ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICSirelandp.com/econ3379/slides/slides20200428.pdf2020/04/28  ·...

Post on 11-Aug-2020

6 views 0 download

Transcript of ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICSirelandp.com/econ3379/slides/slides20200428.pdf2020/04/28  ·...

ECON 337901

FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

Peter Ireland

Boston College

April 28, 2020

These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike4.0 International (CC BY-NC-SA 4.0) License. http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-sa/4.0/.

7 The Capital Asset Pricing Model

A MPT and the CAPM

B Deriving the CAPM

C Valuing Risky Cash Flows

D Strengths and Shortcomings of the CAPM

Asset Prices and Expected Returns

The Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) is usually describedin terms of its implications for expected returns on individualstocks.

But the CAPM is a Capital Asset Pricing Model.

This is because, given future cash flows, an asset’s price andits expected return are closely (though inversely) related.

Asset Prices and Expected Returns

Consider a stock that sells for price P s0 today (time 0) and

makes a single risky (random) payment C̃1 next year (time 1).

As we’ve discussed before, next year’s cash flow C̃1 can consistof a dividend payment (D̃1), a capital gain (P̃ s

1), or anycombination of the two.

And, as we’ve discussed before, adding more cash flowsC̃2, C̃3, . . . C̃T received in additional future periods isconceptually straightforward.

Asset Prices and Expected Returns

Consider a stock that sells for price P s0 today (time 0) and

makes a single risky (random) payment C̃1 next year (time 1).

The stock’s random return r̃ s is

r̃ s =C̃1 − P s

0

P s0

=C̃1

P s0

− 1

And the stock’s expected return µs is

µs = E (r̃ s) = E

(C̃1

P s0

− 1

)=

E (C̃1)

P s0

− 1

Asset Prices and Expected Returns

Given an estimate E (C̃1) of the future cash flow, knowing theasset price P s

0 lets us compute the expected return

E (r̃ s) =E (C̃1)

P s0

− 1

Or knowing the expected return E (r̃ s) lets us compute theasset price:

1 + E (r̃ s) =E (C̃1)

P s0

P s0 =

E (C̃1)

1 + E (r̃ s)

Asset Prices and Expected Returns

E (r̃ s) =E (C̃1)

P s0

− 1

P s0 =

E (C̃1)

1 + E (r̃ s)

Either way, the asset price and its expected return are inverselyrelated.

Given the expected future cash flow, the only way theexpected return can go up is if the asset price falls.

Of course, obtaining the estimate E (C̃1) will require somework!

MPT and the CAPM

The Capital Asset Pricing Model builds directly on ModernPortfolio Theory.

It was developed in the mid-1960s by William Sharpe (US,b.1934, Nobel Prize 1990), John Lintner (US, 1916-1983), andJan Mossin (Norway, 1936-1987).

MPT and the CAPM

William Sharpe, “Capital Asset Prices: A Theory of MarketEquilibrium Under Conditions of Risk,” Journal of FinanceVol.19 (September 1964): pp.425-442.

John Lintner, “The Valuation of Risk Assets and the Selectionof Risky Investments in Stock Portfolios and Capital Budgets,”Review of Economics and Statistics Vol.47 (February 1965):pp.13-37.

Jan Mossin, “Equilibrium in a Capital Asset Market,”Econometrica Vol.34 (October 1966): pp.768-783.

MPT and the CAPM

But whereas Modern Portfolio Theory is a theory describingthe demand for financial assets, the Capital Asset PricingModel is a theory describing equilibrium in financial markets.

By making an additional assumption – namely, that supplyequals demand in financial markets – the CAPM yieldsadditional implications about the pricing of financial assets andrisky cash flows.

MPT and the CAPM

Like MPT, the CAPM assumes that investors havemean-variance utility and hence that either investors havequadratic Bernoulli utility functions or that the random returnson risky assets are normally distributed.

Thus, some of the same caveats that apply to MPT also applyto the CAPM.

That’s why people say, “you can’t use the CAPM to priceoptions.”

MPT and the CAPM

The traditional CAPM also assumes that there is a risk freeasset as well as a potentially large collection of risky assets.

Under these circumstances, as we’ve seen, all investors willhold some combination of the riskless asset and the tangencyportfolio: the efficient portfolio of risky assets with the highestSharpe ratio.

MPT and the CAPM

But the CAPM goes further than the MPT by imposing anequilibrium condition.

Because there is no demand for risky financial assets except tothe extent that they comprise the tangency portfolio, andbecause, in equilibrium, the supply of financial assets mustequal demand, the market portfolio consisting of all existingfinancial assets must coincide with the tangency portfolio.

In equilibrium, that is, “everyone” must “own the market.”

MPT and the CAPM

In equilibrium, that is, “everyone” must “own the market.”

But why? What happens if not enough people want to “ownthe market.”

Asset prices must adjust so that “everyone owns the market.”

This logic turns the MPT – a theory of asset demand – intothe CAPM – an asset pricing model.

Deriving the CAPM

In the CAPM, equilibrium in financial markets requires thedemand for risky assets – the tangency portfolio – to coincidewith the supply of financial assets – the market portfolio.

Deriving the CAPM

The CAPM’s first implications are immediate: the marketportfolio lies on the efficient frontier and is the portfolio withthe highest Sharpe ratio.

Deriving the CAPM

The line originating at (0, rf ) and running through(σM ,E (r̃M)) is called the capital market line (CML).

Deriving the CAPM

Hence, it also follows that all individually optimal portfoliosare located along the CML and are formed as combinations ofthe risk free asset and the market portfolio.

Deriving the CAPM

MPT as originally developed by Markowitz implies thatportfolio managers should find a portfolio on the efficientfrontier.

The separation or two-fund theorem derived later by Tobinimplies that portfolio managers should find the portfolio onthe efficient frontier with the highest Sharpe ratio.

The CAPM implies that portfolio managers should give up onactive management and simply invest in the market portfolio.See also Burton Malkiel’s Random Walk Down Wall Street.

Deriving the CAPM

Recall that the trade-off between the standard deviation andexpected return of any portfolio combining the riskless assetand the tangency portfolio is described by the linearrelationship

E (r̃P) = rf +

[E (r̃T ) − rf

σT

]σP .

Since the CAPM implies that the tangency and marketportfolios coincide, the formula for the Capital Market Line islikewise

E (r̃P) = rf +

[E (r̃M) − rf

σM

]σP .

Deriving the CAPM

And since all individually optimal portfolios are located alongthe CML, the equation

E (r̃P) = rf +

[E (r̃M) − rf

σM

]σP .

implies that the market portfolio’s Sharpe ratio

E (r̃M) − rfσM

measures the equilibrium price of risk: the expected returnthat each investor gives up when he or she adjusts his or hertotal portfolio to reduce risk.

Deriving the CAPM

Next, let’s consider an arbitrary asset – “asset j” – withrandom return r̃j , expected return E (r̃j), and standarddeviation σj .

MPT would take E (r̃j) and σj as “data” – that is, as given.

The CAPM again goes further and asks: if asset j is to bedemanded by investors with mean-variance utility, whatrestrictions must E (r̃j) and σj satisfy?

Deriving the CAPM

To answer this question, consider an investor who takes theportion of his or her initial wealth that he or she allocates torisky assets and divides it further: using the fraction w topurchase asset j and the remaining fraction 1 − w to buy themarket portfolio.

Note that since the market portfolio already includes some ofasset j , choosing w > 0 really means that the investor“overweights” asset j in his or her own portfolio. Conversely,choosing w < 0 means that the investor “underweights” assetj in his or her own portfolio.

Deriving the CAPM

Based on our previous analysis, we know that this investor’sportfolio of risky assets now has random return

r̃P = wr̃j + (1 − w)r̃M ,

expected return

E (r̃P) = wE (r̃j) + (1 − w)E (r̃M),

and variance

σ2P = w 2σ2

j + (1 − w)2σ2M + 2w(1 − w)σjM ,

where σjM is the covariance between r̃j and r̃M .

Deriving the CAPM

E (r̃P) = wE (r̃j) + (1 − w)E (r̃M),

σ2P = w 2σ2

j + (1 − w)2σ2M + 2w(1 − w)σjM ,

We can use these formulas to trace out how σP and E (r̃P)vary as w changes.

Deriving the CAPM

The red curve these traces out how σP and E (r̃P) vary as wchanges, that is, as asset j gets underweighted oroverweighted relative to the market portfolio.

Deriving the CAPM

The red curve passes through M, since when w = 0 the newportfolio coincides with the market portfolio.

Deriving the CAPM

For all other values of w , however, the red curve must liebelow the CML.

Deriving the CAPM

Otherwise, a portfolio along the CML would be dominated inmean-variance by the new portfolio. Financial markets wouldno longer be in equilibrium, since some investors would nolonger be willing to hold the market portfolio.

Deriving the CAPM

Suppose that at W , w > 0. Then asset j is “undervalued” inthe sense that overweighting it will yield a portfolio with ahigher expected return.

Deriving the CAPM

But as all investors buy this undervalued asset, its price willrise.

Given future cash flows (future price from selling the asset plusany dividends earned), a rise the asset’s price will lower itsexpected return.

Buying pressure will continue until the red curve bends backbelow the CML.

Deriving the CAPM

Suppose that at W , w < 0. Then asset j is “overvalued” inthe sense that underweighting it will yield a portfolio with ahigher expected return.

Deriving the CAPM

But as all investors sell this overvalued asset, its price will fall.

Given future cash flows, a fall the asset’s price will raise itsexpected return.

Selling pressure will continue until the red curve bends backbelow the CML.

Deriving the CAPM

Together, these observations imply that the red curve must betangent to the CML at M.

Deriving the CAPM

Tangent means equal in slope.

We already know that the slope of the Capital Market Line is

E (r̃M) − rfσM

But what is the slope of the red curve?

Deriving the CAPM

Let f (σP) be the function defined by E (r̃P) = f (σP) andtherefore describing the red curve.

Deriving the CAPM

Next, define the functions g(w) and h(w) by

g(w) = wE (r̃j) + (1 − w)E (r̃M),

h(w) = [w 2σ2j + (1 − w)2σ2

M + 2w(1 − w)σjM ]1/2,

so thatE (r̃P) = g(w)

andσP = h(w).

Deriving the CAPM

SubstituteE (r̃P) = g(w)

andσP = h(w).

intoE (r̃P) = f (σP)

to obtaing(w) = f (h(w))

and use the chain rule to compute

g ′(w) = f ′(h(w))h′(w) = f ′(σP)h′(w)

Deriving the CAPM

Let f (σP) be the function defined by E (r̃P) = f (σP) andtherefore describing the red curve. Then f ′(σP) is the slope ofthe curve.

Deriving the CAPM

Hence, to compute f ′(σP), we can rearrange

g ′(w) = f ′(σP)h′(w)

to obtain

f ′(σP) =g ′(w)

h′(w)

and compute g ′(w) and h′(w) from the formulas we know.

Deriving the CAPM

g(w) = wE (r̃j) + (1 − w)E (r̃M),

impliesg ′(w) = E (r̃j) − E (r̃M)

Deriving the CAPM

h(w) = [w 2σ2j + (1 − w)2σ2

M + 2w(1 − w)σjM ]1/2,

implies

h′(w) =1

2

{2wσ2

j − 2(1 − w)σ2M + 2(1 − 2w)σjM

[w 2σ2j + (1 − w)2σ2

M + 2w(1 − w)σjM ]1/2

}

or, a bit more simply,

h′(w) =wσ2

j − (1 − w)σ2M + (1 − 2w)σjM

[w 2σ2j + (1 − w)2σ2

M + 2w(1 − w)σjM ]1/2

Deriving the CAPM

f ′(σP) = g ′(w)/h′(w)

g ′(w) = E (r̃j) − E (r̃M)

h′(w) =wσ2

j − (1 − w)σ2M + (1 − 2w)σjM

[w 2σ2j + (1 − w)2σ2

M + 2w(1 − w)σjM ]1/2

imply

f ′(σP) = [E (r̃j) − E (r̃M)]

×[w 2σ2

j + (1 − w)2σ2M + 2w(1 − w)σjM ]1/2

wσ2j − (1 − w)σ2

M + (1 − 2w)σjM

Deriving the CAPM

The red curve is tangent to the CML at M. Hence, f ′(σP)equals the slope of the CML when w=0.

Deriving the CAPMWhen w = 0,

f ′(σP) = [E (r̃j) − E (r̃M)]

×[w 2σ2

j + (1 − w)2σ2M + 2w(1 − w)σjM ]1/2

wσ2j − (1 − w)σ2

M + (1 − 2w)σjM

implies

f ′(σP) =[E (r̃j) − E (r̃M)]σM

σjM − σ2M

Meanwhile, we know that the slope of the CML is

E (r̃M) − rfσM

Deriving the CAPM

The tangency of the red curve with the CML at M thereforerequires

[E (r̃j) − E (r̃M)]σMσjM − σ2

M

=E (r̃M) − rf

σM

E (r̃j) − E (r̃M) =[E (r̃M) − rf ][σjM − σ2

M ]

σ2M

E (r̃j) − E (r̃M) =

(σjMσ2M

)[E (r̃M) − rf ] − [E (r̃M) − rf ]

E (r̃j) = rf +

(σjMσ2M

)[E (r̃M) − rf ]

Deriving the CAPM

E (r̃j) = rf +

(σjMσ2M

)[E (r̃M) − rf ]

Letβj =

σjMσ2M

so that this key equation of the CAPM can be written as

E (r̃j) = rf + βj [E (r̃M) − rf ]

where βj , the “CAPM beta” for asset j , depends on thecovariance between the returns on asset j and the marketportfolio.

Deriving the CAPM

E (r̃j) = rf + βj [E (r̃M) − rf ]

This equation summarizes a very strong restriction: Given rfand E (r̃M), each stock’s expected return (and hence its pricetoday) depends on βj and only on βj .

Andβj =

σjMσ2M

depends on covariance σjM not variance σ2j .