and other crops in China, where

Page 2: Modeling a Government-Manufacturer-Farmer game … › ~jzhuang › Papers › SZ_FoodControl_2017.pdfModeling a Government-Manufacturer-Farmer game for food supply chain risk management

C. Song, J. Zhuang / Food Control 78 (2017) 443e455444

the pesticides is meant to kill pests or keep the product fresh (Mail,2012). Another issue is that the use of poisonous chemical mala-chite green, whichwas used for raisingmandarin fish to avoid themill and was found in Hong Kong. It is said that this chemical isharmful for human health risk (CSR C, 2006). About 60 farms inHenan province fed pigs with illegal ractopamine to make moreprofit, where the ractopamine can speed up the process of musclebuilding and fat burning to produce leaner pork (Post, 2011).

Multi-stage supply chains in modern economies give anonymityto actors at different stages. The limited transmission of informa-tion from suppliers to consumers gives suppliers opportunity tointroduce harmful or fraudulent chemicals that raise their profitswhile harming or defrauding consumers without their knowledge.This strategy benefits individual suppliers in the short run at theexpense of consumers. However, market failure similar to a “mar-ket for lemons” scenario occurs when consumers become aware ofthe risk and have no means of gathering reliable information onproducts. Regulators can gain insights about how to preserve ahealthy market by considering the strategic behavior of differentactors in the supply chain.

1.1. Risky behavior in food supply chain

A food supply chain process is illustrated in Fig. 1, where rawmaterials such as raw milk are initially produced by farmers (rep-resenting suppliers of raw commodities to manufacturers whichinclude farmers and traders). The raw food is then bought andprocessed by the manufacturers, and eventually consumed by cus-tomers. The government receives the tax income through themanufacturer's sale profit. During the supply chain process, chem-ical additives could be added by the farmers or manufacturers topreserve the product's freshness or improve its appearance. (In2008, the contamination of melamine in the aforementioned Sanlucase actually is considered food fraud, and even a food crime, wherethe farmer added melamine to the raw milk.) The consumers mayget sick by consuming the contaminated food. The government in-spects and punishes the risky behavior by farmers ormanufacturersin the food supplychain andmaybe consideredpartially responsiblefor the societal impacts. The government agencies responsible forinspection and punishment include the U.S. Food and DrugAdministration, the European Food Safety Authority, and the Chi-nese Institute of Food Safety Control and Inspection. This paper fo-cuses on the risky behavior of the farmers, who could be motivatedby the low selling profits from manufacturers (Gale & Hu, 2009).

1.2. Motivation for risky behavior by manufacturers or farmers

Chemical additives could preserve the freshness of food andmake it more attractive, which is helpful for selling products. Due toconsiderable sales profits, the manufacturers or farmers may usefood additives even though they are harmful (Harrington, 2011).Inspection and punishment policies could deter the manufacturersor farmers' risky behavior. In the Sanlu case, due to low or even no

Fig. 1. Risky behavior from the farmers and manufacturers in food supply cha

profits from the Sanlu company, farmers had to add melamine toproduce milk with high protein, reduce the production costs, andsatisfy the demand for the Sanlu company, who was aware of suchrisky behavior (DeLaurentis, 2009). Appendix provides the influ-ence diagram for the manufacturer's or farmer's risky behavior.

1.3. Motivation for punishment policy by government

The government encourages the sales demand for the manu-facturers and farmers (whomay add high level of chemicals), whichcould yield considerable tax incomes from an economic perspec-tive. A conflict tradeoff is generated for the government on how tocontrol the risky behavior. We consider the government as the firstmover who sets up punishment, and the farmers or manufacturersas the followers who observe the punishment policy and strategi-cally add chemical additives. The government takes the optimalpunishment strategy considering the farmers' and manufacturers'strategic responses, to farmers and manufacturers, respectively.Appendix provides the influence diagram for the government'spunishment policy.

1.4. Literature review and contribution

Food contamination incidents could derive from the govern-ment's lack of regulations, punishments, and resources to enforcefood safety (Ellis & Turner, 2010; Ming, 2006; Zacha, Doyleb, Bierc,& Czuprynskib, 2012). For the safety of the (food) supply chain,many suggestions on government regulations are proposed: (a) thejoint use of liability and safety regulation (Shavell, 1984)); (b) finesand corrective taxes (Kambhu, 1990); (c) a higher inspection ac-curacy and stronger enforcement (Cheung & Zhuang, 2012; Oh,1995); (d) the imposition of liability for damages (Segerson,1999); (e) transferring costs and benefits from the government tothe manufacturers using penalty contracts (Hobbs & Kerr, 1999);and (f) transferring safety failure costs from the government to themanufacturers (Chen, 2009). This paper focuses on the govern-ment's punishment and taxes.

There exists strategic interactions between companies and theregulating government in the existing literature (Tompkin, 2001).For example, (Rose-Ackerman, 1991) suggests direct regulation andproduct liability that can make incentives for companies to controlfood quality. (Henson& Caswell, 1999) points out that the expectedeconomic benefits and costs affect a firm's response to the gov-ernment regulation. The companies' benefits and costs aremeasured for improving food quality and safety in quality man-agement systems in (Caswell, 1998). (Fares & Rouviere, 2010) findsthat the company's decision of using additives depends on its owncosts (e.g., food spoilage and risks) and benefits (e.g., productivityenhancement), with or without facing the government regulation.

Strategic interactions between companies and the governmentare not new, e.g., (Pouliot& Sumner, 2008) analyzes the food safetyand quality issues from the perspective of traceability in a mar-keting chain composed of farmers, marketers and consumers.

in, under potential government regulation, inspection, and punishment.

Page 3: Modeling a Government-Manufacturer-Farmer game … › ~jzhuang › Papers › SZ_FoodControl_2017.pdfModeling a Government-Manufacturer-Farmer game for food supply chain risk management

Fig. 2. Illustrating the Relationships between the Three Models Studied in this Paper.

Table 1Notation and explanation in the government-manufacturer-farmer (GvMvF) model.

DecisionVariables

PF � 0 Farmer's payment per unit milk set by themanufacturer

x Level of chemical additives set by farmerbF � 0 Punishment to the farmer set by the governmentbM � 0 Punishment to the manufacturer set by the

governmentFunctions QðxÞ � 0 Consumer demand

HðxÞ2½0;1� Probability of sicknessUGðx; bÞ The government's utility functionUMðx; bÞ The manufacturer's utility functionUF ðPF ; bF Þ Farmer's utility function

Parameters pm � 0 Chemical unit cost½x�; xþ� Chemical level lower bound x� and upper bound

c � 0 Coefficient of health cost per number of sick peopleg2½0; 1� Tax rateQ0 >0 Baseline demand for QðXÞq � 0 Slope for QðXÞP � 0 Unit food pricel � 0 Slope for HðxÞcp � 0 Unit production cost for proteincm � 0 Unit production cost for manufacturernp � 0 Amount of nitrogen in unit proteinnm � 0 Amount of nitrogen in unit melamineN � 0 Total required amount of nitrogen in unit milk

powderxp � 0 Level of proteinpp � 0 Unit protein price

C. Song, J. Zhuang / Food Control 78 (2017) 443e455 445

(Song & Zhuang, 2017) studies a two-player government-manu-facturer game where the manufacturer could add chemicals.However, in practice there might exist a third player (e.g., farmer)who add chemical additives (see 14). Therefore, this paper extends(Song & Zhuang, 2017) by analyzing the strategic interactionsamong the regulating government, manufacturers, and farmersconsidering endogenous customers' demands in the context of foodsupply chain risk management. Since Sanlu case is considered asfood fraud, this paper analyzes the risky behaviors of farmers andmanufacturers from an economic way known as economicallymotivated adulteration (EMA, see (Moore, Spink, & Lipp, 2012)).

In particular, we consider a sequential game where the gov-ernment, the first player, sets the punishment policies for manu-facturers and farmers, balancing tax income, punishment incomeand societal cost. The manufacturer, as the second mover, pays thefarmer based on the observable government punishment infor-mation, balancing punishment, tax costs, and sales revenues. Thefarmer, as the third mover, observes the punishment and paymentinformation and chooses the chemical level, balancing punishment,chemical and production costs, and the sales revenue.

The rest of this paper is organized as follows: Section 2 in-troduces the optimization problems in a Government-Manufacturer-Farmer model, provides the best responses for thefarmers and manufacturers and the optimal solution for the gov-ernment punishment policy with numerical illustration, studiestwo types of centralized models, and compares the equilibriumpayoffs and strategies between the centralized and decentralizedmodels. In particular, a government against manufacturer againstfarmer (GvMvF) model is introduced in Section 2.2, a centralizedGovernment-Manufacturer-Farmer (GMF) model is introduced inSection 2.4.1, and a government against manufacturer and farmer(GvMF) model is introduced in Section 2.4.2. Fig. 2 summarizes therelationship and location of all models to be studied in this paper.Section 3 applies the Sanlu case and compares the three models.Section 4 summarizes this paper and provides some future researchdirections. Appendix provides the proofs for the propositions.

2. A government vs. manufacturer vs. farmer (GvMvF) model

In the 2008 tainted Sanlu milk powder accident, the farmeradded melamine into raw milk, the manufacturer purchased theraw milk for further processing, and the government was respon-sible for inspecting and punishing risky behavior of both themanufacturer and farmer (Branigan, 2008). A Government-Manufacturer-Farmer (GvMvF) model is studied in this section.

2.1. Notation, sequence of moves, and assumption

Table 1 lists the notations that are used throughout this section,including four decision variables (farmer's payment per unit milk setby the manufacturer PF, chemical level x, punishment to farmer set

by the government bF , and punishment to the manufacturer set bythe government bM), five utility functions (customer demand QðxÞ,sickness probability HðxÞ, the government's utility UGðx; bÞ, and themanufacturer's utility UMðx; bÞ, farmer's utility UF ), and thirteenparameters (chemical unit cost pm, coefficient of health cost c, taxrate g, basic demand Q0, slope for customer demand q, unit foodprice P, and slope for probability of sickness l, unit production costfor protein cp, amount of nitrogen in unit protein np, amount of ni-trogen in unit melamine nm, total required amount of nitrogen inunit milk powder N, level of protein xp, and unit protein price pp).

Stackelberg competition, an economics strategic game, occurswhen the first “leader” firm makes a decision and provides the firstmove of the game. A second“follower” firm moves sequentiallybased on the leader firm's action. Fig. 3 illustrates the sequence ofmoves for the government, manufacturer, and farmer with publicinformation. We assume that the government is the first moverwho sets the punishment levels bM for the manufacturer and bF thefarmer. The manufacturer is the second mover, and decides thepayment to farmer PF while considering the punishment level bM .Finally, the farmer chooses the chemical level x based on the pay-ment PF , punishment bF , and consumer demand QðxÞ. The farmer,the government, and the manufacturer are assumed to be rationaland maximize their expected payoffs UF , UG, and UM , respectively.

Page 4: Modeling a Government-Manufacturer-Farmer game … › ~jzhuang › Papers › SZ_FoodControl_2017.pdfModeling a Government-Manufacturer-Farmer game for food supply chain risk management

Fig. 3. Sequence of moves for government, manufacturer, and farmer with publicinformation.

C. Song, J. Zhuang / Food Control 78 (2017) 443e455446

We assume that consumer demand QðxÞ as a function of thechemical level x in Equation (1), has the following properties:

QðxÞ ¼ Q0 þ qx; cx2hx�; xþ

i(1)

Qð0Þ ¼ Q0; Q 0ðxÞ � 0; (2)

That is, the higher q is, the faster QðxÞ increases.Similarly, we assume that the probability of sickness HðxÞ as a

function of chemical level x, has the following properties:

HðxÞ2½0;1�; H0ðxÞ � 0; H0 00 ðxÞ � 0; (3)

That is, the higher the chemical level x, the higher the proba-bility of sickness happening.We use parameter l tomodel the slopeof HðxÞ.

HðxÞ ¼ lx (4)

It could be better to use exponential functional forms for theEquations (1) and (4), however, for more analytical results in thelater part, we apply linear forms in this section.

2.2. Optimization problems for the decentralized (GvMvF) model

We assume that the farmer's goal is to choose the appropriatelevel of chemical additives x to maximize expected payoff inEquation (5) below, consisting of: (a) total sales revenue PFQðxÞ; (b)expected punishment cost bFHðxÞQðxÞ; (c) chemical purchase costpmxQðxÞ; and (d) protein production cost cpxpQðxÞ. We assume thatthere is no tax on the farmer.

maxx2½x�;xþ�

UFðx; PF ;bFÞ ¼ PFQðxÞ|fflfflfflffl{zfflfflfflffl}Sales Revenue

� bFHðxÞQðxÞ|fflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflffl{zfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflffl}Punishment Cost

� pmxQðxÞ|fflfflfflfflfflffl{zfflfflfflfflfflffl}Chemical Cost

� cpxpQðxÞ|fflfflfflfflfflffl{zfflfflfflfflfflffl}Production Cost

(5)

From the manufacturer's perspective, the goal is to choose theappropriate payment level to the farmer PF to maximize the ex-pected payoff shown in Equation (6) below, consisting of threeitems: (a) sales revenue ðP � PFÞQðxÞ; (b) punishment costbMQðxÞHðxÞ; (c) tax cost gPQðxÞ; and (d) production cost cmQðxÞ.

maxPF�0

UMðbxðPF ; bFÞ; PF ; bMÞ ¼ ðP � PFÞQðxÞ|fflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflffl{zfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflffl}Sales Revenue

� bMQðxÞHðxÞ|fflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflffl{zfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflffl}Punishment Cost

� gPQðxÞ|fflfflfflffl{zfflfflfflffl}Tax Cost

� cmQðxÞ|fflfflfflffl{zfflfflfflffl}Production Cost

(6)

One of the government's roles is to set the punishment policy todeter manufacturer's and farmer's risky behaviors for the sake ofpublic health, where the corresponding costs of deterrence andimplementation are ignored. Another role of the government is toput appropriate economic burdens on the manufacturer's devel-opment in order to maintain a stable and healthy economic growthand employment rate. From the government's perspective, the goalis to choose the optimal punishment levels to the farmer bF and tothe manufacturer bM to maximize the expected payoff shown inEquation (7) below, consisting of three items: (a) health costcQðxÞHðxÞ; (b) punishment income ðbF þ bMÞQðxÞHðxÞ; and (c) taxincome gPQðxÞ.

maxbF�0;bM�0

UG

�bx�cPF ðbMÞ; bF�; bF ; bM

�¼ � cQðxÞHðxÞ|fflfflfflfflfflfflffl{zfflfflfflfflfflfflffl}

Health Cost

þðbF þ bMÞQðxÞHðxÞ|fflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflffl{zfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflffl}Punishment Income

þ gPQðxÞ|fflfflfflffl{zfflfflfflffl}Tax Income

(7)

Definition 1. We call a pair of strategy (x�; P�F ; b�F ; b

�M) a subgame

perfect Nash equilibrium (SPNE), or “equilibrium” for the GvMvFmodel, if and only if Equations (8e10) below are satisfied:

x� ¼ bx�P�F ; b�F� (8)

P�F ¼ cPF �b�M�(9)

�b�F ; b

�M� ¼ argmax

bF�0;bM�0UG

�bx�cPF ðbMÞ; bF ; bF�;bM

�(10)

where the farmer's and the manufacturer's best responses bxðPF ; bF Þand cPF ðbMÞ are defined in Equations (11e12), respectively.

bxðPF ; bFÞ≡ argmaxx2½x�;xþ�

UFðx; PF ; bFÞ;cPF ; bF � 0 (11)

cPF ðbMÞ≡ argmaxPF�0

UMðbxðPF ; bFÞ; PF ; bMÞ;cbM � 0 (12)

It is hard to test the protein percentage in milk powder, sogenerally a Kjeldahl determination method is used to test nitrogenamounts, which is used to further calculate the amount of proteinin milk powder (Cohen, 1910). In reality, melamine, a fake nitrogenprovider, is used to replace protein with less cost. The relationshipamong nitrogen, melamine, and protein in the Sanlu milk case is asfollows:

npxp|ffl{zffl}Niotrogen in Protein

þ nmx|ffl{zffl}Niotrogen in Chemical

� N|{z}Required Nitrogen

(13)

That is, Equation (13) details the sources where the nitrogencomes from, including protein and the chemical melamine. It isrequired by the standard that the total amount of nitrogen in

Page 5: Modeling a Government-Manufacturer-Farmer game … › ~jzhuang › Papers › SZ_FoodControl_2017.pdfModeling a Government-Manufacturer-Farmer game for food supply chain risk management

C. Song, J. Zhuang / Food Control 78 (2017) 443e455 447

protein meets a certain level (threshold N), where the details willbe discussed in Section 3. Based on Equation (13), we have the levelof protein xp � N�nmx

np. Since the farmer would choose the lowest

bxðPF ; bFÞ ¼

8>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>><>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>:

x� if bF ¼ alq

; PFq� bFlQ0 � �b; or

bF >alq

;bþ PFq� bFlQ0

2ðbFlq� aÞ < x�; or

bF <alq

;UF

x�

� UF

xinterior ¼

bþ PFq� bFlQ0

2ðbFlq� aÞ if bF >alq

;bþ PFq� bFlQ0

2ðbFlq� aÞ 2hx�; xþ

ixþ if bF ¼ a

lq; PFq� bFlQ0 > � b; or

bF >alq

;bþ PFq� bFlQ0

2ðbFlq� aÞ > xþ; or

bF <alq

;UF

x�

<UF

(16)

level of protein tomeet the requirement while minimizing the totalcosts, we have

xp ¼ N � nmxnp

(14)

2.3. Solution and numerical illustration

Inserting Equations (1), (4) and (14) into Equation (5), thefarmer's optimization problem becomes:

maxx2½x�;xþ�

UFðx; PF ; bFÞ ¼�� bFlþ

cpnmnp

� pm

�qx2

þ�PFq� bFlQ0 � pmQ0 �

cpNqnp

þ cpnmQ0

np

�x

þPFQ0 �cpNQ0

np

¼ ða� bFlqÞx2 þ ðbþ PFq� bFlQ0Þxþ PFQ0 �cpNQ0

np

(15)

where a≡q�cpnm

np� pm

�, and b≡� pmQ0 � cpNq

npþ cpnmQ0

np.

Fig. 4. Illustration of the Farmer's best response chemical level bx as functions of the Gov

Proposition 1. The solution to the farmer’s optimization problem(Associated Press, 2007) is given by

Additionally, we have vbxðPF ;bF ÞvPF

¼ q2ðbFlq�aÞ � 0 and

vbxðPF ;bF ÞvbF

¼ lQ0ðbFlq�aÞþlqðbþPFq�bFlQ0Þ2ðbFlq�aÞ2 <0, when bxðPF ; bF Þ ¼ xinterior ,

where bþ PFq� bFlQ0 >0 and bFlq� a>0.

Remark. Proposition 1 shows that the manufacturer's chemical

level, in interior solution bþPFq�bFlQ0

2ðbFlq�aÞ , decreases in the government

punishment to the farmer bF and increases in the payment to thefarmer PF for the intermediate solution.

Inserting Equations (1) and (4) into Equation (6), the manufac-turer's optimization problem becomes:

maxPF�0

UMðbxðPF ; bFÞ; PF ;bMÞ ¼ a0P2F þ b0PF þ c0

where a0≡�q2ðtþbMlqÞt2 �0, t¼2ðbFlq�aÞ>0, b0≡

tq2ð1�gÞP�Q0ðtþbMlqÞt�2q2bMlðb�bFlQ0Þt2 �cmq2

t , and

c0≡��

Q0þqðb�bFlQ0Þt

���1�gÞP�bMlðb�bFlQ0Þ

t

���cmQ0�cmqðb�bFlQ0Þ

t .

Using the baseline values g¼0:5, P¼1, Q0¼1, q¼2, c¼1, pm¼0:5,l¼1, x�¼0, xþ¼1, cp¼0:6, cm¼0, np¼0:16, nm¼0:666, andN¼0:0288, Fig. 4 shows how the manufacturer payment PF and

ernment's punishment bF and the Manufacturer's payment PF in the GvMvF model.

Page 6: Modeling a Government-Manufacturer-Farmer game … › ~jzhuang › Papers › SZ_FoodControl_2017.pdfModeling a Government-Manufacturer-Farmer game for food supply chain risk management

C. Song, J. Zhuang / Food Control 78 (2017) 443e455448

punishment bF affect the farmer's optimal chemical level x. Inparticular, Fig. 4 shows that the optimal chemical level x increasesin PF and decreases in bF .

Proposition 2. The solution to the manufacturer’s optimizationproblem (Branigan, 2008) is given by

cPF ðbMÞ

¼

8><>:b0

�2a0if t >0;

b0

�2a02

"tx� � bþ bFlQ0

q;txþ � bþ bFlQ0

q

#

0 Otherwise

(17)

where a, b, a0, b0 are defined in Section 2.3 and Proposition 1. In

addition, we have dbPF ðbMÞdbM

¼ �lq3 ½2qðb�bFlQ0Þðtþ2bMlqÞþtq2ð1�gÞP�2a02t4

� 0.

Remark. Proposition 2 shows that at the interior solution themanufacturer’s payment to the farmer PF decreases in the gov-ernment punishment to the manufacturer bM.

Fig. 5 shows how the manufacturer’s best response PF isaffected by the punishment bM , when the punishment to thefarmer bF is set at 0.2. In particular, it shows that the optimalmanufacturer's payment PF decreases in punishment bM until thepoint bM ¼ 0:9. We assume that if the government is indifferentbetween different punishment levels that lead to the samepayoff, the lowest punishment level would be chosen from amathematical perspective. The analytical solution for the gov-ernment's optimal strategy is too complex to document in thispaper, but it is available upon request.

xGMF ¼

8>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>><>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>:

x� if c ¼cpnmnp

� pm

l; P � cpN

npþ cmÞq� ðpm þ clÞQ0

q;

c>

cpnmnp

� pm

l;

P � cpN

np� cm

�q� ðpm þ clÞQ0

2pm þ cl� cpnm

np

�q

< x

c<

cpnmnp

� pm

l;U

x�

� U

xinterior if c>

cpnmnp

� pm

l;

P � cpN

np� cm

�q� ðpm þ clÞQ0

2pm þ cl� cpnm

np

�q

2

xþ if c ¼cpNnp

� cm � pm

l; P >

cpNnp

þ cmÞq� ðpm þ clÞQ

c>

cpnmnp

� pm

l;

P � cpN

np� cm

�q� ðpm þ clÞQ0

2pm þ cl� cpnm

np

�q

> x

c<

cpnmnp

� pm

l;U

x�

<U

2.4. Two centralized models

In this section, we consider two types of centralized models: theGovernment-Manufacturer-Farmer (GMF) model introduced inSection 2.4.1 and the Government vs. Manufacturer-Farmer (GvMF)model introduced in Section 2.4.2. It is rare that the governmentcooperates with the manufacturer against the farmer, so we do notconsider the Government-Manufacturer vs. Farmer (GMvF) model.

2.4.1. Government-Manufacturer-Farmer (GMF) modelIn the GMF model, the government, the manufacturer, and the

farmer cooperate together to maximize the societal payoff UðxÞ,which equals the summation of the government, the manufacturer,and the farmer's payoffs in Equations (5e7). From Equation (18)shown below, we see that the punishment and payment to thefarmer are canceled. The only decision variable is the chemical level x.

maxx2½x�;xþ�

UðxÞ ¼ UM þ UF þ UG

¼ PQðxÞ � pmxQðxÞ|fflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflffl{zfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflffl}Sales Revenue

� cpxpQðxÞ � cmQðxÞ|fflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflffl{zfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflffl}Production Cost

� cQðxÞHðxÞ|fflfflfflfflfflfflffl{zfflfflfflfflfflfflffl}Health Cost

(18)

Inserting Equations (1), (4), and (14) into Equation (18), thecooperative optimization problem becomes:

maxx2½x�;xþ�

UðxÞ ¼ ��pm þ cl� cpnm

np

�qx2 þ

��P � cpN

np� cm

�q

� ðpm þ clÞQ0

�xþ �

P � cpxp � cm�Q0

(19)

Solving Equation (19), the optimal chemical level is given byEquation (20).

or

�; or

hx�; xþ

i

0

q; or

þ; or

(20)

Page 7: Modeling a Government-Manufacturer-Farmer game … › ~jzhuang › Papers › SZ_FoodControl_2017.pdfModeling a Government-Manufacturer-Farmer game for food supply chain risk management

C. Song, J. Zhuang / Food Control 78 (2017) 443e455 449

where xinterior ¼P�cpN

np�cm

q�ðpmþclÞQ0

2pmþcl�cpnm

np

q

.

Fig. 5. Illustration of the Manufacturer’s Best Response PF to Punishment bM in theGvMvF Model.

2.4.2. The government vs. Manufacturer-Farmer (GvMF) modelIn the GvMF model, the manufacturer and farmer cooperate

together against the government. The combined manufacturer andfarmer utility equals the summation of the respective manufacturerand farmer utilities in Equations (5e6). From Equation (21) below,we see that the payment to the farmer is canceled out.

maxx2½x�;xþ�

UFMðxÞ¼UMþUF ¼ PQðxÞ|fflfflffl{zfflfflffl}Sales Profit

� pmxQðxÞ|fflfflfflfflfflffl{zfflfflfflfflfflffl}Chemical Cost

�cpxpQðxÞþcmQðxÞ|fflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflffl{zfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflffl}Production Cost

�ðbMþbFÞQðxÞHðxÞ|fflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflffl{zfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflffl}Punishment Cost

�gPQðxÞ|fflfflfflffl{zfflfflfflffl}Tax Cost

(21)

The government's optimization problem remains the same as inEquation (7). Inserting Equations (1), (4), and (14) into Equation(21), the cooperative optimization problem becomes:

maxx2½x�;xþ�

UFMðxÞ ¼ ��pm þ bmlþ bFl�

cpnmnp

�qx2

þ��

P � gP � cpNnp

� cm

�q

� ðpm þ bmlþ bFlÞQ0

�xþ �

P � cpxp � cm�Q0

(22)

Solving Equation (22), the optimal chemical level is given byEquation (23)

xFM ¼

8>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>><>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>:

x� if bm þ bF ¼cpnmnp

� pm

l; P �

ðbmlþ bFlþ pmÞQ0

1� g

bm þ bF >

cpnmnp

� pm

l;

�P � gP � cpN

np� cm

�q� ðpm

2�pm þ bmlþ bFl�

bm þ bF <

cpnmnp

� pm

l;UFM

x�

� UFM

xinterior if bm þ bF >

cpnmnp

� pm

l;

�P � gP � cpN

np� cm

�q� ðp

2�pm þ bmlþ bFl

xþ if bm þ bF ¼cpnmnp

� pm

l; P <

ðbmlþ bFlþ pmÞQ0

1� g

bm þ bF >

cpnmnp

� pm

l;

�P � gP � cpN

np� cm

�q� ðpm

2�pm þ bmlþ bFl�

bm þ bF <

cpnmnp

� pm

l;UFM

x�

<UFM

where xinterior ¼P�gP�cpN

np�cm

q�ðpmþbmlþbFlÞQ0

2pmþbmlþbFl�cpnm

np

q

.

3. Sanlu case study

3.1. Data sources

This paper applies the data from the Sanlu contaminated milkpowder case study in 2008 to validate and illustrate the models inSection 2. The Sanlu company, as the manufacturer, took re-sponsibility for the contamination that resulted in the kidney

cm þ cpNnp

; or

þ bmlþ bFlÞQ0

cpnmnp

�q

< x�; or

m þ bmlþ bFlÞQ0

� cpnmnp

�q

2hx�; xþ

i

cm þ cpNnp

; or

þ bmlþ bFlÞQ0

cpnmnp

�q

> xþ; or

(23)

Page 8: Modeling a Government-Manufacturer-Farmer game … › ~jzhuang › Papers › SZ_FoodControl_2017.pdfModeling a Government-Manufacturer-Farmer game for food supply chain risk management

C. Song, J. Zhuang / Food Control 78 (2017) 443e455450

damages of about 3million infants by selling the contaminatedmilkpowder. The government charged Sanlu a fine of 49.4 million Chi-nese RMB (about $7 million in 2008) (Xinhuanet, 2009) andenforceda902millionRMBcompensation to society (Xinhua, 2009).

We reference the data points (Hau, Kwan, & Li, 2009): (0, 0),(750, 0.2), (1500, 0.5), (3000, 0.7), (6000, 0.9), (12000,1) to estimatethe sickness probability of a human being HðxÞ, where the firstnumber in the bracket is the chemical level x in ppm (parts permillion) and the second is the sickness probability of rats HðxÞ. Thesickness probability function is exponentially regressed asHðxÞ ¼ 1� exp�lx, where l ¼ 389:7.

(Southern Metropolis, 2008) roughly estimated the total salesamount isQðxÞ ¼ 700;000 kg as the chemical level x ¼ 2563 ppm¼2:563�10�3 kg/kg (CCTV com, 2009). Based on the milk powder,price is estimated as P ¼ 25 RMB/400 g ¼ 62.5 RMB/kg (Bloomberg,

2008), we have the coefficient q ¼ QðxÞx ¼ 2:73� 108, once we as-

sume Q0 ¼ 0.From (Food Safety Rapid Detection of Network, 2011), we have

the range of the amount of protein required in milk powder asxp2ð15%;20%Þ, and the amount of nitrogen in protein as np ¼ 16%.We average the protein amount as xp ¼ 18%, and have the totalamount of nitrogen in 1 kg milk powder as N ¼ 0:18�0:16 ¼ 0:0288kg. The nitrogen density from melamine is nm ¼ 66:6%. The cost ofmelamine is one fifth of the cost of protein considering the sameamount of protein being produced. Based on that, we have theprotein price pp ¼ 16%

66:6% � 5 � pm ¼ 0:84 RMB/kg. We also have theunit production cost for protein cp ¼ 2:2 RMB/kg (Gale&Hu, 2009),the melamine cost pm ¼ 0.7 RMB/kg (Wong, 2008), and the tax ratefor milk powder estimated as g ¼ 0.17 (State Administration ofTaxation, 2011).

Fig. 6. Optimal Level of Chemical, Payment to Farmer, and Punishment Strategy as Functions

3.2. The Government-Manufacturer-Farmer model in the Sanlu case

3.2.1. Sensitivity analysis of equilibrium strategiesFig. 6 illustrates the optimal level of chemical x, payment to the

farmer PF, and punishment strategy b with decentralized decisionmaking analyzed as a function of l, Q0, c, g, N, P, np, cp, pm, nm and q.It shows that the chemical level x decreases in coefficient of healthsickness l, basic sales demand Q0, and coefficient of health cost c(Fig. 6 (a, b, c)), while the chemical level x increases in tax rate g

(Fig. 6 (d)). We observe the highest chemical level x, the lowestpayment to the farmer by the manufacturer PF, and the lowestpunishment levels bF and bM , when there is no health cost. Fig. 6 (d)indicates that the government can leverage the tax rate to reducethe chemical level. The optimal payment to the farmer PF has thesame directional change of x in l and Q0. The best punishmentstrategy to the manufacturer bM increases in c and l. The bestpunishment strategy to the farmer bF increases in c which dem-onstrates the government increases punishment b to deter thefarmer's risky behavior.

3.2.2. Comparison between the centralized (GMF) anddecentralized models (GvMvF)

Figs. 7 and 8 compare the equilibrium chemical levels and so-cietal utilities between the centralized GMF model (xc and Uc,respectively) and the decentralized GvMvF model (xd and Ud,respectively). It demonstrates that xc is higher than xd, especiallywhen food price P and slope for sales amount q (Fig. 7 (f, k)) arehigh, or base sales demand Q0, tax rate g, production cost cp andchemical cost pm (Fig. 7 (b, d, h, i)) are low. Fig. 8 shows the sameconditions hold when Uc is higher than Ud.

of l, Q0, c, g, N, P, np , cp , pm , nm and q in the Government-Manufacturer-Farmer Model.

Page 9: Modeling a Government-Manufacturer-Farmer game … › ~jzhuang › Papers › SZ_FoodControl_2017.pdfModeling a Government-Manufacturer-Farmer game for food supply chain risk management

Fig. 7. Comparison between the GMF and GvMvF models for equilibrium chemical levels.

C. Song, J. Zhuang / Food Control 78 (2017) 443e455 451

3.3. Comparison between the centralized (GvMF) and decentralized(GvMvF) models

Figs. 9 and 10 compare the equilibrium chemical levels andsocial utilities between the centralized GvMF model (xc and Uc,respectively) and the decentralized GvMvF model (xd and Ud,respectively). Fig. 9 demonstrates that the chemical level xc ishigher than xd, especially when food price P and slope for sales

Fig. 8. Comparison between the GMF and

amount q (Fig. 9 (f, k)) are high or when sickness slope l, coefficientof society cost c, tax rate g, production cost cp and chemical cost pm(Fig. 9 (a, c, d, h, i)) are low. Fig. 10 demonstrates that the socialutility Uc is higher than Ud, especially when tax rate g, food price P,and slope for sales amount q (Fig. 10 (d, f, k)) are high or when thesickness slope l, coefficient for health cost c, production cost cp andchemical cost pm (Fig. 10 (a, c, h, i)) are low.

GvMvF models for the social utilities.

Page 10: Modeling a Government-Manufacturer-Farmer game … › ~jzhuang › Papers › SZ_FoodControl_2017.pdfModeling a Government-Manufacturer-Farmer game for food supply chain risk management

Fig. 9. Comparison between the GvMF and GvMvF models for equilibrium chemical levels.

C. Song, J. Zhuang / Food Control 78 (2017) 443e455452

3.4. Comparison at all models

Table 2 compares the chemical level x, the punishment to thecompany b, the social utility Uc, and the government utility UGamong the GvMvF, GMF, and GvMF models. It shows that the GvMvFmodel leads to the lowest chemical level x and sickness probabilityHðxÞ, the GvMF model leads to the highest government utility UG,

Fig. 10. Comparison between the GvMF and

and that the GMF model leads to the highest social utility Uc and thehighest sales amount QðxÞ.

4. Conclusion and future research directions

In the food supply chain, it is important, but challenging, for thegovernment to regulate the risky behavior of farmers and

GvMvF models for the social utilities.

Page 11: Modeling a Government-Manufacturer-Farmer game … › ~jzhuang › Papers › SZ_FoodControl_2017.pdfModeling a Government-Manufacturer-Farmer game for food supply chain risk management

Table 2Comparison among the GvMvF , GMF , and GvMF models.

x bM bF Uc UG UF UM QðxÞ HðxÞGvMvF 0 0 1400 0 0 0 0 0 0GMF 4� 10�5 N=A N=A 340377 N=A N=A N=A 10920 0.015GvMF 2� 10�5 30 4400 254309 159748 N=A N=A 5460 0.008

Government Inspects & Punishes

Manufacturer/Farmer Adds

Chemicals

Penalty Cost

Sales Profit

Chemical Cost

Net Profit Value

Chance Nodes Decision NodeIntermediate Value Nodes

Final Value Node

Poten al Sickness

Fig. 11. Influence diagram for the manufacturer's or farmer's risky behavior.

Chance NodesDecision NodeIntermediate Value Nodes

Final Value Node

GovernmentPunishment

Policy

Chemical Level Tax Income

Penalty IncomeNet

Payoff

Health CostPoten alSickness

Fig. 12. Influence diagram for the government's punishment policy.

C. Song, J. Zhuang / Food Control 78 (2017) 443e455 453

manufacturers who may add excessive chemical additives. Suchregulations are further complicated by the factors such as salesprofit, tax income, punishment income, and consumer health risks.This paper builds up a Government-Manufacturer-Farmer modelwith three players, which details and quantifies the risky behaviorsin the process of supply chain risk management. The analyticalsolution for farmer's chemical level and manufacturer's paymentare provided. The three players' corresponding equilibrium strate-gies are numerically illustrated, where the chemical level increasesin the milk payment to the farmer when it is low, and decreases inthe punishment to the farmer. The manufacturer's payment to thefarmer decreases in the government punishment policy. At thispoint, since there are two types of government punishments cor-responding to both the farmer and manufacturer, and in order toavoid the farmer's risky behavior, our suggestion is: (a) the pun-ishment to the farmer should not be too low to deter farmer's riskybehavior; and (b) the punishment to the manufacturer should notbe too high, otherwise it would affect the farmer's benefit from themanufacturer's payment to the farmer, and lead farmer to addchemical additives. The sensitivity analysis of equilibrium strate-gies indicates that the government can leverage the tax rate toreduce the chemical level.

One decentralized Government vs. Manufacturer vs. Farmer(GvMvF) model and two centralized (Government-Manufacturer-Farmer GMF, and the Government vs. Farmer-Manufacturer GvMF)models are analyzed. This paper applies the real data from the 2008Sanlu milk powder contamination case to the three models. Wedemonstrate that (a) the optimal chemical level in the centralizedGMF model is higher than that in the decentralized GvMvF model,especially when the food price and the slope for sales amount arehigh, or the base sales demand, tax rate, production cost, andchemical cost are low; and (b) the optimal chemical level in thecentralized GvMF model is higher than that in the decentralizedGvMvF model, especially when the food price and the slope forsales amount are high, or when the tax rate, sickness slope, coef-ficient of society cost, production cost and chemical cost are low.Finally, we compare all three models and find out the decentralizedGvMvF model leads to the lowest chemical level and sicknessprobability, the GvMF model leads to the highest governmentutility, and the centralized GMF model leads to the highest socialutility and the highest sales amount. This means that the govern-ment should not cooperate with the farmer for the lower use ofchemical additives and sickness probability. Additionally, thefarmer should not cooperate with the manufacturer for the lowersickness probability and government's punishment. This paperdemonstrates the origin cause of the farmer's risky behavior anddirect and indirect effect of the manufacturer and government'sbehavior decisions. It provides some novel government punish-ment policy insights and farmer/manufacturer strategies for thefood supply chain risk management. It could give some managerialinsights for manufacturers on the payment to the farmer andwhether to control the quality of milk.

Some future research directions include: (a) considering thegovernment tax policy as a decision variable affecting the manu-facturers' and farmers' risky behaviors; (b) modeling the farmers'and manufacturers' non-strategic behaviors; (c) analyzing the

competitions between manufacturers or between farmers; and (d)considering the different effects of chemical additives on the food'sperishing rate in a dynamic model.

Acknowledgements

This research was partially supported by the United States Na-tional Science Foundation (NSF) under award numbers 1200899and 1334930. This research was also partially supported by theUnited States Department of Homeland Security (DHS) through theNational Center for Risk and Economic Analysis of Terrorism Events(CREATE) under award number 2010-ST-061-RE0001. In addition,this research was partially supported by the Beijing Natural ScienceFoundation under award number 9174040, Beijing Social ScienceFoundation under award number 16GLC076 and Science Founda-tion of China University of Petroleum, Beijing under award numbers2462014YJRC051 and 2462015YQ0722. However, any opinions,findings, conclusions, or recommendations in this document arethose of the authors and do not necessarily reflect views of thesponsors. We thank anonymous reviewers for constructivecomments.

A. Appendix

A.1. Influence diagrams for the players

Fig. 11 shows an influence diagram (Clemen & Reilly, 2001) ofthe manufacturers' or farmers' decisions on food additives affectedby chance nodes and intermediate value nodes. One chance node isthe “Government Inspects& Punishes,” and another chance node is“Potential Sickness,” where customers could get sick onceconsuming the contaminated food. Both chance nodes coulddirectly affect the level of penalty cost to manufacturers andfarmers. The intermediate values (penalty cost, chemical cost, andsales profit) eventually determine the net profit values.

An influence diagram of the government's decision making onthe punishment policy to the farmers or manufacturers is shown inFig. 12. Two chance nodes are “Potential Sickness” and the farmer'sor manufacturer's “Chemical Level,” (amount of chemical additive)both affecting the intermediate values (tax income, penalty income,and health cost) that eventually determine the government's net

Page 12: Modeling a Government-Manufacturer-Farmer game … › ~jzhuang › Papers › SZ_FoodControl_2017.pdfModeling a Government-Manufacturer-Farmer game for food supply chain risk management

C. Song, J. Zhuang / Food Control 78 (2017) 443e455454

payoff.

A.2. Proof of proposition 1

(i) If bF > alq and bþPFq�bFlQ0

2ðbFlq�aÞ 2½x�; xþ�, we get the interior point

xinterior ¼ bþPFq�bFlQ0

2ðbFlq�aÞ by setting vUF ðxÞvx ¼ 0.where

a ¼ q�cpnmnp

� pm

b ¼ �pmQ0 �cpNqnp

þ cpnmQ0

np

If bþPFq�bFlQ0

2ðbFlq�aÞ < x�, then bx ¼ x�. If bþPFq�bFlQ0

2ðbFlq�aÞ > xþ, then bx ¼ xþ.

(ii) If bF ¼ alq and PFq� bFlQ0 � �b, then UFðbxðPF ; bFÞ; PF ; bF ÞÞ ¼

ðbþ PFq � bFlQ0Þxþ PFQ0cpNQ0np

is a linear function. Whenbþ PFq� bFlQ0 � 0, the optimal x would be at the lowerbound x�, otherwise it would be at the upper bound xþ.

(iii) If bF < alq, the optimal chemical level would be at the bound

that has the highest utility UF .

A.3. Proof of proposition 2

The manufacturer's utility function is rewritten below:

maxPF�0

UMðbxðPF ; bFÞ; PF ;bMÞ ¼ a0P2F þ b0PF þ c0

where t ¼ 2ðbFlq� aÞ>0, a0≡� q2ðtþbMlqÞt2 � 0,

b0≡tq2ð1�gÞP�Q0ðtþbMlqÞt�2q2bMlðb�bFlQ0Þt2 � cmq2

t , and c0≡��

Q0þ

qðb�bFlQ0Þt

���1� gÞP � bMlðb�bFlQ0Þ

t

��� cmQ0 �cmqðb�bFlQ0Þ

t .

(i) When t >0; b0�2a02

"tx��bþbFlQ0

q ; txþ�bþbFlQ0

q

#, then

bx ¼ bþPFq�bFlQ0

2ðbFlq�aÞ . With vUMðxÞvPF

¼ 2a0PF þ b0, we can get the

interior solution cPF ðbÞ ¼ b0�2a0 by setting vUMðxÞ

vPF¼ 0. The

optimal chemical level bx could also be at a lower bound x� orat an upper bound xþ.

(ii) When bx ¼ x�, UMðPFÞ ¼ ðP � PFÞQðxÞ �bMQðxÞHðxÞ � gPQðxÞ�cmQðxÞ ¼ �PFðQ0 þ qx�Þ þ ðP � gP � cmÞðQ0 þ qx�Þ�bMðQ0 þ qx�Þlx�. Since UM decreases in PF , we havecPF ðbMÞ ¼ 0.

(iii) When bx ¼ xþ, UMðPFÞ ¼ ðP � PFÞQðxÞ �bMQðxÞHðxÞ � gPQðxÞ�cmQðxÞ ¼ �PFðQ0 þ qxþÞ þ ðP � gP � cmÞðQ0 þ qxþÞ�bMðQ0 þ qxþÞlxþ. Since UM decreases in PF , we havecPF ðbMÞ ¼ 0.

References

Associated Press. (2007). 104 deaths reported in pet food recall. http://www.nytimes.com/2007/03/28/science/28brfs-pet.html Accessed in February 2017.

Bloomberg. (2008). China says Sanlu milk likely contaminated by melamine. http://www.bloomberg.com/apps/news?pid¼newsarchive&sid¼at6LcKJB6YA8Accessed in February 2017.

Branigan, T. (2008). Chinese figures show fivefold rise in babies sick from contaminatedmilk. http://archive.today/Dtx5y Accessed in February 2017.

Caswell, J. A. (1998). Valuing the benefits and costs of improved food safety andnutrition. Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics, 42(4),409e424.

CCTV com. (2009). AQSIQ announced the detection of melamine in infant formula milkpowder enterprises list. http://news.cctv.com/china/20080916/107375.shtmlAccessed in February 2017.

Chen, S. (2009). Sham or Shame: Rethinking the China's milk powder scandal froma legal perspective. Journal of Risk Research, 12(6), 725e747.

Cheung, M., & Zhuang, J. (2012). Regulation games between government andcompeting Companies: Oil spills and other disasters. Decision Analysis, 9(2),156e164.

Clemen, R. T., & Reilly, R. (2001). Making hard decisions with decision tools. PacificGrove, California: Duxbury/Thomson Learning.

Cohen, J. B. (1910). Practical organic chemistry. https://archive.org/details/PracticalOrganicChemistry Accessed in February 2017.

CSR C. (2006). Mandarin fish found to contain malachite green dye in Hong Kong.http://www.chinacsr.com/en/2006/11/28/882-mandarin-fish-found-to-contain-malachite-green-dye-in-hong-kong/ Accessed in February 2017.

DeLaurentis, T. (2009). Ethical supply chain management. http://www.chinabusinessreview.com/ethical-supply-chain-management/ Accessed inFebruary 2017.

Ellis, L., & Turner, J. (2010). Sowing the Seeds: Opportunities for US-China cooperationon food safety. Woodrow Wilson International Center for Scholars. http://www.wilsoncenter.org/sites/default/files/CEF_food_safety_text.pdf Accessed inFebruary 2017.

Fares, M., & Rouviere, E. (2010). The implementation mechanisms of voluntary foodsafety systems. Food Policy, 35(5), 412e418.

Food Safety Rapid Detection of Network. (2011). Melamine fake protein principle.http://www.china12315.com.cn/html/zt/2011/0412/n_20110412758287.shtmlAccessed in February 2017.

Galarpe, K. (2011). Taiwanese products with DEHP named. May 31st, 2011 http://www.abs-cbnnews.com/lifestyle/05/31/11/taiwanese-products-dehp-namedAccessed in February 2017.

Gale, F., & Hu, D. (2009). Supply chain issues in Chinas milk adulteration incident. InThe international association of agricultural economists 2009 conference in Beijing,China, august (pp. 16e22).

Harrington, R. (2011). China launches yet another food safety crack down. December26th, 2011 http://www.foodproductiondaily.com/Quality-Safety/China-launches-yet-another-food-safety-crack-down Accessed in February 2017.

Hau, A. K., Kwan, T. H., & Li, P. K. (2009). Melamine toxicity and the kidney. Journal ofthe American Society of Nephrology, 20(2), 245e250.

Henson, S., & Caswell, J. (1999). Food safety regulation: An overview of contem-porary issues. Food Policy, 24(6), 589e603.

Hobbs, J. E., & Kerr, W. A. (1999). Cost/benefits of microbial origin (pp. 480e486).Encyclopedia of Food Microbiology in Robinson.

Kambhu, J. (1990). Direct controls and incentives systems of regulation. Journal ofEnvironmental Economics and Management, 18(2), 72e85.

Liu, R., Pieniak, Z., & Verbeke, W. (2013). Consumers' attitude and behavior towardssafe food in China: a review. Food Control, 33(1), 93e104.

Liu, R., Pieniak, Z., & Verbeke, W. (2014). Food-related hazards in China: Consumers’perceptions of risk and trust in information sources. Food Control, 46, 291e298.

Mail, C. D. (2012). Toxic pesticides used to keep ginger fresh in China. https://chinadailymail.com/2012/05/18/toxic-pesticides-used-to-keep-ginger-fresh/Accessed in February 2017.

Ming, L. (2006). Study on establishing a perfect food safety system in China.Management, 11(1), 111e119.

Moore, J. C., Spink, C., & Lipp, M. (2012). Development and application of a databaseof food Ingredient fraud and economically motivated adulteration from 1980 to2010. Journal of Food science, 77(4), 118126.

Oh, Y. (1995). Surveillance or punishment? A second-best theory of pollutionregulation. International Economic Journal, 9(3), 89e101.

Post, T. C. (2011). Clenbuterol-tainted pork latest China food scandal. http://www.chinapost.com.tw/china/national-news/2011/03/18/295146/Clenbuterol-tainted-pork.htm Accessed in February 2017.

Pouliot, S., & Sumner, D. (2008). Traceability, liability, and incentives for food safetyand quality. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 90(1), 15e27.

Rose-Ackerman, S. (1991). Regulation and the law of torts. The American EconomicReview, 81(2), 54e58.

Segerson, K. (1999). Mandatory versus voluntary approaches to food safety. Agri-business, 15(1), 53e70.

Shavell, S. (1984). A model of optimal use liability and safety regulation. RandJournal of Economics, 15(2), 271e280.

Song, C., & Zhuang, J. (2017). Regulating food risk managementa governmentma-nufacturer game facing endogenous consumer demand. International Trans-actions in Operational Research. Forthcoming.

Southern Metropolis. (2008). Sanlu recalled 700 tons of tainted milk. http://www.360doc.com/content/08/0912/12/142_1634909.shtml Accessed in February2017.

Sparks, P., & Shepherd, R. (1994). Public perceptions of the potential hazardsassociated with food production and food consumption: An empirical study.Risk analysis, 14(5), 799e806.

Spiegel Online. (2011). Report claims German company knew of dioxin for weeks.January 7th, 2011 http://www.spiegel.de/international/germany/0,1518,738337,00.html Accessed in February 2017.

State Administration of Taxation. (2011). Announcement on the part of the liquid milk

Page 13: Modeling a Government-Manufacturer-Farmer game … › ~jzhuang › Papers › SZ_FoodControl_2017.pdfModeling a Government-Manufacturer-Farmer game for food supply chain risk management

C. Song, J. Zhuang / Food Control 78 (2017) 443e455 455

VAT applicable tax rate. http://www.chinatax.gov.cn/n8136506/n8136593/n8137537/n8138502/11597032.html Accessed in February 2017.

Tompkin, R. B. (2001). Interactions between government and industry food safetyactivities. Food Control, 12(4), 203207.

U S Food and Drug Administration, & U S Department of Health & Human Service.(2008). Melamine contaminated pet foods - 2007 recall list. June 25, 2008 http://www.accessdata.fda.gov/scripts/petfoodrecall/#Dog Accessed in February 2017.

Wong, S. (2008). Greed, mad science and melamine. http://www.atimes.com/atimes/China/JK14Ad01.html Accessed in February 2017.

Xinhua. (2009). Court declares bankruptcy of Sanlu group. http://www.chinadaily.com.cn/bizchina/2009-02/12/content_7470003.htm Accessed in February2017.

Xinhuanet. (2009). Sanlu group criminal cases reached verdict. http://news.xinhuanet.com/legal/2009-01/23/content_10705325.htm Accessed in February2017.

Zacha, L., Doyleb, M. E., Bierc, V., & Czuprynskib, C. (2012). Systems and governancein food import safety: A U.S. Perspective. Food Control, 27(1), 153162.