1-s2.0-S0022435914000700-main.pdf

15
Journal of Retailing 91 (1, 2015) 19–33 An Analysis of Assortment Choice in Grocery Retailing Kyuseop Kwak a,, Sri Devi Duvvuri b,, Gary J. Russell c a School of Marketing, Faculty of Business, University of Technology, Sydney, Australia b School of Business, University of Washington, Bothell, United States c Tippie College of Business, University of Iowa, United States Abstract Consumers in grocery retailing commonly buy bundles of products to accommodate current and future consumption. When all products in a particular bundle share common attributes (and are selected from the same product category), the consumer is said to assemble an assortment. This research examines the impact of assortment variety on the assortment choice process. In particular, we test the prediction that consumers demand less variety for higher quality items. To investigate this relationship, we employ a flexible choice model, suitable for the analysis of assortment choice. The model, based upon the assumption that the utility of purchase of one item in an assortment depends upon the set of items already selected, allows for a general utility structure across the assortment items. We apply the model to household assortment choice histories from the yogurt product category. Substantively, we show that yogurt choice is affected by brand quality perceptions (quality-tier competition). Moreover, we show that reaction to reductions in variety (number of yogurt flavors) is mediated by brand quality perceptions. Taken together, these empirical facts paint a picture of a consumer who is willing to trade-off variety against product quality in assortment choice. © 2014 New York University. Published by Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved. Keywords: Assortment choice; Variety; Quality perceptions; Bundle models; Multivariate logistic model Introduction For frequently purchased products such as grocery items, consumers can more easily anticipate short-run preferences than long-run preferences (Kahneman and Snell 1990; Luce 1992). In order to balance the trade-off between short-term and long-term preferences, consumers assemble bundles of products during each shopping trip. Of particular interest is the product assort- ment, a bundle consisting of items selected from a single product category (such as breakfast cereals or yogurt). From a choice behavior perspective, assortments allow consumers to buy goods that will be consumed over time. This provides the consumer flexibility in planning for future consumption events and in accommodating the preferences of multiple users in the house- hold (Chernev 2011). From a retail management perspective, understanding the consumer decision process behind assort- ments provides guidelines for the number and variety of items Corresponding author. E-mail addresses: [email protected] (K. Kwak), [email protected] (S.D. Duvvuri), [email protected] (G.J. Russell). that should be stocked in a given product category (Corstjens and Corstjens 2002). Variety of an Assortment An assortment can be viewed as a choice strategy that allows consumers to pursue multiple decision objectives. Due to the transaction costs of grocery shopping, it is more efficient for the consumer to buy an assortment of products that will be con- sumed in the future. Assortments permit consumers to minimize decision conflict on a given trip (Simonson 1990), account for uncertainty in future preference (Kahn and Lehmann 1991; Shin and Ariely 2004; Walsh 1995), and address attribute satiation in consumption (Kim, Allenby, and Rossi 2002). All these studies emphasize that assortments are constructed to maximize variety with respect to item attributes. Research in the store choice and consumer behavior litera- ture argues that assortment variety is a psychological perception that plays a key role in the purchase decision (e.g., Broniarczyk 2008; Hoch, Bradlow, and Wansink 1999). Variety perception has been found to depend upon the size of the assortment (e.g., Broniarczyk, Hoyer, and McAlister 1998; Kahn 1995), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jretai.2014.10.004 0022-4359/© 2014 New York University. Published by Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.

Transcript of 1-s2.0-S0022435914000700-main.pdf

  • Journal of Retailing 91 (1, 2015) 1933

    An Analysis of Assortment Choice iKyuseop Kwak a,, Sri Devi Duvvuri b,

    of Tecn, Bot

    Iowa

    Abstract

    Consume odateparticular bu categresearch exa ss. Inless variety flexchoice. The itemselected, all ly theyogurt produ brandwe show tha d byfacts paint a ct qu 2014 New

    Keywords: Assortment choice; Variety; Quality perceptions; Bundle models; Multivariate logistic model

    Introduction

    For freqconsumers

    long-run prorder to balpreferenceseach shoppment, a buncategory (sbehavior pethat will beflexibility accommodhold (Cherunderstandments prov

    CorresponE-mail ad

    SDDuvvuri@(G.J. Russell)

    that should be stocked in a given product category (Corstjens

    http://dx.doi.o0022-4359/uently purchased products such as grocery items, can more easily anticipate short-run preferences thaneferences (Kahneman and Snell 1990; Luce 1992). Inance the trade-off between short-term and long-term, consumers assemble bundles of products duringing trip. Of particular interest is the product assort-dle consisting of items selected from a single productuch as breakfast cereals or yogurt). From a choicerspective, assortments allow consumers to buy goods

    consumed over time. This provides the consumerin planning for future consumption events and inating the preferences of multiple users in the house-nev 2011). From a retail management perspective,ing the consumer decision process behind assort-ides guidelines for the number and variety of items

    ding author.dresses: [email protected] (K. Kwak),uwb.edu (S.D. Duvvuri), [email protected].

    and Corstjens 2002).

    Variety of an Assortment

    An assortment can be viewed as a choice strategy that allowsconsumers to pursue multiple decision objectives. Due to thetransaction costs of grocery shopping, it is more efficient forthe consumer to buy an assortment of products that will be con-sumed in the future. Assortments permit consumers to minimizedecision conflict on a given trip (Simonson 1990), account foruncertainty in future preference (Kahn and Lehmann 1991; Shinand Ariely 2004; Walsh 1995), and address attribute satiation inconsumption (Kim, Allenby, and Rossi 2002). All these studiesemphasize that assortments are constructed to maximize varietywith respect to item attributes.

    Research in the store choice and consumer behavior litera-ture argues that assortment variety is a psychological perceptionthat plays a key role in the purchase decision (e.g., Broniarczyk2008; Hoch, Bradlow, and Wansink 1999). Variety perceptionhas been found to depend upon the size of the assortment(e.g., Broniarczyk, Hoyer, and McAlister 1998; Kahn 1995),

    rg/10.1016/j.jretai.2014.10.004 2014 New York University. Published by Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.a School of Marketing, Faculty of Business, Universityb School of Business, University of Washingto

    c Tippie College of Business, University of

    rs in grocery retailing commonly buy bundles of products to accommndle share common attributes (and are selected from the same product mines the impact of assortment variety on the assortment choice procefor higher quality items. To investigate this relationship, we employ a

    model, based upon the assumption that the utility of purchase of oneows for a general utility structure across the assortment items. We appct category. Substantively, we show that yogurt choice is affected by

    t reaction to reductions in variety (number of yogurt flavors) is mediate picture of a consumer who is willing to trade-off variety against produ

    York University. Published by Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.n Grocery Retailing, Gary J. Russell chnology, Sydney, Australiahell, United States, United States

    current and future consumption. When all products in aory), the consumer is said to assemble an assortment. This

    particular, we test the prediction that consumers demandible choice model, suitable for the analysis of assortment

    in an assortment depends upon the set of items already model to household assortment choice histories from the

    quality perceptions (quality-tier competition). Moreover, brand quality perceptions. Taken together, these empiricalality in assortment choice.

  • 20 K. Kwak et al. / Journal of Retailing 91 (1, 2015) 1933

    the distinctiveness of alternatives (Gourville and Soman 2005;Markman and Gentner 1993; Van Herpen and Pieters 2007),and the pBradlow, aically belieof alternati(Broniarczand Villas-effort tradechases (Hoitems are pprobabilityorganized)(Chernev 2(Kahn, Moand overallitem/brandceptions in

    Variety and

    Recent theory of chproduct quthe cogniti1980) and tthis theory.of items inquality of tto be a coneach new iThe consuincreasing variety.

    Supposehigh qualitHamilton (marginal bis smaller tity assortma high quamarginal retion is quitassortmentresearch is variety and

    Modeling ATo test

    eral modelproduct bunstructed. Mthe researcthe bundleone anotheFor exampity model

    code each attribute in terms of more is better (maximize thebundle mean) or heterogeneity is better (maximize the bun-

    iancnce

    temsbal tiall

    osingd. By sca

    promodureshougt sunmelly ht is ultaning cdel ac (Mtersing old

    demtly, kage

    iew o

    rem

    e a b, expl mostrury thtern

    assu

    oicedyin. Sub

    yogerg ver,

    yoguerallmiltrese

    ulti

    his sery

    t upoent

    chosroximity and display of alternatives (e.g., Hoch,nd Wansink 1999). While larger assortments are typ-ved to offer greater variety, decreasing the numberves may actually increase the purchase likelihoodyk, Hoyer, and McAlister 1998; Kahn 1995; KuksovBoas 2010). This may be attributed to the time and-off consumers resort to while making grocery pur-yer 1984). Assortments with greater similarity amongerceived to have lower variety, thus lowering the

    of purchase. However, items that are displayed (or together are often perceived to offer greater variety011). Factors such as the marginal utility of itemsore, and Glazer 1987; Kahneman and Snell 1992)

    assortment attractiveness (e.g., inclusion of favorite) (Botti and McGill 2006) supplement variety per-

    motivating assortment preference and purchase.

    Product Quality

    work by Chernev and Hamilton (2009) proposes aoice behavior that links assortment size to perceived

    ality. This theory is based upon the trade-off betweenve effort in evaluating choice alternatives (Shuganhe desire for more variety. Two assumptions underlie

    First, cognitive effort is proportional to the number the assortment, but has no relationship to perceivedhe items. Second, utility for item variety is assumedcave function. Due to decreasing marginal returns,tem in the assortment adds less incremental utility.mer will add new items to the assortment until themental costs overwhelm the added utility of more

    that the consumer constructs assortments from eithery items or low quality items (not both). Chernev and2009) propose that for assortments of equal size, theenefit of adding an item to a high quality assortmenthan marginal benefit of adding an item to a low qual-ent. The argument, in essence, is that each item of

    lity assortment is sufficiently valued that decreasingturns become binding more quickly. Thus, the predic-e simple: consumers will prefer a small high-quality

    over a large low-quality assortment. The goal of ourto evaluate the evidence for this relationship between

    product quality.

    ssortment Choicethis prediction, it is necessary to construct a gen-

    of assortment choice. The academic literature ondles provides insights on how a model might be con-ulti-attribute models of bundle choice assume that

    her has a list of product attributes for each item in and understands how these attributes interact withr in determining consumer preferences (Rao 2004).le, Farquhar and Rao (1976) develop a bundle util-based upon the assumption that the researcher can

    dle varprefereof all ithis glosequenof choselectegrocererence

    utility proced

    Altare no

    envirotypicaover, ito simincludwe mo

    logistiand Peof buyhousehfor thesequenthe lin

    Overv

    Theprovidmodelgenerawe con

    categothe patwhichany chfor stuchoiceamong(BlattbMoreober of The ovand Hafuture

    M

    In tfor a vis buildependin the e). Preference for the bundle, then, reflects consumerfor global features that are derived from the attributes

    in the bundle. Harlam and Lodish (1995) draw uponfeature logic, but assume that the bundle is assembledy (across grocery shopping trips), with the probability

    the next product contingent on the products alreadyecause order of purchase is generally not reported innner datasets, the authors assume that higher pref-

    ducts are purchased earlier. More generally, bundleels can be constructed using conjoint measurement

    (Green, Jain, and Wind 1972).h these models have many attractive features, theyitable for empirical studies in a grocery shoppingnt. The key reason is that the researcher does notave an exhaustive list of product features. More-clear that the modeling framework must be ableeously accommodate various demand relationships,omplementarity and substitution. For these reasons,ssortment choice using a version of the multivariateVL) category incidence model developed by Russellen (2000). The model implies that the probabilityan assortment on a shopping trip depends upon thes valuation of each item in the assortment, adjustedand relationships among the items. As we show sub-the model provides a strong foundation for studying

    between product quality and assortment variety.

    f Research

    ainder of this paper is organized as follows. We firstrief review of the multivariate logistic (MVL) choicelaining how the model can be extended to build adel of assortment choice. Drawing upon this theory,ct an assortment choice model for the yogurt productat links product characteristics (brand and flavor) toof household purchase decisions. This choice model,mes perfect substitution across brand names and pick-

    among flavors within a brand, provides a structureg the role of brand quality perceptions in assortmentstantively, we show that the pattern of competitionurt items is affected by brand quality perceptionsand Wisniewski 1989; Sivakumar and Raj 1997).we show that reaction to reductions in variety (num-rt flavors) is mediated by brand quality perceptions.

    pattern of our findings is consistent with the Chernevon (2009) theory. We conclude with suggestions forarch.

    variate Logistic Model of Assortment Choice

    ection, we describe an assortment model that allowsflexible pattern of product competition. The modeln the conditional utility of choice of a single item,

    on its own marketing mix and the other item choicesen assortment. The development here, which builds

  • K. Kwak et al. / Journal of Retailing 91 (1, 2015) 1933 21

    upon the discussion in Russell and Petersen (2000), yields achoice model specification that is a special case of the multi-variate logithe model The modeleconomicsaccommod

    Model Des

    We begithat an assmembers oh selects amultiple itters. We usattribute inthe laundryignations (la collection

    Denote 1, 2, . . ., CDefine an acating the p

    zbht =[z1h1t

    where zchjtt, and equachoice, the(including out further probability

    We nowgiven choictional utiliton item chitems in thetional on thconsiderati

    U(jc|all els

    where chjth, at time tbaseline utmarketing utility for t

    These interm on thdenoted byFor purposfor [c, j] = later in thience of itehas positiv

    c,chjk < 0 if item k negatively influences item js utility (sub-

    stitution effect), and c,chjk = 0 if there is no influence between(independence). For reasons that will become clear sub-tly, we require that the c,chjk parameters be symmetric inc, j] and [c*, k].implify the presentation of the model, it is useful to definemetric matrix, h, containing all the elements of c,chjk ,

    [1h

    h

    Ch

    chj c of

    can

    ll els

    umiditio

    own bina

    t|all

    as n

    hethe (5) i

    reg Fro

    be variaes o

    asso

    cond of t

    f theal prockins prog in

    ew otherehen stic distribution proposed by Cox (1972). However,is considerably richer than the derivation implies.

    is consistent with theoretical frameworks in both and psychology, and has sufficient flexibility toate complex demand patterns among items.

    cription

    n with a discussion of bundle choice, keeping in mindortment is a bundle of products, all of which aref the same product category. Suppose that householdn assortment b at time t. An assortment b containsems (zero, one or more items) from multiple clus-e the word cluster to mean a set of items with some

    common. For example, in a study of assortments in detergent category, clusters might be submarket des-iquid detergents), family brand names (e.g., Tide), or

    of product features (scented liquid detergents).jc as an item j (= 1, 2, . . ., Jc) in cluster c (=

    ). The total number of alternatives is M = Cc=1Jc.ssortment as a M 1 vector of binary variables indi-resence of the item in an assortment

    , z1h2t , . . ., z1hJ1t , z

    2h1t , z

    2h2t , . . ., z

    2hJ2t , . . ., z

    ChJCt

    ](1)

    = 1 if household h selects item j in cluster c at timels zero otherwise. Under the assumption of pick-anyre are 2M possible assortments that could be selectedthe null assortment containing no purchases). With-restriction, the model subsequently assigns a choice

    to each of these 2M assortments. define the conditional choice probability for an item,es of all other items in the assortment. The condi-

    y consists of two parts: (a) a baseline utility dependentaracteristics and (b) demand interactions with other

    assortment. The utility of item j in cluster c, condi-e observed purchase outcomes of other items underon, is assumed to have the form

    e) = chjt +c

    k

    c,chjk z

    chkt + hjt (2)

    is a baseline utility for item j in cluster c of household and hjt is a Gumbel distributed random error. Theility depends both upon household preferences andmix elements, and can be regarded as the inherenthe item, net of demand interactions with other items.teractions are represented by the double summatione right hand side of Eq. (2). Individual items are

    the notation [c, j] for item j nested within cluster c.es of model identification, we assume that c,chjk = 0,[c*, k] (We discuss the necessity of this restrictions section). The parameter c,chjk captures the influ-m [c*, k] on [c, j]. Accordingly, c,chjk > 0 if item ke impact (complementarity effect) on item js utility,

    items sequenitems [

    To sthe symas

    h =

    =

    where cluster(1), we

    U(jc|a

    Assthe conthe knof the

    Pr(zchj

    where,ting w

    Eq.ogistic1993).seen tochase outcomin the a full and allcess o

    a globinterlo

    Thiworkinovervinotes, only w1, 1h2, . . .,

    1hJ1 ,

    2h1, . . .,

    ChJC

    ]NJ1

    0 1,1h12 1,Ch1JC1,1

    21 0 1,Ch2JC.

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    .

    ,1JC1

    C,1hJC2 0

    NJNJ

    (3)

    is the column vector for the corresponding item j in the matrix h. Using matrix (3) and choice vector

    now rewrite Eq. (2) as

    e) = chjt + chjzbht + hjt (4)

    ng that the error in (4) follows a Gumbel distribution,nal probability of purchasing item j in cluster c, givenpurchase outcomes for all other items, has the formry logit model

    other zs) = {exp(chjt + chjzbht)}

    zchjt

    1 + exp(chjt + chjzbht)(5)

    oted earlier, zchjt {0, 1} is an indicator variable repor-r or not item j is chosen.

    s known in the spatial statistics literature as an autol-ression model (Anselin 2002; Besag 1974; Cressiem the standpoint of statistical theory, Eq. (5) can bethe full conditional distribution of one binary pur-ble (corresponding to item [c, j]), given the knownf the binary purchase variables for all other items

    rtment. Note that each of the M possible items hasitional distribution in the general form of Eq. (5),hese M models collectively describe the choice pro-

    household. The technical problem is to write downbability model that is consistent with this system of

    g equations.blem has been analyzed and solved by researchers

    spatial statistics (Besag 1974). We provide anf the key results in Appendix A. As Besag (1974)

    exists a global probability model consistent with (5)the cross-effect matrix is symmetric (c,chjk = c,chkj ).

  • 22 K. Kwak et al. / Journal of Retailing 91 (1, 2015) 1933

    With this symmetry assumption, the global choice model takesthe form

    Pr(zht = zbht) =exp(Vhbt)b exp(Vhbt)

    exp( zb + 1 {zb zb })

    where hM 1 colditional bahtz

    bht is a

    chosen asssystem of emodel givevalidity of consequencdistributionthe joint (mindicator vthe multivaas the mult

    As discconstraintsond, the mensure thatEq. (6), it iseffect matrmain effecthe cross-eequations iway, if croconsistent

    From a is a signedin the assorof an autolof the relatwith closer(Anselin 20the items inwhich closconsumers

    and PeterseHowever, ubution (Coxoutcomes athe cross-efsary becausof the glob

    1 Marketingand HildebranSeetharaman

    The symmetry of the cross-effect matrix also has anotherinteresting interpretation. As explained in Appendix A, the MVLmodel deriassortmentment notwere actua

    asso

    etric ive ice is

    Inte

    MVctivempls in ution

    Thi beha(6). Tcify ckinm thchoirst inse deAnse, calns a. Inual

    en thwillrket

    theoion

    sec

    mo

    ture guntow

    ey afor + (1ete e (ine actally cont

    L citivertm

    asso

    Thiser b

    leme= ht ht 2 hth ht

    b exp(htz

    bht + 12

    {zb

    ht hzb

    ht

    }) (6)

    t =[1h1t ,

    1h2t , . . .,

    1hJ1t

    , 2h1t , . . ., ChJCt

    ]is a

    umn vector containing the individual (full) con-seline utilities for items in consideration. Here

    summation of baseline utilities for items in theortment b. It is important to understand that thequations given by (5) implies the assortment choicen by (6). That is, once the researcher assumes thethe M equations in (5), Eq. (6) follows as a logicale. Conversely, (6) implies the set of full conditionals in (5). Using statistical terminology, Eq. (6) isultivariate) distribution of the M binary purchase

    ariables zht. Because (6) is known to statisticians asriate logistic distribution (Cox 1972), we refer to (6)ivariate logistic (MVL) choice model.1ussed earlier, the cross-effect matrix h obeys two. First, the diagonal of the matrix is set to zero. Sec-atrix is symmetric. Both are technical restrictions to

    the model is properly specified. Given the form of easily shown that zeros on the diagonal of the cross-

    ix are necessary to allow the parameters in the htzbht

    t terms to be identified. The symmetry restriction onffect matrix is necessary to conclude that the set ofn (5) implies the global model in (6). Put anotherss-effects were asymmetric, then no global model

    with Eq. (5) exists (Besag 1974).more intuitive point of view, the cross effect matrix

    (plus or minus) measure of similarity across itemstment. In the spatial statistics literature, the elementsogistic cross-effect matrix are modeled as functionsive geographic distance between response locations,

    locations having a larger (positive) cross-effect term02; Cressie 1993). Conceptually, it is useful to regard

    the assortment as being located on a mental map iner items have stronger interactions with respect to the

    buying behavior (Moon and Russell 2008; Russelln 2000). The elements of h are not correlations.sing the properties of the multivariate logistic distri-

    1972), it can be shown that the correlations in choicemong the items in the assortment are determined byfect matrix. Thus, symmetry in cross-effects is neces-e of the link between h and the correlation structureal choice model.

    science applications related to the MVL model include Boztugdt (2008), Moon and Russell (2008), Niraj, Padmanabhan, and

    (2008), and Yang et al. (2010).

    ues an

    symmattractsequen

    Model

    Theperspean exa

    procesdistrib1993).choicein Eq. to speinterlo

    FroMVL The fipurchaitems. eraturefunctiolibriumindivid(5), thment) the manomica decis

    Thechoicethe naChintaGentzktwo kutility htz

    bht

    a discrthe truthat thidenticin the the MV

    Intuan asso

    in the items. consum

    If all evation assumes that the consumers valuation of an depends only on the final composition of the assort-

    upon the order in which the items in the assortmentlly selected. Put another way, a consumer who val-rtment solely on the basis of its contents must have ah matrix. This order independence property is quiten grocery retailing applications in which purchase

    not observed.

    rpretation

    L choice model can be viewed from a variety ofs. In the spatial statistics literature, the model is

    e of a conditional autoregressive (CAR) stochasticwhich the researcher uses a set of full conditionals to derive the form of a joint distribution (Cressies interpretation emphasizes the fact that the localvior in Eq. (5) determines the global choice behaviorhe CAR approach provides a way for the researcher

    a complex system by breaking the system into Mg parts, each of which can be developed separately.e standpoint of the marketing science literature, thece model can be given two different interpretations.terpretation treats Eq. (5) as a linkage between thecision for one item and the actual choices of all otherlin (2002), in a review of the spatial econometrics lit-

    ls the system of equations represented by (5) reactionnd the implied global model in (6) the system equi-

    other words, if the consumer simultaneously makesitem choices using a random utility process given bye observed global choice behavior (for the assort-

    be observed to follow (6). In fact, recent work ining science literature by Yang et al. (2010) uses eco-ry to argue that MVL choice model in (6) representsprocess equilibrium.ond marketing science interpretation specifies thedel in (6) directly by making assumptions aboutof the utility function of an assortment. Song anda (2006), using a utility theory argument due to(2007), adopt this approach. These authors makessumptions. First, they assume that the expectedan assortment of goods Vhbt has the general form/2){zbht hzbht}. Here, Vhbt can be considered to be

    variable second-order (quadratic) approximation todirect) utility of assortment b. Second, they assumeual utilities fluctuate around Vhbt due to independent,distributed, extreme value errors. These assumptions,ext of a random utility theory framework, also yieldhoice model in (6).ly, the MVL choice model states that the utility of

    ent depends upon household valuations for each itemrtment, adjusted for interactions among the selected

    theory exhibits clear relationships with work in theehavior literature dealing with product assortments.nts of h are set to zero, then Vhbt is just the sum of

  • K. Kwak et al. / Journal of Retailing 91 (1, 2015) 1933 23

    the utilities of the items in the assortment. This type of modelwas proposed by Janiszewski and Cunha (2004) in a study ofconsumer r

    that the vaeffects andthe marketRao 1976).

    Restricting

    The MVbe exploitetions (suchproduct cativariate lothe probabrandom vavariables (rwill be corof (6) that defined wimodel assudence of irrIt is importto assortmeIn general, (5), the relized by arb

    The IIAform of a write the gin the choicbe observements). Thall remainithis pruninprocess. Foleast one itethat all assowhich no itis

    Pr(zht = z

    = b

    subject to Implicitly, sible assorzero.

    Constraini

    A usefuconstraintswe are pres

    F

    ree its aren uns

    gh t be ry, tholdtrict .g.,

    to dee strmarkccom

    tric (A, matr

    ,1

    ,

    A

    A

    A,A21

    , bos per

    con

    taskrandrix wutionssiblm thtain

    B, oice ator of Eq. (6) becomes exp() = 0). With the struc-

    Eq. (8), there are only 21 (obtained as 3 (23 1))ents for the consumer to consider. In model calibration,

    ameters set to are not actually estimated. Rather, the specification in Eq. (6) is rewritten to exclude assortmentsero purchase probability.eactions to price anchors. More broadly, the notionluation of an assortment depends both upon main

    interactions of item attributes has strong support ining literature (Chung and Rao 2003; Farquhar and

    the Model

    L choice model has an important property that cand to tailor the general model to particular applica-

    as assortment choice with respect to a particulartegory). Given that Eq. (6) has the form of a mul-gistic distribution (Cox 1972), it may be viewed asility distribution of an M-dimensional multivariateriable. This implies, in particular, that these binaryepresenting the choice outcomes of different items)related. Interestingly, it is also clear from the formthe model can be viewed as a simple logit modelth respect to assortments. Accordingly, the MVLmes that choice is characterized by an IIA (indepen-elevant alternatives) property relative to assortments.ant to understand that this IIA property correspondsntsnot to the individual items within an assortment.given the interlocking full conditional expressions inationships between specific items will be character-itrary deviations from IIA.

    assortment property makes it very easy to infer thechoice model subject to various restrictions. First,eneral form of the MVL choice model for all itemse set. Second, discard all assortments that will never

    d (because they are not in the set of possible assort-ird, renormalize the model so that the probabilities ofng assortments sum to unity. Whatever remains afterg process must be the correct model for the choicer example, suppose that the choice task is such that atm must be chosen from a set of M items. This meansrtments are possible, except for the null assortment inems are chosen. Thus, the appropriate choice model

    bht)

    exp(htzbht + (1/2){zbht hzbht}) all nonempty bundles exp(htzb

    ht + (1/2){zb

    ht hzb

    ht })(7)

    the restriction that zbht cannot be the zero vector.the probability of any outcome not in the set of fea-tments in this case, the null assortment is set to

    ng the Matrix

    l way of understanding model restrictions is to place directly on the matrix. Suppose, for example, thatented with assortment choice task with three clusters

    and thclusterhave aAlthouthelesscategoHousebut res(see, enames

    then thof the

    To asymmebrandsthe

    2

    31

    0A

    A

    =

    where 1 and 2impliesumers

    choiceeach b matsubstitare po

    Froing cer{Brandthe chnumer

    ture inassortmthe parmodelwith zig. 1. Pick-any items nested within pick-one clusters.

    ems each within each cluster. Suppose, as well, that considered substitutes, while items within a clusterpecified level of demand dependence on one another.his structure may not appear intuitive, it can never-useful in some settings. For example, in the yogurthere are multiple flavors within each brand name.s typically buy multiple flavors on a shopping trip,their purchases to items having the same brand nameKim, Allenby, and Rossi 2002). If we allow brandfine clusters and the flavors of a brand to define items,ucture shown in Fig. 1 is an appropriate descriptionet structure within the yogurt category.modate this structure, we impose restrictions on the

    matrix in the following manner. Assuming threeB, C) with three flavors within each brand (1, 2, 3),ix takes the form

    ,32

    ,21

    , ,31 32

    ,21

    , ,31 32

    0

    0

    0

    0

    0

    0

    0

    0

    A A

    B B

    B B B B

    C C

    C C C C

    (8)

    denotes the cross-effect parameter between flavorsth from brand A. The symbol (negative infinity)fect substitution. In words, Eq. (8) indicates that con-struct assortments by selecting one brand (pick-one) and then selecting an assortment of flavors within

    (pick-any choice task). Because the parameters of theithin each brand are unrestricted, varying degrees of

    and complementarity among flavors within brandse.e standpoint of the consumer, assortments contain-combinations of items (e.g., {Brand A, flavor 1} andflavor 2}) are excluded from consideration becauseprobability of the assortment equals zero (i.e., the

  • 24 K. Kwak et al. / Journal of Retailing 91 (1, 2015) 1933

    Summary

    At this point, the important properties of the MVL choicemodel should be clear. From the standpoint of assortment choice,the model has two desirable features. First, it implies that themarginal ucharacterisMVL choicoutcome afied simultBecause thtive, variouimposed. Ican be excIn our empstudying th

    As

    We emppurchase hstructure ofEq. (8) aboto explore theory relation, we diswho are prcasts for thnext sectio

    Data Desc

    The datpurchase hhalf year passortmentand collapTaken togeeach brandanalysis areand Othersare able todecisions.

    We splimonths (24specific SKsplit into twtrips over 5over 90 dabrands acrothere is noSKUs havwas no dis

    2 Multiple p

    Table 1Descriptive statistics.

    Calibration data Holdout data

    Number of observations 1443 185Number of households 113 81

    Price 0.5464 (0.074) 0.5278 (0.070)Display 0.0569 (0.216) 0.0226 (0.158)Feature 0.1793 (0.366) 0.2542 (0.403)

    rice ismean

    ses. S Dann

    same

    nding

    s. Ofolds

    holdldoule 2 presents a contingency table showing items that aresed together. Diagonal elements are purchase frequenciesividual SKUs in the calibration data period. The table

    no cross purchases across brands, but many instances ofurchasing of flavors within a brand. We assume the choices for Dannon and Nordica follows the pattern shown in

    pick-one choice across brands, and pick-any choice for within brands. This type of demand pattern correspondsstructure of the matrix discussed earlier in relation to).alibrating the model (discussed below), we also make

    her adjustments. Since the choice histories are restrictedy those instances in which either Dannon or Nordicachased, we never observe a null (empty) assortment.quently, we eliminate the null assortment from the denom-of Eq. (6), thereby fixing the probability of observing thesortment to zero. (As explained earlier, this procedure isd by the IIA property of the choice model with respect tot assortments.) In addition, some items are not available

    eleven of 124 households made purchases across brands on a singleg occasion. This accounts for about 1% of total purchase events. Theselds were excluded from the dataset prior to model calibration. Kim,, and Rossi (2002) also report that almost all yogurt purchase bundlesf items having the same brand name.tility of each item in an assortment depends upon thetics of all other items in the assortment (Eq. (2)). Thee model (Eq. (6)) can be viewed as the equilibrium

    t which all the marginal utility equations are satis-aneously. Second, the model is extremely flexible.e parameters of the matrix can be positive or nega-s patterns of substitution and complementarity can bef necessary, assortments that will never be observedluded, allowing a parsimonious model specification.irical work, we take advantage of this flexibility ine role of product quality in assortment choice.

    sortment Choice in the Yogurt Category

    loy the MVL choice model to analyze householdistories from the yogurt product category using the

    the matrix corresponding to Fig. 1 (as depicted inve). Our main goal is substantive. We use the modelthe predictions of the Chernev and Hamilton (2009)ting demand for variety to product quality. In this sec-cuss technical aspects of model calibration. Readers

    imarily interested in the implications of model fore-e ChernevHamilton theory may wish to skip to then.

    ription

    a are taken from an ERIM scanner panel of yogurtistories from the Sioux Falls area over a two and one-eriod. We focus on the low fat, fruit on the bottom. We select eight common flavors from both brandsse three flavors into one composite flavor (Others).ther, we have total of twelve SKUs (six SKUs for) in the analysis.2 The six common flavors used in the

    Cherry, Mixed Berry, Peach, Raspberry, Strawberry,. By constructing the SKU set in this manner, we

    study the role of brand and flavor in yogurt choice

    t the data into three consecutive periods. The first 80 days) of the data were used to create household-U loyalty variables. The remainder of the data waso sets: a model calibration period (1443 shopping80 days) and a holdout period (185 shopping trips

    ys). Table 1 shows descriptive statistics for the twoss these periods. Due to retailer marketing decisions,

    variation in marketing mix activity across flavoring the same brand name at the same time. Thereplay activity at all for Dannon during the observed

    urchases of a single SKU are considered to be one SKU choice.

    Nordica

    Dannon

    Note: Pare the parenthebecausehave thecorrespo

    periodhousehing thethe ho

    Tabpurchafor indshowsjoint pprocesFig. 2:flavorsto the Eq. (8

    In ctwo otto onlis purConseinator null asjustifieproduc

    3 OnlyshoppinhousehoAllenbyconsist oPrice 0.6456 (0.049) 0.688 (0.008)Display NA NAFeature 0.0699 (0.247) 0.0222 (0.129)

    the mean dollar per eight ounce container. Display and Feature of indicator (01) variables. Standard deviations are shown intatistics for the Dannon Display variable are not available (NA)on does not employ displays in this dataset. Individual flavors

    means and standard deviations on marketing mix elements as the brand name.

    Fig. 2. Assortment choice in the yogurt category.

    the 113 households used for model calibration,3 32 did not make any purchases of these two brands dur-out period. For this reason, only 81 households enter

    t data.

  • K. Kwak et al. / Journal of Retailing 91 (1, 2015) 1933 25

    Table 2Joint purchase table.

    on flavors

    MX BY PCH RBY ST OT Total

    Nordica avoCherry Mixed BerryPeach Raspberry Strawberry Others Dannon avoCherry Mixed Berry Peach Raspberry Strawberry Others

    Total

    Note: For cla odesPCH = peach,

    in the marforth. We asuch occas

    Model Spec

    We first

    phjt = phj

    + where p infor Nordicainfluence oture advertvariable thto buy the LOY

    phj = l

    ber of purcnh shoppinand NJ is name (NJ =are alwaysassume thahousehold.

    Next, wh, followtwo brandsassortmentnever be obbetween an, thus to zero. Ho

    r Dhjutionse refromonderal

    [

    Nh(NorNordica flavors Dann

    CH MX BY PCH RBY ST OT CH

    rs164 44 45 34 54 69 0

    44 165 25 43 49 94 0 45 25 159 37 62 74 0 34 43 37 177 54 81 0 54 49 62 54 233 84 0 69 94 74 81 84 341 0

    rs0 0 0 0 0 0 294 0 0 0 0 0 0 67 0 0 0 0 0 0 33 0 0 0 0 0 0 59 0 0 0 0 0 0 59 0 0 0 0 0 0 123

    410 420 402 426 536 743 635

    rity, row totals, columns totals and diagonal entries are shown in boldface. C RBY = raspberry, ST = strawberry, and OT = other.

    ket at certain time points due to stock-outs, and solso adjusted the model specification to accommodateions.

    ication

    define individual SKUs baseline utility chjt as

    + p1,hPRICEpht + p2,hDISPpht + p3,hFEATphtp4,hjLOY

    phj (9)

    dicates a brand name, here taking on two values, 1 and 2 for Dannon. This specification allows for the

    (Nhjk o

    substitThe

    ments correspthe gen

    h =

    where brand f price (PRICE), in-store display (DISP) and fea-ising (FEAT). The notation LOYphj denotes a loyaltyat adjusts for the households long-run propensityitem (flavor) j within a cluster (brand). We defineog((nphj + 0.5)/(nh. + 0.5NJ )) where nphj is the num-hases of the item j (in brand p) across the householdsg trips in the initial eight months of the dataset,the number of (flavor) SKUs within each brand

    6). Because marketing mix variables (such as price) the same for all flavors of a particular brand, wet marketing mix parameters vary only by brand and

    e specify the structure of the cross-effect matrixing the structural restrictions shown in Fig. 2. The

    are treated as perfect substitutes, implying that any containing both Nordica and Dannon products willserved. That is, we restrict the cross-effects

    (N,Dhjk

    )y two items having different brand names to be

    setting the choice probabilities of these assortmentswever, the cross-effects for flavors within a brand

    must be syWe com

    tions abouheterogeneeffect parahousehold ships

    hN(, hN( , hN( ,

    where hmarketing

    In generfor the pcovariancefor simpliconal. Alth0 0 0 0 0 4100 0 0 0 0 4200 0 0 0 0 4020 0 0 0 0 4260 0 0 0 0 5360 0 0 0 0 743

    67 33 59 59 123 635402 50 93 88 187 887

    50 223 54 48 95 50393 54 521 90 184 100188 48 90 400 180 865

    187 95 184 180 823 1592

    887 503 1001 865 1592 8420

    for flavors are as follows: CH = cherry, MX BY = mixed berry,

    k

    )are unrestricted (allowing for varying degrees of

    , complementarity or independence).strictions reduce the total number of possible assort-

    4095 (=212 1) to 126 (= 2 (26 1)). Theing cross-effect matrix for all brands and flavors has

    form

    Nh

    Dh

    ]1212

    (10)

    and Dh are 6 6 matrices for the flavors within eachdica and Dannon, respectively). These sub-matrices

    mmetric, but need not necessarily be equal.plete the model specification by developing assump-t the pattern of household response parameterity. Define the vector containing all unique cross-meters as h. Using this notation, we assume thatresponse heterogeneity is governed by the relation-

    )))

    (11)

    and h are vectors of item specific intercepts andmix parameters.al, we can estimate any type of covariance structurearameters by properly specifying the variance-

    matrices in (11). In this application, we assume,ity, that all variancecovariance matrices are diag-ough this assumption requires that parameters

  • 26 K. Kwak et al. / Journal of Retailing 91 (1, 2015) 1933

    Table 3Model comparison.

    Model description k LL Cal 2 Cal AI 2

    No Cross-Effects 58 4089.1 0.4109 82Same Cross-Effects 88 4053.1 0.4161 82Differential C 82

    Note: Cal de defi2 = 1 (LL/ d of tto zero. The b

    independenmarketing As we shothe fact thazero.

    Model Cal

    We introthe assortmhousehold standard fo

    L =h

    t

    where, as nHowever, gto constructhe random

    Lh =

    t

    where repgral can behousehold-

    Lh 1R

    r

    which, in tan approximtime points

    Maximito all modlihood (MSfashion arewe implemobtained u2003). Simcorrelated tribution. Bthe MSL p

    tes ore ac

    1,000 randexce

    aramds. Ftion

    Com

    ng t prog the

    com

    t sub, ass

    ting n thiclud

    , call be sed sub-ird bes th, thale 3valut daian In, a

    mo

    l as hDiffeross-Effects 118 4019.1 0.4209 notes calibration data and Hold denotes holdout data. Fit measures are

    LL null) where k is number of parameters, N is sample size, LL is log likelihoooldface entries denote the model with the best performance on each measure.

    tly vary across households, it does not imply thatactions of one item have no impact on other items.w below, such cross-item dependencies exist due tot the cross-effect matrix in Eq. (10) is not equal to

    ibration

    duce the indicator variable Ybht , which equals one ifent b (zbht) is chosen and zero otherwise. Ignoring

    parameter heterogeneity, the likelihood takes on thermb

    {Pr(zht = zbht)}Ybht (12)

    oted earlier, h denotes household and t denotes time.iven our heterogeneity assumptions, it is necessaryt the likelihood of each household by integrating out

    components of the parameters as

    b

    {Pr(zht = zbht|)}Ybht f ()d (13)

    resents all random elements in the model. This inte- approximated using R draws of simulated values ofvarying parameters. In this way, we obtain

    L(r)h =

    1R

    r

    t

    b

    {Pr(zht = zbht|(r))}Ybht (14)

    urn, leads to LL(, , ) h log Lh(h, h, h),ation to the true log likelihood of all households and

    .

    estimabe mousing text ofreport level pmethoestima

    Model

    Usiof ouralterinmodelperfecEffectsrestriczero. Ieters inmodeleters toare baeffect The thassum

    brandsTab

    report holdou(BayescriterioEffectsas welto the zation of the approximate log likelihood with respectel parameters generates Maximum Simulated Like-L) estimates. Parameter estimates obtained in this

    known to be consistent (Lee 1995). In this research,ented the MSL procedure with R = 250 simulates

    sing Randomized Halton Sequence methods (Trainulates drawn from a Halton Sequence are negativelyand evenly cover the support of the parameter dis-oth features substantially improve the accuracy of

    rocedure. Train (2003) reports that MSL parameter

    Parameter

    Table 4for the Difffor price, vor. Moreothe model in its promis, in geneC BIC LL Hold Hold

    94.1 8600.1 670.4 0.243182.2 8746.4 678.3 0.234175.7 8898.9 665.0 0.2493ned as follows: AIC = 2LL + 2k, BIC = 2LL + log(N)k andhe model and LL null is the log likelihood with all parameters set

    btained using 100 draws from a Halton Sequence cancurate than MSL parameter estimates obtained with

    randomly drawn simulates. Moreover, in the con-om coefficient logit models, Huber and Train (2001)llent correspondence between estimates of householdeters obtained using MSL and Hierarchical Bayesor these reasons, MSL was deemed an appropriatemethodology for our model.

    parison

    he MSL methodology, we tested several variationsposed model on the yogurt purchase histories by

    market structure implied by the h matrix. In allparisons, we retained the assumption that brands arestitutes. The first benchmark model, called No Cross-umes independence among flavors within each brand,all elements in the cross-effect matrix (h) to bes instance, we only estimate marketing mix param-ing item specific intercepts. The second benchmarked Same Cross-Effects, allows cross-effects param-estimated, imposing the restriction that cross-effectson flavor (not on brand). This makes the cross-

    matrices identical across brands, that is, Nh = Dh .enchmark model, called Differential Cross-Effects,at cross-effect parameters vary across flavors andt is, Nh /= Dh .

    displays the fit statistics for different models. Wees of the log-likelihood (for both calibration and

    ta), 2, AIC (Akaike Information Criterion) and BICnformation Criterion). With the exception of the BICll fit statistics point toward the Differential Cross-del (shown in the last row of Table 3) in calibrationoldout data. Given these results, we restrict attentionrential Cross-Effects model.Estimates

    presents parameter estimates for baseline utilitieserential Cross-Effects model. Recall that coefficientsfeature and display vary by brand, but not by fla-ver, the display variable for Dannon is omitted frombecause Dannon (in our dataset) never uses displayotions. The parameter values suggest that Dannonral, the preferred brand (larger brand intercepts).

  • K. Kwak et al. / Journal of Retailing 91 (1, 2015) 1933 27Ta

    ble

    4M

    odel

    coef

    ficie

    nts.

    Inte

    rcep

    t

    Loya

    lty

    Pric

    e

    Disp

    lay

    Feat

    ure

    Mea

    n

    SD

    Mea

    n

    SD

    Mea

    n

    SD

    Mea

    n

    SD

    Mea

    n

    SD

    Nord

    ica

    Cher

    ry

    3.21

    4**

    (0.62

    8)

    0.81

    0**

    (0.14

    9)

    2.45

    5**

    (0.30

    6)

    0.28

    9**

    (0.08

    6)

    3.8

    52**

    (0.55

    2)1.

    707*

    *(0.

    144)

    0.22

    3(0.

    137)

    0.18

    0(0.

    134)

    0.73

    7**

    (0.10

    4)0.

    409*

    *(0.

    119)

    Mix

    ed

    Ber

    ry

    2.60

    8**

    (0.53

    9)

    0.08

    9

    (0.15

    7)

    2.09

    9**

    (0.25

    4)

    0.01

    2

    (0.08

    3)Pe

    ach

    2.44

    7**

    (0.58

    6)

    0.63

    0**

    (0.16

    3)

    1.98

    1**

    (0.28

    7)

    0.33

    5**

    (0.07

    4)R

    aspb

    erry

    2.21

    8**

    (0.46

    5)

    0.22

    3

    (0.16

    8)

    1.60

    8**

    (0.24

    9)

    0.16

    1*

    (0.07

    9)St

    raw

    berry

    1.73

    9**

    (0.46

    5)

    0.51

    8**

    (0.15

    1)

    1.18

    4**

    (0.20

    4)

    0.31

    0**

    (0.08

    6)O

    ther

    s

    2.55

    8**

    (0.46

    3)

    0.00

    1

    (0.11

    6)

    1.39

    1**

    (0.21

    3)

    0.11

    4**

    (0.08

    9)Dan

    non

    Cher

    ry

    4.72

    9**

    (0.77

    4)

    0.39

    0

    (0.19

    1)

    1.66

    8**

    (0.19

    0)

    0.36

    1**

    (0.07

    9)

    5.4

    30**

    (1.01

    1)1.

    866*

    *(0.

    147)

    NA

    NA

    1.01

    8**

    (0.19

    5)0.

    678*

    *(0.

    167)

    Mix

    ed

    Ber

    ry5.

    229*

    *

    (0.79

    5)

    0.54

    0**

    (0.11

    5)

    1.99

    3**

    (0.23

    7)

    0.49

    6**

    (0.08

    9)Pe

    ach

    4.62

    6**

    (0.82

    3)

    0.00

    4

    (0.17

    0)

    2.02

    1**

    (0.27

    3)

    0.48

    7**

    (0.09

    9)R

    aspb

    erry

    5.60

    0**

    (0.74

    6)

    0.79

    1**

    (0.18

    3)

    2.16

    8**

    (0.19

    5)

    0.27

    6**

    (0.08

    2)St

    raw

    berry

    4.00

    6**

    (0.77

    0)

    0.18

    5

    (0.16

    5)

    1.31

    2**

    (0.22

    2)

    0.56

    7**

    (0.07

    6)O

    ther

    s

    4.83

    8**

    (0.71

    5)

    1.08

    9**

    (0.13

    7)

    1.65

    8**

    (0.18

    4)

    0.35

    8**

    (0.05

    3)No

    te:

    The

    no

    tatio

    n

    SD

    indi

    cate

    s sta

    ndar

    d

    dev

    iatio

    n

    of t

    he

    hous

    ehol

    d

    hete

    roge

    neity

    distr

    ibu

    tion.

    Sign

    ifica

    nce

    level

    s are

    deno

    ted

    as

    p

    0 for complements,

    for substitutes, and S(j, k) = 0 for independence.pute aggregate elasticities, we first define the over-hares as MSj =

    h

    tPr(j)ht/NT where NT (the

    useholds (N) times average number of shopping tripssehold) is the number of total observations in a par-

    set. Following procedures outlined in Russell and(1994), we differentiate this expression and use thelevel derivatives in (B5) to infer market share elastic-rocess yields the expressions

    MS(jp)RICE

    pj

    =[{

    hphPr(jp)h[1 Pr(jp)h]

    }/N

    MS(jp)

    ]PRICE

    pj

    MS(jp)PRICE

    qk

    = [{

    hqhPr(jp)hPr(kq)h

    }/N

    MS(jp)

    ]PRICE

    pk

    MS(jp)RICE

    pk

    =[{

    hph

    [Pr(jp, kp)h Pr(jp)hPr(kp)h

    ]}MS(jp)

    ]PRIC

    References

    2002), Under the Hood: Issues in Specification and Interpretation Regression Models, Agricultural Economics, 27 (November),

    d James Lattin (1998), Shopping Behavior and Consumer Pref- Store Price Format: Why Large Basket Shoppers Prefer EDLP,

    Science, 17 (1), 6688.oshe and Steven R. Lerman (1985), Discrete Choice Analysis:d Application to Travel Demand, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    (1974), Spatial Interaction and the Statistical Analysis of Lattice Journal of the Royal Statistical Society B, 36, 192236.bert C. and Kenneth J. Wisniewski (1989), Price-Induced Patternstition, Marketing Science, 8 (4), 291309.eter and Joseph C. Nunes (2001), Reducing Assortment: An

    Based Approach, Journal of Marketing, 65 (July), 5063. and Ann L. McGill (2006), When Choosing is Not Deciding: ThePerceived Responsibility on Satisfaction, Journal of Consumer

    33 (September), 2119.

    Boztug,With(Oct

    BrieschDoeRese

    Broniarsum

    The166

    BroniarPsyc

    ChernevInte

    ChernevAttrRese

    Chung, witht brands

    (B5)

    me brand

    (B6)

    for brands p /= q

    j /= k for same brand

    (B7)

    min and Lutz Hildebrandt (2008), Modeling Joint Purchasesultivariate MNL Approach, Schmalenbach Business Review, 60, 40022.ard A., Pradeep K. Chintagunta and Edward J. Fox (2009), Howortment Affect Grocery Store Choice, Journal of Marketing

    66 (April), 17689.Susan M., Wayne D. Hoyer and Leigh McAlister (1998), Con-erceptions of the Assortment Offered in a Grocery Category:

    ct of Item Reduction, Journal of Marketing Research, 35 (May),

    Susan (2008), Product Assortment, in Handbook of Consumery New York, NY: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates.75579.

    xander (2011), Product Assortment and Consumer Choice: Anlinary Review, Foundations and Trends in Marketing, 6 (1), 161.ander and Ryan Hamilton (2009), Assortment Size and Option

    ness in Consumer Choice Among Retailers, Journal of Marketing 44 (June), 41020.

    Vithala R. Rao (2003), A General Choice Model for Bundlesiple-Category Products: Application to Market Segmentation and

  • K. Kwak et al. / Journal of Retailing 91 (1, 2015) 1933 33

    Optimal Pricing for Bundles, Journal of Marketing Research, 40 (May),11530.

    Corstjens, Judith and Marcel Corstjens (2002), Store Wars: The Battle forMindspace and Shelfspace, New York: John Wiley and Sons.

    Cox, David R. (1972), The Analysis of Multivariate Binary Data, AppliedStatistics (Journal of the Royal Statistical Society Series C, 21 (2),11320.

    Cressie, Noel A.C. (1993), Statistics for Spatial Data, New York: John Wileyand Sons.

    Farquhar, Peter H. and Vithala R. Rao (1976), A Balance Model for EvaluatingSubsets of Multiattributed Items, Management Science, 22 (5), 52839.

    Gentzkow, Matthew (2007), Valuing New Goods in a Model With Comple-mentarity71344.

    Gourville, JoType: Wh38295.

    Green, Paul Hof Item Co

    Harlam, BariChoices o40418.

    Hoch, Stephean Assortm

    (2002), RAttribute-

    Hoyer, WayneRepeat-Pu

    Huber, Joel aBayesian 12 (Augus

    Janiszewski, Ccount FramResearch,

    Kahn, Barbarvices, Jo

    Kahn, BarbarAssortme

    Kahn, BarbarStructure Consumer

    Kahn, BarbarConstrain

    Kahneman, DDecision Chicago:

    Kahneman, DDo PeopleMaking, 5

    Kamakura, WModel forketing Res

    Kamakura, Wworking p

    Kamakura, WPreferencAnalytic Rin Market

    Kim, Jaehwan, Greg M. Allenby and Peter E. Rossi (2002), Modeling Con-sumer Demand for Variety, Marketing Science, 21 (Summer), 22950.

    Kuksov, Dmitri and J. Miguel Villas-Boas (2010), When More AlternativesLead to Less Choice, Marketing Science, 29 (MayJune), 50724.

    Lee, Lung-Fei (1995), Asymptotic Bias in Simulated Maximum LikelihoodEstimates of Discrete Choice Models, Econometric Theory, 11, 43783.

    Luce, Mary Frances (1992), Buying More Than We Can Use: Factors Influ-encing Forecasts of Consumption Quantity, In Advances in ConsumerResearch, Vol. 19, Sherry John F. Jr. and Sternthal Brian eds. , 5848.

    Ma, Yu, P.B. (Seethu) Seetharaman and Chakravarthi Narasimhan (2005),Empirical Analysis of Competitive Pricing Strategies with ComplementaryProduct Lines, Working Paper. University of Alberta.

    n, Ary Comangk

    rred Ct Scieakeshgory ketingStephSA, H

    ithalaeptionent: e ed.

    Gary in M

    Garypetitiarch,

    woonvailabMay),

    Steveeptemn, Itaeekinar, Ktegy aar, K

    nge Ing, 61seonge Effober)ennetbridg

    rpen, rovingnal oJohn re Talin anies Ual Sta

    ha, Yisehole), 47: Online Newspapers, The American Economic Review, 97 (3),

    hn T. and Dilip Soman (2005), Overchoice and Assortmenten and Why Variety Backfires, Marketing Science, 24 (Summer),

    ., Wind Yoram and A.K. Jain (1972), Preference Measurementllections, Journal of Marketing Research, 9 (November), 3717.

    A. and Leonard M. Lodish (1995), Modeling Consumersf Multiple Items, Journal of Marketing Research, 32 (November),

    n J., Eric T. Bradlow and Brian Wansink (1999), The Variety ofent, Marketing Science, 18 (4), 52746.

    , andejoinder to The Variety of An Assortment: An Extension to the

    Based Approach, Marketing Science, 21 (Summer), 3426. D. (1984), An Examination of Decision Making for a Commonrchase Product, Journal of Consumer Research, 11, 8229.nd Kenneth Train (2001), On the Similarity of Classical andEstimates of Individual Mean Parthworths, Marketing Letters,t), 25969.hris and Marcus Cunha Jr. (2004), The Influence of Price Dis-ing on the Evaluation of a Product Bundle, Journal of Consumer

    30 (March), 53446.a E. (1995), Consumer Variety-Seeking Among Goods and Ser-urnal of Retailing & Consumer Services, 2 (July), 13948.a E. and Donald R. Lehmann (1991), Modeling Choice Amongnts, Journal of Retailing, 67 (3), 27499.a E. and Brian Wansink (2004), The Influence of Assortmenton Perceived Variety and Consumption Quantities, Journal of

    Research, 30 (March), 51933.a E., William L. Moore and Rashi Glazer (1987), Experiments ined Choice, Journal of Consumer Research, 14 (June), 96113.aniel and Jackie Snell (1990), Predicting Utility, in Insights inMaking: A Tribute to Hillel J. Einhorn, Hogarth Robin M. ed.University of Chicago Press, 295310.aniel and Jackie S. Snell (1992), Predicting a Changing Taste:

    Know What They Will Like?, Journal of Behavioral Decision (3), 187200.agner A. and Gary J. Russell (1989), A Probabilistic Choice

    Market Segmentation and Elasticity Structure, Journal of Mar-earch, 26 (November), 37990.agner A. and Kyuseop Kwak (2012), Menu-Choice Modeling,aper. Rice University.agner A. and Carl Schimmel (2013), Uncovering Audience

    es for Concert Features From Single-Ticket Sales With a Factor-andom-Coefficients Model, International Journal of Research

    ing, 30 (2), 12942.

    Markmalarit

    Moon, SInfemen

    Niraj, RCateMar

    Orgish, the U

    Rao, VPercagemSonk

    Russell,ence

    Russell,ComRese

    Shin, JiUna50 (

    Shugan,7 (S

    Simonsoety S

    SivakumStra

    SivakumChaketin

    Song, InPric(Oct

    Train, KCam

    Van HeImpJour

    Walsh, Futu

    Wu, HuSpeclogic

    Yang, SHou(Junt. B. and D. Gentner (1993), Structural Alignment During Simi-parisons, Cognitive Psychology, 25 (October), 43167.

    il and Gary J. Russell (2008), Predicting Product Purchase Fromustomer Similarity: An Autologistic Model Approach, Manage-nce, 54 (January), 7182., V. Padmanabhan and P.B. Seetharaman (2008), A Cross-Model of Households Incidence and Quantity Decisions,

    Science, 27 (MarchApril), 22535.en (2002), Market Report on the Refrigerated Yogurt Market inouston: Swiss Business Hub, United States of America.

    R. (2004), Bundles of Multi-attributed Items: Modelings, Preferences and Choice, in Cross-Functional Innovation Man-Perspectives From Different Disciplines Working Paper, Albers

    New York: Gabler Publishers, 17690. J. and Ann Petersen (2000), Analysis of Cross Category Depend-arket Basket Selection, Journal of Retailing, 76 (3), 36792.

    J. and Wagner A. Kamakura (1994), Understanding Brand Priceon with Micro and Macro Scanner Data, Journal of Marketing

    31 (May), 289303.g and Dan Ariely (2004), Keeping Doors Open: The Effect ofility on Incentives to Keep Options Viable, Management Science,

    57586.n (1980), The Cost of Thinking, Journal of Consumer Research,ber), 99111.mar (1990), The Effect of Purchase Quantity and Timing on Vari-g Behavior, Journal of Marketing Research, 27 (May), 15062.

    . (2000), Price Tier Competition: An Integrative Review, Pricingnd Practice, 9 (5), 27690.. and S.P. Raj (1997), Quality Tier Competition: How Pricefluences Brand Choice and Category Choice, Journal of Mar-

    (July), 7184. and Pradeep K. Chintagunta (2006), Measuring Cross-Categoryects with Aggregate Store Data, Management Science, 52, 1594609.h (2003), Discrete Choice Models With Simulation, Cambridge:e University Press.Erica and Rik Pieters (2007), Anticipated Identification Costs:

    Assortment Evaluation by Diagnostic Attributes, Internationalf Research in Marketing, 24 (March), 7788.W. (1995), Flexibility in Consumer Purchasing for Uncertainstes, Marketing Science, 14 (2), 14865.d Fred W. Huffer (1997), Modeling the Distribution of Plantsing the Autologistic Regression Model, Environmental and Eco-tistics, 4, 4964.

    Zhao, Tulin Erdem and Ying Zhao (2010), Modeling the Intra-d Behavioral Interaction, Journal of Marketing Research, 47084.

    An Analysis of Assortment Choice in Grocery RetailingIntroductionVariety of an AssortmentVariety and Product QualityModeling Assortment Choice

    Overview of Research

    Multivariate Logistic Model of Assortment ChoiceModel DescriptionModel InterpretationRestricting the ModelConstraining the MatrixSummary

    Assortment Choice in the Yogurt CategoryData DescriptionModel SpecificationModel CalibrationModel ComparisonParameter Estimates

    Variety and Quality in the Yogurt CategoryQuality Tiers in the Yogurt CategoryProduct Quality and Assortment VarietySummary

    ConclusionsSubstantive ContributionsModeling Assortment ChoiceLimitations and Extensions

    Appendix A Derivation of Assortment ModelAppendix B Derivation of Price ElasticitiesReferences