ECON30010-L2-2016

download ECON30010-L2-2016

of 20

Transcript of ECON30010-L2-2016

  • 8/20/2019 ECON30010-L2-2016

    1/48

    Topic 2: Constrained optimisation

    ECON30010 Microeconomics

    9 - 16 March

    ECON30010 Topic 2: Constrained optimisation 9 - 16 March 1 / 48

  • 8/20/2019 ECON30010-L2-2016

    2/48

    Topic 1 refresherIn most economic problems, the following assumptions seem reasonable:

    Completeness : any two bundles x = ( x 1, x 2) and y = ( y 1, y 2) can becompared.

    Transitivity : if bundle x is at least as good as y and y is at least asgood as bundle z, then x is at least as good as z.

    Continuity (not an exact denition): if bundle x is better than bundley and bundle z is sufficiently close to y, then x is better than z.

    TheoremIf preferences over bundles of goods x satisfy completeness, transitivity,and continuity, then there exists a continuous utility function u (x) that represents these preferences.

    Why is this theorem important? Because mathematicians are very good atworking with functions, and we can use a lot of their tools.

    ECON30010 Topic 2: Constrained optimisation 9 - 16 March 2 / 48

  • 8/20/2019 ECON30010-L2-2016

    3/48

    The plan and the why Having a continuous utility function is very useful, but not enough.

    Budget set Utility maximisation problem◦ Strict monotonicity We cover these two axioms here because they◦ Convexity are related to the maximisation problem.

    The Lagrange method

    Marshallian demandThe name of this topic sounds like math. And our main focus will bemath: it is going to be applied to an economics problem, but my maingoal is to make sure you are comfortable with constrained optimisation.

    Why?We ourselves will need it later, but, more importantly, other subjects willneed it, and much more desperately than we would.So, any effort to become fully comfortable with constrained optimisationwill pay off handsomely in the future (when your macro lecturer will zip pastthe calculations and straight to the optimal solution).

    ECON30010 Topic 2: Constrained optimisation 9 - 16 March 3 / 48

  • 8/20/2019 ECON30010-L2-2016

    4/48

    Constraint

    Constraint A typical agent wants “stuff”. If fth TV set in a room does not

    make an agent any happier, something else (more time? extra hike inmountains?) would make the agent more satised. If an agent to face a meaningful problem – where the solution is notgiving an agent an innite amount of something – we need tointroduce some constraint.

    Earlier, we have dealt with a simple constraint: an agent had $5 thatshe needed to allocate.

    This is not the most typical constraint the agent face, although wewill see plenty of similar simple constraints in this subject.

    We now turn to a more typical one: budget constraint.Budget constraint is often thought of as income and prices, but youwill see on a tutorial that we can interpret the same constraint assomething completely different.

    Even though I “focus” on budget constraint, everything we study

    applies to other “types” of constraints, including $5 one.ECON30010 Topic 2: Constrained optimisation 9 - 16 March 4 / 48

  • 8/20/2019 ECON30010-L2-2016

    5/48

    Constraint

    Budget ConstraintBudget constraint: good 1 and good 2 cost money and an agent (evenWarren Buffet) has a limited amount of it.

    A consumer is restricted to choose a consumption bundle q = ( q 1, q 2)such that p 1q 1 + p 2q 2 ≤ Y . Right now, we are not interested where pricesp 1, p 2 and income Y come from.

    q 1

    q 2

    Y / p 1

    Y p 2

    Budget set p 1q 1 + p 2q 2 ≤ Y

    Budget line p 1q 1 + p 2q 2 = Y

    If q 1 = 0, p 2q 2 = Y ⇒ q 2 = Y / p 2

    If q 2 = 0 , p 1q 1 = Y ⇒ q 1 = Y / p 1

    ECON30010 Topic 2: Constrained optimisation 9 - 16 March 5 / 48

  • 8/20/2019 ECON30010-L2-2016

    6/48

    Consumer maximisation problem

    Consumer maximisation problem

    Formally, we can write this problem as:

    maxq 1 ,q 2

    u (q 1, q 2)

    subject to p 1q 1 + p 2q 2 ≤ Y

    Note that I can write my $5 problem as: maxx , y u (x , y )

    subject to x + y = 5

    ECON30010 Topic 2: Constrained optimisation 9 - 16 March 6 / 48

    bl

  • 8/20/2019 ECON30010-L2-2016

    7/48

    Consumer maximisation problem

    Indifference curves: ECON20002 recapIn ECON20002 you have learned1 that the indifference curve is the

    solution to u (x , y ) = u 0, for different levels of u 0.

    q1

    q 2

    Example for u (q 1, q 2) = q 1q 2

    1In Tutorial 1 you have looked at a similar problem.ECON30010 Topic 2: Constrained optimisation 9 - 16 March 7 / 48

    C i i i bl

  • 8/20/2019 ECON30010-L2-2016

    8/48

    Consumer maximisation problem

    Solving consumer maximisation problem graphically:ECON20002 recap

    q 1

    q 2

    Y / p 1

    Y p 2

    We are looking for the North-East-most indifference curve2, such that ittouches budget constraint (to guarantee the feasibility of the solution).

    2Utility increases in that direction – see the picture on the previous slideECON30010 Topic 2: Constrained optimisation 9 - 16 March 8 / 48

    Cons mer ma imisation problem

  • 8/20/2019 ECON30010-L2-2016

    9/48

    Consumer maximisation problem

    What can go wrong? SatiationConsider an agent, Ann, with preferences:

    u A(q 1, q 2) = − (q 1 − 1)2

    − (q 2 − 1)2

    A similar function appeared in Tutorial 1. We know that this function ismaximised at q = (1 , 1).

    Suppose now that Ann has plenty of money($4) and prices are p 1 = p 2 = 1. Her budgetconstraint is q 1 + q 2 ≤ 4.From Tutorial 1, 3 we know that Ann’sindifference curves are circles. We can alsond that at point q = (2 , 2) indifference

    curve touches the budget line.4

    q 1

    q 2

    Y / p 1

    Y p 2

    But point (2 , 2) is not the maximum! What is going on here?. 3Note: tutorials are very useful!

    4How: by symmetry, we can guess that the point is on the intersection of budget lineand a 45 ◦ line, then nd this po int.

    ECON30010 Topic 2: Constrained optimisation 9 - 16 March 9 / 48

    Consumer maximisation problem

  • 8/20/2019 ECON30010-L2-2016

    10/48

    Consumer maximisation problem

    Strict monotonicity This would not happen if utility function u were increasing: then for

    any point in the interior of the budget set you could increase utility bygiving more of some good.

    However, we should not impose this assumption on utility function:utility function is a fake, and we need to know what it means in termsof something that is not a fake (something that we can observe, suchas choice/preferences).

    This leads us to a new condition on preferences, strict monotonicity:5

    Denition

    If bundle x contains at least as much as bundle y of every good and strictly more of at least one good

    then a consumer with strictly monotone preferences strictly prefers x to y.5This condition was introduced in ECON20002 under the name “more is better”.

    ECON30010 Topic 2: Constrained optimisation 9 - 16 March 10 / 48

    Consumer maximisation problem

  • 8/20/2019 ECON30010-L2-2016

    11/48

    Consumer maximisation problem

    Implication of strict monotonicity.

    Theorem: With strictly monotonic preferences, we can replace inequality≤ with equality = in the consumer maximisation problem, so thatp 1q 1 + p 2q 2 = Y .

    Proof: Suppose not.6 That is, suppose that we cannot replace ≤ by =because the optimal consumption of a consumer, ( q 1, q 2), is such thatp 1q 1 + p 2q 2 = Y < Y . Then consumer has Y − Y of income left over,which can be spent on good 1 and good 2 (say, equally). Yet, if preferences are strictly monotonic, then the consumer is better off. So, if (q 1, q 2) is an optimal consumption bundle, preferences could not be

    strictly monotonic.

    6The proof technique where you assume that the statement of the theorem is wrongand then prove that the condition of the theorem is not satised is called “proof bycontradiction”. Here the statement is that “we can replace ≤ with =” and the condition

    is “preferences are strictly monotonic”.ECON30010 Topic 2: Constrained optimisation 9 - 16 March 11 / 48

    Consumer maximisation problem

  • 8/20/2019 ECON30010-L2-2016

    12/48

    Consumer maximisation problem

    Strict monotonicity, example 1, washing dishes

    DenitionIf bundle x contains

    at least as much as bundle y of every good and

    strictly more of at least one good

    then a consumer with strictly monotone preferences strictly prefers x to y.

    Suppose that the (only) good is “washingdishes”. It does not satisfy monotonicity.

    However, this is not a problem: we only need todene the good as “not washing dishes”.

    ECON30010 Topic 2: Constrained optimisation 9 - 16 March 12 / 48

    Consumer maximisation problem

  • 8/20/2019 ECON30010-L2-2016

    13/48

    Consumer maximisation problem

    Strict monotonicity, example 2, exercise & chocolateDenition

    If bundle x

    contains at least as much as bundle y of every good and

    strictly more of at least one good

    then a consumer with strictly monotone preferences strictly prefers x to y.

    Exercise is good, but too much of exercise is bad.Eating one chocolate bar is fantastic, but fth kilo maycause death.

    In most cases, these examples are not a cause of concern

    because: (1) goods would be more generally dened (e.g.consumed over longer periods of time) and (2) the range of consumption in the problem is where the satiation does nothappen (you won’t eat chocolate only).

    You still need to examine your problem to see whether the assumption ts.ECON30010 Topic 2: Constrained optimisation 9 - 16 March 13 / 48

    Consumer maximisation problem

  • 8/20/2019 ECON30010-L2-2016

    14/48

    p

    What if no strict monotonicity?Strict monotonicity is a “technical” assumption: it is much easier to solvea problem if this assumption is imposed, but we are not doomed if thisassumption does not make sense in our problem. There are moresophisticated methods to nd a solution.With equality, we will use the Lagrange method. With inequalities, wewould need to use the Kuhn-Tucker method.

    You can check when they lived and guess which method is easier.ECON30010 Topic 2: Constrained optimisation 9 - 16 March 14 / 48

    Consumer maximisation problem

  • 8/20/2019 ECON30010-L2-2016

    15/48

    What can go wrong? Non-convexitySuppose that indifference curves look like this:

    q 1

    q 2

    Y / p 1

    Y p 2

    Two optimal consumption bundles

    We then have two optimal consumption bundles. This is not a big problemif nding optimal bundle is our ultimate goal. However, if we want toknow how consumption changes in response to change in prices, havingtwo bundles is not convenient: we do not know which one the agent wouldbe consuming.

    Hence, we want to rule out this situation too.ECON30010 Topic 2: Constrained optimisation 9 - 16 March 15 / 48

    Consumer maximisation problem

  • 8/20/2019 ECON30010-L2-2016

    16/48

    Convexity in chocolate and candy (recap of ECON20002)The usual assumption is that our marginal utility is decreasing: you areecstatic about the rst bar of chocolate, but not so much about thesecond bar.

    This naturally leads to convexity assumption: if you are indifferentbetween

    x : 3 bars of chocolate & 1 candy andy : 3 candies & 1 bar of chocolate,

    then you must prefer (z ) 2 bars of chocolate and 2 candies to x and y .

    Does this assumption always hold? Not necessarily: both aspirin andparacetamol are good against a headache (so, you are, conceivably,indifferent), but having 1/2 of aspirin and 1/2 of paracetamol is a recipefor a disaster.Similarly to strict monotonicity: this is unlikely to be a problem with moregenerally dened goods. At the same time, as always , when you think about

    your specic problem, you do need to think whether this assumption is satised.ECON30010 Topic 2: Constrained optimisation 9 - 16 March 16 / 48

    Consumer maximisation problem

  • 8/20/2019 ECON30010-L2-2016

    17/48

    ConvexityI have told you what convexity means when we talk about 3 chocolates

    and 1 candy. We need to be a bit more general than that.Formal denition of convexity:7

    DenitionSuppose that a consumer is indifferent between bundle x and y. Considera bundle z := αx + (1 − α)y for any α such that 0 < α < 1.8

    The preferences are convex if z x , z y .9

    The preferences are strictly convex if z x , z y .

    7

    Do not confuse convex preferences and convex functions. These are two differentnotions. (Only if you are very curious: The set of better allocations – the inside of the indifference curve – is a convex set;the set above the convex function is a convex set. Convex set is the set that contains a straight line that connects any two

    points of the set.)8This is called a convex combination of x and y.9I do not need the second relation, z y , because I have already assumed

    transitivity. Check that you understand why. The same applies to strict convexity.ECON30010 Topic 2: Constrained optimisation 9 - 16 March 17 / 48

    Consumer maximisation problem

  • 8/20/2019 ECON30010-L2-2016

    18/48

    Strict convexity on a graphDenitionSuppose that a consumer is indifferent between bundle x and y. Consider abundle z := αx + (1 − α)y for any α such that 0 < α < 1.

    The preferences are strictly convex if z x , z y .

    q 1

    q 2

    x

    yz

    Straight line connects x and y.

    Any point on this line is “z” fromthe denition.

    If utility increases in the northeast direction (as it usually does), then thewhole straight line should be above the indifference curve (recall that

    points above indifference curve are more desirable bundles).ECON30010 Topic 2: Constrained optimisation 9 - 16 March 18 / 48

    Consumer maximisation problem

  • 8/20/2019 ECON30010-L2-2016

    19/48

    Solution is unique with strict convexity

    q 1

    q 2

    Y / p 1

    Y p 2

    x

    y

    z

    Straight line connects x and y.Any point on this line is “z” fromthe denition.

    With strict convexity, we will have a unique solution to our maximisationproblem.

    ECON30010 Topic 2: Constrained optimisation 9 - 16 March 19 / 48

    Consumer maximisation problem

  • 8/20/2019 ECON30010-L2-2016

    20/48

    Convexity on a graphDenitionSuppose that a consumer is indifferent between bundle x and y. Consider abundle z := αx + (1 − α)y for any α such that 0 < α < 1.

    The preferences are strictly convex if z x , z y .

    The preferences are convex if z x , z y .

    q 1

    q 2

    x

    yz

    These preferences are convex, but not strictly convex.ECON30010 Topic 2: Constrained optimisation 9 - 16 March 20 / 48

    Consumer maximisation problem

  • 8/20/2019 ECON30010-L2-2016

    21/48

    No unique solution with convexity

    q 1

    q 2

    Y / p 1

    Y p 2

    s

    S

    Convexity holds, but solution is not unique: there is an interval of solutions from s to S .

    ECON30010 Topic 2: Constrained optimisation 9 - 16 March 21 / 48

    Consumer maximisation problem

  • 8/20/2019 ECON30010-L2-2016

    22/48

    Non-convexityDenitionSuppose that a consumer is indifferent between bundle x and y. Consider abundle z := αx + (1 − α)y for any α such that 0 < α < 1.

    The preferences are convex if z x , z y .

    q 1

    q 2

    Y / p 1

    Y p 2

    xy

    z

    These preferences are not convex.ECON30010 Topic 2: Constrained optimisation 9 - 16 March 22 / 48

    Consumer maximisation problem

  • 8/20/2019 ECON30010-L2-2016

    23/48

    More assumptions

    I will also assume that utility function is differentiable, or twice

    differentiable. These assumptions are also traceable to assumptions onpreferences. However, it becomes too technical and I will skip that.

    ECON30010 Topic 2: Constrained optimisation 9 - 16 March 23 / 48

    Consumer maximisation problem

  • 8/20/2019 ECON30010-L2-2016

    24/48

    Solving consumer maximisation problemmaxq 1 ,q 2

    u (q 1, q 2)

    subject to p 1q 1 + p 2q 2 = Y

    This is called constrained maximisation problem because you need to (i)nd max u (q 1, q 2) and (ii) satisfy your constraint (here p 1q 1 + p 2q 2 = Y ).Problem (i) alone is called unconstrained optimisation problem. You can

    guess that constrained maximisation problem is usually more difficult thanan unconstrained one.

    How do you solve constrained maximisation problem? Sometimes you can “see” what the solution is (for example, when

    goods are perfect complements or perfect substitutes); You can substitute in budget constraint ( q 1 = 1p 1 (Y − p 2q 2)) (this iswhat you have done in ECON20002)

    Or you can use the Lagrange methodYou can also use a “shortcut” which comes from the Lagrange method;

    this is what you’ve also done in ECON20002.ECON30010 Topic 2: Constrained optimisation 9 - 16 March 24 / 48

  • 8/20/2019 ECON30010-L2-2016

    25/48

    Consumer maximisation problem

  • 8/20/2019 ECON30010-L2-2016

    26/48

    Constrained Optimisation: Lagrange’s Method, Example 1

    maxq 1 ,q 2 ,λ L (q 1, q 2, λ ) = u (q 1, q 2) + λ[Y − p 1q 1 − p 2q 2]Solve for u (q 1, q 2) = q 1q 2:

    ∂ L (q 1,q 2,λ )∂ q 1 = 0∂ L (q 1,q 2,λ )

    ∂ q 2 = 0∂ L (q 1,q 2,λ )

    ∂λ = 0 .

    ECON30010 Topic 2: Constrained optimisation 9 - 16 March 26 / 48

    Consumer maximisation problem

  • 8/20/2019 ECON30010-L2-2016

    27/48

    Constrained Optimisation: Lagrange’s Method, Example 1

    maxq 1 ,q 2 ,λ L (q 1, q 2, λ ) = u (q 1, q 2) + λ[Y − p 1q 1 − p 2q 2]Solve for u (q 1, q 2) = q 1q 2:

    ECON30010 Topic 2: Constrained optimisation 9 - 16 March 27 / 48

    Consumer maximisation problem

  • 8/20/2019 ECON30010-L2-2016

    28/48

    Constrained Optimisation: Lagrange’s Method, Example 1

    maxq 1 ,q 2 ,λ L (q 1, q 2, λ ) = u (q 1, q 2) + λ[Y − p 1q 1 − p 2q 2]Solve for u (q 1, q 2) = q 1q 2:

    ECON30010 Topic 2: Constrained optimisation 9 - 16 March 28 / 48

    Consumer maximisation problem

  • 8/20/2019 ECON30010-L2-2016

    29/48

    Lagrangian: A more careful look

    ∂ L

    (q 1 ,q 2 ,λ )∂ q 1 = ∂ u (q 1 ,q 2)∂ q 1 − λ p 1 = 0∂ L (q 1 ,q 2 ,λ )

    ∂ q 2= ∂ u (q 1 ,q 2)∂ q 2 − λ p 2 = 0

    ∂ L (q 1 ,q 2 ,λ )∂λ = Y − p 1q 1 − p 2q 2 = 0 .

    MU 1(q 1, q 2) = λp 1MU 2(q 1, q 2) = λp 2p 1q 1 + p 2q 2 = Y

    ⇒MRS = MU 1(q 1 ,q 2)MU 2(q 1 ,q 2) =

    p 1p 2

    p 1q 1 + p 2q 2 = Y .

    λ = MU 1

    p 1=

    MU 2p 2

    λ is equal to marginal utility of good i divided by the price of thatgood; that is, an increase in utility if income Y is increased by 1 cent.

    ECON30010 Topic 2: Constrained optimisation 9 - 16 March 29 / 48

    Consumer maximisation problem

  • 8/20/2019 ECON30010-L2-2016

    30/48

    Shadow value of a constraint: an exampleRevisit our utility function u (q 1, q 2) = q 1q 2.

    Recall that MU 1 = q 2, MU 2 = q 1, q 1 = Y 2p 1 , and q 2 = Y 2p 2 ; from theprevious slide λ = q 2/ p 1 = q 1/ p 2

    Let Y = 1 , p 1 = 1 / 2, p 2 = 2. Then q 1 = 1 , q 2 = 1 / 4, u (q 1, q 2) = 0 .25 andthe shadow value of a constraint is λ = 1 / 2.

    Let Y = 1 .01 now; p 1 = 1 / 2, p 2 = 2 as before. Then q 1 = 1 .01,q 2 = 1 .01/ 4, u (q 1, q 2) = 1 .012/ 4 = 0 .255025.

    Note that

    ∆u

    = 0 .255025−

    0.25 = 0 .005025≈

    0.005 = 1 / 2·

    (1.01−

    1) = λ·

    ∆Y

    Change in u is almost equal to λ times the change in “how binding” theconstraint is. It would have been exactly 0.005 if the increase in income Y has been even smaller (you can try that at home).

    ECON30010 Topic 2: Constrained optimisation 9 - 16 March 30 / 48

    Consumer maximisation problem

  • 8/20/2019 ECON30010-L2-2016

    31/48

    Constrained Optimisation: Lagrange’s Method, Example 2Consider another utility function: u (q 1, q 2) = q 1q 2 + 3 q 1. Let p 1 = p 2 = 1

    and Y = 2The Lagrangian is

    L (q 1, q 2, λ ) = q 1q 2 + 3q 1 + λ[2 − q 1 − q 2],

    ∂ L (q 1 ,q 2 ,λ )∂ q 1 = q 2 + 3 − λ = 0

    ∂ L (q 1 ,q 2 ,λ )∂ q 2 = q 1 − λ = 0

    ∂ L (q 1 ,q 2 ,λ )∂λ = 2 − q 1 − q 2 = 0 .

    q 1 = q 2 + 3q 2 + 3 + q 2 = 2

    ⇒ 2q 2 = − 1

    Not the best news. . .ECON30010 Topic 2: Constrained optimisation 9 - 16 March 31 / 48

    Consumer maximisation problem

  • 8/20/2019 ECON30010-L2-2016

    32/48

    Constrained Optimisation: Lagrange’s Method, Example 2

    q 1

    q 2

    Y / p 1

    Y p 2

    Optimal consumption bundle

    (corner solution)Optimal consumption bundle

    if can consume negative quantities

    Lagrange method is not aware that you cannot consume negative

    quantities.ECON30010 Topic 2: Constrained optimisation 9 - 16 March 32 / 48

    Consumer maximisation problem

  • 8/20/2019 ECON30010-L2-2016

    33/48

    A diversion: a complete constrained problem

    maxq 1 ,q 2

    u (q 1, q 2)

    subject top 1q 1 + p 2q 2 = Y q 1 ≥ 0

    q 2 ≥ 0Yet, the solution to this problem, using Kuhn-Tucker conditions, would betoo messy. Hence, we ignore some of the constraints, with a hope thatthey would not matter, but need to revisit our problem once we obtained

    the solution to a simplied problem.

    Surprisingly, a lot of problems in economics are solved this way: Originalproblem is too hard; let us try to solve a simplied problem, hoping that itssolution will satisfy other constraints; if not, try a different simplication.

    ECON30010 Topic 2: Constrained optimisation 9 - 16 March 33 / 48

    Consumer maximisation problem

  • 8/20/2019 ECON30010-L2-2016

    34/48

    Marshallian demand function

    Revisit our solution in Example 1:

    q 1 = Y 2p 1

    q 2 = Y

    2p 2

    Note that we obtained the solution for any prices p 1, p 2 and any incomeY . That is, we could write the solution as functions q 1(p 1, p 2, Y ) andq 2(p 1, p 2, Y ). These functions are called Marhsallian, or uncompensated, 10

    demand.

    10You can look up your notes from ECON20002 if you want to know right now why

    the demand is called uncompensated, or you can wait a little.ECON30010 Topic 2: Constrained optimisation 9 - 16 March 34 / 48

    Summary

  • 8/20/2019 ECON30010-L2-2016

    35/48

    Summary and what’s next:

    Main points:

    Assumptions on individual preferences allow us to represent thesepreferences by a continuous utility function;

    Maximisation of a utility function subject to a budget constraint(using Lagrange method) leads to Marshallian demand functions.

    Lagrange method: turn constrained optimisation problem intounconstrained maximisation problem.Solve unconstrained maximisation problem using standard methods.

    What’s next:

    A more difficult constrained maximisation problem. An odd maximisation problem. Normal, inferior and Giffen goods.

    Testing consumer demand theory: a search for Giffen goods.

    ECON30010 Topic 2: Constrained optimisation 9 - 16 March 35 / 48

    Utility maximisation problems

    l bl ( )

  • 8/20/2019 ECON30010-L2-2016

    36/48

    Utility maximisation problem 1 (Ii)

    u (q 1, q

    2) = ln( q

    1− b

    1) − 2ln(b

    2− q

    2)

    For numerical calculations I use b 1

    = 1 , b 2

    = 3 , p 1

    = 1 , p 2

    = 1 , Y = 4

    ECON30010 Topic 2: Constrained optimisation 9 - 16 March 36 / 48

    Utility maximisation problems

    U ili i i i bl 1 (II)

  • 8/20/2019 ECON30010-L2-2016

    37/48

    Utility maximisation problem 1 (II)

    maxq 1 ,q 2

    u (q 1, q 2) = ln( q 1 − b 1) − 2ln(b 2 − q 2)

    subject to p 1q 1 + p 2q 2 = Y

    Corresponding Lagrangian

    L = ln( q 1 − b 1) − 2ln(b 2 − q 2) + λ [Y − p 1q 1 − p 2q 2]

    ECON30010 Topic 2: Constrained optimisation 9 - 16 March 37 / 48

    Utility maximisation problems

    S l i bl 1 FOC

  • 8/20/2019 ECON30010-L2-2016

    38/48

    Solving problem 1: FOC∂ L∂ q 1

    = 1

    q 1 − b 1− λp 1 = 0

    ∂ L∂ q 2

    = 2

    b 2 − q 2− λp 2 = 0

    ∂ L∂λ

    = Y − p 1q 1 − p 2q 2 = 0

    1

    q 1 − b 1= λp 1

    2b 2 − q 2

    = λp 2

    p 1q 1 + p 2q 2 = Y

    b 2 − q 2q 1 − b 1

    = 2p 1p 2

    p 1q 1 + p 2q 2 = Y

    q 2 = b 2 − 2 p 1p 2(q 1 − b 1)

    Y = p 1q 1 + p 2q 2 = p 1q 1 + p 2(b 2 − 2p 1p 2

    (q 1 − b 1))

    = p 1q 1 + p 2b 2 − 2p 1(q 1 − b 1) = p 2b 2 − p 1q 1 + 2p 1b 1

    q 1 = 2b 1 − Y − p 2b 2

    p 1; q 2 = b 2 − 2

    p 1p 2

    b 1 − Y − p 2b 2

    p 1

    = b 2 − 2 1p 2

    (b 1p 1 − Y + p 2b 2) = 2Y − b 1p 1

    p 2− b 2

    Reminder: ln(x ) is a dream for differentiation: ln( x ) = 1 / x ECON30010 Topic 2: Constrained optimisation 9 - 16 March 38 / 48

    Utility maximisation problems

    S l ti t tilit i i ti bl 1

  • 8/20/2019 ECON30010-L2-2016

    39/48

    Solution to utility maximisation problem 1Marshallian (uncompensated) demand is:

    q 1(p 1, p 2, Y ) = 2 b 1 − Y − p 2b 2

    p 1

    q 2(p 1, p 2, Y ) = 2Y − b 1p 1

    p 2− b 2

    However, this is not the end of the solution:11 suppose thatY = 3 , b 1 = b 2 = p 1 = p 2. Then q 1 = 2 − 3− 11 = 0. If we go back to theutility function, u (q 1, q 2) = ln( q 1 − b 1) − 2ln(b 2 − q 2), it is not dened if q 1 = 0 and b 1 = 1 because it leads to ln(0 − 1), which is undened. Toensure that q 1 − b 1 > 0 and b 2 − q 2 > 0 we need to impose the followingconditions:

    For q 1 > b 1 we need 2b 1 − Y − p 2b 2

    p 1> b 1 hence Y − p 2b 2 < p 1b 1 and

    for 0 < q 2 < b 2 we need Y − p 2b 2 < p 1b 1 < Y − p 2b 2/ 211 We always need to check that our solution makes sense, but in simple examples it is

    “obvious”.ECON30010 Topic 2: Constrained optimisation 9 - 16 March 39 / 48

    Types of goods

    T f g d l g d

  • 8/20/2019 ECON30010-L2-2016

    40/48

    Types of goods: normal goods

    Consider good 2:

    ∂ q 2(p 1, p 2, Y )∂ Y =

    ∂ ∂ Y 2

    Y − b 1p 1p 2 − b 2 =

    2p 2 > 0 because p 2 > 0.

    The consumption of good 2 increases as the income of this individualincreases.These goods are called normal .

    ECON30010 Topic 2: Constrained optimisation 9 - 16 March 40 / 48

    Types of goods

    Types of goods: luxury goods

  • 8/20/2019 ECON30010-L2-2016

    41/48

    Types of goods: luxury goodsIn fact, we can do even more math and look at what share of income thisindividual spends on good 2, and how it changes with income:

    ∂ ∂ Y

    p 2q 2(p 1, p 2, Y )Y

    = p 2Y ∂ ∂ Y q 2(p 1, p 2, Y ) − q 2(p 1, p 2, Y )

    Y 2

    = 2Y − (2(Y − b 1p 1) − b 2p 2)

    Y 2 = b 1p 1 + b 2p 2

    Y 2 > 0

    This is a luxury good. For this good, the individual spends larger share of her income on the good as income rises. That is, if an individual spends

    10% of income on good 2 at income level Y, if income increases by , theshare spent from this would be above 10%.12 In fact, in our case it ispossible that b 1p 1+ b 2p 2Y 2 > 1, so an individual spend the whole and more on good 2.

    12

    This sentence implies that luxury goods must also be normal.ECON30010 Topic 2: Constrained optimisation 9 - 16 March 41 / 48

    Types of goods

    Types of goods: inferior goods

  • 8/20/2019 ECON30010-L2-2016

    42/48

    Types of goods: inferior goodsConsider good 1:

    ∂ q 1(p 1, p 2, Y )∂ Y

    = ∂ ∂ Y

    2b 1 − Y − p 2b 2

    p 1= −

    1p 1

    < 0 because p 1 > 0

    The consumption of good 1 decreases as the income of this individualincreases.These goods are called inferior .

    Note that our formula implies that if the price of good 1 is very low, theconsumption of this good decreases extremely fast as income increases. It maysound peculiar on a rst sight, but should not be surprising: if price of good 1 isvery low, then this individual consumes a lot of good 1 to begin with, so the fallin consumption is also very large.

    ECON30010 Topic 2: Constrained optimisation 9 - 16 March 42 / 48

    Types of goods

    Giffen goods

  • 8/20/2019 ECON30010-L2-2016

    43/48

    Giffen goodsConsider good 1 again:

    ∂ q 1(p 1, p 2, Y )∂ p 1

    = ∂ ∂ p 1

    2b 1 − Y − p 2b 2

    p 1=

    Y − p 2b 2(p 1)2

    Suppose Y , p 2 and b 2 are such that Y − p 2b 2 > 0. Then ∂ q 1(p 1 ,p 2 ,Y )

    ∂ p 1 > 0.It means that as price of good 1 increases, the consumption of good 1increases. These goods are called Giffen goods. This is an unusualproperty and we will explore it in a little more detail.

    First, let us see what the condition Y − p 2b 2 > 0 implies in terms of theamount of good 1 consumed. The demand for good 1 is 2b 1 − Y

    − p 2b 2p 1 , so

    if Y − p 2b 2 > 0, then q 1 < 2b 1. That is, ∂ q 1(p 1 ,p 2 ,Y )

    ∂ p 1 > 0 only when theconsumption of good 1 is low.

    ECON30010 Topic 2: Constrained optimisation 9 - 16 March 43 / 48

    Types of goods

    Giffen property vs Giffen goods

  • 8/20/2019 ECON30010-L2-2016

    44/48

    Giffen property vs. Giffen goods

    ∂ q 1(p 1, p 2, Y )∂ p 1

    > 0 if Y − p 2b 2 > 0

    ∂ q 1(p 1, p 2, Y )∂ p 1

    < 0 otherwise

    We see that derivative may change for different values of Y , p 2 and b 2.A more proper terminology should be a good that “exhibits Giffenproperty” in the range b 1 < q 1 < 2b 1.13

    All other goods can be change their “properties” depending on particularprices and income; for example, a good can be normal over a range of prices and incomes and inferior over a different range.

    13

    The condition b

    1 < q

    1 comes from slide (39).ECON30010 Topic 2: Constrained optimisation 9 - 16 March 44 / 48

    Types of goods

    Another example of constrained optimisation

  • 8/20/2019 ECON30010-L2-2016

    45/48

    Another example of constrained optimisation

    We will talk more about Giffen behaviour; before we turn to that, we willrevisit our utility function that gave Giffen behaviour and will change justone coefficient.

    Old:

    u (q 1, q 2) = ln( q 1 − b 1) − 2 ln(b 2 − q 2)

    New:

    u (q 1, q 2) = ln( q 1 − b 1) − ln(b 2 − q 2)

    ECON30010 Topic 2: Constrained optimisation 9 - 16 March 45 / 48

    Types of goods

    Solving problem 2: FOC

  • 8/20/2019 ECON30010-L2-2016

    46/48

    Solving problem 2: FOC

    ∂ L

    ∂ q 1=

    1

    q 1 − b 1− λp 1 = 0

    ∂ L∂ q 2

    = 2

    b 2 − q 2− λp 2 = 0

    ∂ L∂λ

    = Y − p 1q 1 − p 2q 2 = 0

    1q 1 − b 1 = λp 1

    2b 2 − q 2

    = λp 2

    p 1q 1 + p 2q 2 = Y

    b 2 − q 2

    q 1 − b 1=

    p 1

    p 2p 1q 1 + p 2q 2 = Y .

    q 2 = b 2 − p 1p 2

    (q 1 − b 1)

    Y = p 1q 1 + p 2q 2 = p 1q 1 + p 2(b 2 − p 1p 2

    (q 1 − b 1))

    = p 1q 1 + p 2b 2 − p 1(q 1 − b 1) = p 2b 2 − p 1b 1

    Where is q 1?Or q 2?What if p 2b 2 − p 1b 1 is not equal Y ?

    ECON30010 Topic 2: Constrained optimisation 9 - 16 March 46 / 48

    Types of goods

    How a new utility function looks like?

  • 8/20/2019 ECON30010-L2-2016

    47/48

    How a new utility function looks like?

    Indifference curves are indifference lines, like with perfect complements! Itis not surprising that we cannot nd a solution (it is akin to maximisinglinear function f (x ) = x using rst order conditions: you’ve triedsomething like this in Tutorial 1).

    ECON30010 Topic 2: Constrained optimisation 9 - 16 March 47 / 48

    Types of goods

    Summary

  • 8/20/2019 ECON30010-L2-2016

    48/48

    Summary

    Skills: Lagrange method of optimisation. Cases when Lagrange method does not produce meaningful results ordoes not work.

    Necessity to watch for corner solutions / impose conditions to ensurethat your solution makes sense.

    Economics:

    Marshallian demand, formal denitions of different types of goods.

    ECON30010 Topic 2: Constrained optimisation 9 - 16 March 48 / 48