Mexican Enclaves and the Price of Culture

19
Ž . JOURNAL OF URBAN ECONOMICS 43, 273]291 1998 ARTICLE NO. UE972049 Mexican Enclaves and the Price of Culture Arturo Gonzalez 1 Mexican American Studies and Research Center, Uni ¤ ersity of Arizona, Tuscon, AZ 84721 Received August 13, 1996; revised March 13, 1997 Studies of Mexican immigrant earnings consistently find a negative relationship w between concentration of Mexicans and earnings. Smith and Newman Economic Ž .x w Inquiry, 15, 51]66 1977 and Yuengert Journal of Human Resources, 30, 194]204 Ž .x 1995 , among others, attribute this enclave effect as the compensating differential for culture. However, the existence of a land market suggests that the ‘‘price’’ of culture may also depend on culture’s effect on the price of land. Adopting a model w Ž .x developed by Roback Economic Inquiry, 26, 23]41 1988 , I first show that the price of Mexican culture is a function of culture’s effect on both earnings and rents. Second, using data for California and Texas from the 1990 Census, I estimate the price for Mexican culture. Consistent with the model, culture lowers earnings and increases rents in enclaves with larger concentration of Mexicans. In fact, land’s share of the price of culture is as much as 42%. Therefore, studies that attribute the lower earnings in enclaves as the compensating differential for enclave externalities underestimate the value of culture. This paper also tests several predictions implied by the theoretical model. Satisfying the general equilib- rium conditions, the earnings of other workers are higher in enclaves. Further- more, except for Mexican-Americans, the assumption that culture is not an amenity to other workers is supported by the data. Q 1998 Academic Press I. INTRODUCTION Approximately 75% of all Mexican immigrants in the United States live in Texas and California. But within these states, Mexican immigrants are concentrated in the enclaves established by previous immigrants. Studies of immigrant earnings that incorporate this ethnic concentration in their analysis consistently find a negative relationship between Mexican enclaves and Mexican earnings. A common explanation for this finding is that Mexican enclaves offer cultural amenities which attract Mexican im- 1 This is a revised version of a paper presented at the WEA International Conference, June 29, 1996. I especially thank Ed Funkhouser, Jon Sonstelie, and Steve Trejo, as well as Eric Brunner, Ken Ardon, Mike Hilmer, Christine Meyer, and seminar participants at the University of Massachusetts ]Amherst and San Diego State University for many helpful comments. Two anonymous referees provided excellent suggestions. 273 0094-1190r98 $25.00 Copyright Q 1998 by Academic Press All rights of reproduction in any form reserved.

Transcript of Mexican Enclaves and the Price of Culture

Page 1: Mexican Enclaves and the Price of Culture

Ž .JOURNAL OF URBAN ECONOMICS 43, 273]291 1998ARTICLE NO. UE972049

Mexican Enclaves and the Price of Culture

Arturo Gonzalez1

Mexican American Studies and Research Center, Uni ersity of Arizona,Tuscon, AZ 84721

Received August 13, 1996; revised March 13, 1997

Studies of Mexican immigrant earnings consistently find a negative relationshipwbetween concentration of Mexicans and earnings. Smith and Newman Economic

Ž .x wInquiry, 15, 51]66 1977 and Yuengert Journal of Human Resources, 30, 194]204Ž .x1995 , among others, attribute this enclave effect as the compensating differentialfor culture. However, the existence of a land market suggests that the ‘‘price’’ ofculture may also depend on culture’s effect on the price of land. Adopting a model

w Ž .xdeveloped by Roback Economic Inquiry, 26, 23]41 1988 , I first show that theprice of Mexican culture is a function of culture’s effect on both earnings andrents. Second, using data for California and Texas from the 1990 Census, Iestimate the price for Mexican culture. Consistent with the model, culture lowersearnings and increases rents in enclaves with larger concentration of Mexicans. Infact, land’s share of the price of culture is as much as 42%. Therefore, studies thatattribute the lower earnings in enclaves as the compensating differential forenclave externalities underestimate the value of culture. This paper also testsseveral predictions implied by the theoretical model. Satisfying the general equilib-rium conditions, the earnings of other workers are higher in enclaves. Further-more, except for Mexican-Americans, the assumption that culture is not anamenity to other workers is supported by the data. Q 1998 Academic Press

I. INTRODUCTION

Approximately 75% of all Mexican immigrants in the United States livein Texas and California. But within these states, Mexican immigrants areconcentrated in the enclaves established by previous immigrants. Studiesof immigrant earnings that incorporate this ethnic concentration in theiranalysis consistently find a negative relationship between Mexican enclavesand Mexican earnings. A common explanation for this finding is thatMexican enclaves offer cultural amenities which attract Mexican im-

1This is a revised version of a paper presented at the WEA International Conference, June29, 1996. I especially thank Ed Funkhouser, Jon Sonstelie, and Steve Trejo, as well as EricBrunner, Ken Ardon, Mike Hilmer, Christine Meyer, and seminar participants at theUniversity of Massachusetts]Amherst and San Diego State University for many helpfulcomments. Two anonymous referees provided excellent suggestions.

273

0094-1190r98 $25.00Copyright Q 1998 by Academic Press

All rights of reproduction in any form reserved.

Page 2: Mexican Enclaves and the Price of Culture

ARTURO GONZALEZ274

migrants and Mexican immigrants are willing to pay a compensating dif-ferential for these benefits. Several studies conclude that the negativerelationship between Hispanic concentration and immigrant earnings is

w xthe price of enclave culture 2, 9, 20, 21, 23 .Previous calculations of the price of culture implicity assume that

culture does not affect land rents in the enclave. In this paper, I add tow xthese studies by applying a model developed by Roback 19 to demon-

strate how the migration decisions of workers and firms are constrained byalso including the price of land in their optimization problem. Formulatingthe migration decision in this manner yields a ‘‘price’’ for Mexican culturethat is a function of culture’s impact on both earnings and land rents.Since workers and firms must make land payments to live and produce inthe enclave, the compensating differential for culture may also includehigher rents. This possibility is theoretically attractive because it explainswhy firms in enclaves do not earn positive profits.

Under plausible assumptions, the Roback model predicts that enclaveswith higher cultural amenities have both lower earnings and higher rents.Using data for California and Texas from the 1990 Census, I demonstratethat not only are rents higher and earnings lower in enclaves, but the shareof the price of culture attributable to rents is as much as 42%. Therefore,studies that calculate the compensating differential for culture from onlyearnings regressions underestimate the value of culture.

This paper also test several predictions made by the model regarding theeffect of Mexican culture on the earnings and preferences of otherworkers. First, the general equilibrium framework of the model predictsthat if enclave land rents are higher, then workers without preference forenclave culture must be compensated with higher earnings in order tokeep them from moving. This is found to hold for Asians, Blacks, andWhites, but not for Mexican-Americans. Second, I also test the assumptionthat Mexican culture does not add to the utility of other ethnic groups.The hypothesis that the price of Mexican culture equals zero is notrejected for Asians, Whites, and Blacks, but for Mexican-Americans the

Žprice of culture is statistically significant yet still lower in magnitude than.for Mexican immigrants . While many studies apply the Roback model to

empirical studies of local amenities,2 this is the first to test the generalequilibrium implications and the assumptions often made to derive predic-tions from the model.

2 w x w xStudies that have used this model to calculate prices for local amenities include 19 , 8 ,w x w x22 , and 17 .

Page 3: Mexican Enclaves and the Price of Culture

MEXICAN ENCLAVES AND THE PRICE OF CULTURE 275

II. IMMIGRANTS LIVE IN ENCLAVES

Using data from the 1980s, several analyses of the settlement patterns ofw ximmigrants 1, 2, 10, 16 find that Mexican immigrants choose to live in

areas with large numbers of Mexicans.3 Data from the 1990 5% Public UseŽ .Microdata Sample PUMS files reveal that same pattern of geographic

concentration among Mexican immigrants in Texas and California.4

Recognizing the extent of Hispanic concentration in certain labor mar-kets, many previous studies include variables of concentration in log wageregressions. Table 1 presents a list of studies finding a negative relation-ship between ethnic concentration and Mexican immigrant wages. Thetable groups these studies by the relative impact of ethnic concentrationon wages, ranging from small, to medium, to large. A subset of these

w x w xstudies 2, 9, 20, 21, 23 along with Funkhouser and Ramos 7 argue thatthe lower earnings in enclaves is directly attributable to culture. Ingeneral, such studies can be broken down into two types.

The first type are comparative analyses of the earnings of immigrantsliving in different areas. Examples of this type of studies are Smith and

w x w xNewman 20 and Funkhouser and Ramos 7 . Smith and Newman com-pare the wages of workers in Houston to those working along theTexas]Mexico border where the number of Mexican immigrants is greater.After controlling for cost-of-living differences, Smith and Newman findthat wages along the border are 8]10% lower. They attribute this result tothe amount Mexican-Americans give up to live with others of the sameculture. Funkhouser and Ramos compare the earnings of Cubans andDominicans living in enclaves in Puerto Rico, in New York or Miami, andin areas outside of the enclaves. In most instances mean earnings outsidethe enclave are higher than inside the enclave, and this is attributed to atrade-off between culture and work income.

The most common type of study found in the literature, however,controls for differences in enclave population in regressions of individualearnings. Usually relying on individual data from the Census, these regres-

5 wsions generally yield a statistically negative enclave coefficient. Some 2, 3,x21 include dummy variables for various levels of Hispanic concentration in

wSMSAs to measure enclave effects. An approach used by others 5, 9, 18,x23 uses percent Hispanic or Mexican in an SMSA as the enclave variable.

3 w xFunkhouser 6 investigates the geographic concentration of all immigrant groups usingthe 5% sample of the 1980 Census and 1990 Census.

4 For example, 47% of Mexican immigrants live in enclaves with more than 20,000 Mexicanimmigrants. In contrast, only 14% of other ethnic groups live in such areas. See Section IVfor description of the data and sample.

5 w xBartel and Koch 2 find no change in the wages of immigrants that move to SMSAs withhigher percentages of fellow countrymen.

Page 4: Mexican Enclaves and the Price of Culture

ARTURO GONZALEZ276T

AB

LE

1St

udie

sof

the

Eff

ect

ofE

thni

cC

once

ntra

tion

onM

exic

anW

ork

Inco

me

Aut

hor

Mag

nitu

deD

ata

Em

piri

calf

ram

ewor

kR

esul

t

Bar

tela

ndSm

all

1980

Cen

sus

Log

wag

ere

gres

sion

with

dum

my

Imm

igra

nts

mov

ing

toSM

SAs

who

sew

xK

och

2da

tava

riab

les

for

indi

vidu

als

that

chan

ged

perc

ent

fore

ign

popu

latio

nw

assm

alle

rSM

SAs

incr

ease

dth

eir

wag

esw

xK

och

9Sm

all

1980

Cen

sus

Reg

ress

ion

oflo

gm

edia

nfa

mily

inco

me

1%in

crea

sein

the

num

ber

ofim

mig

rant

sin

data

incl

udes

the

log

ofpe

rcen

tof

ethn

icgr

oup

SMSA

lead

sto

a2.

3%de

crea

sein

med

ian

loca

ted

inSM

SAan

nual

inco

me

ofM

exic

anfa

mili

esB

ean

and

Med

ium

1980

Cen

sus

Log

earn

ings

regr

essi

onw

ithca

tego

ries

Mex

ican

sliv

ing

inar

eas

with

10%

orm

ore

wx

Tie

nda

3da

tafo

rva

riou

sle

vels

ofH

ispa

nic

His

pani

csin

labo

rm

arke

tear

n7%

less

conc

entr

atio

nin

SMSA

labo

rm

arke

tsot

her

Mex

ican

sw

xR

eim

ers

18M

ediu

m19

76Su

rvey

ofL

ogw

age

regr

essi

onw

ithst

ate’

spe

rcen

tM

exic

an-A

mer

ican

ssa

crifi

ce5.

8%in

wag

esIn

com

ean

dH

ispa

nic

popu

latio

nfo

r1

1%in

crea

sein

ast

ate’

sH

ispa

nic

Edu

catio

npo

pula

tion

Smith

and

Med

ium

1970

Cen

sus

The

real

earn

ings

ofw

orke

rsin

Hou

ston

Mex

ican

-Am

eric

ans

livin

gal

ong

the

bord

erw

xN

ewm

an20

data

are

com

pare

dto

wor

kers

inth

ree

bord

ersa

crifi

ce8

to10

%of

real

inco

me

citie

s,co

ntro

lling

for

wor

ker

and

area

rela

tive

toth

ose

inH

oust

onch

arac

teri

stic

sT

iend

aan

dL

arge

1980

Cen

sus

Log

annu

alea

rnin

gsre

gres

sion

with

Mex

ican

men

earn

10%

less

ifth

eyw

ork

inw

xW

ilson

21da

tadu

mm

yva

riab

lefo

rSM

SAs

who

had

SMSA

with

high

conc

entr

atio

nsof

fello

wgr

eate

rth

anav

erag

epe

rcen

tM

exic

anM

exic

anw

orke

rsw

orke

rsin

the

labo

rfo

rce

wx

Bor

jas

5L

arge

1980

Cen

sus

Log

annu

alea

rnin

gsre

gres

sed

onth

eA

10%

incr

ease

inth

esu

pply

ofM

exic

anda

tasu

pply

ofva

riou

sla

bor

forc

egr

oups

imm

igra

nts

redu

ces

own

wag

esby

13%

Yue

nger

tL

arge

1980

Cen

sus

Log

earn

ing

regr

essi

onof

Mex

ican

1%in

crea

sein

perc

ent

Mex

ican

imm

igra

ntw

x23

data

for

150

imm

igra

nts

with

perc

ent

Mex

ican

lead

sto

a11

%re

duct

ion

inth

eea

rnin

gsof

larg

est

SMSA

sim

mig

rant

sin

SMSA

incl

uded

inM

exic

anim

mig

rant

ssp

ecifi

catio

n

Page 5: Mexican Enclaves and the Price of Culture

MEXICAN ENCLAVES AND THE PRICE OF CULTURE 277

The empirical framework of this paper follows the second set of studiesby controlling for the Mexican population in the regressions below. How-ever, rather than limiting the analysis to culture’s effect on earnings, thisstudy adds to the existing literature by analyzing culture’s effect on rents.The empirical justification for analyzing both earnings and land rents

w xcomes from the model developed by Roback 19 .

III. THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK

One explanation for the geographic concentration of Mexican immi-grants argues that enclaves provide benefits valued by immigrants. Pecu-

w xniary benefits include self-employment opportunities 23 and increasedopportunity for occupational achievement. Non-pecuniary neighborhoodamenities found inside enclaves include information networks, social net-

w x w xworks 16 , and the ability to speak Spanish with others 7, 13 . Usingw xRoback’s 19 model, I incorporate such non-pecuniary cultural amenities

into an individual’s utility maximization problem.ŽRoback’s model balances the trade-off between the cost of housing land

.rents , earnings, and non-pecuniary benefits}enclave culture in this case.Although the quality of culture is not rooted to a specific geographic areaby nature, the quality nonetheless results from the persistence of enclavesover time in a geographic area.6

Each location contains an amount c of cultural quality which enters theŽ . Ž .utility function of workers, immigrants I and natives N . For any given

location, immigrants and natives provide one unit of work and spend theirwork income W to consume an amount z of the numeraire commodity Zand R units of housing at price r per unit. Workers choose to reside in thelocation that maximizes utility UU. The indirect utility in equilibrium is

V j W j, r ; c s UU j ZU j, RU j ; c s ¨ j 1Ž . Ž . Ž .

� 4 jfor each type of workers j s I, N , where ¨ is the maximum utility ofeach type of worker. In the case of immigrants, culture increases utility,and therefore V I ) 0.c

The conditions that describe firms in equilibrium are derived fromprofit-maximizing behavior. At any given location, firms use immigrants,

Ž .natives, and land B in a constant-returns-to-scale production function toproduce the numeraire good.7 Letting W I and W N be the price for the

6 w xAs LaLonde and Topel 11 point out, the geographic distribution of immigrants replicatesitself over time, and thus the locational decisions of immigrants is exogeneous.

7Since the average Mexican workers has English skills and education levels much lowerthan the average native of any ethnic group, it is not unreasonable to assume that immigrantsand natives are imperfect substitutes in production.

Page 6: Mexican Enclaves and the Price of Culture

ARTURO GONZALEZ278

labor inputs, the firm’s unit cost function C must equal the price of theoutput

C W I , W N , r ; c s 1. 2Ž . Ž .

In equilibriums firms}just like workers}have no incentives to move.The trade-off between earnings, rents, and culture is found by totally

differentiating the indirect utility function and the cost function andsolving for dW Irdc and drrdc. Under the working assumptions thatculture is a neutral good for natives and firms,8

V N s 0 and C s 0, 3Ž .c c

the reduced-form effects of culture on area rents and immigrant earningsare

I I Idr V dW Vc c NI Ns a C ) 0 and s a y C q C R - 0,Ž .W r WI Idc dcV VW W

4Ž .

Ž I I N N .y1 j j jwhere a s R C q R C q C ) 0, R s yV rV is the amountW W r r Wof residential land consumed by each type of worker, and C is theXmarginal increase in unit costs of hiring an additional unit of input X.Finally, the reduced-form effect of culture on the earnings of nativeworkers is

N IdW VcNIs a R C ) 0. 5Ž .WIdc VW

Ž .Thus, the two equations in 4 demonstrate the earnings of immigrantsfall in enclaves with greater levels of culture. Furthermore, the value of theenclave culture for immigrants can be derived from these results. Theimplicit price of culture for immigrants is

V I R Ir d log r W 1 d log W IcIp s s y . 6Ž .c I c d log c c d log cVW

The important result from the Roback model is that the price of any localamenity must include the amount that is capitalized into rents.

8 It is possible that large enclaves improve the information about the local labor market andthus improve the employer]employee match. This makes the firm more productive. However,since no general statement of the effect of culture on the firm’s productivity can be made, the

Ž .working assumption with qualifications is that culture is a neutral good.

Page 7: Mexican Enclaves and the Price of Culture

MEXICAN ENCLAVES AND THE PRICE OF CULTURE 279

It should be noted that this model does not attempt to explain how orwhere enclaves are formed. Nor does it guarantee the existence of en-claves. Gi en the existence of encla¨e, however, the model describes theequilibrium conditions. Since this paper is interested only in the compara-tive statistics, and not the dynamics, of enclave culture, the price of culture

Ž .in 6 is well suited for this purpose.

IV. EMPIRICAL FRAMEWORK AND DATA

A. Empirical Model

Allowing for individual characteristics, the empirical specification im-plied by the reduced-form results is

log Income s X b q A g q l log c q P M q « ,i k i W k W W k k ik

log Rent s Y b q A g q l log c q P R q n , 7Ž .hk h R k R R k k hk

where X is a set of human capital variables for immigrant i, Y consists ofhousing quality for household h, and A is a set of amenity variablescommon to all households and workers of area k; log Income is the log ofannual immigrant work income and log Rent is the log of monthly housingcosts for Mexican householders in town k. Lastly, log c is a measure ofenclave size, defined as the log of the number of Mexicans immigrants.b , b , g , g , l , and l are variables to be estimated. « and n areW R R W R Windividual-specific errors, and P M and P R are unobservable area charac-k k

Ž 2 . 9teristics, each distributed normally, P ; N 0, s . The random-effectsk Pprocedure captures individual town heterogeneity that affects rents andearnings.

The coefficients of log c from the log rents and from the log earningsŽ .regressions are substituted into 6 to calculate the price of culture. Under

the assumptions made in Section II, the sign of the culture coefficient inthe earnings regression is theorized to be negative, and positive in therents regression. Two further tests are implied by the Roback model. First,because other workers must be used in production, it is possible to test ifthese workers receive higher earnings in Mexican enclaves. Second, the

Ž N .assumption that other workers derive no utility V s 0 implies that thecŽ .price of culture calculated from Eq. 6 is zero for other workers.

9 w xMoulton 14 demonstrates that estimating the earnings and rent equations by OLS resultsin biased standard errors due to intra-enclave error correlation. A random errors model is

2 Ž .applied by including the location-specific error term, P . If s s 0, then 7 reduces to ank POLS specification. This model reduces the danger of spurious regression and also improvesthe precision of the estimated coefficients.

Page 8: Mexican Enclaves and the Price of Culture

ARTURO GONZALEZ280

B. The Data

Because approximately 75% of Mexican immigrants live in Californiaand Texas, I use the 1990 5% Public Use Microdata Sample files forCalifornia and Texas to derive individual and household data. The depen-dent variable in the log earnings regression is the log of 1989 self-reportedwork income. The independent variables for this regression are a constant,age, age-squared, dummy variables for education level, English abilitydummies, marital status, rural, citizenship status, and years in the UnitedStates dummy variables.

Years in the United States is included to control for the fact thatinformation about U.S. labor markets increases with time in the UnitedStates, and for other aspects of the immigrant’s life-cycle correlated withearnings. Since migrant networks steer immigrants to certain enclaves, it isunlikely the first job of immigrants will pay the wage appropriate for theirskills. Over time, however, information about the labor market will in-crease opportunities and, therefore, reliance on these migration networkswill decrease. Furthermore, increased levels of U.S.-specific skills, such asEnglish, improve the labor market opportunities. As a consequence,

w xFunkhouser 6 finds that after 15 to 20 years in the United States,immigrants move to less ethnically concentrated areas. Hence, more timein the United States reduces any compensating differential that newarrivals are willing to pay for information about labor markets in theUnited States.

To provide the purest test of the effect of culture on earnings, Iconcentrate on male Mexican immigrants between the ages of 18 and 64meeting the following criteria. Mexican immigrants are those non-citizenmales that state their Hispanic origin as Mexican and were born inMexico. Furthermore, to minimize self-selection issues, self-employed per-sons and those in school are dropped from the sample. To estimate theeffect of Mexican culture on other ethnic groups, similar sample selectioncriteria are applied separately to Mexican-Americans, non-Hispanic Asians

Ž .and Whites natives and immigrants , and native-born Blacks.The dependent variable of the rents regression is the capitalized value of

Žowner-occupied homes, or the reported gross rent depending on renter. 10status of Mexican immigrant householders. To control for housing

quality, the regression includes a constant, year-built dummy variables,number of bedrooms dummies, whether there are more than two units in

10 w xLinneman and Voith 12 find that the mean annual capitalization rate of owner-oc-Ž .cupied homes is approximately 10%. The monthly amount 0.0083 is applied to the owner-re-

ported house value. Since house values are reported in brackets, the midpoint of each bracketis used as the value of the house.

Page 9: Mexican Enclaves and the Price of Culture

MEXICAN ENCLAVES AND THE PRICE OF CULTURE 281

the structure, condominium status, rural dummy variable, and renterstatus.

I define an enclave based on the geographic structure of the Census,which assigns each person in the PUMS file to a Public Use Microdata

Ž . 11Area PUMA . This census-defined area is a county-based region ofapproximately 200,000 persons. The measure of enclave size used in theregressions below is the log of the number of Mexican immigrants in the

Ž .PUMA log MI .In addition to the immigrant and household-specific variables, several

community variables that serve as controls for area amenities are includedin each specification. The first two are calculated from the 5% PUMS file:the log of the area’s population minus Mexican immigrants, and thepercent of persons 25 years and older with a high school diploma. Theremaining amenity variables are taken from the 1994 edition of the County

Ž . Žand City Data Book C & C . They are climate variables mean January. Žtemperature and mean inches of rain , health measures infant mortality

.per 1000 live births and the number of hospital beds per 100,000 , andŽsocio-economic status variables serious crimes per 100,000, persons 16]19

.years old not in school, and population density .Location-specific variables from C & C are included in the specification

to capture characteristics that affect rents and wages as suggested by thestudies that use the Roback model. However, one drawback of using thisdata is that information is available only for incorporated cities with 25,000persons or more. Due to this restriction, 283 out of 332 PUMAs are usedin this study. However, the majority of deleted PUMAs are located wherethere are not many pockets of Mexican immigrants. Some large Mexican

Ž .communities, however, such as East Los Angeles unincorporated andŽ . 12Delano total population below 25,000 , were dropped.

C. Summary Statistics

The summary statistics for Mexican immigrants and California house-holds are shown in Table 2. The unstandardized effects of enclave size canbe seen by dividing the same into ‘‘High’’ and ‘‘Low’’ concentrations ofMexicans immigrants, where Low enclave areas are PUMAs with less than15,000 Mexican immigrants and High enclave areas are PUMAs with morethan 15,000 Mexican immigrants. The average work income of immigrants

11 In deriving the enclave measure, it must be pointed out that these enclaves do notnecessarily correspond to any one particular municipality. Because a PUMA corresponds toan area within a county consisting of about 200,000 persons, the same city may be locatedacross different PUMAs, or more than one city may be located within one PUMA. Therefore,

Ž .in order to incorporate the County and City Data Book C & C information into the analysis,all C & C variables are weighted by each city’s population in the PUMA.

12 The results are similar when all PUMAs are included. See footnote 13.

Page 10: Mexican Enclaves and the Price of Culture

ARTURO GONZALEZ282T

AB

LE

2a

Sum

mar

ySt

atis

tics

for

Sele

cted

Var

iabl

es:M

exic

anIm

mig

rant

san

dH

ouse

hold

ers

Mex

ican

Imm

igra

nts

Mex

ican

Hou

seho

lder

s

All

Low

Hig

hA

llL

owH

igh

Mea

nM

ean

Mea

nM

ean

Mea

nM

ean

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

Var

iabl

est

d.de

v.st

d.de

v.st

d.de

v.V

aria

ble

std.

dev.

std.

dev.

std.

dev.

Log

rent

9.28

99.

327

9.26

5L

ogre

nt6.

245

6.26

26.

235

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

0.83

90.

844

0.83

50.

761

0.78

90.

744

Inco

me

14,3

1514

,998

13,8

75R

ent

675

705

656

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

11,4

4012

,645

10,5

7053

560

249

1M

exic

anIm

mig

rant

s10

,700

9,87

329

.959

Mex

ican

10,7

009,

873

29,9

59Ž

.12

,678

12,3

2629

,361

Imm

igra

nts

12,6

7812

,326

29,3

61A

ge33

.107

32.6

5033

.401

Ren

ter

0.58

90.

580

0.59

.10

.494

10.2

8810

.614

0.49

20.

494

0.49

1M

arita

l0.

645

0.64

70.

643

Tw

oun

its0.

375

0.38

30.

370

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

0.47

90.

478

0.47

90.

484

0.48

60.

483

Rur

al0.

081

0.08

70.

062

Rur

al0.

081

0.08

70.

062

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

0.27

40.

283

0.24

20.

274

0.28

30.

242

Citi

zen

0.20

00.

219

0.18

80

bedr

oom

s0.

107

0.08

40.

121

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

0.40

00.

414

0.39

10.

310

0.27

70.

327

No

scho

ol0.

125

0.11

30.

133

1be

droo

m0.

296

0.28

60.

302

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

0.33

10.

317

0.33

90.

456

0.45

20.

459

Gra

des

1]4

0.14

10.

137

0.14

32

bedr

oom

s0.

307

0.32

70.

295

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

0.34

80.

344

0.35

00.

461

0.46

90.

456

Gra

des

5]8

0.29

80.

302

0.29

63

bedr

oom

s0.

224

0.23

10.

220

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

0.45

80.

459

0.45

70.

417

0.42

10.

414

Gra

des

9]11

0.22

40.

220

0.22

74

bedr

oom

s0.

056

0.06

10.

053

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

0.41

70.

414

0.41

90.

229

0.23

90.

223

Hig

hsc

hool

grad

uate

0.12

10.

127

0.11

75

bedr

oom

s0.

010

0.01

20.

009

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

0.32

60.

333

0.32

10.

101

0.11

00.

095

Som

eco

llege

0.05

40.

061

0.05

019

89]

900.

023

0.01

70.

026

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

0.22

70.

239

0.21

90.

148

0.12

90.

159

Page 11: Mexican Enclaves and the Price of Culture

MEXICAN ENCLAVES AND THE PRICE OF CULTURE 283C

olle

gede

gree

0.03

60.

040

0.03

419

85]

880.

081

0.07

40.

085

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

0.18

60.

195

0.18

00.

272

0.26

10.

278

Eng

lish

only

0.03

30.

031

0.03

419

80]

840.

096

0.09

70.

096

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

0.17

80.

174

0.18

00.

295

0.29

60.

294

Eng

l.ve

ryw

ell

0.20

40.

227

0.19

019

70]

790.

189

0.20

80.

178

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

0.40

30.

419

0.39

20.

392

0.40

60.

382

Eng

.wel

l0.

238

0.25

30.

228

1960

]69

0.19

40.

203

0.18

.0.

426

0.43

40.

420

0.39

50.

402

0.39

1E

ng.n

otw

ell

0.34

10.

345

0.33

919

50]

590.

195

0.19

70.

193

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

0.47

40.

475

0.47

30.

396

0.39

80.

395

Eng

l.no

tat

all

0.18

40.

145

0.20

919

40]

490.

117

0.11

30.

120

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

0.38

80.

352

0.40

70.

322

0.31

70.

325

Yea

rsin

U.S

.0]

30.

133

0.13

50.

132

Bef

ore

1940

0.10

60.

091

0.11

.0.

340

0.34

20.

338

0.30

80.

287

0.31

9Y

ears

inU

.S.4

]5

0.12

00.

125

0.11

7C

ondo

0.04

10.

042

0.04

.0.

325

0.33

10.

322

0.19

90.

200

0.19

8Y

ears

inU

.S.6

]8

0.10

10.

110

0.09

.0.

302

0.31

30.

294

Yea

rsin

U.S

.9]

100.

121

0.12

60.

117

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

0.32

60.

332

0.32

1Y

ears

inU

.S.1

1]15

0.19

90.

193

0.20

.0.

399

0.39

40.

402

Yea

rsin

U.S

.16]

200.

161

0.14

80.

169

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

0.36

70.

355

0.37

5Y

ears

inU

.S.2

1]25

0.07

40.

071

0.07

.0.

261

0.25

80.

263

Yea

rsin

U.S

.26]

300.

044

0.04

40.

044

Ž.

Ž.

Ž.

0.20

60.

206

0.20

6Y

ears

inU

.S.3

1]40

0.03

70.

039

0.03

.0.

190

0.19

20.

188

Yea

rsin

U.S

.41q

0.01

00.

009

0.01

.0.

099

0.09

50.

101

Sam

ple

size

43,9

4717

,211

26,7

36Sa

mpl

esi

ze47

,079

17,5

2129

,588

Sour

ce:

5%19

90PU

MS

file

ofC

alifo

rnia

and

Tex

as.

aL

owen

clav

esi

zeis

defin

edas

PUM

As

with

few

erth

an15

,000

Mex

ican

imm

igra

nts,

and

high

encl

ave

size

isde

fined

asar

eas

with

mor

eth

an15

,000

Mex

ican

imm

igra

nts.

Page 12: Mexican Enclaves and the Price of Culture

ARTURO GONZALEZ284

is $14,315. However, in low areas the mean income is $14,998 and in Highareas, $13,875. Overall, the plurality of immigrants have only 5]8 years ofeducation. However, 20% of persons in High areas have at least a highschool diploma, compared to 23% in Low areas. Also, about 53% of allimmigrants do not speak English well or at all, but 21% of immigrants inHigh areas do not speak English at all, compared to 15% in Low areas.Lastly, around 48% of current immigrants have 10 years or less U.S.experience.

The mean rent is slightly higher in Low enclave areas and lower in Highenclave areas, but the mean characteristics of housing quality differ acrossenclaves to some extent. Differences in housing quality that are notcaptured in average rents include the fact that homes have more roomsŽ .and thus are larger in Low enclave towns: 18% of homes in Low enclavesareas have four or more bedrooms, compared to 9% in High enclave areas.Similarly, only 12% of High enclave homes have no bedrooms, comparedto 8% in Low enclave areas. Lastly, 9% of the homes in Low areas arerural areas, compared to 6% in High enclaves areas. As shown below, theapparent negative relationship between enclave size and rents is accountedfor by differences in housing quality and other location-specific qualities.

V. RESULTS: THE EFFECT OF CULTURE ON MEXICANEARNINGS AND RENTS

Ž .The results of estimating the equations in 7 are shown in Table 3. Thetwo columns show the coefficients of the PUMA-level variables fromrandom effects regressions log annual earnings and log monthly rents onquality characteristics of individuals and places. Consistent with the theoryand with other studies shown in Table 1, an increase in enclave sizereduces the earnings of Mexican immigrants. Of greater significance,however, is that increases in enclave size increases rents, holding otherfactors constant.

The estimates of the full specification in the first column imply that a10% increase in the Mexican immigrant population of an enclave results ina 0.56% decrease in annual earnings and a 0.73% increase in monthlyrent.13 The price of culture reported at the bottom of Table 3 is the price

Ž . Ž .of culture taken at the mean of enclave size 10,700 , income 14,315 , andŽ . 14rent 675 . The cost of moving from the averaged-sized enclave with an

13 The rent and earnings equations were also estimated using the full PUMA sample. Theseregressions included the two PUMS community variables, plus a dummy variable for 283PUMAs included in the original specification. The coefficient of log Mexican immigrants inthe log earnings is y0.039 and in the log rents regression it is 0.105. Rents and earnings arehigher in the 283 PUMAs of the original sample, but only rents are statistically higher.

14 Ž . Ž . Ž . Ž . Ž .From Eq. 6 , 12) 675r10, 700 ) 0.0725 y 14, 315r10, 700 ) y0.0560 s 0.1298. Thestandard error of this estimate treats enclave size, income, and rent as constants.

Page 13: Mexican Enclaves and the Price of Culture

MEXICAN ENCLAVES AND THE PRICE OF CULTURE 285

TABLE 3aRegression Results: Mexican Immigrants and Households

Log income regression Log rent regression

Estimate EstimateŽ . Ž .Variable std. err. std. err.

Personsrsq. mile 0.1000 0.3750Ž . Ž .0.038 0.049

Crimer100,000 y0.0135 y0.0619Ž . Ž .0.037 0.051

Hospital bedsr100,000 y0.6270 y3.707Ž . Ž .0.547 0.708

Infant mortalityr1000 y0.0127 y0.0158Ž . Ž .0.005 0.006

January mean temperature 0.0014 0.0055Ž . Ž .0.001 0.001

Rainfall, average number of inches 0.0065 0.0091Ž . Ž .0.001 0.002

Log PUMA population excluding y0.0384 y0.2156Ž . Ž .Mexicans immigrants 0.027 0.039

Percent high school graduates 0.0013 2.0013Ž . Ž .0.001 0.154

Log Mexican immigrants y0.0560 0.0725Ž . Ž .0.013 0.016

bPrice of Culture $0.1298Ž . Ž .Std. err. 0.022

a The log income regressions also include a constant, plus the corresponding variablesfrom Table 2. The log rents regressions also include the variables from Table 2, plus aconstant term. The parameter estimates of Crimer100,000, Personsrsquare mile, andHospital bedsr100,000 are multiplied by 10,000.

b The price of culture refers to the increase in rents and decrease in earnings resultingfrom an additional Mexican immigrant, holding other populations constant.

additional 5,000 Mexican immigrants implies a compensating differentialof $649 per year, or about $0.13 per immigrant. Given that most studiesattribute the negative relationship between earnings and ethnic concentra-tion as the compensating differential for enclave culture, it is important tonote that excluding the impact on rents reduces the estimate of thecompensating differential by 42%.15

Ž .However, since Eq. 6 is a function of the number of Mexican immi-grants, I also estimate the price of culture at various enclave sizes. I dividethe enclave population of Mexican immigrants into different sizes and then

15 Using other measures of cultures yields statistically similar results. These alternativemeasures are the log of Spanish-speaking persons of Mexican descent and the log of personsof Mexican descent.

Page 14: Mexican Enclaves and the Price of Culture

ARTURO GONZALEZ286

FIG. 1. Price of culture at various enclave sizes.

use the corresponding means in these areas to derive prices for Mexicanculture. Figure 1 graphs the relationship between the level of culture andthe price of culture at various enclave sizes, with the estimated standarderror around each point. As shown there, the price decreases with higherlevels of culture, from a high of $1 to a low of $0.03.16 That is, immigrantsliving in enclaves with low levels of culture are willing to pay more for a1% increase in culture than immigrants with high levels of culture. Sincethe price of culture is a marginal measure of the value of culture, movingfrom an enclave with 11,384 to one with 13,906 Mexican immigrants,implies a cost of culture of $328; then a move from the enclave with 13,906to 16,085 Mexican immigrants implies a cost of $218. Therefore, a move-ment from the enclave with 11,384 immigrants to the enclave with 16,085

Ž .immigrants or an increase of about 4,700 more immigrants implies a costof culture of $546 per year, for a per-immigrant price of $0.116.

The negative relationship between enclave size and rents described inTable 2 is reversed in the rents regression. The variable causing thisreversal is the area’s high school graduation rate. When the variable‘‘percent high school graduates’’ is dropped from both specifications, theenclave coefficient in the earnings regression is slightly decreased to

16 Specific estimates for all enclave sizes are available upon request.

Page 15: Mexican Enclaves and the Price of Culture

MEXICAN ENCLAVES AND THE PRICE OF CULTURE 287

y0.067, but in the rents regression this coefficient switches sign toy0.087. Since Mexicans, in general, have lower than average educationlevels, their concentration results in a negative relationship between highschool graduation sizes and enclave size. These additional regressionsimply that once differences in high school graduation rates across PUMAsare controlled for, Mexican culture is associated with higher rental prices.Thus, lower rents in the housing market is associated with lower educationachievement, not Mexican culture per se.17

Although the model assumes that each PUMA is an individual labormarket, I investigated the possibility that workers could avoid lowerearnings by working outside the PUMA in which they live. One way ofcontrolling for this possibulity is to examine the effect of culture on theearnings of commuters. Empirically, I re-estimated the log earnings regres-sion using only those with commutes of 30 minutes or less, and then againusing those with commutes of 15 minutes or less. Approximately 81% and40% of all Mexican immigrants have commute times that are less than orequal to 30 and 15 minutes, respectively. The enclave coefficient estimatefor these commute times are y0.0519 and y0.0459, respectively. Thesecoefficients are not statistically different from the original estimate ofy0.056.18

The key point of the paper, however, remains that immigrants choose torent houses in enclaves and, therefore, limit their job opportunities. Sincean unrestricted set of job opportunities is always better than a restrictedset, this implies that immigrants sacrifice earnings for culture by the virtueof living in enclaves. Evidence for this is provided by O’Regan and Quigleyw x15 , who find that employment opportunities decrease with higher levelsof minority concentration. Commuting, however, is one way of increasingjob opportunities. This implies that immigrants in larger enclaves will haveto travel farther than immigrants in smaller enclaves in order to attain thesame set of job opportunities. Because those with long commutes revealthat they are willing to incur large commuting costs, this implies that theadverse employment opportunities in the enclave impacts them the most.19

Therefore, it is not surprising to see a larger negative enclave coefficientamong those with long commute times.20 Conversely, those that do not

17 The positive relationship between land rents and education could arise if the housingmarket places a premium on neighborhoods with educated residents, presumably becauseresidents of this type embody ‘‘desirable’’ elements.

18 Ž .The mean incomes of these immigrants $14,709 and $14,572, respectively imply that theprices of culture are $0.1263 and $0.1182, respectively.

19 Immigrants with lower unobservable characteristics will be less successful than otherimmigrants in the enclave.

20 Ž .The estimated coefficient among those with commute times of 31 16 minutes or more isŽ .y0.705 y0.795 .

Page 16: Mexican Enclaves and the Price of Culture

ARTURO GONZALEZ288

face adverse employment conditions in the enclave do not need to com-mute. Those with shorter commute times should have smaller negativeenclave coefficient. The direction of the coefficients above are consistentwith this hypothesis. At the margin, commuters and non-commuters acceptlower earnings and pay higher rents for the enclave culture.

VI. CONSISTENCY WITH THE ROBACK MODEL

In the previous section, it was assumed that enclave culture is not anamenity for other workers or for producers. Under these assumptions, themodel predicts that the earnings of native workers must be higher inenclaves because enclaves have higher land costs, all else equal. The modelalso predicts that the price of culture is zero for non-Mexican immigrantworkers.21 While these assumptions seem reasonable, it is possible to testfor evidence against them.

The results of the test of the first hypothesis are shown in the firstcolumn of Table 4. The first column of Table 4 shows the coefficient

ˆNŽ .estimate of the enclave variable Log MI l from an earnings regressionWfor Mexican-Americans, non-Hispanic Asians, native Blacks, and Whites,controlling for the same variables as in the earnings regression for Mexi-

TABLE 4aTests of the Roback Model for Asians, Blacks, Mexican-Americans, and Whites

Test 1 Test 2

N N bˆ ˆŽ . Ž .Log MI l Average Average Log MI l Price of cultureW RŽ . Ž . Ž .Ethnicity std. err. income rent std. err. std. err.

U UAsians 0.037 25,616 1364 0.101 $0.066Ž . Ž . Ž .0.016 0.018 0.046

U UBlacks 0.307 18,895 663 0.112 $0.018Ž . Ž . Ž .0.015 0.016 0.029

U UMexican- 0.001 17,654 704 0.097 $0.075Ž . Ž . Ž .Americans 0.013 0.015 0.012

U UWhites 0.045 31,690 1158 0.138 $0.046Ž . Ž . Ž .0.007 0.012 0.026

a Ž .All variables used to estimate Eq. 7 are also included in each of theseregressions. The sample size for the log earnings and log rent regressions are 20,080and 37,335, respectively, for Asians; 20,643 and 53,934 for Blacks; 33,113 and 54,243for Mexican-Americans; and 198,838 and 450,208 for Whites.

b The price of culture refers to the increase in rents and decrease in earningsresulting from an additional Mexican immigrant, estimated at the mean values ofenclave size, income, and rent.

* Significant at the 1% level.

21 Ž .It can be seen from Eq. 6 that since p s V rV , then V s 0 implies that p s 0.c c W c c

Page 17: Mexican Enclaves and the Price of Culture

MEXICAN ENCLAVES AND THE PRICE OF CULTURE 289

ˆNŽ .cans. The coefficient of Log MI l is positive for all four groups and isW

statistically significant at the 1% level for all groups except for Mexican-Americans. Thus, the general equilibrium prediction of the Roback modelcannot be rejected. Since Mexican-Americans share a similar culturalheritage as Mexican immigrants, it is not surprising that they do notrequire compensation for higher rents.

The second hypothesis is that the price of culture for natives is zero. InN N ˆN N ˆN y1 nwŽ . xother words, p s rR l y W l c s 0, where rR is mean an-R W

nual rent and W N is mean annual income of natives. To estimate p N,separate rent regressions for these ethnic groups are carried out using thesame specification as for Mexican immigrants. In the second-to-last col-

ˆNŽ .umn of Table 4, the coefficient estimate of log MI l is shown. And inR

the last column, the price of culture is estimated at the mean values ofenclave size, rents, and incomes for each ethnic group; the standard erroris reported in parantheses.

The t-statistic of they hypothesis that the price of culture is differentfrom zero is 1.43 for Asians, 0.62 for Blacks, and 1.77 for Whites. ForMexican-Americans, however, the t-statistic is 6.25. Since the price ofculture is not significantly different from zero at the 1 or 5% level forall of these ethnic groups save for Mexican-Americans, the hypothesisthat Mexican culture provides no value for these groups cannot be re-jected. Again, since Mexican-American share a similar cultural heritage asMexican immigrants, the results of this test support the notion thatMexican-Americans derive some benefit from the culture in enclaves. It isinteresting to note that the Mexican immigrants value enclave culture byabout 43% more than Mexican-Americans.

VII. CONCLUSION

The empirical results of this paper indicate that studies of the compen-sating differential of enclave culture must include culture’s impact onrents. The share of the compensating differential for enclave attributableto rents is 42%. Studies that examine only the effects of culture on workincome underestimate the full cost of enclave culture.

The model presented here demonstrates how earnings and rents re-spond to non-pecuniary enclave amenities which encourage in-migration.Enclaves consisting of Mexican immigrants provide cultural amenities thatattract immigrants, but the majority of immigrants fails to concentrate in

Ž .only a few enclaves despite economies of scale to enclave culture becauseincreases in land rents and decreases in work income sort immigrantsacross enclaves of various sizes. The price for the cultural quality in theaverage-sized enclave provided by an additional 5000 Mexican immigrants

Page 18: Mexican Enclaves and the Price of Culture

ARTURO GONZALEZ290

is $649. This value represents approximately 4.5% of the average immi-grant’s income.

This paper also presented several ways of testing the assumptionsemployed to yield predictions from the model. The model is complicatedby the presence of the utility of other groups and by the costs of firms, andit is, therefore, often necessary to make simplifying assumptions. Testssupport the assumption that Mexican culture provides no value for Whites,Asians, and native Blacks. Interestingly, however, there is evidence thatMexican-Americans value enclave culture, although not as much as Mexi-can immigrants. Lastly, controlling for the correlation between Mexicanconcentration and low high school graduation rates reveals that Mexicanculture has a positive effect on rents.

REFERENCES

1. A. P. Bartel, Where do the U.S. immigrants live? Journal of Labor Economics, 7, 371]391Ž .1989 .

2. A. P. Bartel and M. J. Koch, Internal migration of U.S. immigrants, in ‘‘Immigration,Ž .Trade, and the Labor Market’’ J. M. Abowd and R. B. Freeman, Eds. , Univ. of

Ž .Chicago Press, Chicago 1991 .3. F. D. Bean and M. Tienda, ‘‘The Hispanic Population in the United States,’’ Sage, New

Ž .York 1987 .4. G. J. Borjas, Ethnicity, neighborhoods, and human-capital externalities, American Eco-

Ž .nomic Re¨iew, 85, 365]390 1995 .5. G. J. Borjas, Immigrants, minorities, and labor market competition, Industrial and Labor

Ž .Relations Re¨iew, 40, 382]392 1987 .6. E. Funkhouser, The geographic concentration of immigrants and assimilation, Univ. of

Ž .California, Santa Barbara October 1995 .7. E. Funkhouser and F. A. Ramos, The choice of migration destination: Dominican and

Cuban Americans to the mainland United States and Puerto Rico, InternationalŽ .Migration Re¨iew, 27, 537]556 1993 .

8. J. P. Hoehn, M. C. Berger, and G. C. Bloomquist, A hedonic model of interregionalŽ .wages, rents and amenity values, Journal of Regional Science, 27, 605]620 1987 .

9. J. V. Koch, The incomes of recent immigrants: A look at ethnic differences, SocialŽ .Science Quarterly, 68, 294]310 1987 .

10. M. M. Kritz and J. M. Nogle, Nativity concentration and internal migration among theŽ .foreign men, Demography, 31, 509]524 1994 .

11. R. J. LaLonde and R. H. Topel, Labor market adjustments to increased immigration, inŽ‘‘Immigration, Trade, and the Labor Market,’’ J. M. Abowd and R. B. Freeman,

. Ž .Eds. , Univ. of Chicago Press, Chicago 1991 .12. P. Linneman and R. Vioth, Housing price functions and ownership capitalization rates,

Ž .Journal of Urban Economics, 30, 100]111 1991 .13. W. S. McManus, Labor market effects of language enclaves, Journal of Human Resources,

Ž .25, 228]252 1990 .14. B. R. Moulton, An illustration of a pitfall in estimating the effects of aggregate variables

Ž .on micro units, Re¨iew of Economics and Statistics, 72, 334]338 1990 .

Page 19: Mexican Enclaves and the Price of Culture

MEXICAN ENCLAVES AND THE PRICE OF CULTURE 291

15. K. M. O’Regan and J. M. Quigley, Teenage employment and the spatial isolation ofŽ .minority and poverty households, Journal of Human Resources, 31, 692]702 1996 .Ž .16. A. Portes and R. L. Bach, ‘‘Latin Journey,’’ Univ. of California Press, Berkeley 1985 .

17. J. E. Rauch, Productivity Gains from geographic concentration of human capital}evi-Ž .dence from the cities, Journal of Urban Economics, 34, 380]400 1993 .

18. C. Reimers, The wage structure of Hispanic men: Implications for policy, Social ScienceŽ .Quarterly, 65, 401]416 1984 .

19. J. Roback, Wages, rents, and amenities: Differences among workers and regions, Eco-Ž .nomic Inquiry, 26, 23]41 1988 .

20. B. Smith and R. Newman, Depressed wages along the U.S.]Mexico border: An empiricalŽ .analysis, Economic Inquiry, 15, 51]66 1977 .

21. M. Tienda and F. D. Wilson, Migration and the earnings of Hispanic men, AmericanŽ .Sociological Re¨iew, 57, 661]678 1992 .

22. R. Voith, Capitalization of local and regional attributes into wages and rents: Differencesacross residential, commercial, and mixed-use communities, Journal of Regional

Ž .Science, 31, 127]148 1991 .23. A. M. Yuengert, Testing hypothesis of immigrant self-employment, Journal of Human

Ž .Resources, 30, 194]204 1995 .