Electronic Journal of Sociology Privatisation

download Electronic Journal of Sociology Privatisation

of 32

Transcript of Electronic Journal of Sociology Privatisation

  • 7/30/2019 Electronic Journal of Sociology Privatisation

    1/32

    Electronic Journal of Sociology (2003)

    ISSN: 1198 3655

    Theorising Privatisation: Policy, Network Analysis, and Class

    Fran M. [email protected]

    Abstract

    In the last two decades of the twentieth

    century many governments across the world

    have displayed an unprecedented attraction

    toward policies which encourage and allow

    the marketisation of the public sector and the

    privatisation of public assets and services.While the financial and social impact of this

    policy shift has been empirically documented,

    theoretical development regarding possible

    underlying causal processes remains in its

    infancy. This paper explores current theories

    of the policy process of privatisation from a

    sociological perspective, and proposes a

    potentially useful direction for future policy

    analysis.

    In the 1980s Australian policy followed other nations (particularly Britain) in participating in

    what Hood described as an international policy boom (1994:4) and reversed previous

    commitments to a large and healthy public sector. Within the space of a few years, policy

    shifted from a reliance on bureaucratic regulation and the use of public enterprise as

    mechanisms for national development, to a new focus on cutting government budgets, self-

    regulation, de-regulation, competition, privatisation and the marketisation of the public sector.

    mailto:[email protected]://www.icaap.org/mailto:[email protected]
  • 7/30/2019 Electronic Journal of Sociology Privatisation

    2/32

    Evidence of this policy reversal in the Australian context is mounting, with studies

    documenting the impact on wages, jobs and conditions (eg. Herd, 1998); on citizenship (eg.

    Salvaris, 1995), on accountability and the provision of information to the consumer (eg.

    Carter, 1998:17); on the fiscal health of the state (eg. Quiggin, 1996; Walker and Walker,

    2000); on welfare (eg. Saunders, 1994; Nevile, 2000); and differentially across the spectrum

    of social groups (eg. Langmore ,1987).

    Policy Studies and the Policy Process

    There have been however, far fewer attempts to analyse this policy reversal, to define its

    characteristics, explain its origins, and theorise its global spread. In part, this lacuna is the

    consequence of the comparatively recent emergence of the trend, for although privatisation,

    commercialisation, and other state-private sector relationships are not new, they have seldom

    previously been entered into with such vigour nor been so widespread (see Collyer et al.,

    2001). However this theoretical black hole may also stem from problems within policy

    studies itself. Despite the central importance of policy to the everyday life of the citizen, to

    the structure and functioning of institutions, and to the exchange relations between countries,

    the theory of policy has been a peculiarly undeveloped area of scholarship. In particular,

    sociology, like anthropology, has in many ways failed to contribute to the study of policy

    making and policy processes (for a discussion of the potential role for anthropology, see

    Shore and Wright, 1997), though it must be acknowledged that sociology has invested heavily

    in exploring the impact of both social and public policy, particularly on vulnerable social

    groups.

    This sociological deficit in policy studies is reflected in the way privatisation has become

    defined in public discourse. Though there remains some contention over the concept (Thynne,

    1995:3-4), the prevailing view is of privatisation as an economic or fiscal technique of

    government, fundamentally concerned with the transfer ofassets or activities from the public

    to the private sector (eg. Domberger and Piggott, 1986:145). While there is much truth to thisdefinition, it remains an extremely narrow and one-dimensional view, with an exclusive focus

    on financial transactions and exchanges. More pertinent, at this point, is that this mainstream

    definition assumes a particular kind of policy process in operation, in which privatisation has

    been a rational, intentional, coherent, policy response to a fiscal problem. In the typology

    devised by Dudley and Vidovich, this conception of policy would be akin to the rational

    comprehensive model in which the best course of action and the public interest is determined

    through a rational, linear, neutral process of collective decision making (1995:16-18).

  • 7/30/2019 Electronic Journal of Sociology Privatisation

    3/32

    The rational perspective also presents policy making as a process which relies upon, and is the

    application of, rational techniques such as the gathering of empirical data, the systematic

    clarification of aims and objectives, cost-benefit analysis, economic modelling, and impact

    simulation. In the policy literature, many documents offer flow charts and diagrams setting

    out the stages of privatisation, often beginning with feasibility studies and options papers

    and moving through to legislative and organisational changes before the sale process begins

    (for an example, see Walshe and Daffern, 1990:90-3). Such analyses often confuse the ideal

    case with the actual processes, and assume policy makers will, and have, learned from past

    experiences. For example Domberger states that Governments now have sufficient

    experience in the sale of public sector assets to avoid unintentional underpricing (1995: 44).

    There is also little evidence that policy makers use rational techniques or existing research

    evidence when making policy choices (Jansson, 2000:47) particularly in the case of

    privatisation (Kay and Thompson, 1986:31; Collyer, 1997; Collyer et al., 2001).

    This rational perspective on policy is highly problematic. It is steeped within a positivist

    epistemology, proceeding on the premise that there is a readily identifiable problem which

    can be addressed through policy (Bacci, 1999:17). Yet this is how privatisation is widely

    presented and understood. For instance, at a time when the claims by pro-privatisation

    advocates were at their most articulate in Britain, the Financial Secretary to the Treasury

    stated The privatisation program is coherent, and well thought out (Moore, 1986:93). Claims

    continue to be made that privatisation will address a very diverse range of problems such as

    economic inefficiency and lack of innovation in the public sector, political interference in

    the management of enterprises, unemployment, trade union power, welfare dependency, big

    government, and the high cost of public services - to name just a few. Within the rationalist

    perspective on policy, the basis of these claims are rarely questioned. Indeed policy is often

    presented as a rational response to market forces or market problems (eg. Bradley and

    Neja, 1989:12). Sociologically of course, social and economic problems are not fixed

    properties of society but socially constructed, and there is a concern with how only specific

    issues are recognised as a problem and placed on the political agenda (Edelman, 1987).

    The Politics of Privatisation

    Although the orthodox, economic definition of privatisation is virtually hegemonic, other

    discipline areas have sought to develop alternative understandings of privatisation. For

    example Feigenbaum and Henig (1994), Gormley (1994), and Chamberlin and Jackson (1987)

    see privatisation as fundamentally a political phenomenon rather than economic,

    administrative, or fiscal. From this perspective, privatisation is a policy strategy used to shift

    power between various constituencies, alter the structural capacity of government and its

  • 7/30/2019 Electronic Journal of Sociology Privatisation

    4/32

    responsibilities, realign and restructure decision making and institutions, and/or create new

    interest groups and classes (cf. Henig et al., 1988; Samson, 1994:90).

    These analyses throw light on the political aspects of the policy process, and generally avoid

    many of the pitfalls of the rationalist approach by acknowledging the diverse aims of

    government and the range of interest groups that have input into the policy process. In

    particular, they avoid the fallacy of assuming policy to be the consequence of a normative

    consensus between key individuals, and expressing a shared set of societal goals to which all,

    particularly the state, aspire. This normative perspective of the policy process is one that has

    come to us from TH Marshalls (1981) conception of the welfare system, in which policy is

    the end product of an harmonious interaction between market economy, government and

    welfare institutions, each defined by their distinctive value-realm. This normative focus is

    extremely limited (Mishra, 1982:106). Without a theory of interest group struggle andcompetition, Marshall cannot explain the dominance of some value positions, and it

    problematically assigns values and goals to organisations and institutions. Despite these

    faults, the normative approach is prevalent, with many studies presuming that privatisation

    policy is selected in order to achieve key goals such as equity, efficiency, reliability and/or

    consumer choice (see for example, Wanasinghe, 1991; Waters, 1987; Gormley, 1994:230).

    As already stated, an alternative to the consensus approach is to probe deeply into the nature

    of the nation state and the policy process. Here it is proposed that policy is a fundamentally

    political activity, that politics are not confined to the final, implementation stage of the policy

    cycle (Dalton et al., 1996:106,118). Furthermore, the state is itself an arena of political

    activity. It is not conceived as a neutral mechanism through which the will of the people is

    expressed. Instead government often fails to act in the interests of the people as a whole, may

    act in its own interests, and policy outcomes generally accord with the interests of the more

    powerful members of society. This allows us to understand why privatisation policies might

    be adopted by governments even where rational economic theory suggests it is not always the

    best financial or economic solution; why privatisation is used even though the proceeds of a

    sale may not cover more than a few years of dividends from the public enterprise; why it is

    used even when the newly private firm demands a costly indemnity against previously

    incurred risk; and why it is used where the costs of regulating the new company clearly

    outweigh tax revenues returned to government.

    This political approach acknowledges that power and resources are not equally distributed

    across society, and that competition between these groups does not in itself prevent the

    concentration of power within segments of society (cf. Bachrach and Baratz, 1977). Instead

    power is unevenly distributed, and, despite the democratic processes of government, well

    organised groups are able to influence public policy according to their interests (eg. see Dahl,

  • 7/30/2019 Electronic Journal of Sociology Privatisation

    5/32

    1984). When used in empirical studies of privatisation, this theoretical approach is able to

    reveal the multitude of interest groups which shape the policy process. For instance Kay and

    Thompson found in their study of privatisation in the UK that the most influential interest

    group in the decision making process is the senior management of the potentially privatised

    enterprise (1986:29), and Gupta reveals that those who gain most from privatisation are the

    political leaders, bureaucrats and the newly emergent capitalists (1996:46). Not surprisingly

    perhaps, this group of studies tends to be highly critical of government rhetoric and pro-

    privatisation discourse, disputing claims of greater cost efficiency, reduced administrative

    costs, or a reduction in government outlays (eg. Gupta, 1996:46-7).

    Policy and Pluralism

    Despite its strengths, this approach to policy via the pluralist perspective has its (well

    documented) shortcomings. One of these is the way it places an emphasis on policy as the

    outcome of the action of key individuals. Here the underlying causes of privatisation can be

    located in the differing motivations of key actors, each of whom has a specific goal and the

    means to make policy through attracting supporters or by strategically altering the rules of

    the game so that other actors must reassess their interests and strategies (eg. Feigenbaum and

    Henig, 1994). Where it is used simplistically, pluralism may portray governments as having

    human characteristics such as desires and objectives. For example:

    Since the government was eager to privatize ... [and] fearful ofbeing accused of selling outto the private sector ... (Campo-Flores, 1994:241).

    Although governments in developing countries are eager to increase the efficient use of theresources that they have at hand ... (Vernon, 1987:7).

    More sophisticated uses of pluralism generally avoid such reductionism, though they do have

    the tendency to conflate the various concepts of motivation, intentions, objectives and

    interests, and fail to maintain a distinction between objectives, which are publicly

    announced by the government in power, with objectives that are analytic constructionsimposed by the theorist (eg. Ernst, 1994:81,83; Whitfield, 1992:129). Pluralist studies also

    remain open to the charge of offering a one dimensional perspective on power. This is the

    very criticism levelled by Lukes (1974), who reminds us that policy rarely conforms to the

    intentions of particular individuals, but results from collective forces and social arrangements.

    Power is multifaceted, yet pluralism focuses only on observable acts of power, ignoring the

    way in which action can be indirectly manipulated by the creation of a set of circumstances

    that favour one set of preferences over another. Pluralist perspectives ultimately ignore the

    impact of underlying social arrangements upon which the struggle for dominance is playedout. Applying Lukes expos on power to privatisation policy, Samson argues pluralism

  • 7/30/2019 Electronic Journal of Sociology Privatisation

    6/32

    focuses only on policy decisions that are on the political agenda and fails to investigate how

    agendas are narrowed to prevent the consideration of alternative proposals (1994:81). Thus

    we can see that a pluralist conception of the policy process fails to offer an adequate analysis

    of privatisation because it reduces power to the interaction between public figures, revealing

    only the public face of power. As such it is in danger of over-rationalising the policy

    process, presenting the outcome as the consequence of rational, intentional, and conscious

    choices of individuals and groups.

    Policy and Functionalism

    Interestingly, when we seek to theorise policy change (ie. the rise in popularity of

    privatisation), rather than explain the policy process itself, privatisation research is often

    implicitly functionalist rather than pluralist in orientation. Here specific policy initiatives are

    thought to result not from particular group interests and pressures but as a consequence of

    becoming functionally necessary for societies that have reached a certain stage in their

    development (Hall et al., 1975:6). Here privatisation policy is conceived as an inevitable

    response to a societal need or prerequisite. Although it is rarely explained how this need

    came to be recognised (or by whom), the policy literature is replete with functionalist

    examples. Some imply that privatisation has become functionally necessary as a consequence

    of normative or cultural prerequisites, while for others it has been an inevitable response to

    new economic circumstances. For instance, Vernon proposes that privatisation occurs when

    the time is ripe (1987:2); and Foster contends that privatisation is a response to the need to

    reduce public expenditure and public borrowing in a period of severe economic crisis

    (1994:493; see also Gupta, 1996:42; Flora and Heidenheimer, 1984).

    Privatisation as a result of economic need is the more common of the functionalist

    explanations. This is perhaps understandable given the prevailing emphasis on privatisation as

    an economic or financial transaction. The idea here is that as a consequence of the global and

    national economic downturn after the oil crisis of the early 1970s, governments found itincreasingly difficult to continue their support for an extensive welfare state and a large public

    sector: and were thus driven to privatisation and other market oriented reforms (eg.

    Franzway et al., 1989:24). This version assumes a) that policy is a function of economic

    circumstances, b) that all countries were facing the same problems, and c) that they all

    adopted privatisation as the solution. Yet the national differences are vast. For example,

    where British public enterprises were restrained from capital expansion, Australian enterprises

    were relatively efficient and endowed with flexible borrowing regimes (cf. Steel and Heald,

    1982:337-4; Productivity Commission, 1998). Thus while some argument might be made that

    Britain was forced to privatise, this need was not part of the Australian experience.

  • 7/30/2019 Electronic Journal of Sociology Privatisation

    7/32

    Moreover, such a proposition assumes privatisation to be a mechanism for reducing

    government outlays and is thus the best policy option in a time of scarcity. As yet there is no

    conclusive evidence that privatisation has decreased government outlays, or that privatisation

    is a more cost efficient means to provide essential services. This argument is discussed more

    extensively below, but it is necessary at this point to note the tautological problem inherent

    within this perspective: that is, the idea that we can argue a particular social practice occurred

    because of the outcome that it subsequently produced (or claimed to produce).

    Although functionalism has been criticised for this logical fault in regards to many areas of

    social life, it appears to have been rarely tackled in social policy: possibly there is an

    assumption that policy practices are different from other social practices, enabling us draw an

    immediate and inevitable causal link between intention, strategy and outcome. Sociologically

    this proposition cannot be sustained. Policy practice, like other social practices, needs to beunderstood as historically produced and socially contingent. Thus an answer to the puzzle of

    privatisation cannot be founded upon financial or other system imperatives, nor upon claims

    based upon the subsequent outcomes of policy initiatives.

    Policy and Ideational Theories of Change

    Among the alternatives to pluralist and functionalist theories of privatisation, are ideational

    theories of policy change and policy spread. Here we find suggestions that privatisation

    results from an intellectual disillusionment with the Keynesian approach (eg. Hall, 1993; Bell,

    1997:25), a response to the fall of the command economies such as the USSR (eg. Gupta,

    1996:39), the cross-national adoption of policy fashions (eg. Ikenberry, 1990), and the rise

    of doctrines of economic rationalism and neo-classical economics (eg. Ernst, 1998; Self,

    1990:19, 21).

    There is much to be said for a theory of privatisation and policy change which depend, at least

    in part, on the role of ideas, values and beliefs. A new paradigm has indeed emerged in

    which privatisation is portrayed as a politically neutral process of economic exchange. Within

    this paradigm there is a new moral imperative to remove public and collective forms of

    ownership, and to seek social progress and efficiency through market mechanisms. This

    package of ideas and beliefs, like all ideas and beliefs, are influential because they structure

    the terms of political discourse (Bell, 1997:24). However, it is difficult to find empirical

    support for an ideational theory of change: as even when there was strong presidential support

    for small government during the 1980s in the USA, there were few asset sales (see Henig et

    al., 1988:477,450). It is also difficult to build a theory of privatisation around the role of ideas.

    An ideational theory of policy change offers an explanation only in terms of a policy

  • 7/30/2019 Electronic Journal of Sociology Privatisation

    8/32

    fashion, implying an innocent or accidental pattern, as if other policy initiatives might

    equally have emerged. Missing from such a conception is a sense of the social context that

    shapes the reservoir of ideas from which policy makers draw, and within which problems

    and opportunities for action occur. Thus in order to explain the systematic emergence of

    privatisation in countries that are economically, culturally, and politically diverse, ideas must

    be linked theoretically to social practices and social structures.

    Policy, Ideology, and Discourse

    Two concepts which potentially link the two realms are ideology and discourse, with the

    latter tending to be a fashionable replacement for the former. A handful of studies have

    emerged recently which imply that privatisation is the result of new (or revived) discourses or

    ideologies concerning the role of the state and the relative merits of the private and public

    sectors. For example Michael Pusey suggests there has been a fundamental change of

    orientation towards civil society and culture (1991:224) and elsewhere it is suggested that

    privatisation is the result of the adoption of fashionable ideologies (eg. Walker and Walker,

    2000; Mansfield, 1987). These observations are not without foundation. It has been noted that

    rather than a rational and careful consideration of the evidence, many studies of privatisation

    merely assert the greater efficiency of the private sector, and fail to offer compelling evidence

    to support their generalisations (cf. Mansfield, 1987:75; Heald, 1983:308). It is not difficult to

    find evidence of simplistic assumptions and assertions of this nature within the literature.

    For instance:

    A state entity cannot be as efficient as a private entity in the production of the same output.We know that (Waters, 1987:55).

    The generalization that private is more efficient than public is a reasonable enoughassumption (Vernon, 1987:7).

    ... government-owned enterprises perform poorly, provide an inadequate service or product,and serve as a burden on the taxpayer (Campo-Flores, 1994:235-6).

    These and similar claims are endlessly repeated by advocates of privatisation, often with little

    evaluation of the evidence for the relative efficiencies of the two sectors. Although there are

    methodological difficulties with the comparative evaluation of such claims (see Collyer

    1996), well designed and independent studies show that neither sector is inherently more

    efficient (eg. Martin and Parker, 1997; Goodman and Loveman, 1991:35). What most

    comparative studies of the two sectors generally fail to emphasise however, is the different

    functions of the private and public sectors, and the failure of the private sector to perform all

    previous functions of the divested public sector unit, leaving the state the least profitable areas

    to assign to other units within the bureaucracy (and without the capacity to fund these

  • 7/30/2019 Electronic Journal of Sociology Privatisation

    9/32

    activities through cross-subsidisation). Such an analysis should render the private/public

    comparison invalid. However the new pro-privatisation paradigm has been so effective in its

    message that any current defence of the public sector is considered illegitimate, out of date,

    and utterly misplaced. Rationally produced evidence which stands contrary to the paradigm is

    rejected and it is clear that a process is operating in which the truth, or the possibility of

    discovering the truth, is being systematically obscured.

    For some, this process is regarded as ideology, for others it is discourse. Unfortunately,

    these concepts are rarely explicitly defined, and often embedded within an ideational concept

    of social change where they are assumed to refer to a set of ideas or beliefs, or to the

    communication of these ideas and beliefs. Indeed the words are often used inter-changeably

    with rhetoric or doctrine (eg. Shore and Wright, 1997:18; Agger, 1998:8,19,23). These

    definitions propose that discourses and ideologies have no material or observable existence:there is only the text itself. This prioritising of ideational phenomena makes it difficult to

    adequately theorise the relationship between language and lived experience, and moreover,

    social change cannot be explained. Only within Marxism is ideology defined differently. Here

    it is a set of beliefs which serves the interests of its proponents at the expense of other social

    groups (see for example, Hughes et al., 1995:38). This definition separates ideologies from

    other common or prevalent sets of ideas, because they are fundamentally connected to the

    activities of elites and interest groups as these seek to secure their own interests (cf. Marx and

    Engels, 1976:67).

    Policy and Marxism

    There are only isolated examples of research on privatisation which use the concept of

    ideology in its fully theorised, Marxist, and specifically Gramscian sense, where its definition

    includes the customs, practices and behaviours which reflect, consciously or unconsciously,

    ideas about society and the nature of reality (cf. Navarro, 1982:46). Here, ideology is the

    organic cement which does not simply express the reality of the economic base, but isconstituted by both social practices and institutional arrangements, and thus bridges both

    structure and superstructure (Daly, 1999:69). One of these studies is Samsons (1994), where

    this conceptual framework is used to critique the prevailing, economic definition of

    privatisation. Sampson regards this definition as part of an ideology of privatisation, in which

    people are coerced into accepting a particular set of policy strategies. Although these policies

    are harmful to some social groups this facet of privatisation is conveniently obscured by

    another: a view that privatisation is a politically neutral, economic transaction. Beyond this

    however, privatisation is more than the mere sale of public assets or the contracting-out of

    services, it also involves public sector and welfare cuts, trends toward intensive market

  • 7/30/2019 Electronic Journal of Sociology Privatisation

    10/32

    commodification, a new emphasis on self-provisioning, and the increased domestic burden

    being placed on women and families. Samson argues that these aspects of privatisation are

    kept hidden from the public, as a broader and more political definition of privatisation would

    have politically negative consequences, revealing the full range of likely effects and

    exposing the yawning gap between the beneficiaries of the policy and those who are harmed

    by its introduction (1994:88-94). Thus for Samson, privatisation is an ideology which is not

    just about ideas but is fully realised in social practices and institutions.

    It is only when the Gramscian version of ideology, or the Foucaultian version of discourse,

    are used, that we can successfully theorise policy change. If either is simply a system of, or

    communication of, ideas, then there is no explanation for how these ideas change over time. It

    is only when we use these concepts to refer to relationships between ideas, practices and

    structures, that we can see that ideas and policies change because they are always part of anongoing struggle: that there is always conflict and dissent and a struggle for meaning and

    dominance. And this social activity produces change - or perhaps rather, it is the process of

    change in action.

    Despite its appeal, few studies have examined policy change from this perspective: that is, as

    a consequence of class conflict and dissent. Indeed the concept of class - once a major tool of

    sociology - has currently fallen out of favour. Not only has it become unfashionable to use

    class, but there is a particular reluctance to use it as an analytic rather than descriptive tool in

    policy analysis (Mooney, 2000:157,161-2).

    Policy and Capitalism

    As a consequence of the demise of class analysis, the more common conflict approach is to

    examine policy actors in terms of interest groups, often referring to them as stakeholders

    (eg. Gupta, 1996; Chamberlin and Jackson, 1987; Henig et al., 1988) or as players (eg. Kerr

    and Savelsberg, 2001:25). In most cases, these studies employ a pluralist framework in which

    class denotes the characteristics of a group of similar individuals: they rarely refer to class as

    an element of a social system. This means they are unable to explain possible links between

    the interest groups and other developments in the social system (such as globalisation). Policy

    is presented as an adhoc process of struggle between diverse interest groups and taken up by

    the many national policy communities as a new policy fashion and coincidently imitating

    the policies of other, apparently, successful nations. They do not show the possibility of

    privatisation as a class project, in which government restraints on the market system are

    systematically eased or removed, and where government activities are depoliticised by

    transferring them to the market. Nor do they show how privatisation policy might alter the

  • 7/30/2019 Electronic Journal of Sociology Privatisation

    11/32

    power balance between classes: such as in Britain where privatisation was directed at

    curtailing the power of groups such as the medical profession, coal miners and steel workers.

    This is because the balance of power between classes is not altered by changes in power

    between different interest groups. Thus they are clearly unable to demonstrate how

    privatisation maintains a system of class inequality, by taking from the majority of the

    population their collective access to, and ownership of, public resources, while

    simultaneously enriching already privileged groups.

    Where class is used in an analytic or relational sense, these problems do not emerge. Notable

    here is the analysis of privatisation by Samson (1994). Samson sidesteps the typological

    problem presented by pluralism, where privatisation is a class policy only where there has

    been an intention to alter class boundaries and where these projects are undertaken with

    little thought to ideology (Feigenbaum and Henig, 1994:195, 200). Samson proposes insteadthat privatisation is always about class. He defines privatisation as a cultural and political

    mission, in which a package of ideas about individual liberty and consumer choice is

    intertwined with strategies and techniques for the management of the national economy. This

    package of ideas and practices alters established relationships between both groups and,

    importantly, between classes, and as such it can be understood as an hegemonic project

    aimed at altering consciousness and power relationships (Samson, 1994: 79,90).

    Samsons thesis on the class basis of privatisation rests on an interpretation of Marxism in

    which the motivations of individual policy actors, and the characteristics of these actors (eg.

    social background, level of education or past career choices) play little part. Instead this

    approach concentrates on identifying key groups according to the objective effects of their

    actions (eg. Therborn, 1982:229), and emphasises the structural and institutional restraints

    placed on these policy actors rather than on their capacity for agency (see also Deacon and

    Mann, 1999). It is a level of analysis which explains macro-level factors that can play a

    major role in shaping the environment in which individuals behave and in which policy

    choices are made (Bell, 1997:41).

    This approach is however, problematic in the way it entirely collapses the individuals and

    groups within the policy making community into the institution of the state. It assumes that

    politicians choose privatisation because the state has a commitment to the maintenance and

    reproduction of capitalist social relations: that the interests of the policy makers and the state

    are the same (Mooney, 2000:165). The reductionism of this approach has been extensively

    discussed elsewhere (see Hay, 1999:164-71, on the Miliband-Poulantzas Debate), and does

    not need to be revisited here. Nevertheless some further points need to be made, given that the

    recent global shift toward privatisation can only be explained within a coherent theory of the

    policy process, and specifically, the policy process within capitalist societies.

  • 7/30/2019 Electronic Journal of Sociology Privatisation

    12/32

    From an orthodox Marxist position the state is merely an agent of capital, and policy is fully

    determined by class interests. This is the Althusserian interpretation of Marx, and it relies on

    the view that capitalism has a hidden structure that generates, in a mechanistic way, its forms

    and surface movements (Jessop, 2001b:3). It is a concept of structural causality wherein the

    economic base of the society determines the political system, and thus the realm of policy. In

    its favour, this framework offers a strong challenge to pluralism with its plethora of unrelated

    stakeholder groups each acting to secure their own interests, where policy can be reduced to

    individual intentions and motivations, and where policy outcomes show little overall

    patterning or systemic bias. It also offers a challenge to neo-statism, where the state is

    presumed to be an autonomous entity, fully able to pursue its own interests (eg. Dandeker,

    1990; Skocpol, 1985); and to autopoietic theories of the state, in which the state is portrayed

    as a self-producing, self-referential, self-controlling political system (cf: Jessop, 2001a:9).

    Nevertheless, this orthodox Marxist position is untenable because of the way it limits the roleof policy makers to agents of capitalism, collapses their actions into the logic of the whole,

    and theorises the policy process as a direct outcome of the logic of capitalist accumulation.

    Fortunately there is an alternative Marxist interpretation of the policy process. Here there is a

    rejection of economic reductionism, and a re-focusing on the complex interplay of structure

    and agency (Mooney, 2000:162). This is an interpretation of that within Marxism which is,

    Daly argues, already postmodern (1999:65). Marx tells us in the Grundrisse that everything

    that has a fixed form appears merely as a vanishing moment in the movement of society:

    The conditions and objectifications of the process ... are themselves equally moments of it,and its only subjects are individuals, but individuals in mutual relationships, which theyequally reproduce and produce anew (1973:712).

    This passage highlights the idea of agency as fundamental to any notion of social structure,

    and points toward a solution in the way it integrates structure and superstructure, economy,

    state, culture and ideology into a relational, rather than just a causal, schema (Daly, 1999:69).

    This interpretation of Marxism shares some similarities with the approach to the state taken

    by Gramsci (1971). Gramsci provided an analysis of the institutional form of the state, how

    this influences class struggle, and how this political struggle in turn shapes the institutional

    form of the state. This method of analysis places emphasis on the state as an arena of action,

    but not one which is separate from capital or other social relations, nor one which is fully

    determined by capitalism. Instead the emphasis is on the reciprocal nature of the relationship

    between base and superstructure (Jessop, 2001b:4). The Gramscian capitalist state is not

    necessary, but contingent, and its actions are political and hegemonic, not determined or

    economistic - even though it advances the interests of capital (in Marsh, 1999:327-8). This

    reciprocity of state and capital is important because it allows for the possibility of a capitalisteconomic system connecting with a policy community, in which policy is often, but not

  • 7/30/2019 Electronic Journal of Sociology Privatisation

    13/32

    always, capitalist in character or impact. Policy decisions may be made in the interests of

    policy makers themselves, may assist specific capitalists, and sometimes may assist the

    working class by protecting employment conditions or negotiating public access to privately

    owned goods (cf. Collyer et al., 2001). Thus policy is produced through a process of social

    struggle. The policy system is historical, unstable, contingent and contested.

    What then, is the specific relationship between policy and capitalism? How is it that, as

    Gramsci argued, the economic and political orders of society are coupled into an historic

    bloc? (cf: Jessop, 2001a). For both Jessop and Harvey, the answer is found in the

    construction of capitalism itself. As an historically developed system of social relations,

    capitalism comprises both a system of economic relations and a system of political relations.

    The state has a crucial role in the construction of economic forms of capital, and in how

    capital is organised and circulated (Harvey, 1982:281-2). Or, as Jessop argues, the capitalrelation is incomplete and indeterminate, and relies, in a rather unstable way, on extra-

    economic conditions (2001b:8). And because capitalism cannot reproduce itself purely

    through market forces, the system of political relations is a part of the constitution and

    regularisation of capital accumulation (Jessop, 2001c:9).

    Policy Actors

    It is with this framework that we can better understand the relations between policy and

    capitalism. In a capitalist social system, policy reflects capitalist relations not because policy

    is determined and unfolding according to a teleological plan or logic of necessity, but because

    policy is created as a result of human behaviour and interaction in the complex interplay

    between the political and the economic systems. And it cannot be created without policy

    actors.

    Throughout the 1970s and 80s, sociological analysis of policy focused on the structural

    qualities of the social system, and was largely silent on the role of actors. Perhaps this might

    have been, in part at least, a reaction to the increasing dominance of a neo-liberal discourse in

    which the victim was blamed for their own plight. More recently however, there has also been

    a rejection of over-arching structural categories and a developing interest in the role of actors

    and active human subjects in the policy process (Deacon and Mann, 1999:417; Mann, 1992).

    This has rejuvenated the search for theoretical frameworks that can explain the role of policy

    makers in the policy process. Past attempts at linking agency with structural levels of analysis

    through locating specific groups within the class structure have been theoretically

    problematic: as Narravo (1978:86-7) and Johnson (1972) discovered when they sought to

    empirically demonstrate the class location of the professions. They found they could only

  • 7/30/2019 Electronic Journal of Sociology Privatisation

    14/32

    assert the connection as a truth through theoretical analysis, because at the empirical level,

    the task involved conflating occupational or professional groups of individuals with an

    abstract notion of class (eg. Willis, 1983:13).

    The same reasoning applies if instead of investigating the class location of the professions we

    seek to empirically examine the class position or role of policy makers. Again the problem

    would be that policy makers do not constitute a class. This is a diverse group: policy (in its

    widest sense) is produced by individuals and groups from many occupations and institutions:

    media owners and employees, bureaucrats and politicians, owners and managers of private

    firms, philanthropic organisations, community representatives etc. Class locations are mixed:

    employees, owners of capital, petite bourgeois. Consequently, using an orthodox Marxist

    analysis we cannot empirically demonstrate the class basis of privatisation without conflating

    the concept of the group with the concept of class.

    What is needed then, is a theoretical framework which bridges the empirical world of policy

    making with the conceptual and analytical structures of the state, class and capitalism. This

    framework must not be reductionist, it must not seek complete closure or full determinism,

    and, most importantly, it must link macro and micro levels of analysis to make sense of the

    relationship between the activities of the individual (and the group) and structural formations.

    One answer to this problem is the policy network approach.

    Policy Networks

    There are a variety of approaches to policy network analysis. Some analyses tend to collapse

    the notion of a policy network with that of a policy community or policy culture, and as such

    emphasise a sharing of values and collective goals (eg. Marsh and Rhodes, 1992; Putnam,

    1995). For example, Pross (1992:119) defines a policy network as a group of individuals with

    similar outlooks and values and a common approach to policy. As such, it excludes actors

    with alternative perspectives or different policy agendas. Moreover, although values and

    norms are an important concern within the policy making process, a sole focus on this aspect

    of social life results in a lack of attention being paid to the impact of the state (and other

    institutions) on the policy process (Maloney et al., 2000). It also fails to include the role of

    groups and organisations in the policy process, as it is problematic to assign a mindset or

    worldview to a group or organisation, and, importantly, it overlooks the possibility that

    policy outcomes may be an amalgam or compromise of various positions, views, and values.

    Coleman and Skogstad take a different view. They argue that a policy network is a concept

    reserved for describing the properties that characterise the relationships among the particular

    set of actors that form around an issue of importance to the polic y community (Coleman and

  • 7/30/2019 Electronic Journal of Sociology Privatisation

    15/32

    Skogstad, 1990:26). The focus of the policy network approach is thus the relationships among

    the actors involved in the policy making process, rather than the values or characteristics of

    the actors.

    This reading of the policy network avoids the problem of trying to ascertain the intent or

    motivation of participants in the policy process, and enables a greater focus on relationships,

    particular relations of power, within the network. This form of network analysis has been used

    in conjunction with a pluralist perspective, where there has been an examination of the role of

    interest groups in policy process. Saward (1990) for example, examines the nature of

    resources held or captured by different interest groups, and how these influence their capacity

    to shape policy; and Whiteley and Winyard (1987) propose a typology in which policy actors

    can be characterised according to their lobbying strategies.

    There is no inherent reason however, why pluralism must be the only, or dominant theoretical

    approach to network analysis. Pluralism doesnt offer an adequate explanation for the way

    policy initiatives, such as privatisation, both reflect existing inequalities and become

    structured into the operation of social institutions, thus ensuring a policy regime will become

    entrenched and resistant to further change. One attempt at a solution for this problem has been

    the path dependency approach (eg. Berman, 1998; Goldstone, 1998; Wilsford 1994; Greener

    2002a, 2002b). This approach assumes that policy reflects established regulatory regimes,

    entrenched institutional positions, established industrial structures, and past government-

    industry relationships. This entrenchment of institutional patterns ensures policy becomes

    fixed and difficult to change, so that policy development is likely to be incremental rather

    than innovative. It argues that historical legacies determine future policy trajectories. As

    Lfgren and Benner (2003:27) suggest, path dependency perspectives emphasise the

    stickiness of institutional arrangements: once a nation has developed a particular

    institutional set-up, it is difficult to change tack.

    The path dependency approach provides an explanation for the apparent stability of a policy

    regime: that it is the unique configuration of institutional relationships in each national settingwhich determine the policy outcome. Unfortunately, this approach doesnt account very well

    for policy innovation: and this is important if we are to theorise the recent radical shift toward

    privatisation. Empirically we know that policy designs are not created and then simply fixed

    in time, but continue to be contested and remain malleable (Alexander, 2001). And although

    institutional legacies can restrict change, social and institutional resources are also combined

    in creative ways to produce new policy solutions and directions (Neilson, Jessop and Hausner,

    1995:3-46). Moreover, cross-national comparisons have found that path dependency is not a

    good predictor of policy direction, particularly when countries, each with very different

    institutional histories, are facing profound pressures for radical change (Lfgren and Benner,

  • 7/30/2019 Electronic Journal of Sociology Privatisation

    16/32

    2003:27). Even the idea of conjunctures, offered by Wilsford (1994) to explain policy

    change, is not of assistance here. Wilsford argues that structural forces curtail policy

    processes, keeping policy to established pathways, while conjunctures enable deviations and

    radical innovations. The established pathways may occur initially as the result of quite

    random variables (Wilsford, 1994:253), but then, like the QWERTY keyboard, channel

    present and further policy along certain paths (ibid:256). Conjunctures, on the other hand,

    are the fleeting coming together of a number of diverse elements into a new, single

    combination (ibid:257), providing incentives for radical change.

    The main difficulty with this approach is that Wilsford has no theoretical framework to assist

    with distinguishing between factors or conditions that are likely to inhibit change, and those

    which encourage innovation. His selection of conjunctures is ultimately adhoc, and this

    produces dispute from others. For instance Greener (2002a:170-1) contests Wilsfordsselection of critical conjunctures to explain radical policy change for Britains National

    Health Service, arguing that, amongst other factors, Wilsford places too much emphasis on

    Margaret Thatchers authority, and on the disorganisation of the medical profession during the

    salient period. As Greener argues, the conjuncture argument seems to place an excessive

    burden onto fate and does not give us a coherent theoretical underpinning for how actors

    are constrained or break free of structures (2002b:615).

    The solution then, is to disregard both the pluralist and the path-dependency approaches in

    favour of a combination of class and network analysis within the parameters set out in the

    above discussion. This means employing a combination of the strengths of network analysis,

    with its emphasis on the relationships within policy networks, and those of class analysis,

    with its capacity to make sense of the continuing, asymmetric relations between actors in the

    policy making process. With this combination, we can reveal the way that policy networks,

    and their outcomes, are shaped by the class system at both the national and international

    levels.

    What would such a combined approach look like? We might take the example of theCommonwealth Employment Service (CES). This was an agency established in 1947, initially

    corporatised, and then fully privatised in 1998. Over its fifty years of operation there were

    several attempts to privatise it, most notably perhaps by the McMahon government, which

    sought to allow private employment agencies entry to the job placement system. Its demise

    began with the publication of the controversial Norgard Report (1977) which recommended

    systematic changes in the operation of the CES, and the successful elimination of the

    Professional Employment Service by the Fraser Coalition government. The end of the

    organisation was secured with the passage of legislation in 1994 under the Hawke-Keating

    Labour government, to allow the introduction of private sector competition. These changes

  • 7/30/2019 Electronic Journal of Sociology Privatisation

    17/32

    prepared the way for the later full privatisation and dismantling of the CES under the Howard

    Coalition government. Announced in August 1996, the CES ceased to function in its old form

    in November 1997, interim arrangements were put into place, and the new Job Network

    emerged in May 1998. Heralded under the rhetoric of enhancing consumer choice and

    introducing the efficiencies of market competition, the new service (estimated at the time to

    be worth approximately $AUS1.7 billion), offered via tender, contracts in which agencies

    would be paid by government to place individuals into jobs. Over 300 contracts were signed

    with private (for-profit) enterprises, community organisations, and one public organisation,

    Employment National. The privatisation of the CES is a typical example of the emergent form

    of privatisation for policy delivery, in which private operators distribute funds or perform

    services that were once the responsibility of government.

    . network analysis would reveal the characteristics of, and relationships between constituentsof the network, showing for example, their degree of autonomy or inter-dependence (as it

    does in the work of Ornstein (2003) on Canadian corporate networks, or the work of Burt

    (1983) on the market relationships between various industries). In the case of the CES,

    network analysis would also indicate the prominent role of religious organisations in the new

    Job Network, and the formation of alliances between agencies (particularly in the early

    period, where many were without adequate skilled staff or resources to fulfill the terms of

    their contracts). Class analysis on the other hand, would highlight the asymmetry in the

    relationships of power between capital and labour, showing how privatisation shifted the

    balance to favour employers and capital. For example, with the demise of the CES we see the

    undermining of union power, as 5000 unionised, permanent public servants lost their jobs and

    were shifted into casualised positions in the private sector, many working on contracts

    offering poorer and less secure working conditions, and most no longer represented by a

    union.

    A combinednetwork/class analysis however, would reveal the way the policy networks are

    shaped by the class system. To focus once again on the new Job Network that emerged in

    May 1998, a combined approach shows, first of all, the way in which the state works with

    capital to initiate and support the privatisation process. Evidence of this is found in the

    awarding of contracts to favour private businesses, particularly those in electoral areas held by

    a member of government. Indeed private job agency sites granted to safe government seats

    were double the number of those in safe Labor seats (Haslem, 2000c). Evidence is also

    provided in the stated intentions of government. In discussing the privatisation of the job

    network, the discourse focuses explicitly on the need to form a social coalition between

    businesses, community organisations and government. This coalition would enable the private

    sector to expand their workforces, develop new business opportunities, and, in return for

  • 7/30/2019 Electronic Journal of Sociology Privatisation

    18/32

    delivering welfare services, enable these entities to put something back into their

    communities (Shanahan, 1999).

    Secondly, the effects of the class system on the network itself are evident in the alliances

    formed to place pressure on government. Some of these are large and formal alliances, such as

    Job Futures, a consortium of 40 agencies; National Employment Services, representing over

    60 agencies; and Jobs Australia, representing 300 delivery organisations. In 1998 these actors

    lobbied for large funding increases of over $AUS1b on the grounds that 80 businesses were

    about to go to the wall (Gratton, 1998; Dore, 1998). These alliances have enabled particular

    agencies to monopolise resources, shape the rules and processes for inclusion and exclusion,

    and ensure that the flow of benefits is toward private capital. As the powerful alliances swung

    into action, they demanded not only large increases in their fees, but a role in the policy

    process. Their demands included a role in designing the terms of subsequent tender rounds, tohave more areas of the job network placed under tender (rather than publicly provided), the

    granting of base grants not tied to the fee-for-service system, and a widening of the

    eligibility criterion to ensure agencies will be paid to service other groups of job seekers

    (Green, 1998; Gratton, 1998). This heavy lobbying from placement agencies had its intended

    effect, with several subsequent overhauls of the infant Job Network, including an additional

    $AUS55m proffered just prior to the election and a further $AUS100m in grants and higher

    payments prior to the second round of contracts (Dore, 1998; Dore et al, 1998).

    Clearly missing from these alliances was Employment National, the one public provider of

    services in the Job Network. This organisation was expected to operate as a corporate entity

    on the same basis as its private sector competitors. The birth of this organisation was a

    difficult one, given that it was the offspring of the previously much larger CES, and began its

    new life with only 10% of its workforce and staff morale at a low ebb (Peake, 1998).

    Moreover, it came into operation in an environment that was fiercely pro-privatisation and

    opposed to government involvement in employment services. A Morgan and Banks opinion

    poll of 3,700 businesses in 1997 indicated the business community was behind the

    privatisation of employment services, with more than half stating they believed privatisation

    would make the system more efficient (Sunday Telegraph, 1997).

    While Employment National was initially provided with a 40% share of government contracts

    (Haslem, 2000a), press coverage of its first year of operation was generally negative, with

    constant demands for its removal from the network via privatisation. The criticism had the

    intended affect, and in the second round, announced at the end of 1999, Employment National

    was awarded only 1% of the contracts (McGregor, 1999). This left the Salvation Army as the

    largest provider, with contracts worth over $AUS280m, and reflect[ed] the Howard

    Governments push to deliver welfare services through community-based organisations,

  • 7/30/2019 Electronic Journal of Sociology Privatisation

    19/32

    particularly the churches [which now] deliver nearly 25% of $AUS700 million worth of

    employment services (Haslem, 2000b). Other reasons given for the demise of the agency

    concerned problems with its tendering strategy, problematic performance, bias and

    politicisation of the tender process (Kelly, 2000; Dore, 1999), and, more pointedly, the

    deliberate destruction of its capacity to function effectively by the government (Haslem,

    2000a; Haslem and Marris, 1999). The agency continues to operate in a limited way with

    government financial support, although the threat of privatisation remains, most of its staff

    have taken redundancy packages, and many of its offices have closed.

    Thirdly, the operation of the network is clearly capitalist in the way it functions to channel

    public funds to the private sector. Despite the stated intentions, these public funds are not

    necessarily given to providers. Ten percent of the businesses that succeeded in obtaining

    contracts perform no employment services, but merely subcontract these to other agencies (cf:Peake, 1998). Interestingly, this sub-contracting is done with the explicit permission of

    government (Taylor, 1998). This case of the capture of public funds by the private sector

    offers support for Jamroziks thesis that the welfare system, and social expenditure more

    generally, has many beneficiaries other than the poor. Jamrozik (2001:51) argues that social

    expenditure also enhances the social functioning of the service provider through the

    provision of wages or salary for middle class occupational groups such as doctors, teachers

    and social workers. Broadening the debate, Jamrozik (2001:49) argues that although not

    usually classified as welfare, public expenditure is also provided to business and industry in

    the form of tax concessions. Extending from this, it is not difficult to see how the private

    sector has, in this and many other cases, managed to obtain a significant level of public funds

    out of the welfare budget. Indeed there has been a massive shift of public funds between the

    private and public sectors in Australia in recent decades, with the Productivity Commission

    estimating that budget handouts to industry in the form of business welfare is now greater

    than $AUS14b, an increase of 15% in the past five years (Marris, 2002). While it may not be

    necessary to support Samsons (1994:79,90) concept of privatisation as an hegemonic

    project - with its underlying notion of a class conspiracy or at least ruling class co-operative

    activity - such cases of privatisation lend support to Taylor Goobys (1997:184) view that the

    pursuit and implementation of privatisation policies have enabled the ruling class to

    articulate its interests more effectively.

    The example of the CES shows that a combined network and class approach throws new light

    on the theory of privatisation. OConnor (1993) has previously argued that state expenditure

    on services and infrastructure is essential to lower production and reproduction costs and to

    ensure the expansion of private industry. Moreover, OConnor argued that one of the

    problems of late capitalism is the tendency for state expenditure on the social expenses ofproduction to increase beyond the states financial capacity, thus increasing the risk of a

  • 7/30/2019 Electronic Journal of Sociology Privatisation

    20/32

    legitimation crisis. Although the capacity of privatisation to reduce state expenditure is

    difficult to ascertain (in part because of the claim that data is commercially sensitive, cf:

    Wright, 1998; Taylor, 1998; Kelly, 2000) and is certainly much disputed (cf: Collyer, 1996;

    Collyer and White, 1997, 2001), nevertheless it can be concluded that privatisation operates at

    two levels. At one level privatisation is ideological. Privatisation is used by the state to make

    it appear as if there is a sharing of social expenditure between the private and public sectors.

    At the level of practice and structure, privatisation is not just a fashionable policy trend, but

    a unique development in late capitalism which enables capital to secure new sources of funds,

    expand business opportunities into areas previously prohibited to private capital (such as

    welfare services), and to expand the commodification process.

    Conclusion

    This paper has traversed much territory and it is time to meld its many strands. We have seen

    how the policy process of privatisation has been inadequately characterised within a

    functionalist framework, leading to a distortion of policy as if it were an inevitable response

    to societal and economic pre-requisites; within a pluralist framework, where the policy

    process is fundamentally political but is theorised, problematically, as arising from individual

    motivations and accidental groupings; within an ideational framework, where policy is

    reduced to fashion and untethered to material life; and within orthodox Marxism, where

    policy is merely derivative of structure. Against these conceptions, this paper has argued that

    the policy process is fundamentally social, historically contingent, and structured by relations

    of power - as is found in all other areas of social life.

    As noted at the start of this paper, policies of privatisation have become commonplace in

    almost all countries over the past few decades. This policy trend, which began in the capitalist

    countries and was largely driven by their agendas, is best explicated in terms of policy

    networks. Such networks are embedded within structures of power relations, where networks

    operate within a framework of institutions and a capitalist global market system. The paperhas shown how particular groupings of policy actors form networks that monopolise the

    policy process and shape the rules and processes for inclusion and exclusion. A combination

    of network and class analysis was used to explain the privatisation boom (the recent

    intensification of privatisation and other pro-market policies), not as a policy fashion but as

    a structural process within which actors agitate for the removal of all government restrictions,

    for the creation of new opportunities and for further privatisation. Thus the process of

    privatisation itself assists with the building of new, powerful alliances demanding greater

    reform, and thus drives further privatisation. In this way we can understand policy change,

    not as an outcome of logical structural imperatives, nor as an adhoc, discursive process, but as

  • 7/30/2019 Electronic Journal of Sociology Privatisation

    21/32

    a social process undertaken by social actors and in accordance with a capitalist social

    structure.

    References

    Agger, B. (1998) Critical Social Theories: An Introduction Colorado:

    Westview Press.

    Alexander, G. (2001) Institutions, Path Dependence, and Democratic

    ConsolidationJournal of Theoretical Politics 13(3):249(22).

    Bacci, C.L. (1999) Women, Policy and Politics London: Sage

    Publications.

    Badie, B. and Birnbaum, B. (1983) The Sociology of the State Chicago:

    University of Chicago Press.

    Bachrach, P. and Baratz, M. (1970) Power and Poverty New York: Oxford

    University Press.

    Baumgartner, F. and Jones, B. (1993)Agendas and Instability in American

    Politics Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Bell, S. (1997) Ungoverning The Economy Melbourne: Oxford University

    Press.

    Benner, T.; Reinicke, W. and Witte, J. (2003) Global Public Policy

    Networks The Brookings Review Washington: Spring 21 (2) 4 pgs.

    Berman, S. (1998) Path Dependency and Political Action: Re-examining

    the Responses to the Depression Comparative Politics 30:379-400.

    Bradley, K. and Nejad, A. (1989)Managing Owners: The National

    Freight Consortium in Perspective Sydney: Cambridge University

    Press.

    Burt, R. (1983) Corporate Profits and Copation Vancouver, University of

    British Columbia Press.

  • 7/30/2019 Electronic Journal of Sociology Privatisation

    22/32

    Campo-Flores, F. (1994) Lessons From Privatization of Argentinas

    National Telephone Company Policy Studies Review 13(3/4):235-48.

    Carter, M. (1998) Case Studies Of Public Hospital PrivatisationHealth

    Issues 56:15-17.

    Chamberlin, J. and Jackson, J. (1987) Privatization as Institutional

    ChoiceJournal of Policy Analysis and Management6(4):586-604.

    Cohen, P. (1968)Modern Social Theory London: Heinemann.

    Collyer, FM. (1996) Measuring Privatisation: An Overview of

    Methodological ApproachesJust Policy Number 7, August. pp. 24-

    34.

    Collyer, F.M. (1997) The Port Macquarie Base HospitalJust Policy

    10:27-39.

    Collyer, F.M; McMaster, J. & Wettenhall, R.W. (2001) Case Studies in

    Australian Public Enterprise DivestmentFiji: University of South

    Pacific Press.

    Collyer, FM. & White, KN. (1997) Enter The Market: Competition,Regulation and Hospital Funding in AustraliaAustralian and New

    Zealand Journal of Sociology 33 (3) November, pp. 344-363.

    Collyer, FM. and White, KN. (2001) Corporate Control of Healthcare in

    Australia Discussion Paper No. 42, Australia Institute, Australian

    National University.

    Coleman, W. and Skogstad, G. (1990) Policy Communities and Policy

    Networks in Coleman, W. and Skogstad, G. (eds) Policy

    Communities and Public Policy in Canada: A Structural Approach

    Toronto: Copp Clark Pittman.

    Dalton, T; Draper, M; Weeks, W. and Wiseman, J. (1996) (eds)Making

    Social Policy in Australia Sydney: Allen and Unwin.

    Daly, G. (1999) Marxism and Postmodernity, in A. Gamble; Marsh, D.

    and Tant, T. (eds)Marxism and Social Science London: Macmillan,pp. 61-84.

  • 7/30/2019 Electronic Journal of Sociology Privatisation

    23/32

    Dandeker, C. (1990) Surveillance, Power and Modernity: Bureaucracy

    and Discipline From 1700 to the Present Day Cambridge: Polity.

    Deacon, A. and Mann, K. (1999) Agency, Modernity and Social Policy

    Journal of Social Policy 28(3):413-35.

    Domberger, S. (1995) What Does Privatisation Achieve? - A Comment

    on Quiggin The Australian Economic Review 2nd Quarter:43-47.

    Domberger, S. and Piggott, J. (1986) Privatization Policies and Public

    Enterprise: A SurveyEconomic Record62 (177):145-62.

    Dorner, D. (2002) The Essential Services Policy Network: Organizational

    Influence in Canadas Information Highway Policy DevelopmentProcessLibrary Quarterly 72(1):27-84.

    Dore, C. (1998) Howards $100m Gift For Job Agencies The Australian

    16th December.

    Dore, C. (1999) Job Network Agency Losses $12m The Australian 9-10

    January.

    Dore, C.; Green, P. and Lunn, S. (1998) $55m Rescue For Ailing JobNetwork The Australian 26 August.

    Dowding, K. (1995) Model or Metaphor? A Critical Review of the Policy

    Network Approach Political Studies XLIII(1):136-58.

    Dudley, J. and Vidovich, L. (1995) The Politics of EducationAustralian

    Educational Review No. 36Melbourne: The Australian Council for

    Educational Research.

    Edelman, M. (1987) Constructing The Political Spectacle Chicago:

    University of Chicago Press.

    Ernst, J. (1994) Whose Utility? Buckingham: Open University Press.

    Ernst, J. (1998) Privatization in Shafritz, JM. (ed)International

    Encyclopedia of Public Policy and Administration Boulder,

    Colorado: Westview Press.

  • 7/30/2019 Electronic Journal of Sociology Privatisation

    24/32

    Feigenbaum, H.R. and Henig, J.R. (1994) The Political Underpinnings Of

    Privatisation: A Typology World Politics 46 (1):185-208.

    Flora, P. and Heidenheimer, A. (1984) The Development of Welfare States

    in Europe and America New Jersey: Transaction Books.

    Franzway, S. Court, D. and Connell, R.W. (1989) Staking A Claim

    Sydney: Allen and Unwin.

    Gains, F. (2003) Executive Agencies in Government: The Impact of

    Bureaucratic Networks on Policy OutcomesJournal of Public Policy

    23(1):55-79.

    Goldstone, J. (1998) Initial Conditions, General Laws, Path-Dependence,and Explanation in Historical SociologyAmerican Journal of

    Sociology 104:829-45.

    Goodman, J.B. and Loveman, G.W. (1991) Does Privatisation Serve The

    Public Interest?Harvard Business Review 69 (6):26-38.

    Gormley, W.T. (1994) Privatization Revisited Policy Studies Review

    Autumn/Winter 13(3/4):215-34.

    Gramsci, A. (1971) Selections From The Prison Notebooks London:

    Lawrence and Wishart.

    Grattan, M. (1998) Job Providers Want Some Urgent Changes The

    Australian Financial Review July 24th.

    Green, P. (1998) Job Agencies Demand A Fix The Australian 8-9

    August.

    Greener, I. (2002a) Understanding NHS Reform: The Policy-Transfer,

    Social Learning, and Path-Dependency Perspectives Governance: An

    International Journal of Policy, Administration, and Institutions

    15(2):161-83.

    Greener, I. (2002b) Theorising Path-Dependency: How Does History

    Come to Matter in Organisations?Journal of Management History

    40(6):614-19.

  • 7/30/2019 Electronic Journal of Sociology Privatisation

    25/32

    Gupta, A. (1996) PrivatisationJournal of Institute of Public Enterprise

    (India) 19 (1-2):38-51.

    Hall, P.A. (1993) Policy Paradigms, Social Learning and the State

    Comparative Politics 25:275-96.

    Hall, P.; Land, H.; Parker, R. and Webb, A. (1975) Change, Choice and

    Conflict in Social Policy London: Heinemann.

    Harvey, D. (1982) The Limits of Capital Oxford: Blackwell.

    Haslem, B. (2000a) Job Agency Dumps Long Contacts The Australian

    7th Feb.

    Haslem, B. (2000b) Army Steals March onJob Providers The Australian

    March 25-6, p.5.

    Haslem, B. (2000c) Job Sites Disparity Queried The Australian 23

    December, p. 4.

    Haslem, B. and Marris, S. (1999) Tax Error Cost Job Agency Contracts

    The Australian December 20th.

    Hay, C. (1999) Marxismand the State in Gamble, A.; Marsh, D. and

    Tant, T. (eds)Marxism and Social Science London: Macmillan, pp.

    152-74.

    Heald, D. (1983) Public Expenditure Oxford: Martin Robertson.

    Henig, J. Hamnett, C. and Feigenbaum, H.B. (1998) The Politics Of

    Privatization. Governance 1 (4):442-68.

    Herd, B. (1998) Deconstructing The Current Account Balance Of

    Payments in M. Alexander; S. Harding; P. Harrison; G. Kendall; Z.

    Skrbis, and J. Western (eds)Refashioning Sociology Brisbane: TASA

    Conference Proceedings.

    Hood, C. (1994)Explaining Economic Policy Reversals Buckingham:

    Open University Press.

  • 7/30/2019 Electronic Journal of Sociology Privatisation

    26/32

    Ikenberry, G.J. (1990) The International Spread Of Privatization Policies

    in Suleiman, E.N. and Waterbury, J. (eds) The Political Economy of

    Public Sector Reform and Privatization Oxford: Westview.

    Jamrozik, A. (2001) Social Policy in the Post-Welfare State Longman,

    Frenchs Forest.

    Jansson, B. (2000) Policy Analysis in Midgley, J.; Tracy, M. and

    Livermore, M. (eds) The Handbook of Social Policy London: Sage

    Publications, pp. 41-52.

    Jessop, B. (1982) The Capitalist State Oxford: Martin Robertson.

    Jessop, B. (1999) Narrating The Future of the National Economy and theNational State? Remarks on Remapping Regulation and Reinventing

    Governance in Steinmetz, G. (ed) State/Culture: State Formation

    After The Cultural Turn Ithaca, Cornell Press, pp. 378-405.

    Jessop, B. (2001a) Bringing The State Back In (Yet Again): Reviews,

    Revisions, Rejections, and Redirections published by the Department

    of Sociology, Lancaster University, at

    www:comp.lancs.ac.uk/sociology/soc070rj.html

    Jessop, B. (2001b) Capitalism, the Regulation Approach, and Critical

    Realism in Brown, A.; Fleetwood, S. and Roberts, J. (eds) Critical

    Realism and Marxism London, Routledge.

    Jessop, B. (2001c) On The Limits of Limits to Capitalpublished by the

    Department of Sociology, Lancaster University, at

    http:www.comp.lancs.ac.uk/sociology/soc129ri.htm

    Johnson, T. (1972) Professions and PowerLondon: Macmillan Press.

    Kay, J.A. and Thompson, D.J. (1986) Privatisation The Economic

    Journal 96 (March):18-32.

    Kelly, P. (2000) Jobs Agency Bungled Tender Bid The Australian 14th

    Feb.

    Kerr, L. and Savelsberg, H. (2001) The Community Service Sector in theEra of the Market ModelJust Policy 23:22-32.

  • 7/30/2019 Electronic Journal of Sociology Privatisation

    27/32

    Langmore, J. (1987) Privatisation in Abelson, P. (ed.) Privatisation: An

    Australian Perspective Sydney: Australian Professional Publications.

    Lfgren, H. and Benner, M. (2003) Biotechnology and Governance in

    Australia and Sweden: Path Dependency or Institutional

    Convergence?Australian Journal of Political Science 38(1):25-43.

    Lukes, S. (1974) Power: A Radical View London: Macmillan.

    McGregor, R. (1999) Job Agent Put Out of Work The Australian 4-5th

    Dec.

    Maloney, W. Smith, G. and Stoker, G. (2000) Social Capital and Urban

    Governance Political Studies 48:802-20.

    Mann, K. (1992) The Making of an English Underclass? The Social

    Divisions of Welfare and LabourBucks: Open University Press.

    Mansfield, B. (1987) The Public Sector in Abelson, P. (ed.)

    Privatisation: An Australian Perspective Sydney: Australian

    Professional Publications, pp. 70-95.

    Marris, S. (2002) Business Welfare Budget Costs Taxpayers $14bn The

    Australian 23rd December.

    Marsh, D. (1999) Resurrecting Marxism in Gamble, A.; Marsh, D. and

    Tant, T. (eds)Marxism and Social Science London : Macmillan, pp.

    320-40.

    Marsh, D. and Rhodes, R. (1992) Policy Networks in British Government

    Oxford: Clarendon Press.

    Marsh, D. and Smith, M.J. (2000) Understanding Policy Networks:

    Towards a Dialectical Approach Political Studies 48(1):4-21.

    Marshall, T.H. (1981) The Right To Welfare and Other Essays

    Heinemann.

    Martin, S. and Parker, D. (1997) The Impact of Privatisation London:

    Routledge.

  • 7/30/2019 Electronic Journal of Sociology Privatisation

    28/32

    Marx, K. (1973) Grundrisse Harmondsworth: Penguin.

    Marx, K. and Engels, F. (1976) German Ideology [1845-6] Moscow:

    Progress Publishers.

    Melossi, D. (1990) The State of Social Control: A Sociological Study of

    Concepts of State and Social Control in the Making of Democracy

    Cambridge: Polity.

    Mishra, R. (1982) Book Review of TH Marshall (1981) The Right To

    Welfare and Other Essays Critical Social Policy 2 (1) Summer:105-

    7.

    Mooney, G. (2000) Class and Social Policy in Lewis, G.; Gewirtz, S. andClarke, J. (eds)Rethinking Social Policy London : Sage, pp. 156-70.

    Moore, J. (1986) Why Privatise? in Kay, J.; Mayer, C. and Thompson,

    D. (eds) Privatisation and Regulation Oxford: Clarendon Press.

    Navarro, V. (1982) The Crisis of the International Capitalist Order and Its

    Implications For the Welfare State Critical Social Policy 2 (1)

    Summer:43-62.

    Navarro, V. (1978) Class Struggle, The State and Medicine New York:

    Prodist.

    Neilsen, K.; Jessop, B. and Hausner, J. (1995) (eds) Strategic Choice and

    Path-Dependency in Post Socialism. Institutional Dynamics in the

    Transformation Process Aldershot: Edward Elgar.

    Nevile, A. (2000) The Implementation of Competitive Tendering in the

    Australian Social Welfare SectorJust Policy 18:15-23.

    Norgard, JD. (1977)Review of the Commonwealth Employment Service

    AGPS, Canberra.

    OConnor, J. (1993) The Fiscal Crisis of the State London, St Martins

    Press.

    Ornstein, M. (2003) The Canadian Corporate Network in Comparative

    Perspective Comparative Sociology 2(1):197-213.

  • 7/30/2019 Electronic Journal of Sociology Privatisation

    29/32

    Peake, R. (1998) Jobs at Stake - But Whose?Canberra Times May 2nd.

    Poulantzas, N. (1979) State, Power, Socialism London: Verso.

    Productivity Commission (1998) Performance of Government TradingEnterprises 1991-92 to 1996-97Canberra: AusInfo.

    Pross, P. (1992) Group Politics and Public Policy second edition, Toronto:

    Oxford University Press.

    Pusey, M. (1991)Economic Rationalism in Canberra Melbourne:

    Cambridge University Press.

    Putnam, R. (1995) Bowling AloneJournal of Democracy 6 (1):65-78.

    Quiggin, J. (1996) Great Expectations St Leonards: Allen and Unwin.

    Salvaris, M. (1995) Privatisation, Citizenship and the Public InterestJust

    Policy 4:37-43.

    Samson, C. (1994) The Three Faces Of Privatisation Sociology 28

    (1):79-97.

    Saunders, P. (1994) Welfare and Inequality Melbourne: Cambridge

    University Press.

    Saward, M. (1990) Co-option and Power Political Studies 38:588-602.

    Self, P. (1990) Whats Wrong With Government? Canberra Bulletin of

    Public Administration 60:17-21.

    Shanahan, D. (1999) Abbott Given To Charity The Australian 4-5December.

    Shore, C. and Wright, S. (1997) Policy in Shore, C. and Wright, S. (eds)

    Anthropology of Policy London: Routledge, pp. 3-39.

    Skocpol, T. (1985) Bringing The State Back In: Strategies of Analysis in

    Current Research in Evans, P.B. et al (eds)Bringing The State Back

    In Cambridge; Cambridge University Press, p. 3-37.

  • 7/30/2019 Electronic Journal of Sociology Privatisation

    30/32

    Steel, D. and Heald, D. (1982) Privatising Public Enterprise Political

    Quarterly 53 (3):333-49.

    Sunday Telegraph(1997) Firms Back Private CES 10 August.

    Taylor, M. (1998) Subcontractors Job Fees Go Unchecked The

    Canberra Times 11th June.

    Taylor-Gooby, P. (1997) In Defence of Second-Best Theory: State, Class

    and Capital in Social PolicyJournal of Social Policy 26(2):171-92.

    Therborn, G. (1982) What Does The Ruling Class Do When It Rules? in

    Giddens, A. and Held, D. (eds) Classes Power and ConflictLondon:

    Macmillan, pp. 224-48.

    Thynne, I. (1995) Basic Concepts and Issues in Thynne, I. (ed.)

    Corporatization, Divestment and the Public-Private Mix Hong Kong:

    AJPA and IASIA, pp. 1-9.

    Toke, D. and Marsh, D. (2003) Policy Networks and the GM Crops Issue:

    Assessing the Utility of a Dialectical Model of Policy Networks

    Public Administration 81(2):229-51.

    Vernon, R. (1987) Economic Aspects of Privatization Programs. The

    Economic Development Institute and the World BankMarch, pp. 1-

    14.

    Walker, B. and Walker B. (2000) Privatisation: Sell Off or Sell Out?

    Sydney: ABC Books.

    Walshe, G. and Daffern, P. (1990)Managing Cost-Benefit Analysis

    London: Macmillan.

    Wanasinghe, S. (1991) Privatisation in Gouri, G. (ed.) Privatisation and

    Public Enterprise New Delhi: Oxford and IBH Publishing, pp. 123-

    37.

    Waters, A.R. (1987) The Techniques of PrivatizationEconomic Impact

    61:55-9.

  • 7/30/2019 Electronic Journal of Sociology Privatisation

    31/32

    Whiteley, P.F. and Winyard, S.J. (1987) Pressure For the Poor: the

    Poverty Lobby and Policy Making London: Menthuen.

    Whitfield, D. (1992) The Welfare State London: Pluto Press.

    Willis, E. (1983)Medical Dominance Australia: George Allen and Unwin.

    Wilsford, D. (1994) Path Dependency, or Why History Makes It Difficult

    But Not Impossible To Reform Health Care Systems in a Big Way

    Journal of Public Policy 14 (3):251-83.

    Wright, L. (1998) Unflattering Job Figures Withheld Canberra Times

    6th August.

    Electronic Journal of Sociology

    More info

    Web searchTheorising Privatisation: Policy, Network Analysis, and Class

    Web search: Theorising Privatisation: Policy, Network Analysis...LSE Research - Items where Subject is H Social Sciences - HT Communities.Classes. Races - LSE Research OnlineBarnett, Edward (2012) An analysis ofcommunity involvement in primary schools in Malawi. Calhoun, Craig (1982) Bookreview: protest and participation: the new working class in Italy. Cheshire, Paul(2006) Resurgent cities, urban myths and policy hubris: what we need toknow.eprints.lse.ac.uk/view/subjects/HT.type.htmlItems where Year is 1999 - Lancaster EPrintsArmstrong, H W and de Kervenoael,R F (1999) An economic perspective on the assignment ofpolicy powers: the caseof tourism policy. Armstrong, H W and Taylor, J (1999) The Economics of RegionalPolicy. (1999) The effects of belief and logic on syllogistic reasoning: evidence from

    an eye-tracking analysis.eprints.lancs.ac.uk/view/year/1999.htmlSchool of Management - QUT ePrints - Current - SchoolsEvans, Peter (2008)Teaching in the Global Business Classroom. Evans, Peter, & Lawson, Lynda (2011)Learning in the global classroom: a guide for students in the multicultural university.In Carter, Sara & Jones-Evans, Dylan (Eds.) Enterprise and Small Business:Principles, Practice and Policy.eprints.qut.edu.au/view/divisions/som.htmlGreenwich Academic Literature Archive - Items where Year is 2010 - GreenwichAcademic Literature ArchiveAde-Ojo, Gordon (2010) Do teachers trust policy andpolicy makers. Between the rhetoric ofpolicy and the reality of implementation inUK literacy policy since 2001. Acton, Thomas (2010) Theorising mobility: migration,nomadism, and the social reconstruction of

    ethnicity.gala.gre.ac.uk/view/year/2010.html

  • 7/30/2019 Electronic Journal of Sociology Privatisation

    32/32

    e-Prints Soton - Items where Subject is H Social Sciences - HM Sociology -ePrints SotonColombi, David, Rafferty, Jackie and Steyaert, Jan (eds. 1993) Humanservices and information technology: a European perspective, UK, EuropeanNetwork for Information Technology, 208pp. Clarke, John, Cochrane, Allan andMcLaughlin, Eugene (eds. 1994) Managing social policy, London, GB, Sage,

    257pp.eprints.soton.ac.uk/view/subjects/HM.htmlKent Academic Repository - Items where division is Faculties - Social Sciences- School of Social Policy Sociology and Social ... (1998) Caring for frail elderlypeople: Policies in evolution. Caring for frail elderly people: Policies in evolutionOrganization for Economic Cooperation and Development, 1996. Journal ofEuropean Social Policy, 8 (4). Pp 341-2 ISSN 0958-9287. (1999) Culture: Themissing variable in understanding socialpolicy.kar.kent.ac.uk/view/divisions/13701.htmlBrowse by Year - Warwick Research Archive Portal - WRAP(1995) ANALYSISAND REDUCTION OF VIBRATION AND ACOUSTIC NOISE IN THE SWITCHEDRELUCTANCE DRIVE. (1995) ANALYSIS OF BIFURCATIONS IN REACTION-

    DIFFUSION SYSTEMS WITH NO-FLUX BOUNDARY-CONDITIONS. (1995)ANALYSIS OF HEAT-SHOCK PROTEIN EXPRESSION IN MYELOID-LEUKEMIACELLS BY FLOW-CYTOMETRY.wrap.warwick.ac.uk/view/publications_year/1995.htmlBournemouth University - PublicationsDo formal policies for sustainabledevelopment make a difference. Migrant networks, language learning and tourismemployment. Analysis and Decision. Analysis and Decision, 15 May 2011,Guildford. Analysis and decision, 14 May 2011,Bristol.eprints.bournemouth.ac.uk/view/subjects/bmm.default.htmlItems where Year is 2006 - WestminsterResearchAassve, Arnstein andEngelhardt, Henriette and Francavilla, Francesca and Kedir, Abbi Mamo and Kim,Jungho and Mealli, Fabrizia and Mencarini, Letizia and Pudney, Stephen andPrskawetz, Alexia (2006) Poverty and fertility dynamics: a comparativeanalysis.westminsterresearch.wmin.ac.uk/view/year/2006.htmlCentAUR - Items where Division is Faculty of Science - School of Human andEnvironmental Sciences - CentAUR(2012) Fine-root turnover rates of Europeanforests revisited: an analysis of data from sequential coring and ingrowth cores.(2012) Carbon and nitrogen stable isotope ratio analysis of freshwater, brackish andmarine fish from Belgian archaeological sites (1st and 2nd milleniumAD).centaur.reading.ac.uk/view/divisions/3=5Ff0785a3c.html

    Search results fromblekkoTM

    http://blekko.com/http://blekko.com/http://blekko.com/http://blekko.com/