Economics 325 Public Economics - University of...

47
Economics 325 Public Economics Martin Farnham University of Victoria Fall 2014 1 Econ 325--Farnham

Transcript of Economics 325 Public Economics - University of...

Page 1: Economics 325 Public Economics - University of Victoriaweb.uvic.ca/~mfarnham/325/T1_intro_review.pdf · Economics 325 Public Economics ... • In this case, government intervention

Economics 325 Public Economics

Martin Farnham University of Victoria

Fall 2014

1 Econ 325--Farnham

Page 2: Economics 325 Public Economics - University of Victoriaweb.uvic.ca/~mfarnham/325/T1_intro_review.pdf · Economics 325 Public Economics ... • In this case, government intervention

Econ 325--Farnham 2

What is Public Economics?

•  Used to be called Public Finance, which caused some confusion –  Not about corporate finance/banking –  Not about macroeconomic fiscal policy

•  What it is –  Economics of the public sector –  Study of what government should do, and what

effect government has at micro level (on markets and individual behaviour)

Page 3: Economics 325 Public Economics - University of Victoriaweb.uvic.ca/~mfarnham/325/T1_intro_review.pdf · Economics 325 Public Economics ... • In this case, government intervention

Econ 325--Farnham 3

The Role of Government in a Market Economy

Why might the government want to intervene in a market economy?

Four main reasons 1)  Establish/maintain property rights 2)  Correct market failures 3)  Promote fairness/equity 4)  Paternalism (arguably a bad reason, though

maybe not always)

Page 4: Economics 325 Public Economics - University of Victoriaweb.uvic.ca/~mfarnham/325/T1_intro_review.pdf · Economics 325 Public Economics ... • In this case, government intervention

Econ 325--Farnham 4

Property Rights

•  Government establishes legal framework for economic interactions –  Protects property rights

•  Otherwise little incentive to create wealth; lots of resources diverted to defending ones assets against seizure

–  Enforces contracts between individuals •  Otherwise individuals are forced to rely on trust when

entering into agreements with others

•  This aspect of government accounts for a relatively small fraction of total expenditures

•  Not really a big topic of public economics

Page 5: Economics 325 Public Economics - University of Victoriaweb.uvic.ca/~mfarnham/325/T1_intro_review.pdf · Economics 325 Public Economics ... • In this case, government intervention

Econ 325--Farnham 5

Market Failure

•  Under perfect competition (and other ideal assumptions), equilibrium is Pareto-efficient (markets work)

•  Ideal conditions are pretty unrealistic; when these fail we likely have market failure

•  In this case, government intervention can be social welfare improving (i.e. policy can make society better off)

Page 6: Economics 325 Public Economics - University of Victoriaweb.uvic.ca/~mfarnham/325/T1_intro_review.pdf · Economics 325 Public Economics ... • In this case, government intervention

Econ 325--Farnham 6

Examples of Market Failure

1)  Externalities: Benefits or Costs of market interaction accrue to people other than buyer and seller

2)  Imperfect competition: Monopoly, oligopoly, monopsony, oligopsony (covered in an Industrial Organization course—not really a public econ topic)

3)  Public goods: Non-rival, non-excludable goods subject to free-riding

4)  Asymmetric information: Adverse selection and moral hazard. Market doesn’t exist, in extreme cases (e.g. insurance, good used cars)

Page 7: Economics 325 Public Economics - University of Victoriaweb.uvic.ca/~mfarnham/325/T1_intro_review.pdf · Economics 325 Public Economics ... • In this case, government intervention

Econ 325--Farnham 7

Fairness/Equity

•  Recall it is Pareto Efficient to give everything to one person in society, and nothing to everyone else (just one of many possible efficient allocations) –  Can have efficient outcomes with starvation –  Probably not socially desirable

•  Government can use taxes and expenditures in order to equalize income, consumption, or wealth; or to maintain minimum standard

Page 8: Economics 325 Public Economics - University of Victoriaweb.uvic.ca/~mfarnham/325/T1_intro_review.pdf · Economics 325 Public Economics ... • In this case, government intervention

Econ 325--Farnham 8

Paternalism •  Principle of consumer sovereignty holds that

individuals know what is best for themselves •  Paternalism goes against this principle

–  Government sometimes tries to protect individuals from perceived ignorance or short-sightedness.

–  e.g. Seatbelt laws, criminalization of drugs, mandatory education, laws against child labour, workplace safety standards

•  However the new field of behavioural economics is causing economists to rethink paternalism –  Might touch on this toward the end of the course

Page 9: Economics 325 Public Economics - University of Victoriaweb.uvic.ca/~mfarnham/325/T1_intro_review.pdf · Economics 325 Public Economics ... • In this case, government intervention

Econ 325--Farnham 9

Brief Outline of Course •  Review micro theory •  Externalities and public goods •  Income inequality •  Asymmetric information in insurance markets •  Analysis of various government expenditure

programs •  Analysis of effects of taxation •  Analysis of some taxation issues in Canada •  Possible additional topics at end

Page 10: Economics 325 Public Economics - University of Victoriaweb.uvic.ca/~mfarnham/325/T1_intro_review.pdf · Economics 325 Public Economics ... • In this case, government intervention

Econ 325--Farnham 10

Course logistics

Professor: Martin Farnham [email protected] BEC 354 Office Hours: Tuesdays

11:30-12:30 and 1:30-3:00 (note: I’ll need to reschedule 2 office hour sessions this term due to Department Meetings—Sept 23 and Nov 18)

TA: Sinan Ozel

Page 11: Economics 325 Public Economics - University of Victoriaweb.uvic.ca/~mfarnham/325/T1_intro_review.pdf · Economics 325 Public Economics ... • In this case, government intervention

Econ 325--Farnham 11

Course logistics (cont) •  Evaluation

–  Midterm 1, 25% (Wednesday Oct 1, 7-8pm, Bob Wright Centre B150)

–  Midterm 2, 25% (Tuesday Nov 4, 7-8pm, Bob Wright Centre B150)

–  Final Exam 50% (details TBA) •  Text: Rosen et al. “Public Finance in Canada”

–  Recommended, but not required. •  Assignments

–  Ungraded problem sets –  Readings assigned occasionally

Page 12: Economics 325 Public Economics - University of Victoriaweb.uvic.ca/~mfarnham/325/T1_intro_review.pdf · Economics 325 Public Economics ... • In this case, government intervention

Econ 325--Farnham 12

Course Logistics (cont)

•  Attendance –  If miss every one of first three classes,

automatically dropped (else notify me) – Technically attendance not required;

however, strongly recommended. – You are responsible for anything you miss – Lecture notes posted, but not necessarily

complete

Page 13: Economics 325 Public Economics - University of Victoriaweb.uvic.ca/~mfarnham/325/T1_intro_review.pdf · Economics 325 Public Economics ... • In this case, government intervention

Econ 325--Farnham 13

Course logistics (cont)

•  Office hours –  Use them!!

•  Learning in this course –  Do readings –  Keep good notes –  MOST importantly, do problem sets carefully and

thoroughly –  Think!

•  See syllabus for additional details

Page 14: Economics 325 Public Economics - University of Victoriaweb.uvic.ca/~mfarnham/325/T1_intro_review.pdf · Economics 325 Public Economics ... • In this case, government intervention

Econ 325--Farnham 14

A note on email etiquette

•  Please don’t email me about –  Information available elsewhere (course website,

course outline, etc.) –  What you missed if you skipped a lecture –  What’s going to be on an exam –  Things you could ask me in office hours –  I reserve the right to ignore emails that I deem

inappropriate •  Please use the standard letter format

–  Sign your email –  Don’t use text message abbreviations (I won’t

understand them!)

Page 15: Economics 325 Public Economics - University of Victoriaweb.uvic.ca/~mfarnham/325/T1_intro_review.pdf · Economics 325 Public Economics ... • In this case, government intervention

Econ 325--Farnham 15

Review of Microeconomics •  Reading for Micro Review

–  Your principles of micro text and/or notes –  Rosen Chapter 2 appendix

•  In this course we will be analyzing market outcomes 1) with an interest in policy that will correct market failures when such failures occur; and 2) with an interest in the costs associated with redistributive or paternalistic policy

•  Primary questions throughout: –  To what outcomes do markets lead? –  Under what circumstances are these outcomes desirable? –  If markets outcomes are undesirable, what would be the

desirable outcome? What is the correct policy response?

Page 16: Economics 325 Public Economics - University of Victoriaweb.uvic.ca/~mfarnham/325/T1_intro_review.pdf · Economics 325 Public Economics ... • In this case, government intervention

Econ 325--Farnham 16

Review of Microeconomics •  Analyzing what happens involves positive analysis

•  Terms desirable and undesirable imply we are also interested in normative analysis.

•  Positive analysis involves asking what an outcome will be under certain circumstances: –  Ex: in equilibrium, how much carbon will drivers emit?

•  Normative analysis involves asking questions about what outcomes we would like to see. (what should be) –  Ex: what is the right (socially optimal) amount of carbon

emissions?

•  Points to the need for a normative criterion by which to judge outcomes as “good” or “bad”.

Page 17: Economics 325 Public Economics - University of Victoriaweb.uvic.ca/~mfarnham/325/T1_intro_review.pdf · Economics 325 Public Economics ... • In this case, government intervention

Econ 325--Farnham 17

Review of Microeconomics •  Normative criterion we use in economics is typically that of

economic efficiency.

•  Important to keep in mind that economic efficiency

–  has utilitarianism as its philosophical base –  says nothing about fairness or equity –  is only one of many criteria that we can (should?) use to

judge market outcomes.

•  With these caveats in mind, in this class we will (usually) judge outcomes in terms of whether or not they are economically efficient. –  Normative statements like “outcome X should happen”

should be read as shorthand for “outcome X should happen if we are using economic efficiency as the sole criterion for decision-making.”

Page 18: Economics 325 Public Economics - University of Victoriaweb.uvic.ca/~mfarnham/325/T1_intro_review.pdf · Economics 325 Public Economics ... • In this case, government intervention

18

Review of Microeconomics •  Economic efficiency defined:

–  An outcome is efficient if it maximizes net benefits, where net benefits are equal to total benefits minus total costs.

•  Tells us that, at its core, the analysis of economic efficiency is simply cost-benefit analysis.

•  We will be analyzing efficiency in a variety of contexts, such as: 1.  What is the “right” amount of a pollutant to allow an industry to

produce? •  Ex: what is the efficient level of particulate emissions in the

electricity-producing industry? 2.  Should the government undertake an infrastructure project

(binary decision-making)? •  Ex: Should Victoria build a new hospital? A light-rail system?

3.  Which firms should abate carbon emissions to meet treaty targets?

Econ 325--Farnham

Page 19: Economics 325 Public Economics - University of Victoriaweb.uvic.ca/~mfarnham/325/T1_intro_review.pdf · Economics 325 Public Economics ... • In this case, government intervention

Econ 325--Farnham 19

Review of Microeconomics •  We will focus on answering questions such as these by using cost-

benefit analysis to identify the outcomes that make net benefits as large as possible. Once we know the best outcomes, we can then identify policies that will lead to those outcomes.

•  Important point: we need to make sure we have correctly identified and measured all of the costs and benefits associated with a given activity/outcome.

•  An alternative characterization of efficiency (that we may pick up on at various points throughout the term):

–  An outcome is efficient if it is impossible to come up with an alternative outcome in which at least one person can be made better off without any one person being made worse off.

•  Although it may not be immediately obvious, we will see that this characterization of efficiency will be satisfied if net benefits are maximized.

Page 20: Economics 325 Public Economics - University of Victoriaweb.uvic.ca/~mfarnham/325/T1_intro_review.pdf · Economics 325 Public Economics ... • In this case, government intervention

Econ 325--Farnham 20

Review of Microeconomics •  In order to answer normative questions such as those posed

above, we first need to understand how to answer positive questions.

–  For instance, we need to understand what market outcomes look like, in order to work out whether they are desirable (efficient).

•  This means we need to recall some basic ideas we learned in principles of microeconomics.

•  Specifically, we want to understand: 1.  How consumers decide what goods to buy (demand). 2.  How producers decide what goods to produce (supply). 3.  How markets bring producers and consumers together

(equilibrium).

•  Once we understand this, we can assess whether consumers and producers act in such a way as to achieve an economically efficient outcome.

Page 21: Economics 325 Public Economics - University of Victoriaweb.uvic.ca/~mfarnham/325/T1_intro_review.pdf · Economics 325 Public Economics ... • In this case, government intervention

Econ 325--Farnham 21

Review of Microeconomics 1.  Review of Demand.

•  Three areas to cover on the demand side: i.  Interpreting an individual consumer’s demand curve ii.  Measuring consumer well-being using the demand curve iii.  Deriving aggregate demand from individual demand

Page 22: Economics 325 Public Economics - University of Victoriaweb.uvic.ca/~mfarnham/325/T1_intro_review.pdf · Economics 325 Public Economics ... • In this case, government intervention

Econ 325--Farnham 22

Review of Microeconomics: Demand i.  Interpreting an individual’s demand curve

•  Recall that a demand curve maps out a relationship between price and quantity.

Price (P)

Quantity (Q)

Demand curves usually slope downwards: known as the “law” of demand

while on the vertical axis we are measuring the price per unit (P), in some form of currency (dollars, cents etc)

Remember, on the horizontal axis we are measuring units of the good consumed (Q),

How to interpret this demand curve? Two interpretations, each of which will be useful, depending on the context.

Demand Curve (D)

Page 23: Economics 325 Public Economics - University of Victoriaweb.uvic.ca/~mfarnham/325/T1_intro_review.pdf · Economics 325 Public Economics ... • In this case, government intervention

Econ 325--Farnham 23

Review of Microeconomics: Demand

•  The first interpretation of the demand curve is probably the most familiar to you:

P

Q

Interpretation 1: the D curve tells us how many units of a good a consumer wishes to buy in total, at a given price per unit for the good.

For instance, the D curve tells us that if the price per unit is P1, then the consumer would like to buy Q1 units.

We can think of this interpretation as reading the D curve horizontally: that is, if we plug in values for P, we get out values for Q.

D

P1

Q1

etc. Q2

P2

Page 24: Economics 325 Public Economics - University of Victoriaweb.uvic.ca/~mfarnham/325/T1_intro_review.pdf · Economics 325 Public Economics ... • In this case, government intervention

24

Review of Microeconomics: Demand

•  The second interpretation of the demand curve may be less familiar to you:

P

Q

Interpretation 2: the height of the D curve at any given point tells us how the consumer values additional units of the good.

For instance, the D curve tells us that if the consumer currently has Q1 units of the good, then a small increase in quantity would be worth P1 per unit to the consumer, etc.

D

P1

Q1 Q2

P2

We can think of this interpretation as reading the D curve vertically: that is, if we plug in values for Q, we get out values for P. We will elaborate on this interpretation by use of an example.

Econ 325--Farnham

Page 25: Economics 325 Public Economics - University of Victoriaweb.uvic.ca/~mfarnham/325/T1_intro_review.pdf · Economics 325 Public Economics ... • In this case, government intervention

Econ 325--Farnham 25

Review of Microeconomics: Demand

Example: Suppose that demand is given by Q = 5 - (1/2)P.

P($)

Q

From the D function, if P=$10, Q=0 will be demanded. But if P = $8, Q = 1 will be demanded.

consumer’s maximum willingness to pay for the first unit is somewhere between $8 and $10.

D

10

5

So we know that the maximum willingness to pay for the first unit is something less than $10. Can we be more precise than this?

Area of the rectangle ($10) thus gives an upper bound on consumer’s willingness to pay for the first unit. 1

8

Page 26: Economics 325 Public Economics - University of Victoriaweb.uvic.ca/~mfarnham/325/T1_intro_review.pdf · Economics 325 Public Economics ... • In this case, government intervention

Econ 325--Farnham 26

Review of Microeconomics: Demand Now consider smaller changes in P. Say P from $10 to $9 so that Q from 0 to 0.5.

P($)

Q

Consumer did not buy the first half unit when it cost $5, but does when it costs $4.50.

consumer’s maximum willingness to pay for this first half unit is something less than $5.

D

10

0.5

Now suppose P from $9 to $8, so that total Q from 0.5 to 1.

Consumer did not buy the second half unit when it cost $4.50, but does when P falls.

1 5

9 8

consumer’s maximum willingness to pay for this second half unit is something less than $4.50. This tells us that the consumer’s maximum willingness to pay for the first unit is in fact something less than $9.50 (as opposed to $10).

Page 27: Economics 325 Public Economics - University of Victoriaweb.uvic.ca/~mfarnham/325/T1_intro_review.pdf · Economics 325 Public Economics ... • In this case, government intervention

27

Review of Microeconomics: Demand We could consider even smaller changes in prices and quantities.

P($)

Q

For instance we could now lower the price in $0.50 increments, rather than in $1.00 increments.

Doing this allows us to see that the consumer’s maximum willingness to pay for the first unit is something less than $9.25.

D

10

9

8

0.5 1 5

In the limit, as we consider smaller and smaller price changes, what we are doing here is calculating the area under the demand curve between Q=0 and Q=1.

This area tells us the exact maximum willingness to pay by this consumer for the first unit of the good. In this case, the area of that trapezoid is equal to $9. The consumer is willing to pay at most $9 for the first unit.

Econ 325--Farnham

Page 28: Economics 325 Public Economics - University of Victoriaweb.uvic.ca/~mfarnham/325/T1_intro_review.pdf · Economics 325 Public Economics ... • In this case, government intervention

Econ 325--Farnham 28

Review of Microeconomics: Demand By the same logic, the area under the demand curve as we increase Q from 1 to 2 units tells us the maximum willingness to pay for the second unit.

P($)

Q

In this case, that area equals $7.

10

1 5

Indeed, the area under a D curve between any two quantities tells us the maximum willingness to pay for that additional quantity.

In the limit, as we consider tiny tiny increases in Q, the base of the trapezoid goes to zero, and the willingness to pay (per unit) for these tiny tiny increases in Q is just equal to the height of the demand curve.

2

6 If we consider very small increases in quantity, than the trapezoid representing the willingness to pay has a very small base.

8

Page 29: Economics 325 Public Economics - University of Victoriaweb.uvic.ca/~mfarnham/325/T1_intro_review.pdf · Economics 325 Public Economics ... • In this case, government intervention

Econ 325--Farnham 29

Review of Microeconomics: Demand This is the logic behind the second interpretation of the demand curve, that the height at any point tells us how consumers value small Q.

P($)

Q

As we have seen, this is equivalent to telling us how much the consumer is willing to pay for small Q.

When we are thinking about the D curve in this way, we will refer to it variously as the:

We can also think about this as telling us how much additional benefit a consumer would get from a small Q.

1.  Marginal Value (MV) curve 2.  Marginal Willingness to Pay (MWP) curve 3.  Marginal Benefit (MB) curve

Note that these terms are equivalent!

Page 30: Economics 325 Public Economics - University of Victoriaweb.uvic.ca/~mfarnham/325/T1_intro_review.pdf · Economics 325 Public Economics ... • In this case, government intervention

Econ 325--Farnham 30

Review of Microeconomics: Demand ii.  Measuring consumer well-being using the demand curve.

P($)

Q

1st interpretation of D curve: tells us Q demanded at a given P.

But, how much did consumer actually have to pay for Q1?

2nd interpretation of D curve: area under the D curve measures consumer’s willingness to pay for Q1 units.

Definition: consumer surplus (CS) = what a consumer is willing to pay minus what they have to pay.

P1

Q1

Expenditure (price times quantity) given by area P1Q1.

consumer willing to pay more than she has to pay.

Difference between willingness to pay and expenditure measures consumer well-being.

In the diagram above, the CS from buying Q1 units at P1 per unit is equal to the triangle A.

A

Page 31: Economics 325 Public Economics - University of Victoriaweb.uvic.ca/~mfarnham/325/T1_intro_review.pdf · Economics 325 Public Economics ... • In this case, government intervention

Econ 325--Farnham 31

Topic 1(b): Review of Consumer Theory iii.  Deriving aggregate demand from individual demand

P

QA

Suppose two individuals - A and B - each with D curves drawn below.

At P1, A demands Q1A and B demands Q1

B.

P1

QA1

We are horizontally aggregating individual demands to get aggregate demand.

DA

QB

QB1

DB

QA1+QB

1 QA2 QB

2 QA2+QB

2

Aggregate D

P2

Aggregate demand at P1 therefore equals Q1A + Q1

B.

At P2, A demands Q2A, B demands Q2

B, and agg. D = Q2A

+ Q2B.

P

Page 32: Economics 325 Public Economics - University of Victoriaweb.uvic.ca/~mfarnham/325/T1_intro_review.pdf · Economics 325 Public Economics ... • In this case, government intervention

Econ 325--Farnham 32

Topic 1: Introduction and Review 1.  Review of Supply.

•  Three areas to cover on the supply side: i.  Interpreting an individual producer’s supply curve ii.  Measuring producer well-being using the supply curve iii.  Deriving aggregate supply from individual supply

Page 33: Economics 325 Public Economics - University of Victoriaweb.uvic.ca/~mfarnham/325/T1_intro_review.pdf · Economics 325 Public Economics ... • In this case, government intervention

Econ 325--Farnham 33

Topic 1: Introduction and Review: Supply i.  Interpreting a firm’s supply curve

•  Recall that a supply curve maps out a relationship between price and quantity.

Price (P)

Quantity (Q)

Supply curves usually slope upwards: known as the “law” of supply

i.e., firms that take the prices of output and inputs as given.

NB: Throughout this class we will only be looking at the supply behavior of competitive firms.

How to interpret this supply curve? Like D curve, there are two interpretations of the S curve.

Supply Curve (S)

Page 34: Economics 325 Public Economics - University of Victoriaweb.uvic.ca/~mfarnham/325/T1_intro_review.pdf · Economics 325 Public Economics ... • In this case, government intervention

Econ 325--Farnham 34

Topic 1: Introduction and Review: Supply

•  The first interpretation of the supply curve is (again) probably most familiar:

P

Q

Interpretation 1: S curve tells us how many units of a good a producer wishes to sell in total, at a given price per unit for the good.

If the price per unit is P1, then the firm would like to sell Q1 units. etc, etc.

We can think of this interpretation as reading the S curve horizontally: that is, if we plug in values for P, we get out values for Q.

S

P1

Q1

Page 35: Economics 325 Public Economics - University of Victoriaweb.uvic.ca/~mfarnham/325/T1_intro_review.pdf · Economics 325 Public Economics ... • In this case, government intervention

Topic 1: Introduction and Review: Supply

•  The second interpretation of the supply curve should also be (relatively) familiar:

P

Q

Interpretation 2: the height of the S curve at any given point tells us how much additional units of the good cost to produce.

i.e., the supply curve is also a Marginal Cost (MC) curve.

If the firm is currently producing Q1 units of the good, then a small increase in quantity would cost P1 per unit to produce.

S P1

Q1

We can think of this interpretation as reading the S curve vertically: that is, if we plug in values for Q, we get out values for P. Again, useful to work through an example.

35 Econ 325--Farnham

Page 36: Economics 325 Public Economics - University of Victoriaweb.uvic.ca/~mfarnham/325/T1_intro_review.pdf · Economics 325 Public Economics ... • In this case, government intervention

Econ 325--Farnham 36

Topic 1: Introduction and Review: Supply

Example: Suppose that supply is given by Q = P - 5.

P($)

Q

From the S function, if P=$5, Q=0 will be supplied. But if P = $6, Q = 1 will be supplied.

firm’s cost of supplying that first unit (the MC of that unit) is somewhere between $5 and $6.

S

And area under S curve from Q=1 to Q=2 equals cost of producing 2nd unit.

And area under S curve from Q=0 to Q=2 tells us how much the firm’s costs increase going from Q=0 to Q=2.

Turns out that the exact cost of producing this first unit = area under the S curve between Q=0 and Q=1.

1

5

6

7

2

$5.50 $6.50

$12

Page 37: Economics 325 Public Economics - University of Victoriaweb.uvic.ca/~mfarnham/325/T1_intro_review.pdf · Economics 325 Public Economics ... • In this case, government intervention

Econ 325--Farnham 37

Topic 1: Introduction and Review: Supply

•  Area under S curve up to a given Q actually tells us the Variable Cost (VC) of producing that Q.

•  Recall that a firm’s Total Costs (TC) have 2 components: TC = Fixed Costs + Variable Costs

= FC + VC.

•  By definition, FC don’t change as Q changes, while VC do.

•  So MC = ΔTC/ΔQ = Δ (FC+VC) /ΔQ = ΔVC /ΔQ.

area under the S curve up to a given Q = MC of 1st unit + MC of 2nd unit + MC of third unit etc. etc.

•  And adding up MCs is the same as calculating VC.

Page 38: Economics 325 Public Economics - University of Victoriaweb.uvic.ca/~mfarnham/325/T1_intro_review.pdf · Economics 325 Public Economics ... • In this case, government intervention

Econ 325--Farnham 38

Topic 1: Introduction and Review: Supply ii.  Measuring producer well-being using the supply curve.

P($)

Q

1st interpretation of S curve: tells us Q supplied at a given P.

If producer sells Q1 units at P1 per unit, then Total Revenue (TR) received = area of rectangle P1Q1.

2nd interpretation of S curve: area under S curve measures VC of producing Q1 units.

Definition: producer surplus (PS) = TR - VC.

P1

Q1

producer receives revenue greater than VC.

Difference between TR and VC provides a measure of producer well-being.

In the diagram above, the PS from selling Q1 units at P1 per unit is equal to the triangle A.

A

Page 39: Economics 325 Public Economics - University of Victoriaweb.uvic.ca/~mfarnham/325/T1_intro_review.pdf · Economics 325 Public Economics ... • In this case, government intervention

Econ 325--Farnham 39

Topic 1: Introduction and Review: Supply

ii.  Measuring producer well-being using the supply curve.

•  More common measure of producer well-being is profit (π). –  What is the relationship between PS and π?

•  Recall:

PS = TR - VC; and

π = TR - TC π = TR - VC - FC

PS π = PS - FC

or PS = π + FC.

Page 40: Economics 325 Public Economics - University of Victoriaweb.uvic.ca/~mfarnham/325/T1_intro_review.pdf · Economics 325 Public Economics ... • In this case, government intervention

Econ 325--Farnham 40

Topic 1: Introduction and Review: Supply

•  Recall that CS measures the NB to consumers from consuming.

•  Similarly, we can think about PS as telling us about the NB to producers from producing.

•  That is, tells us how much better off the firm is by choosing Q>0.

•  If Q = 0, TR=0 and TC=FC. π = -FC.

•  If Q>0, TR>0 and TC=FC+VC. π = PS - FC.

•  Tells us that maximizing π is equivalent to maximizing PS.

•  So even though π is the “true” measure of firm well-being, we can use PS instead.

π as Q = PS as Q

Page 41: Economics 325 Public Economics - University of Victoriaweb.uvic.ca/~mfarnham/325/T1_intro_review.pdf · Economics 325 Public Economics ... • In this case, government intervention

Econ 325--Farnham 41

Topic 1: Introduction and Review: Supply iii.  Deriving aggregate supply from individual firm supply

P

QA

Suppose two firms - A and B - each with S curves drawn below.

At P1, A supplies QA1 and B supplies QB

1.

P1

QA1

We are horizontally aggregating individual firm supplies to get aggregate supply.

SA

QB

QB1

SB

QA1+QB

1 QA2 QB

2 QA2+QB

2

Aggregate S

P2

Aggregate supply at P1 therefore equals QA1 + QB

1.

At P2, A supplies QA2, B supplies QB

2, and agg. S = QA2 + QB

2.

Page 42: Economics 325 Public Economics - University of Victoriaweb.uvic.ca/~mfarnham/325/T1_intro_review.pdf · Economics 325 Public Economics ... • In this case, government intervention

Econ 325--Farnham 42

Topic 1: Introduction and Review •  Final topic in Intro/Review: Equilibrium.

–  Bringing both sides of the market together.

•  Definition of equilibrium: –  a state of balance or rest; –  a state where there is no tendency for change.

•  In our supply and demand model, an equilibrium is where: 1.  Consumers are choosing the Q that makes them happiest,

given P. (Consumers choose Q to set MB=P) –  i.e., maximizing CS.

2.  Producers are choosing the Q that makes them happiest, given P. (Producers choose Q to set MC=P) –  i.e., maximizing PS.

3.  Prices are such that consumer and producer behavior are consistent. –  Usually means supply equals demand. (Qs=Qd)

Page 43: Economics 325 Public Economics - University of Victoriaweb.uvic.ca/~mfarnham/325/T1_intro_review.pdf · Economics 325 Public Economics ... • In this case, government intervention

Econ 325--Farnham 43

Topic 1: Introduction and Review: Equilibrium •  Example: take the S and D curves illustrated below

Q1

P1

P

Q

S

D

At price P1, consumers want to buy Q1 units, producers want to sell Q1 units consumer and producer behavior is consistent.

If P > P1, S > D and there would be pressure on P to fall.

At equilibrium of P1 and Q1, NB to consumers = CS = area A and NB to producers = PS = area B.

Agg NB = CS + PS = A + B

A

B

Note that area A is aggregate CS and area B is aggregate PS. That is, CS is sum of all individual consumers’ CS and PS is sum of all individual producers’ PS.

Page 44: Economics 325 Public Economics - University of Victoriaweb.uvic.ca/~mfarnham/325/T1_intro_review.pdf · Economics 325 Public Economics ... • In this case, government intervention

Topic 1: Introduction and Review: Equilibrium •  One very important thing to note: aggregate NB always the same

if Q the same, no matter what happens to P.

•  Another way of saying this is that aggregate NB function only of total Q, while the distribution of NB depends on P.

Q1

P1

P

Q

S

D

Example: here equilibrium would be P1, Q1. But, if government imposes a quota at Q2, new equilibrium would be at P2, Q2 where: CS = A PS = B + C + D

But now suppose that (instead of quota), government instead says P cannot rise above P3 (“price ceiling”). Equilibrium still Q2 but with different P. Now we have: CS = A + B + C PS = D

Agg NB = CS + PS = A + B + C + D

Q2

P2 A B C

P3 D

Agg NB = A + B + C + D Same in total, distribution different. 44

Page 45: Economics 325 Public Economics - University of Victoriaweb.uvic.ca/~mfarnham/325/T1_intro_review.pdf · Economics 325 Public Economics ... • In this case, government intervention

Econ 325--Farnham 45

Topic 1: Introduction and Review Summary:

•  We have seen that (absent quotas, price ceilings etc): –  Consumers choose Q such that P = MB

•  i.e., choose to consume where P cuts D curve. •  NB to consumers = CS.

–  Producers choose Q such that P = MC •  i.e. choose to produce where P line cuts S curve. •  NB to producers = PS.

–  Producer and consumer decisions are such that S=D •  Aggregate NB = sum of individual NB •  Sum of individual NB = CS + PS (if consumers and

producers are the the only agents affected by the market).

•  Note that these are positive questions - describing the way in which markets DO work.

•  Can also ask corresponding normative questions.

Page 46: Economics 325 Public Economics - University of Victoriaweb.uvic.ca/~mfarnham/325/T1_intro_review.pdf · Economics 325 Public Economics ... • In this case, government intervention

Econ 325--Farnham 46

Topic 1: Introduction and Review •  Normative questions of interest are:

1.  What quantity of goods should be produced? •  We know that in equilibrium Q is where S=D. •  Under what circumstances is this the “right” Q in total (the one

that maximizes NB)?

2.  Which firms should produce these goods? •  We know that in equilibrium each firm produces until P=MC. •  Under what circumstances is this the “right” Q for each firm (the

one that minimizes aggregate production costs)?

3.  Which consumers should get to consume these goods? •  We know that in equilibrium each consumer chooses Q such

that P=MB. •  Under what circumstances is this the “right” Q for each

consumer (the one that maximizes aggregate benefits from consumption)?

Page 47: Economics 325 Public Economics - University of Victoriaweb.uvic.ca/~mfarnham/325/T1_intro_review.pdf · Economics 325 Public Economics ... • In this case, government intervention

Econ 325--Farnham 47

Topic 1: Introduction and Review •  We will focus primarily on question (1). The efficient allocation will

occur (in all cases discussed in this course) where MC=MB. –  Try to understand the intuition for this:

•  If MC>MB, this tells us the last little bit produced cost more to produce that it gave to consumers in added benefit. Society would be better off with less of the good (Q should fall).

•  If MC<MB, this tells us the last little bit produced cost less to produce that it gave to consumers in added benefit. This suggest that increasing output would raise overall well-being in society (Q should rise).

•  If MC=MB, this tells us the last little bit produced cost exactly the same amount to produce as it gave consumers in added benefit. This tells us this unit made society no better off than it was before (nor any worse off). This is the efficient point.

–  Note that MC=MB in the equilibrium diagram 4 slides back. In a well-functioning market, MC=MB at equilibrium so that the equilibrium is efficient. However, this does not always have to be the case!

•  When market failure occurs (due to something like the presence of an externality or due to monopolistic control of an industry), it may not be the case that MC=MB at equilibrium

•  In such a case, the equilibrium quantity may be different from the efficient quantity.