ABR 1992Corporate Governance and Disclosure Quality V22N86 111-124 SPRING

download ABR 1992Corporate Governance and Disclosure Quality V22N86 111-124 SPRING

of 15

Transcript of ABR 1992Corporate Governance and Disclosure Quality V22N86 111-124 SPRING

  • 7/23/2019 ABR 1992Corporate Governance and Disclosure Quality V22N86 111-124 SPRING

    1/15

    This article was downloaded by: [University Of South Australia Library]On: 10 October 2012, At: 07:21Publisher: RoutledgeInforma Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954 Registered office:Mortimer House, 37-41 Mortimer Street, London W1T 3JH, UK

    Accounting and Business ResearchPublication details, including instructions for authors and subscription

    information:

    http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/rabr20

    Corporate Governance and Disclosure QualityJohn J. Forker

    a

    aUniversity of Bristol

    Version of record first published: 28 Feb 2012.

    To cite this article:John J. Forker (1992): Corporate Governance and Disclosure Quality, Accounting and

    Business Research, 22:86, 111-124

    To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/00014788.1992.9729426

    PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE

    Full terms and conditions of use: http://www.tandfonline.com/page/terms-and-conditions

    This article may be used for research, teaching, and private study purposes. Any substantialor systematic reproduction, redistribution, reselling, loan, sub-licensing, systematic supply, ordistribution in any form to anyone is expressly forbidden.

    The publisher does not give any warranty express or implied or make any representation that thecontents will be complete or accurate or up to date. The accuracy of any instructions, formulae,and drug doses should be independently verified with primary sources. The publisher shall notbe liable for any loss, actions, claims, proceedings, demand, or costs ordamages whatsoever orhowsoever caused arising directly or indirectly in connection with or arising out of the use of thismaterial.

    http://www.tandfonline.com/page/terms-and-conditionshttp://dx.doi.org/10.1080/00014788.1992.9729426http://www.tandfonline.com/page/terms-and-conditionshttp://dx.doi.org/10.1080/00014788.1992.9729426http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/rabr20
  • 7/23/2019 ABR 1992Corporate Governance and Disclosure Quality V22N86 111-124 SPRING

    2/15

    Accounting and Business Research Vol. 22. No

    6. pp.

    1-124, 1992

    Corporate Governance

    and

    Disclosure

    Quality

    John

    J.

    Forker*

    Abstract-The effectiveness of control exercised over executive remun eration an d the quality of informa tion disclosed

    in financial statements have given rise to concern and have led to proposals for the reform of corporate governance.

    A model of the optim al disclosure decision is presented in terms of m anagerial incentives and the impac t of corporate

    governance structures. An investigation into the quality of share option disclosure in financial statements is used

    as the basis for testing hypotheses derived from the model and for assessing alternative policy options. The results

    support the need for guidance on the duties and responsibilities of audit committees and non-executive directors

    but fall short of providing a basis for deciding whether regulatory action is required. The evidence also supports

    the view that a threat to monitoring quality exists where the roles of chief executive and chairman are combined.

    Introduction

    The quality of information disclosed in financial

    statements and the control exercised over executive

    remuneration have given rise to concern a nd pu blic

    debate in both the United States and the United

    Kingdom. Reaction in the US has focused on

    extending the regulation of corporate governance.

    As

    a means of improving internal accounting

    control the National Commission on Fraudulent

    Financial Reporting (1987), otherwise known as

    the Treadway Commission, recommended that the

    Securities and Exchange Commission require all

    US public companies to establish audit com mittees

    composed solely of independent non-executive

    directors. This contrasts with

    a

    preference in the

    UK

    for the provision of guidance on aspects of

    good governance practice. Most recently the

    Institutional Shareholders Committee (ISC, 1991)'

    *The author is lecturer in accounting at the University of

    Bristol. Financial support from the Research Board of the

    Insti tute of Chartered Ac countants in England a nd W ales and

    the research assistance provided by G eoffrey Elliott and Sa lima

    Paul are gratefully acknowledged. The paper was presented at

    the Universities of Auckland, Bristol and the Australian Na-

    tional University and at the European Accounting Association

    Congress at Maastricht in April, 1991 and to the Financial

    Accounting and A uditing Research conference at the London

    Business School in

    July,

    1991. I tha nk the part icipants a t these

    presentations and am particularly grateful to David Ashton,

    Don Egginton, Michael Mumford, Peter Pope (Touche Ross

    Fellow visiting Bristol from the University of North Queens-

    land) and two anonymous referees for helpful suggestions.

    'These recommendations follow publication by the invest-

    ment protection committee of the Association of British Insur-

    ers

    (1990) of a discussion paper on the role and duties of

    directors. The establishment of a Committee on Financial

    Aspects of Corpora te Governance under the Chairmanship of

    Sir Adrian Cadbury (May 1991) reflects the perceived import-

    ance of the link between financial reporting and corporate

    governance.

    recommended that remuneration committees com-

    prising independent non-executive directors be re-

    sponsible for determining executive remuneration

    and the provisions of share option schemes, and

    that details of the latter be disclosed in financial

    statements. The Committee also acknowledged the

    potential threat posed by dominant personalities

    an d expressed the view tha t the practice of combin-

    ing the roles of chairman and chief executive is

    undesirable.

    The need for action to influence corporate gov-

    ernance structure and accounting disclosure is,

    however, challenged by those who view interven-

    tion as more likely to hinder than improve gover-

    nance.' Th e aim of this paper is to contribu te to the

    debate by modelling and empirically investigating

    the relationship between governance structure and

    the degree of internal control exercised over man-

    agerial remuneration as reflected by the quality of

    share option disclosure in financial statements. Th e

    finding of no association between aud it comm ittees

    or non-executive directors and the qu ality of share

    option disclosure supports the case for policy

    action to enhance control of managerial remunera-

    tion. Th e study covers the period 1987/88 when

    audit com mittees and non-executive directors were

    the main instruments of corporate governance.

    'The case supporting this view, based on the operation of a

    market in decision control for corporate governance, is pre-

    sented in Fama (1980) and Fama and Jensen 1983), and is

    applied to a ccounting disclosure by Benston (1982). The incon-

    clusive nature of the debate

    so

    far is illustrated by successive

    revisions of the Am erican La w Institute propo sals (1982, 1990)

    for the reform of corpor ate governance. A first tentative draft

    published in 1982 has to d ate been replaced b y a ten th tentative

    draft. A comprehensive review of governance proposals,

    to-

    gether with a normative based prop osal for refo rm, is provided

    in Gilson and K raakm an (1990). Tricker (1984) and Clarkh am

    (1989) provide UK-based analyses of c orpora te governance.

    Downloadedby[UniversityOfSouthAustra

    liaLibrary]at07:2110October2

    012

  • 7/23/2019 ABR 1992Corporate Governance and Disclosure Quality V22N86 111-124 SPRING

    3/15

    112 A C C O U N T I N G A N D B U S I N E S S R E S E AR C H

    During that period only two firms in the sample

    disclosed in finan cial statemen ts the existence of a

    remuneration committee. The ISC (1991) proposal

    that executive remuneration should be the specific

    responsibility of a remuneration committee may

    improve control and disclosure in financial state-

    ments. How ever, this is likely to be conditional on

    identification of the duties, and provision of de-

    tailed guidance on the discharge of responsibilities

    of non-executive directors an d audit a nd remuner-

    ation com mittees. The identification of an inverse

    relation between dom inant personalities and audit

    committees and non-executive directors also war-

    rants consideration. The methodology employed

    does not, however, extend to providing a basis for

    deciding if guidance alone would be sufficient or

    whether regulation is also necessary.

    Disclosure quality is described by Verrecchia

    (1990, footnote 3) as the distributional ch aracter-

    istic or variance of a n uncertain event. The event

    focused on in this paper is the granting of share

    options to employees. Deciding on the quality of

    disclosure of share option information allows man-

    agem ent to influence the level of uncertainty faced

    by investors in estimating share option benefits.

    The greater the uncertainty the less effective will be

    the monitoring of share option benefits and the

    greater will be the potential use of options to

    increase rewards beyond levels acceptable to share-

    holders.

    Williamsons (1985b) analysis of transaction

    costs provides a framework linking disclosure

    quality to co rporate governance. This is integrated

    with the positive theory of agency developed by

    Jensen and Meckling (1976) to provide a m odel of

    the discloure decision of management. Manage-

    ment are assumed to balance potential benefits

    from less disclosure against costs in the form of

    lower share prices and increased threat of takeover

    and to choose the quality of disclosure which

    minimises the costs they incur. Adoption of in-

    ternal control devices such as aud it comm ittees and

    non-executive directors, an d separation of the roles

    of chairman and chief executive, enhance m onitor-

    ing quality and reduce benefits from withholding

    information; a s a consequence disclosure quality in

    financial statemen ts is improved.

    Corporate Governance: The Policy Debate

    Doubts about the adequacy of corporate gover-

    nance in the

    UK

    is evident in matters relating to

    executive remuneration and the impact of domi-

    nant personalities on the decision making pro-

    cedures of boards of directors. On the issue of

    executive remuneration. the investment m otection

    voting power when shareholder ap proval is sought

    for executive share option schemes. A subsequent

    discussion paper (ABI, 1990) directed attention

    toward improving internal control, and proposed

    that non-executive directors assume responsibility

    for executive remuneration and the provisions of

    share option schemes and that details of option

    schemes be disclosed in financial statemen ts. These

    proposals are incorporated in the document on

    best practice published by the Institutional Share-

    holders Committee (1991).

    The Bank of England has adopted a wider

    perspective and has repeatedly drawn attention to

    what it regards as the poor state of corporate

    governance in the UK. Bank of England sponsored

    surveys (1983, 1985, 1988) highlight as threats to

    internal control the generally low proportion of

    non-executive directors on company boards, the

    likelihood th at non-executive directors ap pointed

    will not be independent, and the frequency with

    which chief executives also act as chairmen of

    boards of directors.

    The policy option favoured by the British auth-

    orities has been to improve internal me chanism s of

    corporate governance through a process of persua-

    sion and education of the business commun ity. In

    1981 following failure of attempts to obtain statu-

    tory backing for a proposal that companies be

    required to appoint non-executive directors,

    PRONED (Promotion of Non-Executive Direc-

    tors) was established under the sponsorship of the

    Bank of England and major City institutions, to

    promo te and facilitate the appointment of indepen-

    dent non-executive directors. The code of conduct

    published by PRONED (1987) reflects the

    UK

    preference for recommendation rather than regu-

    lation. This contrasts with the situation in the

    US

    where the governance structures of listed compa-

    nies are subject to regu1ation .j This has been

    reinforced by the Treadway Comm ission proposal

    that all companies supervised by the SEC be

    required to establish aud it comm ittees comprising

    independent directors.

    Corporate Governance: The Academic Deb ate

    Public policy on corporate governance has been

    formulated against a background of academic de-

    bate abo ut the regulation of corporate governance.

    Disagreem ent exists abo ut the disciplinary effect of

    comp etition. Those taking a n antago nistic view of

    regulation (Watts, 1977; Watts and Zimmerman,

    1978; Fam a and Jensen, 1983; Scott, 1983) d o

    so

    because they regard market discipline as sufficient

    to realise benefits associated with governance

    committee of the Association of British Insurers

    published guidelines (ABI, 1987) setting limits to

    the benefits which be

    Obtained

    from

    execu-

    tive share o ptions- These guidelines aim to provide

    financial institutions with a focus to exercise their

    3The statutory and regulatory requirements relating to cor-

    porate governance in the

    US,

    and the governance structures

    adopted by

    US firms,

    are described in the Paris Colloquium on

    Corporate Governance (1984) and Birkett (1 986).

    Downloadedby[UniversityOfSouthAustra

    liaLibrary]at07:2110October2

    012

  • 7/23/2019 ABR 1992Corporate Governance and Disclosure Quality V22N86 111-124 SPRING

    4/15

    SP RI NG 1992 113

    control mechanism s. Regulation is justified only if

    it gives rise to net benefits and the onus of proof

    is placed on those advocating regulation. Further-

    more, different contracting structures across firms

    are viewed as having different governance conse-

    quences (Watts, 1988). Free choice of governance

    structure is therefore considered to be important,

    and regulating to impose standard forms of

    governance is viewed as unnecessary and poten-

    tially harmful.

    Fama

    (1

    980) advances a theoretical explana tion

    for a market in decision control. This operates

    through the monitoring activities of independent

    directors who have incentives to protect and

    sus-

    tain repu tations as experts in decision control. T he

    decision ratification and ex post monitoring role

    performed by boards of directors has received

    similar development by Fama and Jensen (1983).

    The de scriptive validity of these theories is chal-

    lenged by those who are sceptical of the effective-

    ness of market discipline. In part, this criticism

    arose because the composition of boards of direc-

    tors in practice is held to militate against effective

    monitoring (Mace, 1971). More specifically, the

    validity of the agency And contracting analogies

    cited in support of these theories has been chal-

    lenged by Clark (1985) and Brudney (1985). In

    addition, P ratt and Zeckhauser (1 985) cite the

    impact of retroactive effects of potential welfare

    improvements on agents to explain why it cannot

    be taken for granted that observed organisational

    forms are op timal. Potential go vernance improve-

    ments may be resisted by executives if they lead to

    uncompensated reductions in utility.

    Opportunism, Disclosure and Governance

    Opportunism according to Williamson (1985a,

    p. 47)

    refers to the incomplete or distorted

    disclosure of information, especially to calculated

    efforts to mislead, distort, obfuscate or otherwise

    confuse. By con trolling the quality of inform ation

    disclosed in financial statements management

    influence the uncertainty attached to the estimates

    that shareholders make of any given variable.

    Greater uncertainty reduces the effectiveness of

    monitoring procedures, which for share options

    rely on estimating costs to allow comparison of

    anticipated and actual benefits. Disclosure policies

    which reduce the quality of information increase

    the scope for opportunistic behaviour. In the case

    of share options these may be granted in circum-

    stances to which shareholders would object had

    more information been available.

    Where opportunism is joined with bounded

    rationality and asset specificity, implications arise

    for the governance of contractual relations. The

    need for flexibility dictates that, because of

    bounded rationality, not all eventualities are

    specified

    ex ante

    in contracts. The desire to pre-

    serve a continuing c ontrac tual relationsh ip because

    ABR

    22/86B

    of asset specificity leads to the setting

    up

    of gover-

    nance structures. These serve to monitor the con-

    duct of contracting parties and provide cost

    effective means for the resolution of disputes.

    The conditions of asset specificity and bounded

    rationality apply to executive remuneration and , in

    particular, to executive share options. T he substan -

    tial investment in human capital undertaken by

    executives is highly specific and often takes tim e to

    develop . It is, therefore, in the interest o f firms and

    their executives to devise reward structures which

    incorporate a deferred component. Given uncer-

    tainty an d with regard to bounded rationality, reward

    structures can be expected to incorporate flexibility

    to allow rewards to be related to achievement.

    Share option schemes satisfy these requirements.

    Share Options: The Constrained Choice Set

    of

    Management

    The im portance of the perceived threat to share-

    holders from share options g ranted to employees is

    indicated by the existence of a comprehensive set

    of constraints on managerial freedom of action.

    These aim to assist internal con trol, facilitate exter-

    nal m onitoring, set limits on the aggregate value of

    options granted and impose upper limits on the

    level of benefit obtained by individual executive

    directors. Authority for these constraints in the

    UK

    is provided by the Com panies Acts, the Stock

    Exchange and the Inland R e v e n ~ e .~he guidelines

    issued by the investment protection committees of

    the financial institutions add a private sector di-

    mension to the control framework. Following

    Watts and Zimmerman (1990), this network of

    restrictions can be interpreted as the ex ante delin-

    eation of the feasible set

    of

    choices available to

    management. Choices made ex post by manage-

    ment with respect to this set can be investigated in

    the light of the scope they offer for opportunistic

    behaviour. In general, the feasible set of choices

    available to management serve to set an upper

    bound on the benefits which can be obtained from

    share options. This pape r focuses on the disclosure

    dimension of managerial choice.

    Option Appraisal: Information Requirements

    The costs to shareholders of share option

    schemes comprise the value of options w hen they

    4The requirements of the Companies Acts relate to infor-

    mation which must be disclosed to shareholders, and recorded

    by the firm regarding options granted to directors. The Stock

    Exchange L isting Agreement serves to cover gaps perceived in

    the statutory requirements on disclosure, and on shareholders

    rights to approve share option schemes. Tax concessions are

    available only on those schemes falling within the restrictions

    set by the Inland Revenue. Finally, the investor protection

    committees of the financial institu tions, particularly the A ssoci-

    ation of British Insurers, have issued comprehensive guidelines

    imposing limits on the benefits available from option schemes.

    These restrictions are summarised in Egginton, Forker and

    Tippett (1989).

    Downloadedby[UniversityOfSouthAustra

    liaLibrary]at07:2110October2

    012

  • 7/23/2019 ABR 1992Corporate Governance and Disclosure Quality V22N86 111-124 SPRING

    5/15

    114

    A C C O U N T I N G A N D B U S I N E SS R E S E A RC H

    are granted, the cost of administering the schemes

    and the cost of dilution perceived by shareholders

    at the date options are granted. The benefits take

    the form of an anticipated improvement in share

    price performance. Satisfaction of the objectives of

    internal control and external monitoring require

    determination of these costs to allow comparison

    against realised share price performance. Judging

    the rate of issue of options and the distribution

    across individual executives depends on access to

    relevant information. Less disclosure impairs con-

    trol and provides scope for opportunism.

    The value of options when they are granted

    represents the biggest component of the cost of

    options to shareholders. Determination of this

    requires full information on the number

    of

    options

    granted

    N),

    the exercise prices X) and the dates

    during which they can be exercised T). The Com-

    panies Act (1985, Sch. 4, para.

    40 2))

    requires

    disclosure of this information if new shares are to

    be issued when options are exercised, but excludes

    shares to be purchased in the market. The ostensi-

    ble purpose of the statutory disclosure requirement

    appears to be to provide shareholders with infor-

    mation on dilution rather than to exercise control

    over the share option component of employee

    remuneration.6 Notwithstanding this difference,

    the disclosure requirements of the Companies Acts

    serve as a potential benchmark for the purpose of

    this study because information on the number of

    optional shares, exercise prices and exercise dates

    are necessary inputs for estimating the value of

    options granted to employees.

    lassijkation

    of

    Option Disclosure

    The quality of share option disclosure is

    classified according to the fineness of information

    provided for

    N, X

    and

    T.

    In particular, only the

    rule for setting X and T might be disclosed; for

    example, it may be stated that exercise prices are

    set equal to share prices when options are granted,

    and that options may be exercised between three

    and five years after the date of grant. A finer

    partition is where ranges for all exercise prices and

    all exercise dates are provided: for example, the

    disclosure that options are exercisable at prices

    between 250 and 550p and at dates between 1993

    5Employee share options are an alternative to cash

    or

    other

    benefits as a means of obtaining improved performance, and

    therefore should be evaluated by comparing costs and benefits.

    Where the value of options (warrants) granted equals the

    expected benefit receivable, Black an d Scholes (1973) and Galai

    and Schneller (1979) show that, under certain assumptions,

    options granted do not adversely affect the wealth of sh arehold-

    ers. Costs of dilution thus relate only to the prospect of a

    reduced proportionate share in the equity capital of the firm.

    61t is evident from inspection of the Articles of Association

    set out in Table A to the Companies Acts that shareholders

    have no direct power over executive remuneration. The C omp a-

    nies Act 1989 (Sch. 7 para 2(B)), howev er, extends the disclosure

    requirements applicable to options held by directors.

    and 1998. The disclosure requirements of the Com-

    panies Acts for options to subscribe for shares

    represent a still finer partitioning where the num-

    bers of options outstanding at each exercise price,

    and for each exercise period, are disclosed. Other

    aspects by which fineness could be measured relate

    to whether disclosure is further partitioned to

    reveal the distribution of options across different

    schemes, and the split in holdings between options

    held by directors and those held by other em-

    ployees of the firm for different option schemes.

    Modelling the Disclosure Decision

    Disclosure quality in financial statements is

    modelled as

    if

    management aim to minimise the

    costs they associate with disclosure. The level of

    these costs for different levels of disclosure is

    determined by variables which include the gover-

    nance structure of the firm. The disclosure dimen-

    sion of the constrained choice set imposes net costs

    if

    no information is provided. Improvements in

    disclosure quality are associated with higher infor-

    mation collection costs and with increases in the

    level of opportunistic benefits foregone by manage-

    ment. Inversely related to disclosure quality are

    costs imposed by auditors for non-compliance and

    monitoring costs incurred by investors. Security

    returns are assumed to be price protected and fully

    to reflect disclosure costs. These costs affect man-

    Disclosure

    Quality

    t

    A

    D O

    CO

    Costs

    o f Disclosure

    Figure 1

    Aggregate disclosure costs are given by AA while

    OB measures the opportunity

    loss

    management

    associated with disclosure. Increasing disclosure

    quality from the origin reduces the net cost of

    disclosure from OA. These costs are minimised at

    C;

    the optimal level of disclosure is Do. For

    disclosure quality better than Donet costs rise as

    disclosure quality is improved.

    Downloadedby[UniversityOfSouthAustra

    liaLibrary]at07:2110October2

    012

  • 7/23/2019 ABR 1992Corporate Governance and Disclosure Quality V22N86 111-124 SPRING

    6/15

    SPRING

    1 9 9 2

    5

    Disclosure Qual i ty

    A

    Costs

    o f Disclosure

    Figure 2

    For the same data as in Figure

    1

    the net cost of disclosure is illustrated. This is minimised at Do, he optimal

    disclosure quality, and increases for improved disclosure quality beyond

    Do.

    agerial wealth through the proportion

    a)

    of

    the firm owned by management and via the impact

    of lower firm values on the threat of takeover.

    These relationships are illustrated schematically

    in Figures 1 to

    3

    where, for illustrative conven-

    ience, linear functio nal forms are assume d.

    OB

    and

    AA represent costs positively and negatively re-

    lated to disclosure quality. OA measured on the

    horizontal axis reflects net costs if no information

    is disclosed. This cost falls as disclosure quality

    improves and is minimised at Do. Figure 2 re-

    flects change in net costs for different levels

    of

    disclosure.

    Higher levels of managerial ownership or in-

    creases in the vulnerability of the firm to takeover

    or tighter application

    of

    auditing standards result

    in outward shifts of aggregate costs from A oAo o

    A,A , in Figure 3 and ceteris paribus increase the

    optimal level of disclosure. OB reflects the oppor-

    tunity loss perceived by management and is given

    by (1 - a ) of the value to management from

    withholding information plus a) times the firms

    data collection costs. Incremental data costs and

    benefits from withholding information will fall as

    a result of improved monitoring by audit commit-

    tees and non-executive directors and w ill shift

    OB,

    to OBI. Increases in the proportion of the firm

    owned by management will have the same effect.

    Conversely, the existence of a dominant personal-

    ity increases the cost associated with disclosure

    from

    OB,

    to

    OB,

    and,

    ceteris paribus,

    lowers

    disclosure quality.

    Hypotheses

    From the model, the following six relationships

    based on the determinants of the cost functions

    facing management are hypothesised. The higher

    are the costs of collecting information, the lower is

    the quality of information disclosed. These costs

    are likely to be determined by the number of

    schemes operated, the num ber of participants, the

    number of executive directors and the proportion

    of options held by directors. Firms ar e not required

    to identify either the different types of scheme

    operated o r the numbe r of participants. Analysis of

    disclosure quality in the sample revealed large

    firms to b e m ore likely to disclose data agg regated

    across schemes and this disclosure is of below

    average quality. Firm size may therefore be a

    proxy for d ata collection costs. These costs are also

    inversely related t o the p roportion of options held

    by directors. Firms are required by the Companies

    Act (1985, s. 325) to maintain a record of options

    granted to directors

    so

    the incremental collection

    cost is lowe r for these options. Firm size measu red

    by the value of equity also proxies for the threa t of

    takeover. The adverse impact of poo r d isclosure on

    share prices,

    ceteris paribus,

    increases the threat of

    takeover (Manne, 1965). This effect is proportion-

    ately greater the lower is the market value of the

    equity of the firm so that, for a given level of

    Aggregate data was provided for some

    or

    all option schemes

    by 89

    firms

    of which 63 were in the top 100 sample.

    Downloadedby[UniversityOfSouthAustraliaLibrary]at07:2110October2012

  • 7/23/2019 ABR 1992Corporate Governance and Disclosure Quality V22N86 111-124 SPRING

    7/15

    116

    A C C O U N T I N G A N D B U S IN E S S R E SE A R C H

    Disclosure Qual i ty

    t

    I

    A 0 A 1

    Cos ts of Disclosure

    Figure 3

    Increases

    in

    aggregate costs from

    A,A,

    to

    A , A ,

    (caused for example by increased sensitivity to the threat of

    takeover and increased managerial ownership interest

    in

    the

    firm

    r reduced opportun ity losses shifting

    OB,

    to OB,

    (caused by improved governance monitoring or a smaller interest in op tions) increases, ceteris paribus,

    the optimal level of disclosure from

    Do

    to

    D,.

    The dominant personality effect shifts the opportunity loss

    function from

    OB,

    to

    OB, and, ceteris paribus,

    reduces disclosure quality.

    disclosure, the impac t on the threa t o f takeover will

    be greater the smaller the firm.

    H , Ceteris paribus, the smaller the firm and

    the higher the proportion of options held by

    directors, th e better w ill be disclosure qua lity.

    The

    UK

    Companies Acts require disclosure in

    financial statements of information on share op-

    tions granted by the firm. This imposes an obli-

    gation on auditors to verify compliance with these

    disclosure requirements. Non-compliance warrants

    qualification of audit reports. While departures of

    this nature may be passed over in practice, poor

    disclosure quality relative to statutory require-

    ments is assumed to generate tension between

    auditors and management. This increases the

    probability o f an aud it qualification in the event of

    a substantive disagreement with management over

    accounting policy. As a negative association has

    been identified between audit qualifications and

    share price returns (Firth, 1980), it is assumed that

    due to auditor pressure aggregate disclosure costs

    wiil increase for levels of disclosure below statu tory

    requirements. This pressure is assumed to be posi-

    tively related to the technical competence of audi-

    tors and to exist at

    a

    uniformly high level for the

    homogeneous group of auditors comprising the

    big six.

    H,

    Ceter is paribus, firms audited by the big

    six provide a higher optimal level

    of

    disclos-

    ure compared to others.

    In the positive theory of agency (Jensen and

    Meckling, 1976) an d the mo del presented in this

    paper, the proportion

    a )

    of equity owned by

    management plays a centrol role. From the model

    three distinct effects of

    a)

    on disclosure quality

    can be identified. Two of these are positive while

    the third is negatively related to disclosure quality.

    The higher is a) the greater will be the level

    of

    costs incurred and,

    ceteris paribus,

    the higher is

    disclosure quality. Similarly, the opportunity loss

    given by (1

    )

    is lower and disclosure quality is

    higher. However, the burden to management of

    information collection costs is positively related to

    a )

    and this negatively affects disclosure quality.

    H, Ceteris paribus,

    the proportion of equity

    owned by management bears an indetermi-

    nate relation to disclosure quality.

    The recommendations of the Treadway Com-

    mission and the Institutional Shareholders Com-

    Downloadedby[UniversityOfSouthAustra

    liaLibrary]at07:2110October2

    012

  • 7/23/2019 ABR 1992Corporate Governance and Disclosure Quality V22N86 111-124 SPRING

    8/15

    S P R I N G 1 9 9 2 117

    mittee are based on the view that features of

    corporate governance have the potential to en-

    hance monitoring a nd internal accounting control.

    Any improvement in mon itoring share option ben-

    efits associated with audit committees and non-

    executive directors reduces the scope management

    perceive for acting opportunistically and improves

    disclosure quality . Th is effect is reinforced because

    monitoring in order to be effective requires infor-

    mation. Incremental information collection costs

    of disclosure should be lower if internal control is

    improved and so disclosure quality will be im-

    proved.

    Agency theory predicts the setting up of audit

    committees and appointment of non-executive di-

    rectors as a means of attenuating agency costs.

    Disclosure in financial statements is the obvious

    means of communicating the existence of these

    devices to the market but, paradoxically, not all

    firms having audit committees

    or

    non-executive

    directors disclose them.8 It is possible th at disclos-

    ure in financial statements enhances monitoring

    and for this reason the audit committee and non-

    executive variables, based as they are in this p aper

    on disclosure rather than existence, may increase

    the likelihood of identifying a positive associa tion.

    H, Ceteris paribus, the disclosure in financial

    statements

    of

    audit committees and non-ex-

    ecutive directo rs is positively associated with

    disclosure quality.

    There is widespread acknowledgement, typically

    based on anecdote, that a dominant personality

    commanding a firm may be detrimental to the

    interest of shareholders. These fears have been

    fuelled in the UK because of difficulties

    experienced by prominent firms where the role of

    chairman and chief executive were combined. Ball

    and F oster (1982, fn. 19) cite do mi nan t personality

    as a possible research issue. Fama and Jensen

    (1983, p. 319) take a relaxed view of this phenom-

    enon. In their opinion any adverse consequences

    were eliminated by market discipline; those who

    sThis phenom enon is not restricted to the

    UK.

    N o firms listed

    in New Zealand in 1981 with an audit com mittee disclosed the

    fact in their financial statements (Bradbury, 1990). Comparing

    the data for this study with the findings of a survey

    of

    the 1985

    Times I000

    firms (Marrian, 1988) reveals that

    10

    firms in the

    Top

    100 firm

    sample had a udit committees but did not report

    this in their financial statements for 1987/88. It appears,

    therefore, that

    41

    firms in the sample may have had audit

    committees althoug h only 31 disclosed this in the acc ounts.

    I

    am

    grateful to Ian Ma rrian a nd Aileen Beatt ie

    of

    the Institute

    of

    Chartered Accountants of Scotland for granting access to their

    data on au dit committees to establish this point. Of the ten firms

    not disclosing an au dit committee, seven had d om ina nt person-

    alities and only three were good disclosers. Reliance on

    disclosure in financial statements to determine the proportion

    of non-executive directors is subject to a similar limitation of

    incomplete disclosure across firms. This is particularly

    so

    for

    small

    firms

    (Bank of England, 1988).

    survive do

    so

    because on balance their special skills

    outweigh any costs. The model presented in this

    paper assumes that dominant personalities impute

    higher op portun ity losses to the disclosure of infor-

    mation on sh are option benefits. T o the extent that

    governance devices like audit committees and

    non-executive directors create pressure for better

    disclosure which is resisted by dominant personal-

    ities, then it is to be expected that they will be less

    inclined to establish audit committees and to ap-

    point non-executive directors. Dominance is prox-

    ied in this study by the disclosure in financial

    statements that the roles of chairman and chief

    executive are combined.

    H,

    Ceteris paribus, the existence of dom inant

    personalities is negatively associated with dis-

    closure quality, and with the existence of

    audit committees and non-executive direc-

    tors.

    Incentives to reduce disclosure quality depend

    on perceived benefits. The greater the use of share

    options as a method of remuneration by the firm

    the higher is likely to be the p otential benefit. In the

    model, the o pportu nity loss will be greater for any

    level of disclosure and, ceteris paribus, the optimal

    level of disclosure lower. The prop ortion of share

    option s outstan ding relative to issued share capital

    and the value of options held by directors serve as

    proxies for the benefit to all employees and to

    directors respectively.

    H, Ceteris paribus, the higher is the pro-

    portion of option s to issued share capital and

    the greater is the value of options held by

    directors the lower will be the quality of

    disclosure.

    Data collection

    Annual financial statements were examined for

    accounting periods ending between October 1987

    and September 1988 for the largest 100 and

    smallest 100 UK quo ted co mpan ies in the 1988-89

    Times

    1000.

    Three firms

    in

    the top 100 and fifteen

    firms in the botto m 100 did not have share option

    schemes, reducing the samp le available for analysis

    to 182 firms. Data on sample firms was also

    obtained from Datastream and the London

    Business School Risk Assessment Service.

    The dependent variable

    The quality of share option disclosure in financial

    statements was classified by the fineness of the

    detail provided. Six discrete mutually exclusive

    disclosure classes

    A

    to F were identified, ranked

    from the finest to the coarsest disclosure. Firms

    providing full details on the number of options

    outstanding, exercise periods and exercise prices

    were allocated t o class A. This is the same level of

    Downloadedby[UniversityOfSouthAustraliaLibrary]at07:2110October2012

  • 7/23/2019 ABR 1992Corporate Governance and Disclosure Quality V22N86 111-124 SPRING

    9/15

    T

    e

    T

    r

    a

    o

    b

    w

    n

    c

    n

    e

    a

    o

    v

    a

    e

    a

    u

    d

    s

    o

    u

    o

    n

    m

    o

    o

    o

    e

    s

    p

    c

    a

    e

    s

    d

    e

    H

    h

    s

    V

    a

    e

    1

    1

    2

    S

    z

    M

    e

    M

    e

    a

    S

    D

    M

    e

    a

    S

    D

    L

    Z

    M

    e

    O

    a

    p

    v

    u

    e

    2

    1

    >

    2

    P

    D

    M

    e

    M

    e

    a

    S

    D

    O

    a

    p

    v

    u

    e

    4

    1

    >

    2

    D

    I

    N

    T

    M

    e

    M

    e

    a

    S

    D

    M

    e

    a

    S

    D

    L

    D

    I

    N

    T

    M

    e

    O

    a

    p

    v

    u

    e

    F

    m

    =

    F

    D

    s

    o

    u

    e

    Y

    e

    =

    b

    L

    3

    S

    1

    1

    2

    5

    4

    4

    7

    1

    8

    0

    3

    0

    2

    1

    0

    2

    0

    1

    0

    0

    0

    1

    3

    0

    2

    7

    2

    2

    2

    1

    2

    7

    1

    7

    0

    0

    9

    0

    1

    0

    1

    0

    1

    0

    0

    0

    0

    0

    0

    3

    3

    4

    2

    2

    7

    6 5 4 3

    8

    3

    9

    0

    7

    0

    4

    1

    0

    3

    0

    2

    0

    1

    0

    0

    0

    2

    1

    2

    7

    2

    4

    1

    7

    F

    m

    9

    1

    5

    2

    5

    9

    6

    3

    1

    7

    0

    0

    0

    1

    0

    1

    0

    1

    0

    0

    0

    0

    0

    0

    0

    1

    2

    9

    2

    8

    2

    3

    0

    3

    F

    D

    s

    o

    u

    e

    N

    o

    L

    5

    2

    1

    2

    7

    2

    7

    0

    0

    8

    0

    3

    0

    1

    0

    1

    0

    1

    0

    2

    0

    0

    1

    0

    0

    0

    0

    3

    0

    3

    4

    1

    2

    7

    0

    2

    S

    4

    9 6

    1

    4

    1

    4

    1

    0

    7

    0

    0

    0

    2

    0

    2

    0

    1

    0

    0

    0

    1

    0

    1

    0

    1

    2

    7

    2

    0

    1

    6

    0

    4

    Downloadedby[UniversityOfSouthAustraliaLibrary]at07:2110October2012

  • 7/23/2019 ABR 1992Corporate Governance and Disclosure Quality V22N86 111-124 SPRING

    10/15

    h

    T

    e

    1

    c

    n

    5

    1

    >

    2

    P

    N

    E

    M

    e

    0

    3

    0

    3

    0

    2

    0

    3

    0

    3

    0

    2

    M

    e

    a

    0

    3

    0

    3

    0

    2

    0

    3

    0

    3

    0

    2

    S

    D

    0

    1

    0

    1

    0

    1

    0

    1

    0

    1

    0

    1

    O

    a

    e

    p

    v

    u

    e

    6

    2

    O

    P

    P

    I

    E

    M

    e

    0

    0

    M

    e

    a

    0

    0

    S

    D

    0

    0

    O

    a

    e

    p

    v

    u

    e

    6

    1