Battle of the Classics

download Battle of the Classics

of 31

Transcript of Battle of the Classics

  • 8/11/2019 Battle of the Classics

    1/31

    http://jcs.sagepub.com/Journal of Classical Sociology

    http://jcs.sagepub.com/content/3/1/67The online version of this article can be found at:

    DOI: 10.1177/1468795X03003001695

    2003 3: 67Journal of Classical SociologyMathieu Deflem

    Battle of the ClassicsThe Sociology of the Sociology of Money : Simmel and the Contemporary

    Published by:

    http://www.sagepublications.com

    can be found at:Journal of Classical SociologyAdditional services and information for

    http://jcs.sagepub.com/cgi/alertsEmail Alerts:

    http://jcs.sagepub.com/subscriptionsSubscriptions:

    http://www.sagepub.com/journalsReprints.navReprints:

    http://www.sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.navPermissions:

    http://jcs.sagepub.com/content/3/1/67.refs.htmlCitations:

    What is This?

    - Mar 1, 2003Version of Record>>

    at BROWN UNIVERSITY on May 9, 2013jcs.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/content/3/1/67http://jcs.sagepub.com/content/3/1/67http://jcs.sagepub.com/content/3/1/67http://www.sagepublications.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/cgi/alertshttp://jcs.sagepub.com/cgi/alertshttp://jcs.sagepub.com/subscriptionshttp://jcs.sagepub.com/subscriptionshttp://www.sagepub.com/journalsReprints.navhttp://www.sagepub.com/journalsReprints.navhttp://www.sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.navhttp://jcs.sagepub.com/content/3/1/67.refs.htmlhttp://jcs.sagepub.com/content/3/1/67.refs.htmlhttp://online.sagepub.com/site/sphelp/vorhelp.xhtmlhttp://online.sagepub.com/site/sphelp/vorhelp.xhtmlhttp://jcs.sagepub.com/content/3/1/67.full.pdfhttp://jcs.sagepub.com/content/3/1/67.full.pdfhttp://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://online.sagepub.com/site/sphelp/vorhelp.xhtmlhttp://jcs.sagepub.com/content/3/1/67.full.pdfhttp://jcs.sagepub.com/content/3/1/67.refs.htmlhttp://www.sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.navhttp://www.sagepub.com/journalsReprints.navhttp://jcs.sagepub.com/subscriptionshttp://jcs.sagepub.com/cgi/alertshttp://www.sagepublications.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/content/3/1/67http://jcs.sagepub.com/
  • 8/11/2019 Battle of the Classics

    2/31

    The Sociology of the Sociology of Money

    Simmel and the Contemporary Battle of the Classics

    MATHIEU DEFLEM University of South Carolina

    ABSTRACT I offer a discussion of Simmels Philosophy of Money in comparison

    with the analyses of money in the writings of Marx, Weber and Durkheim. Based

    on this analysis, I argue that Simmels ambiguous status as a classic can be

    accounted for by some of the characteristics of his approach as well as the

    historical (non-)reception of his work. Simmels relative neglect in sociology for

    the better part of the century as well as his recent revival with the rise of the new

    cultural studies and the postmodern paradigm shift hint at an important interde-pendence between the history and systematics of sociological theory. The theme

    of money has not managed to be accepted as an undisputed topic of sociological

    reflection because of its non-independent status in most social theories (apart

    from Simmels) as well as the factual resistance to totalizing accounts (like

    Simmels) in the history of sociology. Recent transformations in social theory,

    however, indicate that money may, and to some extent already has, become a

    more autonomous topic of inquiry. In conclusion, I argue that Simmels work

    does lend itself to be taken up in postmodern perspectives and that the socio-

    logical study of money can likewise be appropriated by the new cultural studies.However, these new perspectives will have to come to terms with the modernist

    resistance of Simmel and the other sociological classics remaining influence in

    contemporary sociological theory.

    KEYWORDS Durkheim, Marx, modernity, money, Simmel, sociological theory,

    Weber

    I know that I shall die without intellectual heirs, and that is as it should be.My legacy will be, as it were, in cash, distributed to many heirs, each

    transforming his part into use conformed to hisnature: a use which will

    reveal no longer its indebtedness to its heritage.

    (Georg Simmel)

    Journal of Classical SociologyCopyright 2003 SAGE Publications London, Thousand Oaks and New Delhi Vol 3(1): 6796 [1468795X(200303)3:1;6796;031695]

    www.sagepublications.com

    at BROWN UNIVERSITY on May 9, 2013jcs.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/
  • 8/11/2019 Battle of the Classics

    3/31

    This paper takes as a point of departure Georg Simmels study of money in his

    famous book The Philosophy of Money (1900, 1989, 1990). Against the back-

    ground of this work, I will examine how the theme of money was reflected upon

    in the social theories of Karl Marx, Max Weber and Emile Durkheim. This

    comparative investigation will serve to uncover some of the underlying theoreticalassumptions that account for the similarities and differences in the particular

    perspectives of these classics. While Simmels work has regularly been evaluated in

    comparison to any one of the sociological classics (e.g. Beilharz, 1996; Deutsch-

    mann, 1996; Faught, 1985), it has not been assessed in terms of its (dis)associa-

    tions with the classics as a unity. On the basis of an analysis of the money theme,

    therefore, this paper will position and discuss Simmel as a classic among the

    classics.

    While not pretending to offer an in-depth investigation of the manyintricacies involved with comparing Simmel with Weber, Marx and Durkheim, this

    paper will serve to elucidate the status and reception of Simmels work as one of

    the building-blocks in the founding of sociology. Based on the insight that such

    an endeavor has implications for the formation as well as reception of sociological

    theory (Alexander, 1987), I will orient my discussion not only to an examination

    of the sociological study of money proper, but also to the social context of

    Simmels writings, to consider how his work has been received and evaluated in

    sociology. This paper, then, will advance some theoretical ideas on the sociology

    of money as well as present a chapter in the sociology of sociology.I develop my arguments as follows. First, I briefly review the main theses

    of Simmels work on money and relate it to his broader intellectual and socio-

    logical project. Then, I discuss themes of a sociology of money in the writings of

    Marx, Weber and Durkheim, and evaluate their work in comparison to Simmels.

    Finally, I suggest how the reception of Simmels work and some of its assumptions

    have affected, and may continue to shape, the sociological study of money.

    Simmel on Sociology, Money, Individual andSociety

    The work of Georg Simmel is most commonly analyzed in terms of its innovative

    contribution to the study of society, that is, as a distinct mode of sociological

    thinking. In Simmels substantive discussions of society, which have not been

    ignored, his work on the social significance of money has generally not received

    the attention that his other studies of modernity have come to enjoy. To use-fully present Simmels analysis of money, I will discuss the basic themes of his

    theoretical perspective, present a brief description of the various elements in his

    sociology of money, and relate these back to his general sociological

    outlook.

    JOURNAL OF CLASSICAL SOCIOLOGY VOL 3(1)68

    at BROWN UNIVERSITY on May 9, 2013jcs.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/
  • 8/11/2019 Battle of the Classics

    4/31

    A Picture of Simmels Sociology

    Central to Simmels social theory are his conceptions of formal sociology and

    notion of sociation, which are situated in a more encompassing distinction

    between general, formal and philosophical sociology (Simmel, 1964, 1971: 140;see also Frisby, 1985, 1992: 541; Levine, 1971; Wolff, 1964: xxviixl). Simmel

    conceives of sociology in the first place as a method, a point of view from which to

    take a picture of its field of study. The three divisions of general, formal and

    philosophical sociology demarcate different viewpoints of sociological photogra-

    phy. General sociology investigates the whole of historical life inasmuch as it is

    societally formed. Historical developments can be perceived from different per-

    spectives, each of which represents a particular frame of analysis or category of

    thought in order to lay bare the objective, individual (subjective) and/or social

    point of view. The social viewpoint is evidently central to sociology, although the

    link with the other perspectives is for Simmel essential. In this respect, he devotes

    most attention to the relationships and differences between individual and social

    life, especially as they extend the historical narratives on particular groups

    (Simmel, 1964: 2639). Formal sociology is concerned with the study of societal

    forms that result out of the sum of interaction among living humans. These forms

    of life must be distinct from their content, Simmel argues, since groups with

    different substantive content (referring to the relatively variable what of social

    life) may exhibit similar, even identical, forms, while the form of groups (referringto the relatively stable how of social action) can differ though their contents are

    the same. The content of social life refers to the drives, interests, purposes,

    inclination, and psychic states around which individuals come together in inter-

    actions that take on certain forms (Simmel, 1964: 402). Typical for Simmels

    study of formal sociology, for example, are his discussions of sociability, super-

    ordination and subordination, competition and other associational forms as

    informing social life through any historical concreteness of the specific manifesta-

    tions of such principles (e.g. Simmel, 1964: 4057 on sociability). Philosophical

    sociology, finally, deals with the epistemology of the special social sciences

    (engaged in the study of any one particular manifestation of social life) and the

    metaphysics of their specific topics of investigation. As such, philosophical soci-

    ology is the science of social science. In Simmels work, philosophical sociology is,

    as Wolff (1964: xl) has argued, not of central concern apart from its programmatic

    announcement to develop an epistemology of sociology and its indirect treatment

    through a study of intellectual history, for example on individualism in social

    thought from the 18th to the 19th century (Simmel, 1964: 5884).

    Formal sociology is Simmels favored domain, because he considers it toprovide the most distinct sociological response to the critique of historians that

    the study of society would inevitably be bound to the various concrete, distinct

    and always diverse historical forms of social life. The field of formal sociology is

    closely linked to Simmels conception of individual and society, and the form/

    DEFLEM THE SOCIOLOGY OF THE SOCIOLOGY OF MONEY 69

    at BROWN UNIVERSITY on May 9, 2013jcs.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/
  • 8/11/2019 Battle of the Classics

    5/31

    content distinction in individualsocial relationships. With the study of social

    formations, Simmel wants to overcome the problems associated with methodo-

    logical individualism, stressing the primacy of the individual, and holism or

    sociologism, emphasizing the social. According to Simmel, neither one, society or

    individual, is thinkable without the other. Central to the field of sociology are

    precisely those social formations that overcome the individual/social dualism:

    individuals engage with one another and thereby constitute the social. Society is

    not just the sum total of individual acts, but refers to individuals interconnected

    through social interaction.

    Sociation (Vergesellschaftung) is a crucial concept in Simmels formal

    sociology. Sociation constitutes the process that ties the parts to the whole,

    individuals to one another and society. Sociation is the form (realized in

    innumerably different ways) in which individuals grow together into a unity andwithin which their interests are realized. And it is on the basis of their interests . . .

    that individuals form such unities (Simmel, 1971: 24). Most famous in respect of

    Simmels notion of sociation is his perspective that conflict, rather than implying

    any disconnectness, implies an association between the parties involved (e.g.

    Simmel, 1964: 1629). The inherent mutual implication of society and individual

    suggests Simmels dialectical approach and its manifestations across social and

    cultural forms (see Coser, 1977: 1836). In his analysis of the picture frame, for

    instance, Simmel likens the simultaneous wholeness of a work of art and it beinga unified whole with its surroundings to the general difficulty of life that the

    elements of totalities [groups] nevertheless lay claim to being autonomous

    totalities [individuals] themselves (1994: 17). In the many concrete instances of

    social life, also, sociation functions as a binding principle even and especially when

    groups are relatively confined, as is in the case with the secret society (Simmel,

    1964: 34576). Writes Simmel, sociation offers each of [the members of a secret

    society] psychological support against the temptation of disclosure. Sociation

    counterbalances the isolating and individualizing effect of the secret (1964:

    355).

    Social interaction, then, can be studied from the twofold perspective of

    content and form, with the latter as the dominant theme in Simmels work.

    Separated from the content of action, the forms of social life follow a logic of their

    own. Behind every social formation there are forces at work that should be

    isolated from the content of their manifestation their analysis points to the value

    of abstract or pure sociology. As a logical consequence of these premises, Simmel

    studied all kinds of social phenomena, for no matter how much they differ, behind

    and within them forms of social life operate in society as a whole. The wide varietyof topics discussed by Simmel (fashion, law, space, women, poverty, secrecy, the

    city, art, money) is justified by his premise that the study of any one particular

    topic of sociological reflection inevitably implies its relatedness to other manifesta-

    tions of social life. Any sociology of particularities is at once a total sociology.

    JOURNAL OF CLASSICAL SOCIOLOGY VOL 3(1)70

    at BROWN UNIVERSITY on May 9, 2013jcs.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/
  • 8/11/2019 Battle of the Classics

    6/31

    Snapshots of The Philosophy of Money

    Simmel published his Philosophy of Moneyoriginally in 1900, and republished it in

    1907, when the book was expanded to some 700 pages (Simmel, 19012

    [reprinted in Simmel, 1989: 71923], 1989). Divided over two parts, threechapters each, Simmel relates money to just about every imaginable social

    phenomenon and, indeed, argues for the inextricable links between money, the

    individual and, ultimately, modern society in its totality. It is this characteristic of

    total relationalism that is so clearly obvious in Simmels work on money (Turner,

    1986).

    The first part of Simmels book is analytical, and aims at studying the being

    (Wesen) of money out of the preconditions of social life. Most fundamentally,

    Simmel proposes a study of money that transcends a purely economic approach.

    The point, Simmel argues, is to go beyond moneys place in the market by linking

    it to culture and society in order to understand the deeper valuations and currents

    of psychological, yes, even metaphysical presuppositions (1989: 13). First, he

    analyzes the relationship of money to value (Wert), arguing that, while value has

    an objective side to it (the value transgressing the boundaries of social and

    individual realizations), it is through money that subjective values (that people

    attach to particular objects) become objectified. Values can be differently attached

    to one and the same object, and they are closely connected to objective value

    (since they build up subjective values), but only in money can any subjective valuefind full objective expression or manifestation. The desired object while located

    at a distance from the individual can be captured through a monetary exchange

    relation. The value is determined by the desire that people have to obtain an

    object, not the use-value of the object. Trade is, according to Simmel, essential to

    the constitution of moneys value, for trade allows objects to become exchange-

    able with a value that can be expressed in monetary terms.

    Money represents the objectified articulation (verselbstandigte Ausdruck)

    of exchange relationships, because, separated from all other goods, it is the

    transformer of objects into commodities. Money in modern society becomes

    more and more functional: it establishes relationships, and ties people to one

    another by the flow of goods and services. The price of a product in this exchange,

    Simmel contends, is the measure of exchangeability that exists between it and the

    totality of other products (1989: 123). Money represents the relatedness and

    heterogeneity of objects: money expresses the general element contained in all

    exchangeable objects, . . . it is incapable of expressing the individual element in

    them (1964: 3901). Importantly, the substance of money itself no longer plays

    a role in its function in exchange. Where once money had substance-value (e.g.gold and silver coins), it has become a pure symbol to determine qualities

    quantitatively. Money is an instrument entering into nearly all of peoples social

    interactions. Never a purpose in itself (an sich), money has sheer infinite capacities

    of applicability in exchange relations. At the same time, however, money can

    DEFLEM THE SOCIOLOGY OF THE SOCIOLOGY OF MONEY 71

    at BROWN UNIVERSITY on May 9, 2013jcs.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/
  • 8/11/2019 Battle of the Classics

    7/31

    become a purpose for itself (fur sich), precisely because of its unlimited potentials

    as a means: quantities of money become significant qualities. Economic con-

    sciousness, the need to acquire, and monetary greed increase fundamentally in

    significance not only in the market but in most every sphere of social life, a process

    Simmel describes as the commodification of interactions or the general reduction

    of quality to quantity.

    The second, synthetic part of The Philosophy of Money Simmel directs at

    unfolding the workings of money for the world, that is, the world of the

    individual, culture and society. This leads Simmel to analyze money in relation to

    individual liberty. He argues that money frees the person because the obligation

    to use money (Geldverpflichtung) is only related to the product of labor or to the

    buyer/seller on the market, but never to the whole person. Simmel expresses this

    well in an analysis of superordination and subordination, where he writes: Moneyhas carried to its extreme the separation . . . between man as a personality and man

    as the instrument of a special performance or significance (1964: 293). Through

    the formation of ties among innumerable individuals, money secures personal

    liberty. In such relationships, money allows for the movement of property, and

    property itself becomes an act, an engagement in interactions. Freedom, then,

    refers intimately to property, the possession of goods or money, allowing for the

    establishment of ever more relations: The meditating concept for this correlation

    between money on the one hand, and the enlargement of circles [of socialinteraction], as well as the differentiation of individuals on the other, is often

    private property as such (1989: 473). Money can overcome the physical and

    social distance between individuals, Simmel argues, because of its capacity to be

    absolutely transferable, confined with a process of individualization. At the same

    time, however, persons in society are valued more exclusively in terms of money.

    People can be measured in an objective and absolute way according to the

    monetary value that entering a relationship with them represents. As such, money

    exerts its influence in a variety of social domains: legal rights transform into

    monetary claims, and labor relations become useful only inasmuch as they in-

    volve monetary gains (wages).

    Finally, Simmel debates how money also determines culture and the whole

    rhythm of life. Modern life becomes an intellectual endeavor excluding emotional

    considerations in favor of calculability. The culture of things replaces the culture

    of persons, and the creativity of mind is subject to a process of reification

    (Vergegenstandlichung) in terms of calculable matter. A process of rational intellec-

    tualization goes hand in hand with moneys capacity of transforming objects into

    interchangeable commodities, both principles finding their most extreme realiza-tion in the metropolis, the seat of the money economy, [where] in rational

    relations man is reckoned with like a number (1964: 411). The emergence of

    romantic ideals and strong emotions, Simmel maintains, is but a reaction against

    this monetarization of culture: money and intellect are exchangeable, people and

    JOURNAL OF CLASSICAL SOCIOLOGY VOL 3(1)72

    at BROWN UNIVERSITY on May 9, 2013jcs.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/
  • 8/11/2019 Battle of the Classics

    8/31

    culture can be bought. Through money, all can be bought, all is related, all is in

    constant motion the world is in total flux.

    Money and the Photography of SocietyIn the Preface to The Philosophy of MoneySimmel states that his study of money is

    meant as an example of the broader intent of his sociological enterprise to study

    through every singularity of life, the totality of its meaning (1989: 12). As Poggi

    (1993) argues, money is for Simmel the central structure and symbol in the

    historical formation of modern society. As such, Simmels analysis of money is

    exemplary for his sociological approach. Indeed, the main themes of Simmels

    sociological perspective can be retrieved in the book (see Frisby, 1990b: 513;

    Turner, 1986).The most outstanding characteristic of Simmels sociology in his discus-

    sion on money is the relatedness (Wechselwirkung) of money to other social

    phenomena. As Bryan Turner (1986: 95) remarks, in Simmels work any item of

    culture can be the starting point for sociological research into the nature of the

    totality. . . . Nothing is trivial because everything is related (1986: 95). This

    relationalism is typified by his examination of money as a social institution that can

    only be understood within the total social framework within which it is imbedded.

    Money points to the interdependencies of social life, the way in which all events,

    things and individuals are related. Money has no intrinsic meaning but derives itssignificance from its relatedness to money-vested objects and the money-needy

    subjects that want to acquire these objects.

    Money is also an important medium in the creation of social ties between

    people. Society is not just a collection of individuals, and neither one can be

    conceived without the other. Through money, relationships between people are

    established. At the same time, however, these relations are reified into impersonal

    costbenefit alliances that are able to transgress social and physical boundaries.

    The intellectualization process accompanying the expansion of the money econ-

    omy involves a disintegration of substance into impersonal ties. A general

    tendency to calculability and quantitative control, leading social interactions to

    become dictated more by the money people have or represent, appears unavoid-

    able to Simmel, particularly with moneys tendency to become an end in itself. Yet

    personal freedom is preserved, can even be enhanced, on the basis of property to

    be used in relations of calculable exchange. Referring to popular German expres-

    sions for money, Simmel uses the notions of coal (Kohle) and dough (Knete) to

    clarify the freedom-enhancing qualities of money (see Frerichs, 2001). The poor

    by necessity have to use whatever little money they have as coal, burning throughit as they spend it for specific purposes. The rich, however, have the opportunity

    to reshape the purpose of money, as if it is malleable like dough, and can spend,

    save or invest money to accumulate wealth. To Simmel, also, money has eman-

    cipatory effects because it frees the individual from membership restricted to any

    DEFLEM THE SOCIOLOGY OF THE SOCIOLOGY OF MONEY 73

    at BROWN UNIVERSITY on May 9, 2013jcs.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/
  • 8/11/2019 Battle of the Classics

    9/31

    one collectivity to a web of group affiliations with a plurality of individuals across

    social categories and groups. Money in this way creates freedom (as lack of

    constraint), albeit a freedom that dialectically implies a relative absence of en-

    joyment, of sense, of quality. Writes Simmel, money produces both a previously

    unknown impersonality in all economic ownership and an equally enhancedindependence and autonomy of the personality (1991: 18). Money alienates and

    separates but it also creates bonds among the members of the network where it

    circulates.

    Finally, while Simmels differentiation between general, formal and philo-

    sophical sociology was not explicitly developed until after the publication of The

    Philosophy of Money, both formal and philosophical components can be discerned

    in this work. Most clearly, in seeking to go beyond the presuppositions of

    monetary economics, Simmel presents a chapter in philosophical sociology. Heseeks to uncover the ontology of moneys role in society through an inquiry into

    the nature of reality suggested by social phenomena (Wolff, 1964: xxxiv). This

    philosophical aspiration is at the same time imbedded in the formalism of

    Simmels sociology. The central concept of sociation in his formal sociology is not

    present in The Philosophy of Money, but other characteristics of the formal approach

    underscore his analysis. For example, the form/content separation, which Simmel

    sees more and more manifested in modern times, is exemplified by moneys

    evolution from a substance-value (in gold or silver) to a purely functional device

    (paper money). Money thus manages to reify all that social life including theeconomy but also culture entails as content, transforming qualitative worth into

    quantifiable functionality. Through the formal qualities of its operation, money

    enables exchange at a distance and an extreme abstractness that fragments people

    into formal properties, each of which carries a price-tag.

    The Sociological Trinity on Money: Elements ofDeification

    The analysis of Simmels study on money in this paper is intended to position and

    discuss his work in relation to the other sociological classics. I therefore separately

    review the treatment of money in the works of Marx, Weber and Durkheim, to

    indicate those elements in the work of these classics that offer useful points for a

    comparison with Simmels discussion of money. Although the sociological trinity

    did not study money as an independent topic of inquiry, there are distinct

    elements of a monetary theory that can nonetheless be deduced from their

    respective writings.

    Marx: Money and the Contradictions of Capitalism

    In at least three of his writings, Marx paid specific attention to the functions of

    money in society (see also Arnon, 1984; de Brunhoff, 1976; Ingham, 1998;

    JOURNAL OF CLASSICAL SOCIOLOGY VOL 3(1)74

    at BROWN UNIVERSITY on May 9, 2013jcs.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/
  • 8/11/2019 Battle of the Classics

    10/31

    Lavoie, 1986; Morris, 1967). First, in the Economic and Philosophical Manuscripts

    of 1844, Marx (1978) devotes a chapter to The Power of Money in Bourgeois

    Society. He argues that money represents the abstract relationships of private

    property that have become detached from human relations of exchange. Money is

    the epitome of mans alienation: That which is for me through the medium of

    money that for which I can pay (i.e. which money can buy) that am I, the

    possessor of the money (1978: 103). Money is the ultimate good, since it can

    buy all other goods, but it transforms the real powers of man and nature into alien

    abstractions reified in relations of exchange. In On the Jewish Question, the

    alienating force of money Marx attributes particularly to the (Jewish) culture of

    materialism: Money is the jealous god of Israel, beside which no other god may

    exist (1978: 50).

    The humanistic approach to alienation is further elaborated by Marx in hiscrucial work Grundrisse (1973), though here a more strictly economic analysis of

    capitalisms internal contradictions is also presented. Money is considered in

    connection to capitallabor relations, and the focus is more exclusively on wages

    and the formation of capital rather than on money as such. The accumulation of

    the means of production and the transformation of money into capital cause it to

    become an independent force that determines the mode of production. In this

    broader process, Marx argues, money becomes increasingly detached from the

    social relations that paradoxically have initially given rise to the formation of thoserelationships. This element Marx particularly identifies in relation to wage-labor:

    The capitalist, it seems, therefore, buys their [the workers] labour with money.

    They sell him their labour for money (1978: 204). Thus money reflects and

    reifies social relations, and these relations become external to, and independent

    from, the people that engage in them.

    Marxs speculations on the capitalist economy become fully matured in his

    work Capital (1978: 294442). Stripped of the Hegelian language that still

    dominated his early works, Marx now develops a detailed economic analysis and

    argues that the value of money is determined by the forces of production and not

    by the market conditions of supply and demand. In the chapter on Commodities

    and Money (1978: 30229), specifically, Marx argues that to become a com-

    modity, a good must be transferable into any other one, and money is the medium

    that enables this transfer of commodities. The next chapter discusses the impor-

    tance of the transformation of money into capital through the transformation of

    money into commodities and back into money. The change from money to

    capital, however, does not occur in money itself. Instead, in order for money to be

    converted into capital, a special commodity must exist whose consumption is anembodiment of labor and a creation of value this, Marx contends, can only be

    labor-power. This labor-theory of value is based on Marxs critique of commodity

    fetishism as the unquestioned belief that goods possess value as an inherent

    property. Marx writes,

    DEFLEM THE SOCIOLOGY OF THE SOCIOLOGY OF MONEY 75

    at BROWN UNIVERSITY on May 9, 2013jcs.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/
  • 8/11/2019 Battle of the Classics

    11/31

    . . . to find an analogy, we must have resource to the mist-enveloped

    regions of the religious world. In that world the productions of the human

    brain appear as independent beings endowed with life, and entering into

    relation both with one another and the human race. So it is in the world of

    commodities with the products of mens hands. This I call the Fetishismwhich attaches itself to the products of labour, so soon as they are

    produced as commodities, and which is therefore inseparable from the

    production of commodities.

    (1978: 321)

    Unmasking this fetishism, Marxs historical materialism unveiled that a com-

    modity has exchange-value only because it stands in a particular relation to human

    labour and production.Congruent with Marxs theory of value, money is intimately tied up with

    labor and a concept of value based on labor and, therefore, labor products. To

    Marx, money is itself a commodity but one that in abstract form also represents

    the value of other commodities. As such, money is not just a medium of exchange,

    but also a means of domination. For as a universal measure for value (and the

    labor it entails), money symbolizes the capitalist mode of production and its social

    relations of exploitation. It is on the basis of this labor-theory of value that Marx

    goes on to construct his theories of labor power, the creation of surplus value, and

    the expropriation of the worker. The specific but relatively limited role Marxattributes to money in his explanation of the contradictions of capitalism is clear:

    the division of labor, the accumulation of capital, the opposition between

    bourgeoisie and proletariat, and the inherently contradictory mode of capitalist

    production are the central elements that account for industrialized society. The

    study of money to Marx only makes sense as part of a more encompassing analysis

    of capitalism.

    Weber: Money and the Rationalization of SocietyMax Webers treatment of the role of money in society forms part of his

    sociological discussions on the rationalization processes in industrial society. In

    The Protestant Ethic, Weber argues that the ethic of Protestantism has as its

    summum bonumthe earning of more and more money, combined with the strict

    avoidance of all spontaneous enjoyment of life (1976: 53). The acquisition of

    wealth is an end in itself, and the Protestant is preoccupied by the making

    of money, albeit in an ascetic way. It is this methodical attitude that Weber holds

    responsible for the formal-rational conduct to life that he considers so importantin the development of capitalism. The irrational accumulation of wealth (irra-

    tional, because money is denied its very reason for existence, namely exchange)

    accelerates the rationalization of the capitalist money economy. The ethics of

    Protestantism thus contributed to the rise of capitalism by its amazingly good, we

    JOURNAL OF CLASSICAL SOCIOLOGY VOL 3(1)76

    at BROWN UNIVERSITY on May 9, 2013jcs.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/
  • 8/11/2019 Battle of the Classics

    12/31

    may even say a pharisaically good, conscience in the acquisition of money, so long

    as it took place legally (1976: 176).

    Weber also discusses the role of the money economy throughout his later

    works, particularly in the posthumous collection Economy and Society (1954,

    1958a, 1958b, 1958c, 1962). Basically, he outlines the characteristics of ration-alized, modern society in several social domains, and the money economy is

    thereby seen as one of the driving forces. In the paper Religious Rejections of the

    World and Their Direction, for instance, Weber elaborates on the theme of The

    Protestant Ethic, and argues that the calculable method of life, characteristic of the

    rational economy of capitalism, finds in money the most abstract and imper-

    sonal element that exists in human life (1958c: 331). Elsewhere, Weber (1954,

    1962) similarly argues for the social significance of money in creating the

    possibility of rational calculability, the possibility of assigning money values to allgoods and services, which creates impersonal relations of exchange between the

    participants in the market because money is the accepted means of exchange. The

    money economy is also seen to determine the structure of bureaucracies, in that it

    is necessary to provide the income to maintain them (based on a system of

    taxation) since they cannot be derived from private profits (1958b: 2049).

    Webers definition of class, finally, essentially refers to the possession of goods and

    the opportunities for (monetary) income (1958a: 1813). But, of course, while

    Weber in his work emphasizes the role of the money economy in the development

    of nearly all facets of modernity, he also pays considerable attention to cultural,religious, political, technological and legal processes of rationalization in the

    formation of modern society. The elective affinity (Wahlverwantschaft) between

    these factors is precisely one of his most fundamental methodological claims, so

    that he treats money always in relation to other social forces.

    Durkheim: Money and the Morality of the Social Order

    Of all the classics, Durkheim is probably the one who least addressed the issue of

    money in his sociological work. In attempting to reconstruct a Durkheimian

    monetary theory, it is to be noted that Durkheims doctoral dissertation on the

    social division of labor (1984) includes but very minimal discussions of the money

    economy. Instead, the emphasis in his study is on modern societys capacity to

    maintain solidarity in light of growing trends of individualization. He outlines an

    evolutionary model from mechanical to organic solidarity, whereby the nature of

    solidarity is seen to shift from one between identical, substitutable elements to one

    between distinct, functionally specialized parts. The latter refers primarily to the

    division of labor between workers, but also includes social relations establishedthrough monetary exchange. But Durkheim does not discuss economic forces as

    such, instead placing premium on the social regulations, collective beliefs and

    sentiments that underlie these processes they are in the final analysis responsible

    for a societys cohesion (or lack thereof as a result of anomie).

    DEFLEM THE SOCIOLOGY OF THE SOCIOLOGY OF MONEY 77

    at BROWN UNIVERSITY on May 9, 2013jcs.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/
  • 8/11/2019 Battle of the Classics

    13/31

    Additionally, in Suicide, Durkheim (1951) employs a similar argument to

    account for the rise in suicide-rates whenever there is a positive or negative, but

    always abrupt, transition in economic life, and because of the chronic state of

    anomie in the world of trade and industry. Economic crises lead to a sudden

    weakening of social regulations, which brings about a disruption of the sociallimits set to mans desires. Such desires can include the need to acquire more and

    more money, and the economic crises may refer to monetary losses or gains.

    Durkheim specifically mentions prices of the most necessary foods and the fact

    that world expositions bring more money into the country and are thought to

    increase public prosperity (pp. 2445). The lack of regulations in the economic

    world, responsible for suicide as a regular factor, consists in the freeing of

    industrial relations from all constraints on (monetary) needs. However, Durkheim

    conceives of the morality of the social order that can and should guide economicforces as the crucial theme of sociological reflection, not the economy or money as

    such.

    Simmel versus the Trinity: A Stranger among theClassics?

    It is apparent that Marx, Weber and Durkheim did not pay as much exclusive

    attention to money as an autonomous domain of sociological inquiry as Simmeldid, although none of them entirely denied the significance of money in their

    respective analyses. Simmels approach to money diverges from each of the other

    classics in ways that can be explained with reference to their respective general

    theoretical perspectives. On the one hand, of course, Marxs influence on Simmel,

    Durkheim and Weber may indicate a centrality of the influence of historical

    materialism or at least an elective affinity among the classics in their development

    of sociological theory from the second half of the 19th century onwards. On the

    other hand, the concentration on the money theme in Simmels work also licenses

    a thematically more delineated approach that can identify the theoretical concerns

    that distinguish his work from that of the other classics.

    The Age of Sociology

    Since Parsons (1937) as well as some of his critics (e.g. Giddens, 1971), the

    history of sociological thought has firmly been established in the major trans-

    formations of society in the 19th century (Collins, 1994; Holton, 1996). Building

    on the centrality of social change, the classics thereby also converged theirthinking, or at least transformed their thought in substantial respects. The

    transformation from or rift between the younger and older Marx is well docu-

    mented. In Durkheim, the anti-voluntaristic orientation of the early period of

    social realism was refashioned in his later work on religion. And Webers

    JOURNAL OF CLASSICAL SOCIOLOGY VOL 3(1)78

    at BROWN UNIVERSITY on May 9, 2013jcs.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/
  • 8/11/2019 Battle of the Classics

    14/31

    influences from German idealism and romanticism place meaning and inter-

    pretation completely at the center of his methodology.

    In the work of Simmel, similar themes and transformations are at work

    (see Coser, 1977; Frisby, 1987: 4234; Levine, 1997; Scaff, 1988: 37). Among

    Simmels most important initial intellectual influences are German Volkerpsycholo-gie, particularly the notion that social totality historically antecedes the individual,

    but also the idea that there is an evolutionary trend toward the development of

    individuality. The emphasis on individuality in Simmels writings until the late

    1880s leads Simmel himself to refer to his work as psychological contributions.

    Thereafter, however, he explicitly proclaimed sociological objectives, with a

    peculiar interest in philosophically grounding the sociological project. Particularly

    in the last decade of the 19th century, Simmel was heavily involved in sociological

    work and his contribution to establish sociology as an independent science.During this period, he wrote most of his explicitly sociological work and was

    among the first to teach a course in sociology. However, although this task was

    accomplished a decade later in an institutional sense (as sociology had become a

    discipline with its own journals and institutionalization in the academic world),

    Simmels programmatic formulations of a new science of society had not pro-

    duced the results to which he aspired. Disillusioned, he turned to philosophical,

    metaphysical matters. As I will discuss in more detail later, his turn away from

    sociology in the stricter sense of the term was never complete, but this was mostly

    because of efforts on the part of his students (especially Albion Smalls successfulendeavors to bring Simmels work to the attention of American sociologists [see

    Levine, 1997: 1813]).

    These shifts in Simmels work are especially significant in the context of

    The Philosophy of Money. For it is in this work that he shifts from a sociological

    analysis of social forms to an emphasis on moral autonomy, individuality, existen-

    tial responsibility and personal experience (Holton, 1996: 457; Levine, 1997:

    183). Intimately part of this orientation towards a philosophy of culture is the

    notion, which figures so prominently in The Philosophy of Money, that a major

    evolutionary trend in modern society is the development of increasing individ-

    uality. As Levine (1997) has shown, for the notion of an increasing individual

    subjectivity Simmel found intellectual support in the work of Nietzsche and, more

    broadly, Hegels perspective of self-consciousness. More broadly, the general

    evolutionary orientation was of course no stranger to sociological theorizing of

    the latter half of the 19th century, finding expression, most clearly, in the works

    of Durkheim and, especially, Spencer (which had initially stimulated Simmel to

    sociological investigations). The centrality of individuality comes to the fore-

    ground most clearly in The Philosophy of Money, with its emphasis on money as auniversal impersonal measure of value that also enables new and expanded

    subjective experiences. In other words, Simmel maintains that as much as it is true

    that there are de-personalization trends in modernity, it also and still allows for

    individuals to react creatively and make ones own world in the money economy,

    DEFLEM THE SOCIOLOGY OF THE SOCIOLOGY OF MONEY 79

    at BROWN UNIVERSITY on May 9, 2013jcs.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/
  • 8/11/2019 Battle of the Classics

    15/31

    for the metropolitan individual is not simply a passive victim of consumerism

    (Holton, 1996: 46). Let us now consider how the centrality of the money theme

    in Simmels work relates more specifically to the other sociological classics.

    Simmel and Marx

    In the Preface to his study on money, Simmel claims that he wants to adjust

    historical materialism by looking at economic processes as the result of deeper

    presuppositions, while preserving the explanatory model of the influence of

    economic life upon culture (1989: 13). Simmels relation to Marx in the study

    of money thus comprises both similarities and differences in approach (see

    Deutschmann, 1996; Frankel, 1977: 1727; Turner, 1986: 1004). Indeed, on

    the one hand, some of the themes in Marxs work reappear in some form inSimmels study. First, there is the evolutionary sketch of money from simple barter

    to the more complex and more complete existence of money as paper money. In

    addition, both Simmel and Marx use religious analogies to denote the impersonal

    nature of money (the Holy Grail, money as fetish), and this theme of impersonal-

    ization through money is apparent in the writings of both authors. Although

    Marxs Grundrissewere not yet discovered during Simmels life, he unwittingly

    reconstructed some of the classical Marxist themes of objectification and aliena-

    tion (Turner, 1986: 1013). Money is seen by both Simmel and Marx as the

    purest form of reification; it is the technically most perfected medium of moderneconomic exchange that transforms all quality into quantity, alienates people from

    their true existence, and fragments their personalities into formal properties.

    On the other hand, Simmels approach is in several respects antagonistic to

    Marxs throughout The Philosophy of Money. The main difference in their respec-

    tive approaches is that Marx holds the capitalist mode of production responsible

    for the contradictions of modern, industrialized society, while for Simmel it is the

    money economy as such that is the cause of the impersonalization of social

    relations. Marxs theory is primarily concerned with the capitalist sphere of

    production and the relation between money, labor and capital, while Simmel

    concentrates on the distribution and circulation of goods, which are held to

    constitute a value-creating sphere of exchange. Seeking to move deeper than

    historical materialism to reach at the psychological and metaphysical meanings of

    the concrete historical manifestations of economic forms, Simmels Philosophy of

    Money is a fundamental critique of Marxs political economy. While in Marxs

    work, too, money has different functions (as a measure of value, a medium of

    exchange and a means of accumulating wealth), it was always of central concern to

    Marx that money embodied abstract labour and that the value of money wasdetermined by the conditions of production (Turner, 1986: 109). Opposing

    most critically this economicization of money, Simmel locates money resolutely in

    the broad realm of human experience. In Simmel, money is only loosely tied to its

    material basis and instead represents a sociological phenomenon, a form of human

    JOURNAL OF CLASSICAL SOCIOLOGY VOL 3(1)80

    at BROWN UNIVERSITY on May 9, 2013jcs.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/
  • 8/11/2019 Battle of the Classics

    16/31

    interaction. Therefore, also, exchange is for him a crucial form of sociation,

    whereas the economy is only one special form of exchange (see Frisby, 1985:

    5960). Whereas Marxs theory of value is based on the productive relations of

    the human subject with nature through labor, Simmel presents a relativist theory

    of value that posits that the value of things rests on a subjective judgment, onvaluation. Therefore, those goods that are difficult to obtain for the individual

    who wants them within certain limits of feasibility will be the most valuable

    (Sassatelli, 2000).

    The differences between Simmels formal-philosophical sociology, in

    search of the universals of humanity, and Marxs concrete economic-historical

    analysis, aimed at the general laws of capitalism, are manifested in their respective

    value theories. Also, as far as the problematic sides of money are concerned

    (reification, fragmentation), Marxs analysis is, in however paradoxical a way, moreoptimistic, since capitalism, he argues, will one day undermine itself. Simmels

    analysis instead points to the role of money as a world of its own, driven by the

    nature of human life, which cannot just be overthrown. Conversely, along with

    the growth of money as a pure symbol, Simmel defines freedom in relation to the

    possession of money as providing the means to engage in social interactions. For

    Marx, this potential of increased freedom and individualization is of course far

    more problematic: the freedom of some can only be maintained by the unfreedom

    of many others. Underlying these differences in approach, Simmels discontent

    with socialist ideology can be discerned. To Simmel, socialism cannot eradicate alldistinctions between people, at least not without destroying their freedom (see

    Simmel, 1964: 738).

    Simmel and Weber

    The relationship between Simmel and Weber is a peculiar one. They were close

    friends, but the intellectual influences between them are not very clear and have

    been a topic of considerable scholarly debate (see Abel, 1970: 11214; Faught,

    1985; Leger, 1986; Levine, 1972, Lichtblau, 1991; Nedelmann, 1988; Scaff,

    1987, 1988; Turner, 1986: 10410; C. Turner, 1989). On the one hand, there

    are affinities between Simmels and Webers work. They generally share a meth-

    odological concern for the role of understanding (Verstehen), and the accompany-

    ing concepts of sociation and social interaction. Also, Simmels identification of

    the form of social action may have inspired Webers development of ideal-types

    (although the former has metaphysical status, while the latter is a methodological

    device). As members of the intellectual life of Berlin, they both had first-hand

    access to the achievements of modern, metropolitan culture. Although for theProtestant Weber this primarily meant an inquiry into subjective and objective

    culture, while the Jewish Simmel was more attracted to the new aesthetics of

    modernity, they both expressed a fatalistic theme in their sociology and identified

    the cold-hearted objectification of culture.

    DEFLEM THE SOCIOLOGY OF THE SOCIOLOGY OF MONEY 81

    at BROWN UNIVERSITY on May 9, 2013jcs.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/
  • 8/11/2019 Battle of the Classics

    17/31

    The impersonal nature of money in exchange relations identified by

    Simmel corresponds closely to Webers notion of bureaucratization in terms of

    purposive rationality (Zweckrationalitat). Both Simmel and Weber concentrate on

    the role of money in modern society as enabling an increasing quantification of

    relations and fragmentation of the human person into functional partitions.Money is seen to transform personal bonds into calculable instrumental ties.

    Simmels Philosophy of Moneymay well have been a direct source of inspiration for

    Webers analysis of modern bureaucratization. (Weber read the book after a

    period of illness around 1902.) Webers analyses of the methodical conduct of life,

    the rational calculation and intellectualization, the dominance of bureaucratic

    control, and the growing process of secularization into the iron cage of modernity

    presuppose a rational money system, and similar themes are discussed in Simmels

    study on money.Weber in his writings hardly ever referred to Simmels work and, when he

    did, he was quite critical about some of Simmels intentions. Weber wrote a

    critique of Simmels sociological approach, including his analysis of money, but,

    probably because Simmel had difficulties acquiring a full professorship, he never

    finished the paper (Weber, 1972). Still, the unfinished manuscript does indicate

    some of the differences in their perspectives. Weber argues that, while Simmel has

    advanced some important theoretical ideas and made subtle empirical observa-

    tions, there are numerous unacceptable aspects in his methodology. Most criti-

    cally, Weber refutes Simmels methodological approach and his notion ofinteraction. He criticizes Simmels interpretive method for proceeding largely on

    the basis of analogy, which to the specialist is devoid of any sense. With respect to

    Simmels notion of interaction, Weber argues that it is so vague and broad that it

    is not possible to conceive of an influence of one person by another that would be

    purely one-sided, i.e., not containing a certain element of interaction

    (1972: 163).

    In some of Webers other works, more of his disagreements with Simmels

    approach are revealed. Thematically most interesting is that Weber in The

    Protestant Ethicspecifically criticizes Simmels Philosophy of Money. While he calls it

    a brilliant analysis, he also maintains that Simmel does not sufficiently distinguish

    between the money economy in general and capitalism in particular, to the

    detriment of his concrete analysis (1976: 193, 185). Weber in his work indeed

    paid attention to the structural conditions of the capitalist money economy,

    whereas Simmel developed a phenomenology of money as a medium of the

    human experience of reality as such. Weber sought to look beyond the formalism

    of social action, and wanted to unveil its psycho-cultural dimension (why people

    act), while Simmel argued to go beyond substantivism in order to understandsocial interactions in terms of the forms they have (how people act).

    From a methodological viewpoint, Weber maintains in Economy and

    Societythat his work departs from Simmels method (in Soziologieand Philosophie

    des Geldes) in drawing a sharp distinction between subjectively intended and

    JOURNAL OF CLASSICAL SOCIOLOGY VOL 3(1)82

    at BROWN UNIVERSITY on May 9, 2013jcs.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/
  • 8/11/2019 Battle of the Classics

    18/31

    objectively valid meanings; two different things which Simmel not only fails to

    distinguish but often deliberately treats as belonging together (Weber, cited in

    Frisby, 1990b: 14). As Levine (1997: 1789) clarifies, Simmel developed an

    explicit interest in Verstehenonly after 1900. This may have been due to, or at least

    it harmonizes with, the fact that Simmel for strategic reasons did not wish to beexplicit about his opposition to Wilhelm Diltheys hermeneutics. For in contrast

    to the Diltheyan Verstehen method that conceived of society as singular mean-

    ingful events, Simmel in his work seeks to construct general propositions that can

    account for manifold historical events (Dahme, 1990: 1419). This methodo-

    logical conflict was meaningful in a professional sense because Dilthey hindered

    Simmels career opportunities at Berlin.

    Once Simmel had clarified his methodology more explicitly, it was influen-

    tial for Webers approach but mostly as a negative model (see Frisby, 1987:4257; Lichtblau, 1991; Scaff, 1988: 1317; Turner, 1986: 1045). In particular,

    Weber sought to depart from Simmels methodology in formulating a cognitive

    rational interpretation of motives, rather than a psychological theory of conscious-

    ness. For Simmel it was indisputable that all social events . . . are rooted in souls,

    that sociation is a psychological phenomenon (cited in Nedelmann, 1988: 20).

    Against this psychologism, Webers method of understanding of action has to be

    restricted to the subjective intentions of human agents, and is clearly distinguished

    from, if also related to, causal explanations (in the sense of causal pluralism and

    Wahlverwantschaft) of the social structures in which actions are imbedded (seeGerth and Mills, 1958: 5561). Echoing the famous connection Weber draws

    between understanding and explanation, he criticizes Simmel for not clearly

    distinguishing the interpretation of motives of actors and the socio-historical

    context of meaning.

    Simmel and Durkheim

    Durkheim was quite well acquainted with Simmels work and published two

    review articles on books by Simmel, including a review of The Philosophy of Money

    (Durkheim, 19001, 19023). Durkheim also discussed Simmels sociological

    theory at some length in two other papers (Durkheim, 1964, 1982; see also Abel,

    1970: 10812; Bentley, 1926; Frisby, 1990a: xviixviii; Maffesoli, 1988; Mes-

    trovic, 1991: 5474; Naegele, 1958; Thompson, 1982; Wolff, 1958). As far as

    Simmels general sociological theory is concerned, Durkheim strongly disagrees

    with Simmels a-historical formalism. According to Durkheim, form only applies

    to social morphology (an approach that he rejected, particularly in Suicide), and

    the separation of form and content rests on nothing but Simmels idiosyncraticarbitrary judgment. Durkheim asserts that the special social sciences, concerned

    with the processes or variable contents of human existence, are just as much

    sociological as is the study of the external forms of the collectivity. The forms and

    substance of relationships are social facts, that is, for both it holds that one cannot

    DEFLEM THE SOCIOLOGY OF THE SOCIOLOGY OF MONEY 83

    at BROWN UNIVERSITY on May 9, 2013jcs.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/
  • 8/11/2019 Battle of the Classics

    19/31

    but feel present the hand of society, which organises them and whose stamp they

    plainly bear (1982: 191). Contrary to Simmels view of society as being essen-

    tially involved with the sociation of individuals, Durkheim emphasizes that society

    is a moral milieu that serves a function of integration, referring to the (formal)

    attachment of people to society, but that also exhibits a particular regulatoryforce, referring to (substantive) moral codes and rules.

    Simmels conception of the relationship between society and individual is

    markedly different from Durkheims. Of course, as analysts of thefin de si`ecle, they

    share the ideas of a force sui generis (Simmels metaphysics versus Durkheims

    collective conscience) and a historical account of a process into modernity that is

    characterized by a general impersonalization and functional compartmentalization

    of social relations. But Durkheims identification of social facts exerting their

    influence over individuals and having a life of their own regardless of individualmanifestations cannot be easily reconciled with Simmels notion of sociation and

    stress on individual differences in social interactions.

    Durkheims specific objections to Simmels Philosophy of Money fit well

    within this general critique. Durkheim (19001) argues that Simmels book (as

    the title indicates) presents a social philosophy and is not sociology sensu stricto,

    for he discusses just about every conceivable fact and thought related to money,

    especially in the second synthetic part, and the facts he there presents are often

    imprecise and unwarranted. Too many diverse questions are dealt with, Durkheim

    argues, and, lacking any analysis, Simmel fails to see that the force of money doesnot derive from any of its presumed intrinsic values. What is far more important to

    Durkheim is the presence or absence of the regulation to which [money] is

    submitted, and the nature of that regulation (19001: 145). Unlike Simmels

    identification of alienation and the fragmentation of personality into functional

    parts as a result of the essence of money, Durkheim held that the division of labor

    is not pathological as such, but only when it lacks a developed system of solidary

    organizations and the necessary regulations concerning how these organizations

    should come together. In sum, Durkheim cannot agree with Simmels abstract

    approach: money cannot have such a profound moral influence solely on the

    grounds of its formal characteristics. What matters to Durkheim is the moral

    regulation through which money is controlled, not money as such.

    Simmel and the Prospects of a Sociology ofMoney

    This analysis of Simmel in relation to the other classics has revealed some of the

    underlying distinctions between these different perspectives in classical theory.However, this confrontation by itself does not suffice to evaluate Simmel as a

    sociological classic and assess the influence of his work for the sociological study of

    money. Sociological theory-building is the result not only of conceptual argu-

    mentation and debate, but just as much of the actual reception of a body of

    JOURNAL OF CLASSICAL SOCIOLOGY VOL 3(1)84

    at BROWN UNIVERSITY on May 9, 2013jcs.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/
  • 8/11/2019 Battle of the Classics

    20/31

    knowledge in the sociological community (Alexander, 1987; Lamont, 1987). Any

    judgment of sociological theories necessarily implies, and should take into

    account, a clarification of the historical dimension in theory formation.

    Simmels (Lack of) Influence in Sociology

    The influence of Simmels work in sociology is marked by an ambivalence that

    seems to have haunted him throughout his life (see Coser, 1958, 1977: 1949;

    Frisby, 1990a: xvxxv; Gerth and Mills, 1958: 21). While Simmel had good

    connections with Berlins cultural and intellectual elite at the turn of the 20th

    century, he was excluded for a long time from influential university positions. He

    remained a lecturer (Privatdozent) and honorary professor at the University of

    Berlin, and had to move to Strasbourg to become full professor only in 1914. Theslow progression in Simmels career was likely the result of anti-Semitic senti-

    ments, but his eclectic theories also caused him to remain somewhat of an outsider

    in the scholarly environment. Still, during his lifetime Simmels work received

    quite some attention, as can for instance be seen from the large number of, mostly

    positive, reviews of The Philosophy of Money(e.g. Altmann, 1903; Duprat, 1900;

    Mead, 1901; Meyer, 1901).

    The ambivalent reception of Simmels work during his lifetime also

    conditioned his early influence in the United States (Frisby, 1992: 15562;

    Levine, 1991; Levine et al., 1976; Wolff, 1964: xxivxxv). Early issues of TheAmerican Journal of Sociologycontained some 15 papers by Simmel and generally

    paid a lot of attention to the German scholar. (Several Chicago sociologists had

    studied in Germany.) In the later development of American sociology, however,

    Simmels work seems to have been largely ignored. George Herbert Mead (1901)

    wrote a (very positive) review of Simmels Philosophy of Money in an economic

    journal, but to the present day Simmels influence in economics is really non-

    existent. Other American sociologists (Park, Burgess, Spykman) published on

    Simmel, and offered translations of his work to the American readership, but with

    only moderate success. When Parsons (1937) published his first systematic social

    theory, referring abundantly to European sociologists, Simmel was excluded apart

    from some scant references. (Parsons drafted a chapter on Simmel and Tonnies

    but did not include it in his book; see Parsons, 1998.) With the subsequent rise of

    functionalism, little attention was paid to Simmels sociology (Saiedi, 1987).

    Simmels work was marginalized as a result of the rise of Parsonian functionalism,

    and the post-functionalist attack on Parsons did little to revive it (Alexander,

    1987: 3446). As late as 1976, a review paper could be published on the influence

    of Simmels work for substantive areas in American sociological research, without,quite rightly, mentioning the theme of money (Levine et al., 1976).

    Apart from unfavorable historical conditions, there are also theoretical

    causes for Simmels poor reception. There are good reasons to say that any social

    theory, however complex, simplifies reality by ordering modern civilization

    DEFLEM THE SOCIOLOGY OF THE SOCIOLOGY OF MONEY 85

    at BROWN UNIVERSITY on May 9, 2013jcs.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/
  • 8/11/2019 Battle of the Classics

    21/31

    according to an encompassing explanatory model. As my review of the money

    theme in the work of Marx, Weber and Durkheim has shown, their studies took

    into account money as an element of sociological inquiry only within a more

    encompassing perspective aimed at unfolding the central, in this way unifying,

    theme of analyzing (and criticizing) modern industrialized societies. Marx focusedon money within a more encompassing study of the capitalist mode of produc-

    tion; Weber discussed the money economy in relation to the broader trends of

    societal rationalization; and Durkheim concentrated on the moral regulatory

    structures in which money is socially imbedded. Capitalism, rationalization and

    social morality are the respective keywords, providing unity to the traditions of

    sociological theory and diversity to theoretical sociology. Such a clear-cut

    approach is not what characterizes Simmels sociology of everything, which is

    resistant to being pinned down into one or the other determining category ofsociological thought. It is for these reasons that Simmel has often been called a

    talented essayist with a striking love of details (see Levine, 1997: 173; Dahme,

    1990: 17). Also, unlike the other classics of sociology, Simmel did not hold

    industrialism to be the central turning point in the evolution to modern society.

    Rather, he considered the money economy in general, without it being specifically

    tied to capitalism or the division of labor in industrialism, as decisive for the Great

    Transformation into modernity (Lawrence, 1980: 1823). He offered a unique

    characterization of modernity, and provided new basic tools for its sociological

    study (separation of form and content, relationalism, the possibility of socialorder). Still, his disinclination to specialize and his refusal to argue for one clear-

    cut driving force in the evolution to modernity have led his work not to be

    indisputably classified as classic (see Frisby, 1992: 4563).

    Past, Present and Future of the Sociology of Money

    Over the past decades, Simmels social theory has witnessed a notable revival,

    especially with the advent of the new cultural studies and the discussions on

    modernity and postmodernity (see, e.g., Backhaus, 1998; Blegvad, 1989; Dahme,

    1990; Featherstone, 1991; Gross, 2001; Scaff, 1988; C. Turner, 1989; Weinstein

    and Weinstein, 1990, 1993). The sociology of money, too, has been the subject of

    renewed sociological interest (e.g. Baker and Jimerson, 1992; Condominas, 1989;

    Ingham, 1998; Singh, 2000; Zelizer, 1994). Of course, the money theme has

    never been totally absent from sociology. Noteworthy are Parsons and Smelsers

    functional analysis of money as a generalized medium of interaction (Parsons and

    Smelser, 1956; Smelser, 1963), Luhmanns autopoietic notion of money (1985),

    Habermass thesis of the monetary colonization of the lifeworld (1981), andGiddens discussions of money and trust in his structuration theory of modernity

    (1990, 1991). However, none of these renowned authors base their theories on

    Simmel. Habermas, for instance, develops his concept of money out of a critical

    reappraisal of Parsons, and he quotes Simmel only three times in his analysis of

    JOURNAL OF CLASSICAL SOCIOLOGY VOL 3(1)86

    at BROWN UNIVERSITY on May 9, 2013jcs.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/
  • 8/11/2019 Battle of the Classics

    22/31

    theories of modernity (1985: 170, 298, 371). To Habermas (1983, 1996),

    Simmels philosophy of the subject (Lebensphilosophie) is unacceptable from the

    standpoint of post-metaphysical communication-theory. Likewise, Giddens,

    though claiming that The Philosophy of Money is the most far-reaching and

    sophisticated account of the connections between money and modernity (1991:22), only briefly discusses Simmels notions of trust and space (1990: 18;

    1991: 229).

    In addition to the analysis of money in the works of these contemporary

    classics, money has recently gained a more accepted status as a topic of socio-

    logical inquiry (see, e.g., Dodd, 1994; Doyle, 1992; Ganmann, 1988; Ingham,

    1994, 1996; Smelt, 1980; Zelizer, 1989). Some scholars have even begun to

    develop sociological analyses of money in contemporary society explicitly on the

    basis of Simmels ground-breaking work (e.g. Deutschman, 2000; Ritzer, 2001;Sassatelli, 2000). Christoph Deutschman (2000), most clearly, has developed an

    alternative to a functionalist sociology of money by arguing that Simmels

    conceptualization of money as an absolute means allows for a useful perspective

    of moneys role in modern society in relation to broader currents of individualiza-

    tion and modernization.

    Apart from the historical fact that sociologists have mostly neglected

    money (Ingham, 1998; Pixley, 1999), two tensions continue to trouble the

    reception of the sociological study of money. First, sociologies of money cannot

    find a way in to economic studies, where monetary theories are largely developedon the basis of discussions of Keynes, Smith, Ricardo or Marx. This lack of multi-

    disciplinary collaboration is regrettable since economics is after all essentially

    concerned with the study of money. Moreover, because any sociology of money

    should clarify the specific sociological contribution, debate with economic mone-

    tary theories seems indispensable. And, second, the historical neglect of money in

    sociology indicative is the fact that Simmels Philosophy of Moneywas translated

    into English nearly 80 years after the German original cannot be overcome

    overnight. Regardless of whether or not money is theoretically considered a

    suitable topic for sociological investigation, sociologys history de facto constrains

    moneys receptiveness into the field. The vagueness and internal inconsistencies

    that mark most contemporary sociological studies of money, not surprisingly

    therefore, all too clearly confirm that there is no systematic sociology of money

    (Zelizer, 1991: 1304).

    Simmel and the Quest for Sociological Theory

    An assessment of Simmels sociological theory also includes considerations onrelevant aspects in the history of theory formation. The factual resistance against

    Simmels sociology and the study of money as a theme of its own will also

    condition an evaluation of the merits of his work. From this perspective, the

    recent revival of Simmel in postmodern theories deserves attention, minimally

    DEFLEM THE SOCIOLOGY OF THE SOCIOLOGY OF MONEY 87

    at BROWN UNIVERSITY on May 9, 2013jcs.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/
  • 8/11/2019 Battle of the Classics

    23/31

    because Simmel handed down the interconnected particularities of his writings

    and because they have inspired the current debate on postmodernity. This issue

    calls for a more profound investigation than I can offer here, but the discussion of

    Simmels study of money and the confrontation with the other classics offer

    important elements for a useful assessment of Simmel today.

    Apart from the obvious fact that the neglect of Simmels sociology has

    always been more relative than absolute, it should be noted that the contemporary

    (re)appraisal of his work is not the exclusive property of postmodern theories.

    Simmels discussion of small-group interaction has gained an established place in

    symbolic interactionism and, to a lesser extent, in social psychology. Moreover,

    the inspiration of Simmels work on culture is regularly manifested in cultural

    sociology, which is surely not the exclusive domain of postmodern theorizing.

    Additionally, in attempting to construct a synthesis in theoretical sociology,Simmels sociology has also been related to the work of social theorists with a

    more accepted status (see, e.g., Levine, 1991, 2000 on Simmel and Parsons).

    Most remarkable is the fact that over the last decade Simmels work has

    been revived because of its appropriation in postmodern theories. David Frisby

    has offered insightful material to systematically assess Simmels relation to post-

    modernity (Frisby, 1985, 1990c, 1992: 6479, 15574). Frisby describes Sim-

    mels work as characterized by essentially modernist aspirations. Simmels

    conception of modernity is closely akin to Baudelaires formulation of the modernas the mode of experiencing the new as transitory. This is demonstrated by

    Simmels emphasis on the fluidity of forms of action and the interrelatedness of all

    manifestations of modern culture.

    Paradoxically, however, Simmels analysis of modernity has been a major

    source of inspiration for theories of the postmodern. Frisby (1992: 16974)

    discusses Simmels notion of pure exchange, his emphasis on culture, and the

    primacy of the aesthetic experience as decisive in this regard. I would add that

    Simmels relationalist approach and his manifold studies of the dyad, the triad, the

    nobility, the metropolis, silence, secrecy, the stranger, landscapes, sociability, and

    so forth, may well fit with the postmodern claim for order out of chaos. His

    discussions of the interrelatedness of the fragments of modernity, particularly his

    The Philosophy of Money, in which he makes excursions into just about every

    conceivable topic connected to money, ironically fit well with the postmodernist

    contention that the only thing left to discuss is everything. Yet it makes sense to

    argue, as Sassatelli does, that Simmels insistence on relationalism and sociation, in

    his The Philosophy of Money as well as across the rest of his oeuvre, should be

    conceived as the most perilous interdisciplinary pursuit within modern episteme(2000: 209). To what extent the postmodern appropriation of Simmels work can

    indeed be upheld, particularly given the fact that it had modernist aspirations,

    how it will come to terms with the persisting influence of the other classics in

    sociology, and to what extent it may be the case that Simmels sociology will be

    JOURNAL OF CLASSICAL SOCIOLOGY VOL 3(1)88

    at BROWN UNIVERSITY on May 9, 2013jcs.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/
  • 8/11/2019 Battle of the Classics

    24/31

    judged not by its original intentions but by the meaning ascribed to it today are

    the central questions theorists will have to address.

    ConclusionI have evaluated Simmels study of money in confrontation with the other

    sociological classics to indicate the markedly ambivalent place of his writings in the

    history of sociological thought. Although there may be limitations to this

    discussion of the selected classics, my examination revealed that a striking element

    in Simmels writings, as compared to Marx, Weber and Durkheim, is his refusal to

    locate any underlying pivotal force in the course to modernity. The totality of

    formally interrelated parts is modernity, not its explanation through reference to

    the capitalist economy (Marx), the mutual influence of culture and economy(Weber), or the changing nature of morality in light of industrialism (Durkheim).

    Therefore, Simmel can study money as such, while for Marx, Weber and

    Durkheim it would make little sense if a monetary theory is not part of, and

    clarified in relation to, a more broadly explanatory theory of society. In light of

    these methodological considerations, and given the recent reception of Simmels

    work in postmodern theories, there are reasons to argue that Simmel today is a

    postmodern theorist, precisely to the extent in which he is recognized as such by

    contemporary commentators. This historical condition at once poses serioustheoretical challenges to both sides of the modernpostmodern spectrum. In light

    of my review of Simmels theory in relation to the other classics of sociology, some

    indications can be given on the directions this debate could take. On the one

    hand, the present postmodern appraisal of Simmels work calls for Simmelian

    sociologists of a different persuasion to clarify the modernist core of Simmels

    work how to reconcile such a position with Simmels great indeterminacy and

    sheer enumeration (Durkheim, 19023: 649), the diffidence and even indif-

    ference (Frisby, 1987: 423), the emphasis on aesthetics (see Bohringer, 1984;

    Hubner-Funk, 1984), and his leveling down of society to culture; and how to

    account for, offer counterweight to, the postmodernist appropriation of his

    sociology. This may prove a difficult endeavor, given Simmels preoccupation to

    lay bare the non-causal sense of societys totality through an analysis of its

    multiplicities, his preoccupation with the forms of social life, and, above all (in

    light of todays plurality of lifeworlds), his metaphysical contentions, which, by his

    own premises, are not just hypothetical statements, but appeal to the presupposi-

    tions of knowledge as such (Voraussetzungen des Erkennens uberhaupt, Simmel,

    1989: 9).However, postmodern interpretations of Simmel will have to come to

    terms with the remaining persistence of the other sociological classics as well as

    with (the interpretations of) Simmels notion of modernity. With regard to the

    study of money, this especially calls for a clarification of Simmels analysis vis-a-vis

    DEFLEM THE SOCIOLOGY OF THE SOCIOLOGY OF MONEY 89

    at BROWN UNIVERSITY on May 9, 2013jcs.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/
  • 8/11/2019 Battle of the Classics

    25/31

    the study of money from a materialist (Marx), multi-causal (Weber) and socio-

    logistic (Durkheim) perspective. Whatever the shortcomings of the perspectives of

    these theorists may be, each of them, and unlike Simmels, has provided a

    yardstick by which the empirical facts of social life can be systematically ordered

    with an encompassing but differentiating social theory. With their flight into

    aesthetic prose and pose, postmodern theories, however, essentially refuse to

    aspire any longer to this conception of theoretical access to the world. It is the

    tragedy of their fate that they are nevertheless confronted with their modernist

    counterparts and the extent to which the latter rely on the classics as con-

    temporaries. Postmodern sociologist thereby will have to address the criticism that

    they obscure rather than clarify complex societies and prevent an insightful

    sociological understanding, for instance of the money theme. Ironically, then,

    given the postmodern appropriation of Simmel, the first sociologist of modernitymay well become the first to be judged by an evaluation of its most relentless

    critics.

    Acknowledgements

    I am grateful to Eve Darian-Smith, Donald Levine, Gary Marx, Leonard Pinto and anonymous reviewers

    for helpful comments on a previous draft.

    References

    Abel, Theodore (1970) The Foundations of Sociological Theory. New York: Ran-

    dom House.

    Alexander, Jeffrey C. (1987) The Centrality of the Classics, pp. 1157 in A.

    Giddens and J.H. Turner (eds) Social Theory Today. Stanford: Stanford

    University Press.

    Altmann, S.P. (1903) Simmels Philosophy of Money, American Journal of

    Sociology9: 4668.

    Arnon, Arie (1984) Marxs Theory of Money: The Formative Years, History of

    Political Economy16(4): 55575.

    Backhaus, Gary (1998) George Simmel as an Eidetic Social Scientist, Sociological

    Theory16(3): 26081.

    Baker, Wayne E. and Jason B. Jimerson (1992) The Sociology of Money,

    American Behavioral Scientist35(6): 67893.

    Beilharz, Peter (1996) Negation and Ambivalence: Marx, Simmel and Bolshev-

    ism on Money, Thesis Eleven 47: 2032.Bentley, Arthur F. (1926) Simmel, Durkheim, and Ratzenhofer, American

    Journal of Sociology32(2):2506.

    Blegvad, Mogens (1989) A Simmel Renaissance?, Acta Sociologica 32(2):

    2039.

    JOURNAL OF CLASSICAL SOCIOLOGY VOL 3(1)90

    at BROWN UNIVERSITY on May 9, 2013jcs.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/
  • 8/11/2019 Battle of the Classics

    26/31

    Bohringer, Hannes (1984) Die Philosophie des Geldes als aesthetische Theo-

    rie, pp. 178182 in H.-J. Dahme and O. Rammstedt (eds) Georg Simmel

    und die Moderne. Frankfurt: Suhrkamp.

    Brunhoff, Suzanne de (1976) Marx on Money. New York: Urizen.

    Collins, Randall (1994) Four Sociological Traditions. New York: Oxford Uni-

    versity Press.

    Condominas, Georges (1989) De la monnaie multiple, Communications 50:

    95119.

    Coser, Lewis A. (1958) Georg Simmels Style of Work, American Journal of

    Sociology63(6): 63541.

    Coser, Lewis A. (1977) Georg Simmel, 18581918, pp. 177215 in Masters of

    Sociological Thought, 2nd edn. San Diego, CA: Harcourt Brace

    Jovanovich.Dahme, Heinz-Jurgen (1990) On the Current Rediscovery of Georg Simmels

    Sociology: A European Point of View, pp. 1337 in M. Kearn, B.S.

    Phillips and R.S. Cohen (eds) Georg Simmel and Contemporary Sociology.

    Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic.

    Deutschmann, Christoph (1996) Money as a Social Construction: On the

    Actuality of Marx and Simmel, Thesis Eleven 47: 119.

    Deutschmann, Christoph (2000) Geld als absolutes Mittel: Zur Aktualitat von

    Simmels Geldtheorie,Berliner Journal fur Soziologie

    10(3): 30113.Dodd, Nigel (1994) The Sociology of Money: Economics, Reason and Contemporary

    Society. New York: Continuum.

    Doyle, Kenneth O. (1992) Introduction: Money and the Behavioral Sciences,

    American Behavioral Scientist35: 64157.

    Duprat, G.L. (1900) [Review of Philosophie des Geldes by G. Simmel], Revue

    Internationale de Sociologie4: 9414.

    Durkheim, Emile (19001) [Review of Philosophie des Geldes by G. Simmel],

    LAnnee Sociologique5: 1405.

    Durkheim, Emile (19023) [Review of Simmel (19023), (1903)], LAnnee

    Sociologique7: 6469.

    Durkheim, Emile (1951) Suicide: A Study in Sociology. New York: Free Press.

    Durkheim, Emile (1964) Sociology and Its Scientific Field, pp. 35575 in K.H.

    Wolff (ed.) Emile Durkheim et al.: Essays on Sociology and Philosophy,. New

    York: Harper & Row.

    Durkheim, Emile (1982) Sociology and the Social Sciences, pp. 175208 in The

    Rules of Sociological Method, ed. S. Lukes. New York: Free Press.

    Durkheim, Emile (1984) The Division of Labor in Society. New York: Free Press.Faught, Jim (1985) Neglected Affinities: Max Weber and Georg Simmel, British

    Journal of Sociology36(2): 15574.

    Featherstone, Mike (ed.) (1991) Special Issue on Georg Simmel, Theory,

    Culture & Society8(3): 1252.

    DEFLEM THE SOCIOLOGY OF THE SOCIOLOGY OF MONEY 91

    at BROWN UNIVERSITY on May 9, 2013jcs.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/http://jcs.sagepub.com/
  • 8/11/2019 Battle of the Classics

    27/31

    Frankel, S. Herbert (1977) Two Philosophies of Money: The Conflict of Trust and

    Authority. New York: St Martins Press.

    Frerichs, Klaus (2001) Die Kohle und die Knete: Zu Georg Simmels Pragmatik

    des Geldes, Simmel Studies11(1): 8791.

    Frisby, David P. (1985) Georg Simmel: First Sociologist of Modernity, Theory,Culture and Society2(3): 4967.

    Frisby, David P. (1987) The Ambiguity of Modernity: Georg Simmel and Max

    Weber, pp. 42233 in W.J. Mommsen and J. Osterhammel (eds) Max

    Weber and His