Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses...

41
Choice

Transcript of Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses...

Page 1: Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those available.

Choice

Page 2: Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those available.

Economic Rationality

The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those available to it.

The available choices constitute the choice set.

Page 3: Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those available.

Economic Rationality

How is the most preferred bundle in the choice set located?

The answer is simple: the consumer chooses the bundle within the choice set that is on the indifference curve that provides the highest level of utility.

Page 4: Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those available.

Rational Constrained Choice

x1

x2

x1*

x2*

Page 5: Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those available.

Rational Constrained Choice

x1

x2

x1*

x2*

(x1*,x2*) is the mostpreferred affordablebundle.

Page 6: Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those available.

Rational Constrained Choice

When x1* > 0 and x2* > 0 the demanded bundle is INTERIOR.

If buying (x1*,x2*) costs €m then the budget is exhausted.

Page 7: Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those available.

Rational Constrained Choice

x1

x2

x1*

x2*

(x1*,x2*) is interior.(a) (x1*,x2*) exhausts thebudget: p1x1* + p2x2* = m

Page 8: Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those available.

Rational Constrained Choice

x1

x2

x1*

x2*

(x1*,x2*) is interior.(b) The slope of the indiff.curve at (x1*,x2*) equals the slope of the budget constraint

Page 9: Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those available.

Rational Constrained Choice (x1*,x2*) satisfies two conditions: (a) the budget is exhausted

p1x1* + p2x2* = m (b) the slope of the budget constraint,

-p1/p2, and the slope of the indifference curve containing (x1*,x2*) are equal at (x1*,x2*).

Page 10: Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those available.

Rational Constrained Choice For well-behaved (monotonic and

convex) preferences, tangency is a necessary and sufficient condition for optimality.

At the optimum the consumer substitutes one good for the other at a rate identical to the market’s.

Page 11: Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those available.

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example

Suppose that the consumer has Cobb-Douglas preferences.

U x x x xa b( , )1 2 1 2

Page 12: Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those available.

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example

Suppose that the consumer has Cobb-Douglas preferences.

Then

U x x x xa b( , )1 2 1 2

MUUx

ax xa b1

1112

MUUx

bx xa b2

21 2

1

Page 13: Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those available.

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example

So the MRS is

12 1 1 2 2

11 2 1 2 1

/

/

a b

a b

dx U x ax x axMRS

dx U x bx x bx

Page 14: Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those available.

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example.

So the MRS is

At (x1*,x2*), MRS = -p1/p2 so

12 1 1 2 2

11 2 1 2 1

/

/

a b

a b

dx U x ax x axMRS

dx U x bx x bx

** *2 1 12 1*

1 2 2

ax p bpx x

bx p ap (A)

Page 15: Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those available.

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example.

(x1*,x2*) also exhausts the budget so

* *1 1 2 2p x p x m (B)

Page 16: Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those available.

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example.

So now we know that

* *12 1

2

bpx x

ap (A)

* *1 1 2 2p x p x m (B)

Page 17: Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those available.

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example.

So now we know that

xbpap

x21

21

* * (A)

* *1 1 2 2p x p x m (B)

Substitute

Page 18: Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those available.

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example.

So now we know that

xbpap

x21

21

* * (A)

* *1 1 2 2p x p x m (B)

* *11 1 2 1

2

bpp x p x m

ap

Substitute

and get

This simplifies to ….

Page 19: Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those available.

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example.

*1

1( )

amx

a b p

Page 20: Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those available.

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example.

*2

2( )

bmx

a b p

Substituting for x1* in p x p x m1 1 2 2

* *

then gives

*1

1( )

amx

a b p

Page 21: Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those available.

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example.

So we have discovered that the mostpreferred affordable bundle for a consumerwith Cobb-Douglas preferences

U x x x xa b( , )1 2 1 2

is * *1 2

1 2

( , ) ,( ) ( )

am bmx x

a b p a b p

Page 22: Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those available.

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example.

x1

x2

*1

1( )

amx

a b p

*2

2( )

bmx

a b p

U x x x xa b( , )1 2 1 2

Page 23: Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those available.

Rational Constrained Choice When x1* > 0 and x2* > 0

and (x1*,x2*) exhausts the budget,and indifference curves have no ‘kinks’, the ordinary demands are obtained by solving:

(a) p1x1* + p2x2* = m

(b) the slopes of the budget constraint, -p1/p2, and of the indifference curve containing (x1*,x2*) are equal at (x1*,x2*).

Page 24: Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those available.

Rational Constrained Choice

But what if x1* = 0?

Or if x2* = 0?

If either x1* = 0 or x2* = 0 then the ordinary demand (x1*,x2*) is at a corner solution to the problem of maximizing utility subject to a budget constraint.

Page 25: Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those available.

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect Substitutes Case

x1

x2

MRS = -1

Page 26: Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those available.

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect Substitutes Case

x1

x2

MRS = -1

Slope = -p1/p2 with p1 > p2

Page 27: Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those available.

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect Substitutes Case

x1

x2

MRS = -1

Slope = -p1/p2 with p1 > p2

Page 28: Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those available.

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect Substitutes Case

x1

x2

*2

2

mx

p

x1 0*

MRS = -1

Slope = -p1/p2 with p1 > p2

Page 29: Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those available.

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect Substitutes Case

x1

x2

*1

1

mx

p

x2 0*

MRS = -1

Slope = -p1/p2 with p1< p2

Page 30: Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those available.

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect Substitutes Case

So when U(x1,x2) = x1 + x2, the mostpreferred affordable bundle is (x1*,x2*)where

* *1 2

1

( , ) ,0m

x xp

and

* *1 2

2

( , ) 0,m

x xp

if p1 < p2

if p1 > p2

Page 31: Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those available.

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect Substitutes Case

x1

x2

MRS = -1

Slope = - p1/p2 with p1= p2

1

m

p

2

m

p

Page 32: Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those available.

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect Substitutes Case

x1

x2

All the bundles in the constraint are equally the most preferred affordable when p1 = p2

2

m

p

1

m

p

Page 33: Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those available.

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case

x1

x2U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2}

x2 = ax1

Page 34: Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those available.

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case

x1

x2

MRS = -

MRS = 0

MRS is undefined

U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2}

x2 = ax1

Page 35: Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those available.

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case

x1

x2U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2}

x2 = ax1

Which is the mostpreferred affordable bundle?

Page 36: Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those available.

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case

x1

x2U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2}

x2 = ax1

The most preferredaffordable bundle

Page 37: Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those available.

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case

(a) p1x1* + p2x2* = m; (b) x2* = ax1*

Substitution from (b) for x2* in (a) gives p1x1* + p2ax1* = mwhich gives

* *1 2

1 2 1 2

,m am

x xp ap p ap

Page 38: Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those available.

Application: choosing a tax

Which is less harmful, a quantity tax or an income tax, both allowing the same revenue?

1. We can show that an income tax is always better in the sense that given any quantity tax, there is an income tax that leaves the consumer at a higher indifference curve.

Page 39: Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those available.

Application: choosing a tax

2. Outline of the argument:

a) original budget constraint: p1x1 + p2x2 = m

b) budget constraint with quantity tax:

(p1 + t)x1+p2x2 = m

c) optimal choice with tax: (p1+t)x1* + p2x2

* = m

d) revenue raised is tx1*

Page 40: Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those available.

Application: choosing a tax

e) income tax (lump-sum) that raises the same amount of revenue leads to budget constraint: p1x1 + p2x2 = m - tx1*i) this line has the same slope as the original budget line, but lies inwards

Page 41: Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those available.

Application: choosing a tax

ii) also passes through (x1*;x2*)

iii) proof: p1x1*+ p2x2* = m - tx1*

iv) this means that (x1*; x2* ) is affordable under the income tax, so the optimal choice under the income tax must be even better than (x1 *; x2*)