Marcus Stromeyer - Thesis FINAL .pdf

42
Seller Density, Average Price and Price Dispersion Evidence From the General Aviation Fuel Market Marcus Laszlo Stromeyer April 27 th , 2015 IECO 401 – Advisor: Professor Vroman International Economics Senior Thesis Words: 8502 (11.5 TNR) What is the relationship between seller density and price? Furthermore, how does an increase in the number of sellers in a given geographic region affect price dispersion? This empirical study utilizes data from the general aviation fuel market to address these two questions. It finds, with high levels of confidence, that an increase in seller density results in a decrease in average avgas prices. Moreover, the data suggests that increased seller density causes higher price dispersion. By combining both theoretical work and empirical evidence from a yet-unexplored market, this work contributes to a long line of economic work on seller density and prices.

Transcript of Marcus Stromeyer - Thesis FINAL .pdf

  • Seller Density, Average Price and Price Dispersion Evidence From the General Aviation Fuel Market

    Marcus Laszlo Stromeyer April 27th, 2015

    IECO 401 Advisor: Professor Vroman International Economics Senior Thesis

    Words: 8502 (11.5 TNR)

    What is the relationship between seller density and price? Furthermore, how does an increase in the number of sellers in a given geographic region affect price dispersion? This empirical study utilizes data from the general aviation fuel market to address these two questions. It finds, with high levels of confidence, that an increase in seller density results in a decrease in average avgas prices. Moreover, the data suggests that increased seller density causes higher price dispersion. By combining both theoretical work and empirical evidence from a yet-unexplored market, this work contributes to a long line of economic work on seller density and prices.

  • 1

    Acknowledgements

    There are a lot of people who made this work possible. First and foremost, Id like to thank Professor Vroman, Professor Albrecht and Professor Cumby for all their support, mentorship and feedback throughout this process. It was a challenging, thrilling and highly satisfying experience to conduct original research under their guidance. Id also like to recognize the professors in the economics department, such as Professor Schwartz and Professor Evans, who met with me to discuss my research. Id like to thank my brother, Christopher Stromeyer, for always hearing out my ideas and pushing me to continue digging deeper. In addition, this experience was made that much more special by all the countless hours spent in Lauinger library with Lucia Wei, Lexi, Claire and Manu - its been a great ride, team. Finally, Id like to thank my father for introducing me to the joy of aviation and flight.

  • 2

    Table of Contents I. Introduction ................................................................................................................................................... 3 II. Roadmap and Methodology .................................................................................................................... 4 III. Literature Review ........................................................................................................................................ 4 IV. General Aviation Fuel Market and Avgas Sellers ........................................................................ 12 V. Data and Data Concerns ......................................................................................................................... 14 VI. Empirical Strategy .................................................................................................................................... 15 VII. Results: The Impact of Seller Density on Average Price .......................................................... 19 VIII. Results: Seller Density and Price Dispersion ................................................................................ 23 IX. Theory and Empirical Results: Bringing it Together ................................................................ 26 X. Conclusion and Opportunities for Further Research ................................................................ 27 I. Appendix 1: Kernel Density Estimate of Density Calculation .................................................. 29 II. Appendix 2: Histogram of Fuel Prices ............................................................................................... 30 III. Appendix 3: Kernel Density Estimate of Prices ............................................................................. 31 IV. Appendix 4: Map of Airports/Sellers ................................................................................................. 32 V. Appendix 5: Comparison of Airports in my Dataset and All Airports That Sell Fuel ...... 33 I. Table 1: Overview of Variables ............................................................................................................ 35 II. Table 2: Seller Density and Average Price ....................................................................................... 36 III. Table 3: Seller density and Price Dispersion (Without Gini) .................................................... 37 IV. Table 4: Seller density and Price Dispersion (With Gini) ........................................................... 38

  • 3

    I. Introduction These fuel prices are a rip-off. General aviation pilots utter these words of frustration at airports all

    across America. In a market selling an identical good, the variance in aviation gas prices from airport

    to airport is certainly conspicuous1. Therein lies our puzzle. Namely, what are the determinants of

    aviation fuel prices? Or rather, how can we account for price variance when sellers in a given market

    are selling perfect substitutes? Students in their first college economics course will learn that prices

    of such a good should theoretically converge. Why is this not the case for aviation fuel? That is the

    task at hand.

    With this puzzle in mind I bring forth three questions for this study. In doing so, I center my

    analysis around the underlying assumption of this work: that seller density is a key determinant of

    prices. The questions, which will be examined with a theoretical and empirical lens, are as follows:

    Answers to these questions are important, not just because they will bring clarity for an angry mob of

    pilots; instead, the goal of this work is to contribute to the study of economics by furthering work on

    price determination. General aviation fuel prices are simply the case study.

    This study offers two primary findings in response to these questions. First, I find robust

    empirical evidence that an increase in seller density results in a decrease in prices. This finding

    should not come as a surprise. Second, the data suggests that an increase in seller density leads to an

    increase in price dispersion. This result, on the other hand, may seem counter-intuitive at first but can

    nevertheless be theoretically explained. 1 In fact, in my dataset of prices the range of prices is from $3.30 at Umatilla Municipal Airport to $6.74 at Merced County Airport. If one includes large commercial airports, the price ceiling rises to $8.73 at SFO.

    Q1: What is the impact of seller density in a given geographical region on the average price?

    Q2: Moreover, how can seller density help explain price dispersion in a given geographical region?

    Q3: Finally, what characteristics can we infer about the general aviation fuel market from these results?

  • 4

    There exists a plethora of theoretical work on seller density, spatial analysis and prices,

    which by no means presents unanimous conclusions. In addition to the theoretical work, much

    attention has been placed on the retail gasoline market. However, this paper is the first examination

    of general aviation fuel prices. Therefore, as I proceed, there are a variety of interesting questions:

    Which theoretical model will best fit this scenario? Will this study uphold the findings made in the

    retail gasoline market? What can the niche aviation fuel market teach us about market theory?

    II. Roadmap and Methodology This study follows a six-stepped approach. (1) First, I examine the existing literature, both theoretical

    and empirical, to set the stage. This includes an overview of three distinct theories on seller density,

    average price and price dispersion. (2) A brief analysis of the data, and most importantly its

    limitations, is then necessary to set the stage. (3) I then proceed to explain the empirical methodology

    and strategy of this study, much of which is inspired by prior work. (4) I move on to present the

    results of my regressions and analyze their implications, while also remaining mindful of the works

    limitations. (5) In the penultimate section, I bring everything together, linking the theory derived in

    part one with the empirical results of part four. (6) I finish by suggesting opportunities for further

    study and offer some concluding thoughts. The goal of this methodology is clear: I rely both on

    theory and empirical analysis, often intertwining the two, to present my analysis.

    III. Literature Review There is no consensus in the literature on market concentration, average price and price dispersion.

    Much of the disparity is found in the analysis of the latter, price dispersion. For example, Baye et al.

    (2004) examine consumer electronics sold by online retailers and find that an increase in the number

    of sellers decreases price dispersion. In a similar fashion, both Lewis (2008) and Barron et al. (2004)

  • 5

    find this outcome in the retail gasoline market, when controlling for heterogeneous station-level

    characteristics2.

    On the other hand, a portion of the literature presents what one may consider a counter-

    intuitive conclusion. Best known is the work of Joseph Stiglitz (1987), which asks, Are Duopolies

    More Competitive than Atomistic Markets? He grounds his hypothesis on the assumption that an

    increase in the number of firms also increases search costs. A similar argument is also presented by

    Carlson and McAfee (1983), who find that the variance in prices increases with the number of firms.

    Walsh and Whelan (1999) find empirical evidence of such a phenomenon in the Irish grocery market.

    This begs the vital question: how can one account for such different conclusions across the

    literature? The key lies in the different consumer search models applied by the authors.

    Three Models of Seller Density, Average Price and Equilibrium Price Dispersion3

    As I provide an overview of these three models, the reader should keep a close eye on the

    different underlying assumptions of these models. Namely, specific focus must be placed on whether

    products, search costs and seller costs are homogenous or heterogeneous. These key factors help

    differentiate the three models4.

    (1) Monopolistic Model with Heterogeneous Visiting Costs - Barron et al. (2004) note that

    monopolistic competition arises when consumers perceive differentiated products across sellers

    (1044). In addition, such a model assumes that all sellers experience the same marginal costs of

    production and that there is a common distribution of visiting costs for each consumer. This model

    becomes relevant, however, if one pays attention to the work of Perloff and Salop (1985). In

    proposition 2, they hypothesize that the assumptions mentioned above can lead to a single

    2 There is a little bit more nuance to Lewis conclusions, which are examined later on. 3 Note: Barron et al. (2004) do a phenomenal job at taking the reader through these three key models. I therefore derived much of the structure of this section from their work. I also often refer to their conclusions. 4 There is a table summarizing all these models on page 10.

  • 6

    equilibrium price. In other words, the price in such a market is determined by the typical average cost

    limitations. This therefore begs the question: how can this model account for price dispersion?

    The literature suggests a variety of solutions. However, for the sake of this study, I focus on

    heterogeneity in the distribution of visiting costs across sellers (Barron et al. 2004, 1044). The

    model assumes several seller groups that have distinct visiting costs. This is an assumption that

    corresponds nicely with the characteristics of general aviation. In other words, it is safe to assume

    that some airports are easier or less costly for pilots to reach than others. Most important to derive

    from this is that differences in visiting costs result in different price elasticities of demand for sellers,

    if one holds prices constant for each seller (Barron et al. 2004, 1044). Consequently, differences in

    price elasticity across sellers means that identical prices for all sellers will not satisfy the standard

    profit-maximizing conditions (Barron et al. 2004, 1045).

    Let us examine the profit maximizing price function:

    pi =mii, where i =1,...,N where i is the marginal cost, which is constant across firms, and mi can be broken up as follows:

    mi =eiei 1

    >1, where ei = (qi /pi )(pi / qi )

    In this case, as ei (price elasticity for seller i) changes, so will the profit-maximizing price, pi5. Due

    to heterogeneous visiting costs across seller groups, this elasticity of demand is unique to each seller

    group; thus explaining price dispersion in the monopolistic model. Consider three airports/sellers:

    5 In this equation, qi signifies quantity for firm i and pi is the price for firm i.

    Seller Type #1 Not Isolated Low Visiting Costs Low Elasticity of Demand

    Seller Type #2 Somewhat Isolated Medium Visiting Costs Medium Elasticity of Demand

    Seller Type #3 Very Isolated High Visiting Costs High Elasticity of Demand

  • 7

    The primary distinguishing factor across airports, and therefore sellers, is the level of isolation. As

    the level of isolation increases, so do the visiting costs and the elasticity of demand. Elasticity of

    demand and degree of isolation are positively correlated because consumers face a tradeoff between

    expected gain from visiting an airport and cost of visiting that given airport. Buyers will therefore be

    more sensitive to changes in expected gain for more remote airports. If a Seller Type 3 raises their

    price, many consumers may decide that the high visiting costs are no longer worth the price gains

    from visiting this given seller.

    However, the level of isolation is not the only determinant of elasticity. One must also

    account for the number of sellers in each group. It then becomes a reasonable extension of this model

    that an increase in sellers will increase the price elasticity across the various seller groups (Barron et

    al. 2004, 1045).6 These more elastic demand functions will reduce the average price or markup

    across the entire market. In addition, as prices converge towards a zero-profit equilibrium, the price

    dispersion will be reduced.

    (2) Search Theoretic Model with Informed and Uninformed Consumers Varian (1980) remains

    the seminal work for search theoretic models of price dispersion. He begins by borrowing elements

    from the Salop-Stiglitz model explained in Bargains and Ripoffs (Salop and Stiglitz 1977). Salop

    and Stiglitz divide consumers into two groups: the informed, who understand the complete

    landscape of prices and the uninformed, who know nothing about the distribution of prices. Upon

    making this assumption, Varian goes on to explain that firms engage in sales behavior in an attempt

    to price discriminate between the informed and uninformed customers (Varian 1980, 652). Varian

    maps out each stores density function f(p), which indicates the probably of a store charging a

    specific price (See Figure 1 below). In this figure, p* represents the sellers reservation price and r

    indicates the buyers reservation price. Most important to recognize is that firms have a higher 6 Note that this model assumes that the number of seller group types remains constant as the number of sellers increases.

  • 8

    probability of charging extreme prices over prices in the middle of the spectrum. In other words,

    the value of f(p) is higher as you approach the seller and buyer reservation prices. In other words,

    firms aim to either lure the informed buyers with low prices or sell to the uninformed buyers at high

    prices.

    In addition, Varian assumes that the ratio of uninformed to informed buyers remains

    constant. Therefore, as the number of firms increases, the volume that one firm can sell to informed

    customers decreases. In other words, as the number of firms increases, the profits from selling to

    informed buyers decrease; with this, we see an increase in average price. This is demonstrated in

    Figure 2, in which Dale Stahl maps out the different equilibrium density functions as the number of

    firms (N) increases. The probability of a firm catering to informed buyers decreases dramatically as

    N increases. Finally, in terms of price dispersion, Varians model assumes that an increase in the

    number of firms will increase the variance in prices (Barron et al. 2004, 1049). This is because an

    increase in firms will result in a more distinct spectrum of from the equilibrium density function f(p).

    Figure 1 (Varian 1980, 656) Figure 2 (Stahl 1989, 708)

  • 9

    (3) Search Theoretic Model with Heterogeneous Seller and Search Costs The final model that

    merits our attention was primarily developed by Carlson and McAfee (1983) and it addresses the

    prices for a homogenous commodity. Their work develops a search-theoretic approach, which

    assumes heterogeneous seller costs and heterogeneous visiting or search costs. They refer to Stigler

    who observed that price dispersion is ubiquitous even for homogenous goods and try to find an

    explanation (Stigler 1961, 213). Ratchford best explains their model, [Consumers] search

    sequentially for the lowest price using a stopping rule in which search is terminated when the

    expected gain from additional search is less than the constant cost of the additional search

    (Ratchford 2010, 95). From this, they derive the following demand curve:

    qj / q =1 (1 /T )(pj p), where j indicates the firm and the bar indicates the average. The term T is the ceiling value of the

    uniform distribution of search costs7. In sum, this demand equation indicates that an increase in T,

    and therefore an increase in search costs, leads to a decrease in demand elasticity.

    With this, Carlson and McAfee conclude that an increase in the number of sellers decreases

    markups (Barron et al. 2004, 1048). This is because an increase in the number of sellers comes from

    either an increase in market size or a decrease in the fixed cost. Either way, more sellers mean that

    there is a downward shift in the distribution of search costs. This leads to lower average prices.

    In terms of price dispersion, Carlson and McAfee eventually conclude that, ceteris paribus,

    the variance of prices is increased by an increase in the number of firms. (492). This theory is the

    result of supply side dynamics. They hypothesize that if all firms have the same average costs, then

    there will be no price dispersion; or rather, price dispersion is driven entirely by differences in unit

    costs in this model (Ratchford 2010, 95). Therefore an increase in the number of firms will increase

    price dispersion because each firm faces a slightly different cost function. 7 In addition, qj represents quantity and pj represents price for firm j.

  • 10

    Summary - These results (summarized in Table 1 above) are somewhat of a surprise. Only the

    monopolistic model infers a negative correlation between the number of sellers and price dispersion.

    Even more surprising, the second model infers a positive correlation between seller density and

    average price. Therefore, this literature review, and the conclusions it brings forward, constitutes a

    prima facie challenge to the preliminary hypothesis I made when embarking on this study. .

    These counter-intuitive theories are certainly not ignored by the literature. Hopkins (2006)

    notes the positive correlation observed by Varian and points to the work of Baye et al. (2004) to

    counter Varians argument. Lewis (2008) notes, somewhat ambiguously, that the results of Varian

    (1980) and Carlson & McAfee (1983) are almost unique within the consumer search literature

    (665). He goes on to argue that many search models, including Reinganum (1979) and MacMinn

    (1980), assume a continuum of firms and are unable to make predictions about the relationship

    between the number of firms and the equilibrium price distribution. (665) Finally, as an aside,

    Sorensen (2000) examines the prescription drug market and finds that drugs with higher frequency of

    use have lower price dispersion; thus suggesting another factor at play. Therefore, as this empirical

    Model Product Differentiation Search Costs Seller Costs

    Correlation between

    seller density and average

    price

    Correlation between

    number of sellers and price

    dispersion

    Monopolistic Model with Heterogeneous Visiting Costs

    Yes Heterogeneous Heterogeneous Negative Negative

    Search Theoretic Model with Informed and Uninformed Consumers

    No Heterogeneous Homogenous Positive Positive

    Search Theoretic Model with Heterogeneous Seller and Search Costs

    No Heterogeneous Heterogeneous Negative Positive

    Table 1

  • 11

    study proceeds, it will remain cognizant of this literature, while also appreciating the existing

    ambiguity. In many ways, it allows us to keep an open mind.

    Evidence From The Retail Gasoline Market

    While the theoretical work is rather mixed in its conclusions, the empirical work from the

    retail gasoline market offers a somewhat more consistent voice: seller density lowers both average

    prices and price dispersion. Barron et al. (2004) convincingly state that an increase in station density

    consistently decreases both price levels and price dispersion across four geographical areas (0).

    Barron et al. also mention that their results are most consistent with the theoretical framework of

    monopolistic competition (Barron et al. 2004, 24)8.

    Matthew Lewis, who builds on the work of Barron et al. by dividing the sellers into high and

    low brand groups, splits his analysis on price dispersion into two parts: city-wide dispersion and local

    dispersion. In regards to the former, he finds that price dispersion is lower for both high brand and

    low-brand stations when there are more competitors of their own type in the local market (Lewis

    2008, 677). This result refers to unexplained deviations from the city average price (Lewis 2008,

    673). When Lewis examines local dispersion (unexplained deviations from the local average price

    (673)), his result is the opposite9. Namely, Lewis concludes that an increase in sellers in a small

    region leads to an increase in price (673). Therein lies a particular strength of Lewis work: he takes a

    nuanced view at competition and seller heterogeneities.

    To explain an increase in price dispersion at the local level, Lewis argues that an increase in

    high-brand stations will lower dispersion across high-brand stations but will simultaneously increases

    dispersion across low brand groups (675). To account for this result, Lewis suggests that market

    8 They also note that, in terms of average price, the theory presented by Carlson and McAfee (1983) also fits with the results. However, this is not the case for price dispersion. They completely dismiss the theoretical predictions made by Varian (1980). 9 He uses a 1.5-mile radius to determine which stations are local competitors.

  • 12

    composition effects may lead to greater dispersion among stations of the opposite type (676) at the

    local level.

    The literature on the retail gasoline market is indicative of the various factors at play. There

    are station-level characteristics that one must account for; results are impacted when one changes the

    geographic area under review; and finally dispersion is impacted by an interaction between different

    station-types. I keep these factors in mind as I proceed with my own analysis of the general aviation

    fuel market.

    IV. General Aviation Fuel Market and Avgas Sellers Before proceeding, it is worth quickly examining the characteristics of general aviation and 100LL

    avgas. General aviation is all civilian flying except scheduled passenger airlines (AOPA). In other

    words, it ranges from operations such as weekend hobby flying to traffic helicopters for the local

    news. In fact, only about 20% of all pilots in the United States are hired full-time as pilots (AOPA).

    Most of these general aviation pilots fly small single engine planes that can carry between one and

    five passengers.

    The fuel used by these airplanes, and the subject of this study, is 100LL avgas. This is not the

    same fuel used by large airplanes or even executive jets. It is very specific to general aviation. Most

    general aviation planes can carry approximately 40-60 gallons of fuel, but this number is often less

    due to weight limitations. A normal plane may burn around 10 gallons per hour; nonetheless, this

    figure can vary drastically from plane to plane.

    Finally, there are different types of airspace. For the sake of this study one should know that

    the largest airports, such as SFO and JFK, are surrounded by what is known as Class Bravo

    airspace. These observations were dropped from the dataset. Slightly smaller airports, such as San

    Jose International, are surrounded by Class Charlie airspace. These airports were kept in the

    sample but were controlled for using a dummy. It is very common for such airports to have a lot of

  • 13

    general aviation activity in addition to their commercial traffic. Airports in all other types of airspace

    were included without a dummy control.

    Survey of 100LL Avgas Sellers I reached out to a variety of sellers all across the country and asked them how and when they determine their prices10. The survey, which is certainly qualitative and not quantitative, provided one

    overarching insight: sellers set prices in a variety of ways. First, I learned that some sellers update

    their prices every day based on supply and demand.11 Others only update prices when they receive

    a load of fuel. Furthermore, some sellers reported that they always just make a cost plus margin

    calculation. For example, one such respondent stated that their margin is always 75 cents, while

    another seller reported that their markup is 50 cents for self-service and $1 for full-service. In

    contrast to this constant margin method, a different seller explained that they always attempt to be

    lowest in the area. There is certainly a visible contrast between the sellers that look at the landscape

    to determine their price and sellers that impose a constant margin without adjusting to the

    competition.

    Finally, this survey indicated just how competitive this market can be. One respondent

    explained:

    Understanding that if you don't meet the number of gallons goal, it

    can't be made up the next month in volume as you will have to raise

    your price to make up what you lost the previous time period and now

    you are no longer competitive as your competition is not the other guy

    on the field, but the previous and the next stop for the customer.

    This insight clearly shows that sellers are aware that they are often not the only option for buyers. In

    addition, not all sellers get the same wholesale price; Some Airports only receive 1/2 loads of fuel, 10 It was difficult to convince the sellers that I was a student and not a competitor. Therefore, I only received 6 responses after reaching out to over 50 sellers. 11 In order to convince respondents that I was not a competitor, I had to make the survey anonymous. I therefore cannot attribute a quote to a given respondent.

  • 14

    because they do not have large holding tanks, so the fuel will cost more, wrote one respondent.

    Overall, this survey shined light on a variety of market characteristics: intense competition, different

    pricing strategies and heterogeneous seller costs. These qualitative results will be helpful as we

    attempt to explain the forthcoming empirical results.

    V. Data and Data Concerns The dependent variables, average price and price dispersion, are measured using cross-sectional price

    data purchased from FlightAware, a global software company specializing in aviation data. The

    dataset includes the airports IATA code12, the facility name, the price of 100LL avgas13 and the

    timestamp of the last price update. There are 1,497 observations for airports across the United States.

    Appendix 2 and 3 show the distribution of these prices, while Appendix 4 demonstrates a map of

    every airport for which I have data and every airport in the continental United States that sells 100LL

    avgas. Finally, it is worth emphasizing that this price data represents a current snapshot of prices;

    it does not track how prices have changed over time.

    The second dataset is the FAAs Airport Facilities Data. It includes a plethora of variables,

    including geographic location, closest city to the airport and the number of flight operations per year.

    The 19,304 public and private facilities in the United States are all included in this dataset14.

    The final source of data is the 2013 American Community Survey. It allows me to access

    county specific population and economic data, thus allowing me to control for a variety of factors

    that might play a role in impacting fuel prices. I use this data to get population data, household

    income data, gini coefficients and population density numbers.

    Data Concerns

    12 For example, for San Francisco international airport the code is SFO. 13 The data includes price data both for self-service and for full service. For some observations, there is no self-service price available. Therefore, the regression analysis will include a dummy variable to control for this. When both prices are available, I simply use the self-service price and ignore the full service price. 14 There are 13,090 airports after one drops heliports and other facilities.

  • 15

    Finally, it is worth briefly highlighting some specific data concerns. First, this study

    examines a snapshot of prices. One would therefore hope that all the price data is from a single

    point in time. However, some of the price data for more remote airports is delayed by a couple of

    days, and sometimes even weeks15. Second, the data collection method used by FlightAware is not

    ideal. While some of the data is self-reported by FBOs, much of the data is crowd-sourced by pilots.

    It is therefore worth highlighting that there is the possibility that some data points are incorrect.

    Fortunately, such error is randomly distributed and therefore should not compromise the model.

    Finally, the data acquired from FlightAware is not fully indicative of all the airports in the

    United States that sell fuel. In Appendix 5, I compare four key variables between all airports that sell

    100LL avgas (3243) and all airports in my dataset (1497). There emerges one overarching pattern:

    airports in my dataset are generally busier. In other words, they experience more daily traffic and

    have more planes parked there. This should not come as a surprise, given that the price data is crowd-

    sourced and will therefore be biased towards airports more frequently visited by pilots. Nevertheless,

    it is worth remaining mindful of these limitations as I proceed with this analysis.

    VI. Empirical Strategy This empirical strategy is inspired by the work of Lewis (2008) and Barron et al. (2004), while

    simultaneously keeping in mind the characteristics that differentiate this niche market. With this in

    mind, I will first explain my custom approach to calculating seller density and will then move to

    outline the regression specifications.

    Calculating Seller Density

    The work in the retail gasoline market (Lewis 2008, Barron et al. 2004) used a rather simple

    method to calculate density: counting the number of sellers within in a 1.5-mile radius. I would like

    to improve on that methodology. I therefore develop a density variable using the following formula: 15 No data point is older than four weeks.

  • 16

    = 5 105 = 50!!

    The equation weighs the airports, and therefore also the sellers, based on distance between the origin

    airport and the nearby competition. For example, an airport that is 30 nautical miles from origin

    airport, such as KLVK in Figure 3 below, will only add 2/5 to the weighted density variable. An

    airport that is 19 nautical miles away, on the other hand, adds 4/5 to the density variable; thus being

    weighted considerably more16 17.

    16 The use of 50NM as the radius, while not completely scientific, does have some underlying logic. The difference between the 25% and 75% percentile prices in my data is exactly $1 ($4.4 to $5.4). In addition, a plane going 110 knots will take just under 30 minutes to fly 50NM. Assuming that a plane consumes 10 gallons per hour, the trip to and back from an airport exactly 50NM will burn 10 gallons. Taking the average price from the data sample ($4.9), this trip would cost $49. Most single engine planes hold approximately 50 gallons of fuel. Therefore, the cost of going to the cheaper seller ($49) is almost equal to the benefits ($50), assuming you get a full tank of fuel (note that planes do have to hold reserves and therefore will not burn their entire fuel load). While imperfect and filled with assumptions, this process is meant to demonstrate that the 50NM radius does have some underlying logic. 17 I use the terms seller and airport interchangeably across this paper.

    Figure 3 (Authors Sketch)

  • 17

    Appendix 2 demonstrates the Kernel density estimation for this measure of density. It represents a

    nice distribution for airports across the United States. The values range from 0 for Truth or

    Consequences Municipal Airport in New Mexico to 23.8 for Sky Manor Airport in New Jersey,

    which has an astonishing 46 different competitors within a 50NM radius. Finally, to ensure that all

    bases are covered, the regression analysis will also include specifications in which density is simply

    the number of sellers within 25NM.

    Regression Model

    My regression specifications are primarily inspired by the work of Lewis (2008) and Barron

    et al. (2004). They posed the same question in the retail gasoline market and employ a two-step

    methodology. First, they regress fuel price on a variety of variables, including seller density and

    weekly hours of operation. They capture the error terms of this regression and use its square as the

    dependent variable in the subsequent regression. In other words, after controlling for a variety of

    station-specific factors in the first regression, they assume that the squared residuals indicate the

    level of price dispersion. The second regression then regresses the squared residuals on seller density;

    thus examining the relationship between seller density and price dispersion.

    Step 1: Testing Q1 and Collecting Residuals The goal of the first step is two-fold: to analyze the relationship between seller density and average

    price and also to collect the unexplained residuals for step two. With this in mind, I employ the

    following regression specification:

    ln(Fuel Price) = + 1SellerDensity + 2DistanceFromCBD +

    3NumberOfSingleEnginePLanesPlanes + 4OperationsGALocal +

    5OperationsGAItinIn + 4MedianHouseholdIncome +

    6PopulationPerSquareMile + 7NumberOfPilotsInState +

    8NoSelfServiceDummy + 9ClassCharlieDummy + u1

  • 18

    First, note that this regression is set up as a log-linear model. Therefore, a one-unit change for a

    specific regressor is associated with a (100 Coefficient) % change in price. In addition, Table 2

    below provides an explanation and overview of each variable in this regression. Finally, I have 868

    data points that have the self-service price. For the other 629 observations, I use the full service price

    and control for the effect using a dummy (NoSelfServiceDummy).

    This regression was run with four different specifications. First, seller density was measured both by

    the previously mentioned weighted density variable and by counting the number of sellers within

    25NM. Second, this model was run both as a simple OLS regression and by using fixed effects.

    Fixed effects are used to control for state-specific characteristics18. In this case, 46 separate

    regressions were run, one for each state in the dataset19.

    18 Every State has different taxes placed on aviation fuel. This is something that is not accounted for in the standard OLS regression but is controlled for by using fixed effects. 19 Did not have fuel data for all 50 states.

    VARIABLES LABELS/ DESCRIPTION DATASET N mean min max

    DistanceFromCBD Dist. from Central Business District (In Miles) FAA AFD 1,496 3.699 0 68

    NumberOfSellersWithin25NM Number of Sellers Within 25 Nautical Miles FAA + Author 1,497 4.274 0 17

    WeightedDensity Weighted Density Calculation FAA + Author 1,497 7.357 0 23.80

    llfullservicePriceInteger 100 LL Full Service Price FlightAware 1,102 5.309 3.450 7.990

    llselfservicePriceInteger 100 LL Self Service Price FlightAware 868 4.890 3.300 6.740

    NoSelfServiceDummy Dummy if No Self Service FAA AFD 1,497 0.420 0 1

    NumberOfSingleEnginePlanes # of Single Engine Plane at Airport (In Tens) FAA AFD 1,490 5.882 0 81.20

    OperationsGALocal # of Local GA Operations (In Hundreds) FAA AFD 1,497 161.9 0.300 2,128

    OperationsGAItinInHundreds # of Itinerant GA Operations (In Hundreds) FAA AFD 1,497 149.0 0.480 3,321

    ClassCAirspaceDummy Dummy if Airport is in Class Charlie Airspace FAA AFD 1,497 0.045 0 1

    PopulationPerSquareMile Pop Per Square Mile for County (In Tens) ACS 1,497 32.15 0.050 549.5

    NumberOfPilotsInState Number of Pilots in the State (In Thousands) ACS 1,497 21.21 1.037 64.53

    MedianHouseholdIncome County Median HH Income (In Thousands) ACS 1,497 49.37 21.86 106.7

    StateGiniCoefficient State Gini Coefficient ACS 1,497 0.469 0.418 0.510

    Table 2

  • 19

    Step 2: Testing Q2 Assuming step one correctly defines the determinants of aviation gas price, I can now safely join

    Lewis (2008) and Barron et al. (2004) in assuming that the squared residuals measure the

    unexplained variance in prices across markets. (Barron et al., 1060). With this in mind, I use the

    following regression equation:

    An explanation of each variable can be found in Table 2 above. Why are the controls from the first

    equation not present in this equation? In contrast to Step 1, airport-specific characteristics did not

    seem to have any significant effect on price dispersion in any of my tests20. These variables were

    therefore dropped.

    In addition, because Step 1 constituted four different regression specifications, the same holds

    true here. In short, by regressing seller density on the squared unexplained residuals from Step 1, I

    can now examine the relationship between seller density and price dispersion. If I find a negative and

    statistically significant coefficient 1, I will have shown that price dispersion decreases with

    increased competition.

    VII. Results: The Impact of Seller Density on Average Price The results, which are shown in Table 2 of the appendix, provide a robust answer to Q1 outlined in

    the introduction. Namely, an increase in seller density in a given geographic area leads to a

    decrease in average price. In addition, these regression results not only shine light on this specific

    question but also provide insight on a variety of price determinants for avgas. I will therefore analyze

    the results line by line in the forthcoming paragraphs. 20 Including these controls, however, did not alter the sign nor significance on the coefficient of seller density. The results are the same whether the controls are included or not.

    ui2= + 1SellerDensity + + 2NumberOfPilotsInState +

    3StateGiniCoefficient + vi

  • 20

    However, before proceeding, I wish to argue that Specification (3) should be the focus on our

    analysis. As a reminder, these are the four specifications:

    Specification (1) Specification (2) Specification (3) Specification (4)

    Measure of Density

    Weighted Density Calculation

    Number of Sellers Within 25NM

    Weighted Density Calculation

    Number of Sellers Within 25NM

    Fixed Effects NO NO YES YES

    There are two reasons for this choice. First, by using fixed effects, I am able to control for a variety

    of state-specific factors that could have distorted a standard OLS regression. For example, each state

    has slightly different taxes levied on avgas. Second, the weighted density calculation previously

    presented respects the particular characteristics of general aviation. Namely, that flying 5NM to a

    different seller is a much smaller burden, both financially and time-wise, than flying 25NM.

    Therefore, while I list the results from each specification, my analysis will focus primarily on

    specification three21.

    Seller Density and Average Fuel Price

    The coefficient on seller density is negative and significant at the 1% level. This is expected.

    As the amount of competition in a given area increases, prices should fall22. The causal mechanism

    between a decrease in competition and increase in prices is quite clear: the pilot does not have any

    other options. Typical single engine general aviation planes hold enough fuel for about three hours of

    operation. Pilots flying long distances, such as San Francisco to Los Angeles, are often not simply

    able to wait until the next airport to fuel up. In other words, the nature of general aviation means that

    isolated airports face quite inelastic demand curves. 21 The different specifications are also listed to show that the results are generally consistent from specification to specification. 22 Similar results are found when substituting the weighted density value with a count of sellers within a 25 nm radius. The coefficients from (2) and (4) indicate that one more seller in this given radius is expected to decrease the price by approximately 0.4%.

  • 21

    Airport Specific Characteristics

    The study implemented a variety of controls, many of which are airport-specific. The

    coefficients from these controls both validate the robustness of our answer to Q1 and shine light on

    the determinants of general aviation fuel prices.

    One concern when undertaking this study was that the regression analysis would be unable to

    isolate the increased transportation costs for isolated airports from the impact of seller density. One

    way this was addressed was by including a variable, DistanceFromCBD, which indicates the distance

    in miles of the airport to the nearest business district. The results show that, as expected, an increase

    in this distance leads to an increase in prices23; thus indicating that airports farther removed from

    population centers ask higher prices.

    The volume of customers also affects a sellers pricing strategy. Hence, with this in mind, I

    control for the number of single engine general aviation planes at the given airport. The data

    demonstrates that for every 10 more customers, the price of 100LL avgas decreases 0.15% - a

    coefficient that is significant at the 5% level.

    Finally, the number of flight operations at the given airport presents one of the most

    interesting findings of this study. The count of flights is divided into two categories: local flights

    (OperationsGALocal) and itinerant operations (OperationsGAItin). Local traffic is defined as flight

    operations within 20NM of the airport while all other traffic is defined as itinerant operations. In this

    case an increase in local operations is found to lower prices, while an increase in itinerant operations

    raises prices. While this may seem contradictory at first, I suspect that these results are in fact

    ordinary. Airports with a lot of local operations will have highly informed buyers who are very

    familiar with the different sellers in the area. On the other hand, itinerant operations represent out of

    town pilots who will fly into the airport without knowing the market characteristics of the region.

    An increase in such pilots or fuel buyers could therefore easily lead to an increase in prices. 23 For every 1 mile distance between the nearest business district and the airport, the price goes up 0.1%.

  • 22

    Therefore, for every 100 such flights, it is certainly probable that the fuel price rises 0.01% - a

    coefficient that is significant at the 1% level.

    County-Level Controls

    By pulling county-level data from the American Community Survey, I control for local

    factors that may play a role in setting the fuel prices. One such variable was the median household

    income of the airports county. The coefficient for median household income is negative and

    significant at the 10% level a rather unexpected result. General intuition would expect that with an

    increase in income, prices should rise as well because wealthier customers have more inelastic

    demand. One possible explanation for this phenomenon is that general aviation pilots are not a

    normal cross-section of the population. In other words, general aviation pilots tend to be wealthier

    than the population and a statistic that examines the entire spectrum is not indicative. It is possible

    for the median income to be low but for the top 10% of earners to be very wealthy24.

    The population density variable offers another unexpected result. This control was added to

    account for isolated airports that incur higher transportation costs. However, the regression

    coefficient indicates that as the population density increases, so does the price. Once again, this

    coefficient is significant at the 1%. It is very likely that a premium is being charged at airports in

    metropolitan airports; thus leading to this result.

    Finally, for the two specifications that did not include fixed effects, the number of pilots in

    the state was used as a control variable. As expected, an increase in buyers led to a decrease in price.

    Sellers in states with higher aviation activity experience more volume and can therefore offer lower

    prices.

    24 This is indicative of a broader issue when controlling for county-level factors. It is hard to determine just how the local community is related to the airport itself.

  • 23

    Dummy Variables

    The dummy controls, their coefficients and levels of significance, give credence to the results

    from this regression. First, a dummy was included to control for instances in which a self-service

    price is not available. Its coefficient is both positive and highly significant, thus indicating that the

    price is higher for services such as a fuel truck coming to the plane an expected result. This is also

    shown in Appendix 3, where the kernel density estimate distribution is shown for both self-service

    and full-service prices. The second dummy, which indicates whether the seller is at a Class

    Charlie airport25, is also positive and highly significant. Fuel at these larger airports, which often but

    not always have commercial traffic, is more expensive. This is another anticipated result. In sum,

    these dummy variables have the correct sign and help nail down the determinants of fuel prices.

    Concluding Thoughts Overall, these results are very positive. Theory and general intuition predicts that increased

    seller density lowers average prices. This prediction is validated with robust conclusions and

    coefficients. While some unexpected results arise in the county-level controls, they represent that

    airports are often not completely indicative of their surroundings. Having established these

    determinants, we can now move on to the analysis on price dispersion.

    VIII. Results: Seller Density and Price Dispersion Addressing Q2, the impact of seller density on price dispersion, is not as straightforward as the

    preceding section. All things considered, these results are simply not as robust; even though the

    coefficients have a high level of significance. The regression was run with two different

    specifications, one that included a control for the state gini coefficient and one that did not. The

    results are listed in Tables 3 and 4 of the Appendix.

    25 See section 4 for explanation of class charlie.

  • 24

    Seller Density and Price Dispersion Specification (3) demonstrates, with a high level of significance, that an increase in seller

    density also increases price dispersion. This holds true both when I control for the states gini

    coefficient and when I do not. This result contradicts both my original expectation and some of the

    evidence in the retail gasoline market (Lewis 2008, Barron et al. 2004)26. However, the literature

    review did present two theories, presented primarily by Varian (1980) and Carlson and McAfee

    (1983), which predicted such an outcome.

    So how can we explain these results? It is most likely driven by a combination of the causal

    mechanisms presented by Varian (1980) and Carlson and McAfee (1983). Varian suggests that an

    increase in sellers decreases the returns from competing at low margins. A higher level of

    competition decreases the volume you can sell at such a low price point. Hence, rather than

    converging towards a low price, the sellers will most likely try to target different consumers, some

    which will be highly informed and some which will be uninformed. Carlson and McAfee (1983)

    would add that every seller that joins the market faces a different cost curve27. They will therefore

    offer different prices and, as a result, will increase price dispersion. Finally, it is important to note

    that Lewis (2008) did obtain the same result when he examined local price dispersion (1.5 mile

    radius). I would argue that this result by Lewis is more important than his results for citywide

    dispersion. This is because examining dispersion at the local level addresses the same spatial

    competition questions tackled by this work.

    Number of Pilots in State

    All specifications from Table 3 demonstrate a positive correlation between the number of

    pilots in the state and the price dispersion. This is an expected result. An increase in the number of

    pilots leads to a higher number of different consumer groups that sellers can target with different 26 Lewis did have the same result as I did when he focused on a 1.5 mile radius and not on city-wide dispersion. 27 My qualitative survey of sellers did confirm that not all sellers receive the same price for the fuel from the suppliers. They therefore have different cost curves.

  • 25

    pricing strategies. Unfortunately, this finding does not hold true in the Table 4, when one controls for

    the state Gini coefficient.

    County Gini Coefficient and Price Dispersion

    Specification (3), which has been the focus of this analysis, demonstrates that an increase in

    inequality in a given state leads to an increase in price dispersion. This is certainly an anticipated

    phenomenon28. Increased inequality means that sellers face drastically different elasticities of

    demand across the consumer base; they will therefore undertake a variety of different pricing

    strategies to maximize profit. Not only is this result highly significant but it also accounts for a large

    part of the observed price dispersion29.

    How robust are these results?

    These results are certainly not far-fetched. While they do not align with my preliminary

    hypothesis when starting this work, they do support various theoretical assumptions. Nevertheless, I

    suspect that these results are better taken as a hint or indication than as a final conclusion. In this, I

    disagree with the approach taken by both Lewis (2008) and Barron et al. (2004) in their respective

    studies. The significance levels of our respective empirical works are very similar. However, they are

    much quicker to make conclusions on seller density and price dispersions based on these results than

    I am. There are three reasons for my cautious interpretation.

    First, the expectation is that the first regression should encompass all determinants of fuel

    prices. Only then can we assume that the squared residuals are in fact the price dispersion. Having no

    way of determining whether all the effects are captured in the first step, the second steps credibility

    28 This regression was also run using the airports county gini coefficient. In this case, the coefficient on the gini value was not significant. This once again demonstrates the disconnect between airports and their surrounding communities. Or rather, what determines the characteristics of an airport is not the nearby town but the larger market as a whole. It is therefore no surprise that the state gini had an effect while the county did not. 29 The adjusted R squared for the specification (3) with Gini coefficients is three times as high as when the gini coefficient is not included.

  • 26

    is somewhat compromised. Omitted variable bias in the first regression could easily be distorting

    these results.

    Second, it is worth highlighting that these results are only achieved when the residuals from

    the fixed effects regressions in the first step are used in a standard OLS regression in the second step.

    In other words, the effect seems to be so small that it does not achieve levels of significance if one

    uses fixed effects in the second step. This is certainly a cause of concern.

    Finally, while the first regression was able to derive credibility from a variety of controls,

    that is not the case here. In other words, the expected coefficients for the control values in the first

    regression matched, for the most part, the actual results. This type of test is not available because this

    regression did not include regressors with straightforward expected values. Hence, these results,

    while certainly significant, are not as robust as the findings on seller density and average price.

    Nevertheless, on the whole, the indication is that there is a positive relationship between seller

    density and price dispersion in the aviation fuel market.

    IX. Theory and Empirical Results: Bringing it Together The empirical results indicate a negative correlation between seller density and average price and

    suggest a positive relationship between seller density and price dispersion. These results beg the

    question: how do we reconcile these results with the theories presented in the literature review?

    In terms of average price, the predictions prescribed by both the monopolistic model and the

    search model with heterogeneous sellers hold true. On the other hand, Varians conclusion that an

    increase in sellers will cause more sellers to target uninformed buyers was not endorsed by the data.

    In terms of price dispersion, the data corresponds with both the predictions of Varian (198)

    and Carlson and McAfee (1983). It is very likely that both effects are at play. Varian suggested that

    as more sellers enter a market, firms will be less likely to target informed buyers; thus leading to an

    increase of different pricing strategies targeting a mix of uninformed buyers and informed buyers

  • 27

    with high search costs. Carlson and McAfee (1983), which approached this question from a supply

    side perspective, argue that an increase in sellers leads to an increase in different cost functions.

    Because these cost functions are directly responsible for price variance, this means that price

    dispersion will rise.

    In sum, the model that best predicted these results was Carlson and McAfees. Their model

    assumes a homogenous product, heterogeneous seller costs and a distribution of different search

    costs. All the assumptions apply to the aviation fuel market, in which a commodity is sold by

    different sellers with distinct cost functions to consumers with individual search costs. In hindsight,

    given this theoretical literature, these results should have been expected prior to embarking on this

    work.

    X. Conclusion and Opportunities for Further Research The goal of this research was three-fold. First, it was to examine the relationship between seller

    density and average price in the aviation fuel market. The data robustly demonstrated a negative

    correlation. Second, I addressed the interaction between seller density and price dispersion and

    revealed that the data weakly suggests a positive correlation. By tying these results back to the

    theory, I was able to demonstrate that these outcomes should have been expected, given the

    characteristics of the general aviation fuel market.

    Third, the goal of this study was to learn more about the general aviation market as a whole.

    The president of AOPA (Aircraft Owners and Pilots Association) recently wrote that the GA

    industry has had an especially tough time in the recent recession. And the pilot community has been

    shrinking for years (Mark Baker, 2014). The main cause for this phenomenon has been the rising

    costs associated with aviation, with fuel prices being one of the primary factors. This study has

    addressed these fuel costs and placed specific focus on the conspicuous variation in prices across the

  • 28

    United States. The results clearly indicate that a driving cause for such high costs is the lack of

    competition in certain geographic areas.

    This study has contributed to a long line of work around seller density and prices. Sorensen

    (2000) examined the prescription drug market. For Walsh and Whelan (1999) it was the Irish grocery

    market. Rose and Borensteins (1994) case study was the car insurance market. In this case, it was

    the general aviation fuel market that served as a vehicle for a broader study around prices. Therefore,

    while this work represents the first look at the general aviation fuel market, the questions it poses and

    answers are certainly not new.

    On the whole, this analysis is incomplete. There are a lot of questions that remain

    unanswered. What precisely is the causal mechanism between an increase in sellers and an increase

    in price dispersion? We have weak evidence for the phenomenon taking place. However, further

    empirical work should try to find an explanation. In addition, this study had difficulty establishing

    the relationship between county-level characteristics and fuel prices. It is possible that the two are

    isolated. Or rather, how intertwined are airports with their surrounding environments? Do they cater

    to a subset of the population and therefore have little interaction with local factors? This is certainly

    another interesting question worth examining.

    Finally, future study should also expand the scope of this study. The data studied here

    represented a snapshot of prices. Forthcoming work should not only look at the impact of seller

    density on current prices but should also examine how prices change over time to determine the

    relationship between seller density and price rigidity. The general aviation fuel market is an

    interesting market that should help address broader theoretical questions in economics.

    To the pilots who constantly find themselves saying, These fuel prices are a rip-off, this

    study has helped explain this frustration. The large variation in aviation gas prices across the United

    States is largely determined by the amount competition in the surrounding area.

  • 29

    I. Appendix 1: Kernel Density Estimate of Density Calculation

    0.0

    5.1

    Dens

    ity

    0 5 10 15 20 25WeightedDensity

    kernel = epanechnikov, bandwidth = 0.8338

    Density Calculation - Kernel Density Estimate

  • 30

    II. Appendix 2: Histogram of Fuel Prices

    0.2

    .4.6

    .8De

    nsity

    3 4 5 6 7llselfservicePriceInteger

    0.2

    .4.6

    Density

    3 4 5 6 7 8llfullservicePriceInteger

  • 31

    III. Appendix 3: Kernel Density Estimate of Prices

    0.2

    .4.6

    3 4 5 6 7 8Price

    Full Service Price Self Service Price

  • 32

    IV. Appendix 4: Map of Airports/Sellers (ArcGIS)

  • 33

    V. Appendix 5: Comparison of Airports in my Dataset and All Airports That Sell Fuel

    0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70

    All Airports That Sell Fuel My Dataset

    Number of Pla

    nes

    Average Number Of Single Engine Planes

    0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3 3.5 4

    All Airports That Sell Fuel My Dataset

    Miles Average Distance From Central Business District

  • 34

    0 2000 4000 6000 8000 10000

    12000 14000 16000 18000

    All Airports That Sell Fuel My Dataset

    Number of Loc

    al Operations

    Average Number Of Local Operations

    0 2000 4000 6000 8000

    10000 12000 14000 16000

    All Airports That Sell Fuel My Dataset

    Number of Ite

    rant Operation

    s

    Average Number Of Iterant Operations

  • 35

    I. Table 1: Overview of Variables

    VARIABLES LABELS/ DESCRIPTION DATASET N mean min max

    DistanceFromCBD Dist. from Central Business District (In Miles) FAA AFD 1,496 3.699 0 68 NumberOfSellersWithin25NM Number of Sellers Within 25 Nautical Miles FAA + Author 1,497 4.274 0 17 WeightedDensity Weighted Density Calculation FAA + Author 1,497 7.357 0 23.80

    llfullservicePriceInteger 100 LL Full Service Price FlightAware 1,102 5.309 3.450 7.990

    llselfservicePriceInteger 100 LL Self Service Price FlightAware 868 4.890 3.300 6.740

    NoSelfServiceDummy Dummy if No Self Service FAA AFD 1,497 0.420 0 1

    NumberOfSingleEnginePlanes # of Single Engine Plane at Airport (In Tens) FAA AFD 1,490 5.882 0 81.20

    OperationsGALocal # of Local GA Operations (In Hundreds) FAA AFD 1,497 161.9 0.300 2,128

    OperationsGAItinInHundreds # of Itinerant GA Operations (In Hundreds) FAA AFD 1,497 149.0 0.480 3,321

    ClassCAirspaceDummy Dummy if Airport is in Class Charlie Airspace FAA AFD 1,497 0.045 0 1

    PopulationPerSquareMile Pop Per Square Mile for County (In Tens) ACS 1,497 32.15 0.050 549.5

    NumberOfPilotsInState Number of Pilots in the State (In Thousands) ACS 1,497 21.21 1.037 64.53

    MedianHouseholdIncome County Median HH Income (In Thousands) ACS 1,497 49.37 21.86 106.7

    StateGiniCoefficient State Gini Coefficient ACS 1,497 0.469 0.418 0.510

    Table 2

  • 36

    II. Table 2: Seller Density and Average Price

    (1) (2) (3) (4) VARIABLES ln(Fuel Price) ln(Fuel Price) ln(Fuel Price) ln(Fuel Price) WeightedDensity -0.0043*** -0.0058*** (0.001) (0.002) NumberOfSellersWithin25NM -0.0038*** -0.0041** (0.001) (0.002) DistanceFromCBD (In Miles) -0.0003 -0.0003 0.0010* 0.0010* (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) NumberOfSingleEnginePlanes (In Tens) -0.0020*** -0.0018*** -0.0015** -0.0016** (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) OperationsGALocal (In Hundreds) -0.0001** -0.0001** -0.0001*** -0.0001*** (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) OperationsGAItin (In Hundreds) 0.0001*** 0.0001*** 0.0001*** 0.0001*** (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) MedianHouseholdIncome (In Thousands) 0.0011*** 0.0009*** -0.0007* -0.0010** (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) PopulationPerSquareMile (In Tens) 0.0006*** 0.0005*** 0.0006*** 0.0005*** (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) NumberOfPilotsInState (In Thousands) -0.0010*** -0.0010*** (0.000) (0.000) NoSelfServiceDummy 0.0888*** 0.0888*** 0.0855*** 0.0866*** (0.007) (0.007) (0.011) (0.011) ClassCAirspaceDummy 0.1020*** 0.1042*** 0.1031*** 0.1045*** (0.017) (0.017) (0.024) (0.024) Constant 1.5711*** 1.5649*** 1.6444*** 1.6366*** (0.016) (0.016) (0.018) (0.018) Observations 1,489 1,489 1,489 1,489 Adjusted R-squared 0.214 0.208 0.235 0.226 State FE NO NO YES YES Number of StateNumCode 46 46 Robust standard errors in parentheses *** p

  • 37

    III. Table 3: Seller density and Price Dispersion (Without Gini)

    (1) (2) (3) (4) VARIABLES Price Dispersion

    (Squared Residuals) Price Dispersion

    (Squared Residuals) Price Dispersion

    (Squared Residuals) Price Dispersion

    (Squared Residuals) WeightedDensity 0.0003* 0.0005*** (0.000) (0.000) NumberOfSellersWithin25NM 0.0001 0.0002 (0.000) (0.000) NumberOfPilotsInState (In Thousands) 0.0001*** 0.0001*** 0.0001*** 0.0001*** (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) Constant 0.0132*** 0.0145*** 0.0127*** 0.0151*** (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) Observations 1,489 1,489 1,489 1,489 Adjusted R-squared 0.012 0.012 0.015 0.012 State FE NO NO NO NO

    Robust standard errors in parentheses

    *** p

  • 38

    IV. Table 4: Seller density and Price Dispersion (With Gini)

    (1) (2) (3) (4) VARIABLES Price Dispersion

    (Squared Residuals) Price Dispersion

    (Squared Residuals) Price Dispersion

    (Squared Residuals) Price Dispersion

    (Squared Residuals) WeightedDensity 0.0003* 0.0004*** (0.000) (0.000) NumberOfAirportsWithin25NM 0.0001 0.0002 (0.000) (0.000) StateGini 0.0900** 0.0980** 0.1308*** 0.1433*** (0.045) (0.045) (0.047) (0.048) NumberOfPilotsInState (In Thousands) 0.0001* 0.0001** 0.0000 0.0001 (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) Constant -0.0276 -0.0302 -0.0464** -0.0502** (0.020) (0.021) (0.022) (0.022) Observations 1,437 1,437 1,437 1,437 Adjusted R-squared 0.015 0.015 0.020 0.017 State FE NO NO NO NO

  • 39

    Works Cited

    AOPA. "What Is General Aviation?" Let's Go Flying:. N.p., n.d. Web. 05 Apr. 2015.

    .

    AOPA. "FAA Certificated Pilots." FAA Certified Pilots. N.p., Mar. 2011. Web. 05 Apr. 2015.

    .

    Baker, Mark. "Too Expensive." AOPA. N.p., 6 Nov. 2014. Web. 5 Apr. 2015. <

    http://www.aopa.org/News-and-Video/All-News/2014/December/Pilot/prepos >.

    Barron, John M., Beck A. Taylor, and John R. Umbeck. "Number of Sellers, Average Prices, and

    Price Dispersion." International Journal of Industrial Organization 22.8-9 (2004): 1041-

    066.

    Baye, Michael R., John Morgan, and Patrick Scholten. "Price Dispersion In The Small And In

    The Large: Evidence From An Internet Price Comparison Site." Journal of Industrial

    Economics 52.4 (2004): 463-96. Print.

    Carlson, John A., and R. Preston Mcafee. "Discrete Equilibrium Price Dispersion." Journal of

    Political Economy 91.3 (1983): 480-493. Print.

    Hopkins, Ed. "Price Dispersion." N.p., Nov. 2006. Web. 26 Feb. 2015.

    .

    Lewis, Matthew. "Price Dispersion And Competition With Differentiated Sellers." The Journal

    of Industrial Economics 56.3 (2008): 654-78. Print.

    Macminn, Richard D. "Search and Market Equilibrium." Journal of Political Economy 88.2

    (1980): 308-27. Print.

    Perloff, Jeffrey M., and Steven C. Salop. "Equilibrium with Product Differentiation." The

    Review of Economic Studies 52.1 (1985): 107-120. Print.

  • 40

    Rao, Vithala R. Handbook of Pricing Research in Marketing. Cheltenham, Glos, UK: Edward

    Elgar, 2009. Print.

    Ratchford, Brian. "Consumer Search and Pricing." Handbook of Pricing Research in Marketing.

    Ed. Vithala R. Rao. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, 2010. 91-107. Print.

    Reinganum, Jennifer F. "A Simple Model of Equilibrium Price Dispersion." Journal of Political

    Economy 87.4 (1979): 851-858. Print.

    Rose, Nancy, and Severin Borenstein. "Competition and Price Dispersion in the US Airline

    Industry." Journal of Political Economy 102 (1994): 653-683. Print.

    Salop, Steven, and Joseph Stiglitz. "Bargains and Ripoffs: A Model of Monopolistically

    Competitive Price Dispersion." The Review of Economic Studies 44.3 (1977): 493-510.

    Print.

    Stahl, Dale O., II. "Oligopolistic Pricing with Sequential Consumer Search." The Journal of

    Industrial Economics 79.4 (1989): 700-12. Print.

    Sorensen, Alan T. "Equilibrium Price Dispersion in Retail Markets for Prescription Drugs."

    Journal of Political Economy 108.4 (2000): 833-50. Print.

    Stigler, George J. "The Economics of Information." Journal of Political Economy 69.3 (1961):

    213-25. Print.

    Stiglitz, Joseph E. "Competition and the Number of Firms in a Market: Are Duopolies More

    Competitive than Atomistic Markets?" Journal of Political Economy 95.5 (1987): 1041-61.

    Print.

    Varian, Hal R. "A Model of Sales." The American Economic Review 1980th ser. 70.4 (1980):

    651-59. Print.

  • 41

    Walsh, Patrick Paul, and Ciara Whelan. "Modelling Price Dispersion as an Outcome of

    Competition in the Irish Grocery Market." The Journal of Industrial Economics 47.3

    (1999): 325-43. Print.