Adverse Selection in Competitive Search Equilibrium

44
Adverse Selection in Competitive Search Equilibrium Veronica Guerrieri, Robert Shimer, and Randall Wright Stanford GSB, 2009

Transcript of Adverse Selection in Competitive Search Equilibrium

Page 1: Adverse Selection in Competitive Search Equilibrium

Adverse Selection inCompetitive Search Equilibrium

Veronica Guerrieri, Robert Shimer, and Randall Wright

Stanford GSB, 2009

Page 2: Adverse Selection in Competitive Search Equilibrium

Objective

“Adverse Selection and Search” -p. 2

study adverse selection in environments with search frictions

competitive search: principals compete to attract agents

here: uninformed principals compete to attract heterogeneous agents

principals form rational beliefs about matching probability and com-position of agents associated to any contract

Page 3: Adverse Selection in Competitive Search Equilibrium

Objective

“Adverse Selection and Search” -p. 2

study adverse selection in environments with search frictions

competitive search: principals compete to attract agents

here: uninformed principals compete to attract heterogeneous agents

principals form rational beliefs about matching probability and com-position of agents associated to any contract

ISSUE: interaction of adverse selection and competitive search

1. adverse selection affects the search equilibrium

2. search affects the set of contracts offered in equilibrium

Page 4: Adverse Selection in Competitive Search Equilibrium

Results

“Adverse Selection and Search” -p. 3

existence and uniqueness of equilibrium

equilibrium may be constrained inefficient

private information may distort terms of trade or market tightness

three examples:

layoff insurance

asset market

rat race

Page 5: Adverse Selection in Competitive Search Equilibrium

Literature

“Adverse Selection and Search” -p. 4

competitive search: Montgomery (1991), Peters (1991), Shimer(1996), Moen (1997), Acemoglu and Shimer (1999), Burdett, Shi, andWright (2001), Mortensen and Wright (2002)

competitive search with asymmetric information: Inderst and Muller(1999), Faig and Jerez (2005), Moen and Rosen (2006), Guerrieri(2008)

adverse selection with different market structures: Rothschild andStigliz (1976), Miyazaki (1977), Wilson (1977), Riley (1979), Prescottand Townsend (1984), Gale (1992), Dubey and Geanakoplos (2002),Bisin and Gottardi (2006)

Page 6: Adverse Selection in Competitive Search Equilibrium

Roadmap

“Adverse Selection and Search” -p. 5

general model

environment

equilibrium definition

example:

layoff insurance

general results:

existence and uniqueness

other examples:

asset market

rat race

Page 7: Adverse Selection in Competitive Search Equilibrium

Model

“Adverse Selection and Search” -p. 6

Page 8: Adverse Selection in Competitive Search Equilibrium

EnvironmentMotivation

Model

❖ Environment

❖ Timing

❖ Contracts

❖ Incentive Compatibility

❖ Matching

❖ Expected Utilities

❖ Equilibrium

Layoff Insurance

Characterization

Asset Market

Rat Race

Conclusions

“Adverse Selection and Search” -p. 7

large measure of ex-ante homogeneous principals

continuum of measure 1 of heterogeneous agents

πi > 0 agents of type i ∈ {1, 2, ..., I} ≡ I

agent’s type is his own private information

principals and agents have single opportunity to match

Page 9: Adverse Selection in Competitive Search Equilibrium

TimingMotivation

Model

❖ Environment

❖ Timing

❖ Contracts

❖ Incentive Compatibility

❖ Matching

❖ Expected Utilities

❖ Equilibrium

Layoff Insurance

Characterization

Asset Market

Rat Race

Conclusions

“Adverse Selection and Search” -p. 8

each principal can post a contract C at a cost k > 0

agents observe the set of posted contracts C

agents direct search to their preferred one

principals and agents match in pairs

matched principals and agents implement the contract

agents who fail to match get their outside option = 0

Page 10: Adverse Selection in Competitive Search Equilibrium

ContractsMotivation

Model

❖ Environment

❖ Timing

❖ Contracts

❖ Incentive Compatibility

❖ Matching

❖ Expected Utilities

❖ Equilibrium

Layoff Insurance

Characterization

Asset Market

Rat Race

Conclusions

“Adverse Selection and Search” -p. 9

y ∈ Y is an action

Y is a compact metric space (allows for lotteries)

if a principal and a type-i agent match and undertake y:

agent gets ui(y), continuous

principal gets vi(y), continuous

WLOG, contracts are revelation mechanisms

a contract is a vector of actions C ≡ {y1, . . . , yI}, whereyi is prescribed if matched agent reports type i

Page 11: Adverse Selection in Competitive Search Equilibrium

Incentive CompatibilityMotivation

Model

❖ Environment

❖ Timing

❖ Contracts

❖ Incentive Compatibility

❖ Matching

❖ Expected Utilities

❖ Equilibrium

Layoff Insurance

Characterization

Asset Market

Rat Race

Conclusions

“Adverse Selection and Search” -p. 10

a contract C = {y1, . . . , yI} is incentive-compatible iff

ui(yi) ≥ ui(yj) for all i, j

let C be the set of incentive-compatible contracts (C ⊂ C)

Page 12: Adverse Selection in Competitive Search Equilibrium

MatchingMotivation

Model

❖ Environment

❖ Timing

❖ Contracts

❖ Incentive Compatibility

❖ Matching

❖ Expected Utilities

❖ Equilibrium

Layoff Insurance

Characterization

Asset Market

Rat Race

Conclusions

“Adverse Selection and Search” -p. 11

constant returns to scale matching function

Θ(C): principal/agent ratio associated to contract C

γi(C): share of agents of type i seeking C

Γ(C) = (γ1(C), . . . , γI(C))

µ(Θ(C)): probability an agent seeking C matches

η(Θ(C))γi(C): probability a principal posting C matcheswith a type i agent

µ and η are continuous functions, µ(θ) = η(θ)θ

Page 13: Adverse Selection in Competitive Search Equilibrium

Expected UtilitiesMotivation

Model

❖ Environment

❖ Timing

❖ Contracts

❖ Incentive Compatibility

❖ Matching

❖ Expected Utilities

❖ Equilibrium

Layoff Insurance

Characterization

Asset Market

Rat Race

Conclusions

“Adverse Selection and Search” -p. 12

expected utility of principal offering C = {y1, . . . , yI}:

η(Θ(C))I∑

i=1

γi(C)vi(yi) − k

expected utility of type-i agent seeking C = {y1, . . . , yI}:

µ(Θ(C))ui (yi)

Page 14: Adverse Selection in Competitive Search Equilibrium

Competitive Search EquilibriumMotivation

Model

❖ Environment

❖ Timing

❖ Contracts

❖ Incentive Compatibility

❖ Matching

❖ Expected Utilities

❖ Equilibrium

Layoff Insurance

Characterization

Asset Market

Rat Race

Conclusions

“Adverse Selection and Search” -p. 13

A CSE is a vector U = {U1, . . . , UI}, a measure λ on C,and two functions Θ(C) and Γ(C) on C s.t.

(i) profit maximization and free entry : ∀C ∈ C,

η(Θ(C))I∑

i=1

γi(C)vi(yi) − k ≤ 0, with equality if C ∈ C;

(ii) optimal search : ∀C ∈ C and i,

µ(Θ(C))ui(yi) ≤ Ui ≡ max

{

0, maxC′={y′

1,...,y′

I}∈C

µ(Θ(C ′))ui(y′i)

}

,

with equality if Θ(C) < ∞ and γi(C) > 0;

(iii) market clearing

Page 15: Adverse Selection in Competitive Search Equilibrium

Layoff Insurance(Rothschild and Stigliz 1976)

“Adverse Selection and Search” -p. 14

Page 16: Adverse Selection in Competitive Search Equilibrium

ModelMotivation

Model

Layoff Insurance

❖ Model

❖ Contracts and Payoffs

❖ Equilibrium

❖ Rothschild-Stiglitz

❖ Existence

❖ Efficiency

Characterization

Asset Market

Rat Race

Conclusions

“Adverse Selection and Search” -p. 15

principals = homogeneous risk-neutral firms

cost k to search for a worker

can hire at most one worker

productive match produces 1 unit of output

unproductive match leads to a layoff

agents = heterogeneous risk-averse workers

pi = probability of a productive match for type i

2 types with k < p1 < p2, share πi

pi is private info, firms only verify ex-post realization

utility of workers never employed is normalized to 0

Page 17: Adverse Selection in Competitive Search Equilibrium

Contracts and PayoffsMotivation

Model

Layoff Insurance

❖ Model

❖ Contracts and Payoffs

❖ Equilibrium

❖ Rothschild-Stiglitz

❖ Existence

❖ Efficiency

Characterization

Asset Market

Rat Race

Conclusions

“Adverse Selection and Search” -p. 16

action: y = (ce, cu) with

ce = consumption if productive

cu = consumption if unproductive

if firm and type-i worker match and undertake (ce, cu):

worker gets ui(ce, cu) = piU(ce) + (1 − pi)U(cu)

firm gets vi(ce, cu) = pi(1 − ce) − (1 − pi)c

u

contract: C = {(ce1, c

u1), (c

e2, c

u2)}

matching function: µ(θ) = min{θ, 1}

Page 18: Adverse Selection in Competitive Search Equilibrium

EquilibriumMotivation

Model

Layoff Insurance

❖ Model

❖ Contracts and Payoffs

❖ Equilibrium

❖ Rothschild-Stiglitz

❖ Existence

❖ Efficiency

Characterization

Asset Market

Rat Race

Conclusions

“Adverse Selection and Search” -p. 17

there exists a unique separating equilibrium

all workers find a job with probability 1

private info distorts contracts (relative to full info)

ce1 = cu

1 = p1 − k → full insurance

ce2 > ce

1 and cu2 < cu

1 → partial insurance

Page 19: Adverse Selection in Competitive Search Equilibrium

Rothschild-StiglitzMotivation

Model

Layoff Insurance

❖ Model

❖ Contracts and Payoffs

❖ Equilibrium

❖ Rothschild-Stiglitz

❖ Existence

❖ Efficiency

Characterization

Asset Market

Rat Race

Conclusions

“Adverse Selection and Search” -p. 18

in RS if there is an equilibrium, least cost separating

BUT if there are few bad agents, a pooling contract isprofitable deviation ⇒ non-existence result

if offering pooling contract, optimal offer full insurance

consider a contract CP = {(c, c), (c, c)} such that

U(c) ≥ p2U (ce2)+(1 − p2) U (cu

2) > p1U (ce1)+(1 − p1) U (cu

1)

if π1 < 1 − c then the deviation is profitable given that

(1 − π1) − c > 0

Page 20: Adverse Selection in Competitive Search Equilibrium

ExistenceMotivation

Model

Layoff Insurance

❖ Model

❖ Contracts and Payoffs

❖ Equilibrium

❖ Rothschild-Stiglitz

❖ Existence

❖ Efficiency

Characterization

Asset Market

Rat Race

Conclusions

“Adverse Selection and Search” -p. 19

why in our model this deviation is not profitable?

consider the same pooling contract CP = {(c, c), (c, c)}

to attract both types need

µ(

Θ(

CP))

U (c) ≥ U1

µ(

Θ(

CP))

U (c) ≥ U2

as long as one is a strict inequality, Θ(

CP)

would adjustup to

µ(

Θ(

CP))

U (c) = U1

µ(

Θ(

CP))

U (c) < U2

BUT then bad types don’t go → not profitable

Page 21: Adverse Selection in Competitive Search Equilibrium

EfficiencyMotivation

Model

Layoff Insurance

❖ Model

❖ Contracts and Payoffs

❖ Equilibrium

❖ Rothschild-Stiglitz

❖ Existence

❖ Efficiency

Characterization

Asset Market

Rat Race

Conclusions

“Adverse Selection and Search” -p. 20

equilibrium may be constrained inefficient

few low types → cross-subsidization Pareto dominant

consider a planner that restrict firms to post pooling con-tracts

in this case, the associated market tightness will beequal to 1

an equilibrium is constrained inefficient when it does notexists in RS!

Page 22: Adverse Selection in Competitive Search Equilibrium

Characterization

“Adverse Selection and Search” -p. 21

Page 23: Adverse Selection in Competitive Search Equilibrium

AssumptionsMotivation

Model

Layoff Insurance

Characterization

❖ Assumptions

❖ Optimization Problem

❖ Existence

❖ Uniqueness

❖ Positive Utility

Asset Market

Rat Race

Conclusions

“Adverse Selection and Search” -p. 22

define Yi ≡{

y ∈ Y | ηvi(y) ≥ k and ui(y) > 0}

A1. Monotonicity : for all y ∈⋃

i Yi

v1(y) ≤ v2(y) ≤ . . . ≤ vI(y)

A2. Local non-satiation : for all i, y ∈ Yi, and ε > 0

∃y′ ∈ Bε(y) s.t. vi(y′) > vi(y)

A3. Sorting : for all i, y ∈ Yi, and ε > 0, ∃y′ ∈ Bε(y) s.t.

uj(y′) > uj(y) for all j ≥ i

uj(y′) < uj(y) for all j < i

Page 24: Adverse Selection in Competitive Search Equilibrium

Optimization ProblemMotivation

Model

Layoff Insurance

Characterization

❖ Assumptions

❖ Optimization Problem

❖ Existence

❖ Uniqueness

❖ Positive Utility

Asset Market

Rat Race

Conclusions

“Adverse Selection and Search” -p. 23

consider the constrained maximization problem

Ui = maxθ∈[0,∞],y∈Y

µ(θ)ui(y) (P-i)

s.t. η(θ)vi(y) ≥ k,

µ(θ)uj(y) ≤ Uj for all j < i.

call a solution to the collection of (P-i) a solution to (P)

if for some i the constraint set is empty or the problemhas a negative maximum set Ui = 0

Lemma: (P) has a solution and U is unique

recursive structure of (P) ⇒ solve (P-1) first. . .

Page 25: Adverse Selection in Competitive Search Equilibrium

ExistenceMotivation

Model

Layoff Insurance

Characterization

❖ Assumptions

❖ Optimization Problem

❖ Existence

❖ Uniqueness

❖ Positive Utility

Asset Market

Rat Race

Conclusions

“Adverse Selection and Search” -p. 24

Proposition 1 : assume A1-A3,let {Ui}, {θi}, and {yi} be a solution to (P)

there exists a CSE {U , λ, C,Θ,Γ} with

1. U = {Ui}

2. C = {Ci}, where Ci = (yi, . . . , yi)

3. Θ(Ci) = θi

4. γi(Ci) = 1

Page 26: Adverse Selection in Competitive Search Equilibrium

UniquenessMotivation

Model

Layoff Insurance

Characterization

❖ Assumptions

❖ Optimization Problem

❖ Existence

❖ Uniqueness

❖ Positive Utility

Asset Market

Rat Race

Conclusions

“Adverse Selection and Search” -p. 25

Proposition 2 : assume A1-A3,let {U , λ, C,Θ,Γ} be a CSE

let {Ui} = U

take any {θi, yi} s.t. ∃Ci = {y1, . . . , yi, . . . , yI} ∈ C withθi = Θ(Ci) < ∞, γi(Ci) > 0

{Ui}, {θi}, and {yi} solve (P)

Page 27: Adverse Selection in Competitive Search Equilibrium

Positive UtilityMotivation

Model

Layoff Insurance

Characterization

❖ Assumptions

❖ Optimization Problem

❖ Existence

❖ Uniqueness

❖ Positive Utility

Asset Market

Rat Race

Conclusions

“Adverse Selection and Search” -p. 26

Proposition 3 : assume A1-A3,{y ∈ Y|η(0)vi(y) > k and ui(y) > 0} 6= ∅ for all i

in equilibrium, Ui > 0 for all i

NOTE: positive gains of trade for some i do not guaran-tee Ui > 0 (next example)

Page 28: Adverse Selection in Competitive Search Equilibrium

Asset Market(Akerlof 1970)

“Adverse Selection and Search” -p. 27

Page 29: Adverse Selection in Competitive Search Equilibrium

ModelMotivation

Model

Layoff Insurance

Characterization

Asset Market

❖ Model

❖ Assumptions

❖ Equilibrium

❖ No Trade

Rat Race

Conclusions

“Adverse Selection and Search” -p. 28

sellers own heterogeneous apples

buyers value apples more than sellers

an action is y = (α, t):

α = probability seller gives up apple

t = transfer from buyer to seller

if buyer and type-i seller match and undertake (α, t):

seller’s payoff: ui(α, t) = t − αaSi

buyer’s payoff: vi(α, t) = αaBi − t

Page 30: Adverse Selection in Competitive Search Equilibrium

AssumptionsMotivation

Model

Layoff Insurance

Characterization

Asset Market

❖ Model

❖ Assumptions

❖ Equilibrium

❖ No Trade

Rat Race

Conclusions

“Adverse Selection and Search” -p. 29

assume there are only two types I = 2

type 2 sellers have a better apple: aS2 > aS

1 ≥ 0

preferences of buyers and sellers aligned: aB2 > aB

1 ≥ 0

for now assume gains from trade: aBi > aS

i + k

matching µ(θ) = min{θ, 1}

Page 31: Adverse Selection in Competitive Search Equilibrium

EquilibriumMotivation

Model

Layoff Insurance

Characterization

Asset Market

❖ Model

❖ Assumptions

❖ Equilibrium

❖ No Trade

Rat Race

Conclusions

“Adverse Selection and Search” -p. 30

there exists a CSE with:

1. αi = 1 and ti = aBi − k for all i

2. θ1 = 1 and θ2 =aB

1 − aS1 − k

aB2 − aS

1 − k< 1

NOTE: private information affects market tightness

rationing through α would be more costly due to k

Pareto improvement if π1 <aB

2 − aS2 − k

aB2 − aS

1 − k

Page 32: Adverse Selection in Competitive Search Equilibrium

No TradeMotivation

Model

Layoff Insurance

Characterization

Asset Market

❖ Model

❖ Assumptions

❖ Equilibrium

❖ No Trade

Rat Race

Conclusions

“Adverse Selection and Search” -p. 31

now suppose aB1 ≤ aS

1 + k

then, U1 = U2 = 0, no contracts are posted

bad asset shuts down the market for a good one

Page 33: Adverse Selection in Competitive Search Equilibrium

Rat Race(Akerlof 1976)

“Adverse Selection and Search” -p. 32

Page 34: Adverse Selection in Competitive Search Equilibrium

ModelMotivation

Model

Layoff Insurance

Characterization

Asset Market

Rat Race

❖ Model

❖ Assumptions

❖ Benchmark

❖ Equilibrium

Conclusions

“Adverse Selection and Search” -p. 33

workers heterogeneous in preferences and productivity

homogeneous firms need to hire a worker to produce

an action is y = (c, h):

c = wage

h = hours worked

if a firm and a type-i worker match and undertake (c, h)

worker’s payoff: ui(c, h) = ui(c, h)

firm’s payoff: vi(c, h) = fi(h) − c

Page 35: Adverse Selection in Competitive Search Equilibrium

AssumptionsMotivation

Model

Layoff Insurance

Characterization

Asset Market

Rat Race

❖ Model

❖ Assumptions

❖ Benchmark

❖ Equilibrium

Conclusions

“Adverse Selection and Search” -p. 34

assume there are only two types I = 2

wlog type 2 is more productive: f2(h) > f1(h) for all h

single crossing assumption:

−∂u2/∂h

∂u2/∂c< −

∂u1/∂h

∂u1/∂c

matching µ(θ) = min{θ, 1}

Page 36: Adverse Selection in Competitive Search Equilibrium

BenchmarkMotivation

Model

Layoff Insurance

Characterization

Asset Market

Rat Race

❖ Model

❖ Assumptions

❖ Benchmark

❖ Equilibrium

Conclusions

“Adverse Selection and Search” -p. 35

full info equilibrium determined by three equations:

optimality for hours

−∂ui(ci, hi)/∂h

∂ui(ci, hi)/∂c= f ′

i(hi)

optimality for vacancy creation:

µ′(θi)

(

fi(hi) − ci +ui(ci, hi)

∂ui(ci, hi)/∂c

)

= k

free-entry condition

µ(θi)

θi

(fi(hi) − ci) = k

Page 37: Adverse Selection in Competitive Search Equilibrium

EquilibriumMotivation

Model

Layoff Insurance

Characterization

Asset Market

Rat Race

❖ Model

❖ Assumptions

❖ Benchmark

❖ Equilibrium

Conclusions

“Adverse Selection and Search” -p. 36

there is a unique separating equilibrium

private info distorts contracts:

low type not distorted

high type distorted (overemployment):

−∂u2(c2, h2)/∂h

∂u2(c2, h2)/∂c> f ′

2(h2)

market tightness may be distorted in either direction

Page 38: Adverse Selection in Competitive Search Equilibrium

EquilibriumMotivation

Model

Layoff Insurance

Characterization

Asset Market

Rat Race

❖ Model

❖ Assumptions

❖ Benchmark

❖ Equilibrium

Conclusions

“Adverse Selection and Search” -p. 36

there is a unique separating equilibrium

private info distorts contracts:

low type not distorted

high type distorted (overemployment):

−∂u2(c2, h2)/∂h

∂u2(c2, h2)/∂c> f ′

2(h2)

market tightness may be distorted in either direction

NOTE: equilibrium may be constrained inefficient

few low types or high cost of screening, cross-subsidization may Pareto dominate

Page 39: Adverse Selection in Competitive Search Equilibrium

Conclusions

“Adverse Selection and Search” -p. 37

Page 40: Adverse Selection in Competitive Search Equilibrium

ConclusionsMotivation

Model

Layoff Insurance

Characterization

Asset Market

Rat Race

Conclusions

“Adverse Selection and Search” -p. 38

general framework combining search frictions and ad-verse selection

existence and uniqueness

general algorithm to characterize equilibrium

private information can affect contracts and/or matching

equilibrium may be Pareto dominated

Page 41: Adverse Selection in Competitive Search Equilibrium

Incentive Feasibility

Motivation

Model

Layoff Insurance

Characterization

Asset Market

Rat Race

Conclusions

Incentive Feasibility

❖ Allocation

❖ Incentive-Feasibility

“Adverse Selection and Search” -p. 39

Page 42: Adverse Selection in Competitive Search Equilibrium

AllocationMotivation

Model

Layoff Insurance

Characterization

Asset Market

Rat Race

Conclusions

Incentive Feasibility

❖ Allocation

❖ Incentive-Feasibility

“Adverse Selection and Search” -p. 40

An allocation is

a vector U of expected utilities for the agents

a measure λ over C with support C

a function Θ : C 7→ [0,∞]

a function Γ : C 7→ ∆I

Page 43: Adverse Selection in Competitive Search Equilibrium

Incentive-FeasibilityMotivation

Model

Layoff Insurance

Characterization

Asset Market

Rat Race

Conclusions

Incentive Feasibility

❖ Allocation

❖ Incentive-Feasibility

“Adverse Selection and Search” -p. 41

An allocation is incentive feasible if

1.

(

η(Θ(C))I∑

i=1

γi(C)vi(yi) − k

)

dλ(C) = 0;

2. for any C ∈ C and i s.t. γi(C) > 0 and Θ(C) < ∞,

µ(Θ(C))ui(yi) = Ui = maxC′∈C

µ(Θ(C ′))ui(y′i)

3.∫

γi(C)

Θ(C)dλ(C) ≤ πi, with equality if Ui > 0

Page 44: Adverse Selection in Competitive Search Equilibrium

MIT OpenCourseWarehttp://ocw.mit.edu

14.461 Advanced Macroeconomics IFall 2009

For information about citing these materials or our Terms of Use, visit: http://ocw.mit.edu/terms.