Download - Shipping and Trade in Rammeside Egypt

Transcript

Shipping and Trade in Ramesside EgyptAuthor(s): Edward W. CastleSource: Journal of the Economic and Social History of the Orient, Vol. 35, No. 3 (1992), pp.239-277Published by: BRILLStable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/3632733 .Accessed: 05/03/2011 16:33

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at .http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unlessyou have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and youmay use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use.

Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at .http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=bap. .

Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printedpage of such transmission.

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range ofcontent in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new formsof scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].

BRILL is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Journal of the Economic andSocial History of the Orient.

http://www.jstor.org

Journal of the Economic and Social History of the Orient, Vol. XXXV

SHIPPING AND TRADE IN RAMESSIDE EGYPT*

BY

EDWARD W. CASTLE

(University of Chicago)

Apart from commerce carried on at the local level between villages, the redistribution system of the Egyptian economy, in a physical sense, operated by shipping along the Nile and ancillary canals. For this reason, a study of the documents concerned with shipping and trade is essential to a study of the commercial operations of the large institutions, their relationship to one another and whatever private enterprise may have existed apart from these institutions.

On this last point, it should perhaps be kept in mind from the start that because any small scale private enterprise is less likely than the bureaucracies of the large institutions to have left direct documentary evidence on papyrus, we should expect to find a bias towards the official bureaucracies there. On the other hand, evidence on ostraca is likely to be biased towards transactions on a smaller scale.

In general, the main sources on which we have to rely are records

kept by temple and state institutions. These may include documents

dealing with the transport of grain, ship's logs recording daily tran- sactions and movements of personnel and goods, accounts of transac- tions between institutions and other entities, administrative

* I would like to thank Professor Edward F Wente for reading the original draft of this paper, and for his many helpful comments and suggestions. I would also like to thank Professor John A. Brminkman for his active interest in its subject matter, and for assistance with the Mesopotamian material. I am also obliged to Professor Dennis Pardee for his comments on the Ugaritic material. Nevertheless, respon- sibility for its content remains mine alone.

240 E. W. CASTLE

correspondence such as reports from officials to their superiors, records of legal proceedings, royal decrees and some few others.

Shzpping and the Central Economy

The backbone of Egypt's economy was its agricultural production, mainly of grain, and particularly of emmer and barley. Documents

support the expectation that riverine traffic was intense following the harvest when grain had to be transported from field to granary. The late Ramesside pAmiens') deals with a flotilla of twenty-one ships belonging to the great temple of Amun engaged in the transport of

grain. The ships involved were of considerable size, two of them car-

rying cargo of over 900 sacks each, equivalent to almost forty-three tonnes and occupying approximately 65.5 cubic metres of each

vessel2). According to the Nauri Decree3), the temple of Osiris at

Abydos was provided with ships one hundred cubits, or over fifty metres in length. pHarris 14) records the building of a sacred barge 130 cubits, or almost sixty-eight metres in length. By comparison, the

funerary vessel of Khufu 5) found at Giza measures just under forty- four metres. According to pHarris 16), Ramesses III donated no less than eighty-two vessels to the temple of Medinet Habu, though most of these were not large transport ships.

The grain carried by the flotilla of pAmiens was collected from various provincial estates, with each ship carrying grain belonging to several separate foundations. Gardiner supposed that the cargo was to be discharged at Thebes en masse, to be distributed from there to the institutions having a claim on it 7). It is known that temples might

1) Gardiner, RAD, 1-13 2) Gardiner, JEA 27 (1941), 47 3) Nauri decree, 24, KRI I, 45-58. 4) pHarris I, 7, 5 W Erichsen, Papyrus Hams I, Brussels: Fondation Egyp-

tologique Relne Elisabeth. Bibliotheca Aegypthaca V, 1933 5) I. E. S. Edwards, The Pyramtds of Egypt. Viking, 1986, 121. 6) pHarris I, 12b, 10ff. 7) Gardiner, JEA 27 (1941), 41.

SHIPPING AND TRADE IN RAMESSIDE EGYPT 241

possess estates far afield from the temple proper, and consequently possessed an administrative network that might extend throughout the country. pAnastasi IV8) attests to the fact that a temple of Sety II in Thebes possessed vineyards and administrators (rwdw) in the northern delta. It would be clearly inefficient for an institution to

transport produce over long distances in half-empty ships9) for

redistribution from the temple's immediate precincts. Administrative

cooperation between the various temple institutions and the Crown is to be anticipated, and evidence for this is found in the Amiens and Harris papyri.

pAmiens rt. 2, 4-6 contains the following entry: 2,4) imw n imy-r3 ChCw Mnw-scnb s3 B3k-Imn n pr Imn r bt.f 2,5) rdit n.f m p3 iw n Imn-shsh-t.f hr _dnw n web Ky-sn m it n rmnyt

pr RC-ms-sw-mry-Imn n .Hwt-r-p3-wd

r bt.fh3r 600, smn 335, rmnyt Tbw h3r 37 1/4 1/8

2,6) rdit n.f m st tn hr dnw pn m zt n rmnyt pr Sty-Mr-n-Pth m pr Imn

r bt.f h3r 227 2/4 1/8

2,4) Vessel of the ships' commander Minseankh son of Bakamun of the house of Amun, under his authority:

2,5) What was given to him in the Island of Amun-who-runs-

across-his-boundary at the threshing-floor of the priest Ky-sen, namely grain of the domain of the House of Ramessu-Mry- Imn of Mansion-by-the-Stela, under his authority: 600 sacks. Balance 335. Domain of Tjebu: 37 3/8 sacks.

2,6) What was given to him in this place at this threshing-floor: namely grain of the domain of the House of Sety-Merenptah in the House of Amun, under his authority: 227 5/8 sacks.

It seems clear here and in other cases, that grain from fields belong- ing to the House of Sety-Merenptah is being tallied as belonging to

8) pAnastasi IV, 7, 1 = Gardiner, LEM 41, 14.

9) pAnastasi VIII demonstrates that inefficient use of shipping could be subject to administrative rebuke. See KRI III, 499, passim.

242 E. W. CASTLE

the Karnak temple of Ramesses IIo0). As Gardiner11) puts it, the tem-

ple of Sety-Merenptah seems to be under some financial obligation to the temple of Ramesses II. But to put it another way, what we have here is likely to be just one part of a reciprocal arrangement by which the two institutions obtained the most efficient use of available trans-

port and manpower12). The Wilbour papyrus, in Gardiner's words "teems" with evidence of similar obligations between temples, and between Temple and Crown13).

pTurin 188214), vs. 1,2 ff. and pLeyden 34815), vs. 9,1 are con- cerned with transport of grain receipts. In both cases, the ships are described as ChCw. The same type of vessel is described as transporting inw from Nubia in the Nauri decree16). In the case of the Turin

papyrus, the shipment of grain belonging to the temple of Amun-Re was under the authority of a stable-master of the Residence, attesting to the close administrative cooperation between Temple and Crown.

The Crown too possessed its own boats. The verso of pSallier IV 7) 9, 1 ff. refers to grain which has been loaded onto a boat belonging to the granary of Pharaoh under the authority of a royal scribe and overseer of the granary who in turn is under the supervision of a

deputy commander of the army'8). The letter is written by a royal scribe and steward of the funerary temple of Merenptah at Thebes "in the House of Amun". Again we see the symnbiotic relationship between Temple and Crown administration. In the opinion of

10) According to Gardiner, part of the Karnak complex comprismg the Hypostyle Hall. See JEA 27 (1941), 44.

11) Gardiner, JEA 27 (1941), 50. 12) Cf. Gardiner, The Wilbour Papyrus, vol. II. Oxford: Oxford University Press,

1948, 209f. 13) Gardiner, JEA 27 (1941), 50. 14) pTurin 1882 (= re-edition of pTurin A of Gardiner, LEM), Gardiner,

RAD, 82. 15) Gardiner, LEM, 132-137 Translated m Caminos, LEM, 489-501. 16) Nauri decree, 83 17) pSallier IV, vs. 9, lff. = Gardiner, JEA 27 (1941), 62ff. 18) On which see J -M. Kruchten, Le Dicret d'Horemheb Brussels: Editions de

l'Universit6 de Bruxelles, 1981, 45.

SHIPPING AND TRADE IN RAMESSIDE EGYPT 243

Kees19), these royal officials carried out these extensive

administrative duties in a reciprocal arrangement by which certain cultivable lands belonging to the temple were placed at the disposal of the Crown. Since, as he observes, they were responsible for the

receipt of temple revenues, and several sources attest to vast royal donations to the temples, it might be better to consider that the Crown had a vested and controlling interest in the Temple, in which case the vast concessions granted to the temples would have served the interests of the Crown as much as the Temple.

But the temples' ships were not solely concerned with the transport of grain. During the Ramesside period, the delta area around Lake Menzalah was renowned for its orchards and vineyards, and title to these estates might be possessed by foundations in the far south. The vast orchards and vineyards of the estate of Ka-en-keme belonged to the domain of Amun during the reign of Ramesses II, and wine- dockets from there are common at his mortuary temple at Thebes, while olive oil from the same orchards later found its way to the tem-

ple at Medinet Habu20). As stated above, pAnastasi IV2') reveals that a mortuary temple of

Sety II in Thebes possessed vineyards in the delta. A captain of a scow belonging to this temple reports loading over 1500 jars of wine and fruit including grapes onto two cattle-ferries belonging to the

temple and conveying them, not south, but north from Piramesse to be handed over to temple administrators somewhere north of Piramesse. The vineyard concerned is reported to have had twenty- one workers, of which four were said to be old men and six children.

The ships belonging to the temples were not restricted to domestic

transport. The Nauri inscription indicates that ships belonging to the

temple of Osiris at Abydos traded in Nubia. Line 40 of the same

19) H. Kees, Ancient Egypt: A Cultural Topography Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1961, 209

20) H. Kees, Ancient Egypt, 201f. 21) pAnastasi IV 6,11 = Gardiner, LEM, 34-55

244 E. W. CASTLE

inscription mentions foreign traders (iwtyw n h3st) attached to the

temple. pHarris 1.29, 1 refers to ships attached to the 'temple for

transport of goods from God's Land to the treasury and storehouse of Medinet Habu. The historical section of pHarris I describes a

royal expedition returning from a voyage to Punt via the Red Sea and overland to Coptos22), while lines 78, 1 ff. refer to a journey by ship and land to copper mines, probably in the Sinai.

Taxes on Shipping

The Nauri decree expressly forbids commanders of a fortress built

by Sety I near Nauri from taking goods from ships belonging to the aforementioned temple of Osiris returning from Nubia. Kees con- siders this an exemption from the normal exaction of imposts. Some

support for this may be found in the inscriptions of Rekhmire 23) from the reign of Thutmose III. These inscriptions include a list of taxes

paid by officials including one Senmut, commander of the fortress of

Bigeh. The items specified as paid include precisely the kinds of goods that the Nauri inscription forbids the fortress commanders from tak-

ing from the temple's ships: specifically gold and hides. It appears that officials were levied a fixed amount to be paid in taxes to the

Crown, while what they were able to exact in excess of that con- stituted personal income24).

This suggests that some fixed rate should have applied to the exac- tion of imposts, to check uncontrolled exploitation. Nevertheless, Lichtheim 25) has shown that claims of a ten-percent tariff on imports at Naucratis26) and Elephantine27) are based on a misinterpretation

22) pHarris I. 77, 8. 23) See Breasted, AR II, 716.

24) H. Kees, Ancient Egypt, 104f. 25) M. Lichtheim, "The Naucratis Stela Once Again", in Studies in Honor of

George H. Hughes. Studies in Ancient Oriental Civilizations 39 (1976), 139ff. 26) Erman, ZAS 38, 130ff. 27) Roeder, G., Urkunden zur Religion des alten Aegypten, Jena, 1915, 177f.

SHIPPING AND TRADE IN RAMESSIDE EGYPT 245

of the texts, so that if there was a fixed rate of duty, it remains unknown.

If the interests of Temple and Crown were as close as the evidence of overlapping administrative functions seems to indicate, the exemp- tions from transit taxes may be seen to disadvantage not royal interests so much as those of the officials charged with collecting the taxes. On this question, Kees28) considers highly probable Schaedel's

opinion that such exemption decrees were intended to reimburse the

temples for financial and logistic support during wartime29). Wars were and remain highly expensive undertakings. The temples pos- sessed vast financial reserves, and as we have seen, large numbers of

ships of the type which would be ideal for the transport of troops and

matirnel during military campaigns. The vast quantities of booty returned to the treasuries of Amun following such campaigns could be seen as repayment, lending additional weight to the theory.

It can be shown from the Amarna letters that official imposts were exacted from foreign ships entering Egypt from the north. Diplomatic correspondence from the king of Alagiya to an Egyptian king reads, in part:

" Ces hommes sont mes marchands. Mon frire, laisse-les aller si2rement et sans [de]laz. Que personne ne s'approche de mes marchands ou de mon navire pour exiger quelque chose en ton nom. "so0)

Private Participation in the Economy

The second column on the verso of the Amiens papyrus records the collection of small amounts of grain from various individuals. Some of these amounts consist of only one or two sacks, and individual cultivators are named as suppliers of the grain. Line x + 2 records 1 1/4 sacks of grain "of the domain of the administrator (rwdw)

28) Anczent Egypt, 104. 29) Schaedel, Dze Ltsten des grossen Papyrus Harrs. Leipzzger Aegytologische Studien 6.

Glueckstadt: J J Augustin, 1936, 70. . 30) EA 39, 14-20: transl. William L. Moran, Les Lettres d'el Amarna. Paris: Les

Editions du Cerf, 1987, 208.

246 E. W. CASTLE

Ptahmose by the hand of the cultivator (ihwty) Efenennebu, brought from the house of the overseer of cattle Amenhotep" 31). Another line

(x + 4) records grain provided "by the hand of the scribe Pen-

nestowe, brought from the house of the sandalmaker Heryebhimace from the farm land that he tilled". Lines x + 6 and x + 9 contain the phrase "by the hand of'" the same scribe, while the corresponding entry in x + 11 has "by the hand of the rwdw Hori". From these

parallels, it seems clear that the term ihwty does not necessarily refer to the individual who performs the actual cultivating of the land, as Gardiner concluded by different reasoning32). Menu33) agreed with Gardiner that the term is not restricted to field labourers, and may also refer to a type of manager or administrator. Stuchevsky, in a

publication recently reviewed by Janssen34), has proposed that this term was applied to three different kinds of individuals: firstly, it was

applied to actual farm labourers on state and temple estates; secondly to "agents of the fisc" responsible for controlling the production of

eight to twelve of these primary cultivators or fieldhands; thirdly, it was applied to private possessors of fields.

According to the recorded yield from the kind of land mentioned in pValengay I as being cultivated by landholders or lessees35) at

Elephantine, one sack of grain would constitute the expected yield from only one tenth of an aroura36). The vivid picture of the terrified

peasant in pLansing confronted by a failed crop on the one hand and

31) Gardiner, JEA 27, 52 = RAD 9, 1-3 32) Gardiner, JEA 27, 21f. 33) Bernadette Menu, Le rig'mejuridique des terres et du personnel attache h la terre dans

le Papyrus Wilbour Lille: 1970, 139ff. 34) I. A. Stuchevsky, Zemledel'tsy gosudarstvennogo khozyarstva drevnego Egzpta epokhi

Ramessidov (The Cultivators of the State Economy in Ancient Egypt durinng the Ramesside Period), Moskva: Izdatel'stvo "Nauka", 1982. Review- Janssen, Agrarian Administration in Egypt during the Twentieth Dynasty, in Bibliotheca Ornentalis XLIII, 3/4 (1986), 351 ff.

35) The status of these individuals is discussed below 36) This concurs with the average yield on basin land, as noted by Klaus Baer

"The Low Price of Land in Ancient Egypt", in JARCE 1 (1962), 30.

SHIPPING AND TRADE IN RAMESSIDE EGYPT 247

the tax-collector on the other comes to mind37). However, it is not

necessary to conclude that these quantities constituted the total yield of fields cultivated by these individuals, and in fact some entries record balances apparently outstanding38).

The individuals recorded on the verso of pAmiens as having pro- duced grain "from the farm land the he/she tilled" are variously a sandalmaker (x + 4), a townswoman (Cnh n nzwt, x + 5) and a scribe

(x + 6). The Gurob fragments M39) name various individuals from whom grain is being collected, and one of these is also a woman40). Whether or not field cultivation was exclusively a male occupation 4), it was certainly one eschewed by scribes42). It would seem then that at least some of these individuals held some kind of lease or title to the lands in question and were not mere sharecroppers working for the temple. Neither do they appear to be Temple employees. Despite the expression "from the land which he/she tilled", it seems that they must have employed others to do the actual cultivating on lands to which they enjoyed some kind of right43). Baer considered private ownership of land to be attested for all periods in ancient Egypt44). According to Gardiner, the status of the numerous smallholders men- tioned in the apportioning paragraphs of pWilbour "either was, or else closely resembled, that of private owners"15). Baer considered

37) On which, cf. Gardiner, JEA 27, 53, n. 1.

38) E.g. x + 4, x + 5

39) Gurob fragments M = RAD 33 Gardiner, Wilbour II, 207 40) Gurob fragments M, line 10. Gardiner, RAD, 33,12. 41) That it was is suggested for the Middle Kingdom by the list of servants in

William C. Hayes, A Papyrus of the Late Middle Kingdom in the Brooklyn Museum. New York: The Brooklyn Museum, 1955, 108. No feminine form of ihwty is known to the Wb. (1. 214), nor to William A. Ward, Essays on Feminine Titles of the Middle Kingdom and Related Subjects. Beirut: American University of Beirut, 1986.

42) Cf. pAnastasi II, 6, 7ff. = Caminos, LEM, 50ff. 43) Cf. Gardiner, The Wilbour Papyrus, vol. II, 209 44) Klaus Baer, "The Low Price of Land in Ancient Egypt", In JARCE 1

(1962), 25ff. 45) Gardiner, The Wilbour Papyrus, vol. II, 75

248 E. W. CASTLE

pWilbour "a register of rents due to various institutions for land to which they held complete or partial ownership rights"'46).

The question of private enterprise is an interesting one, on which I intend to publish more in the near future. The Horemheb Decree contains the following statement:

"If a nm4y makes a vessel with its gear for himself in order to be able to serve Pharaoh [...]"47)

The same class of people designated as nm4yw appear in pValengy I where they are described as paying gold into the royal Treasury in return for cultivation rights. The mayor of Elephantine complains to the Chief Taxing Master that a scribe of the House of the Adoratress of Amun is demanding taxes supposedly due to that institution from certain lands for which payments as rent or taxes are already being remitted directly to the Royal Treasury by the nmhyw engaged in their cultivation. That these payments are specified as being made in

gold, rather than in grain as we have seen in the case of the cultivators named in the Gurob fragments, suggests a greater degree of

independence. Payment in gold rather than in kind seems to indicate that the nmbyw are not attached as staff to either Temple or Crown. In the light of the available evidence, Kruchten considers nmkyw to be private individuals 48). Baer considers these lands to be privately owned49), in which case the gold would represent taxes. The question of the use of gold in exchange will be taken up below.

Considering the private status of these cultivators and the above

passage in the Horemheb decree involving nm4yw, it is certain that

private ownership of ships existed during the Ramesside period50). pTurin 1895 + 200651) records the use of fishing boats for the

46) Klaus Baer, JARCE 1 (1962), 32. 47) J -M. Kruchten, Le Dicret d'Horemheb. Brussels: Editions de l'Unlversit6 de

Bruxelles, 1981, line 13 48) Kruchten, Le Dicret d'Horemheb, 45. 49) Klaus Baer, JARCE 1 (1962), 40, n. 98. 50) See also Janssen, Ship's Logs, 99. 51) Gardiner, RAD, 35ff. JEA 27 (1941), 22ff.

SHIPPING AND TRADE IN RAMESSIDE EGYPT 249

transport of grain. This text records the use by a scribe of the

necropolis of two boats, one belonging to a fisherman and another to a "skipper". The fisherman is allowed one sack as rations, whereas the skipper is given twenty for his services. In neither case is the boat

designated as belonging to any institution, and they would appear to be private vessels hired out by the scribe of the necropolis for the immediate purpose. The amounts given to the fisherman and skipper are not to be relied upon absolutely since Gardiner52) has been able to show that the accounts have been falsified by the scribe using some creative but incriminatingly inaccurate accounting.

Other instances of the transport of grain by fisherman are recorded. A similar payment of one sack is recorded as payment for boat expenses in pTurin 2008 + 201653), while in the same text three sacks are allowed for the hire of a boat to travel from a place called "The New Land of the Pylons of the House of Osiris" to Heliopolis. pGeneva D191, 13 records the use of an Cq3y-boat of a fisherman for the transport of grain54). The three men connected with this vessel seem to be taking advantage of a woman acting in an official capacity in her husband's absence in order to remunerate themselves rather

lavishly to the amount of 2 1/2 sacks of grain each 55). These instances seem clear evidence, if it were necessary, that private vessels were available for hire for the transport of people and goods. It appears that the large official institutions made use of these vessels whenever

necessary, and as the Nauri decree seems to imply, officials had the

power to requisition them, a power which did not go unabused. Some evidence for the private ownership of vessels engaged in

foreign trade is supplied by pAnastasi IV:

p3y.k mnsw ii hr H3r 3tpw m bt nb nfr "Your ship is come from Syria loaded with all manner of good things.''" 56)

52) JEA 27 (1941), 30ff. 53) eTurin 2008 + 2016, III, 15ff. = Janssen, Ship's Logs, 78. 54) Cerny, LRL, 57 55) Cf. Jac. J Janssen, Wepwawet 2, 30-31. 56) pAnastasi IV 3, 10f. = Gardiner, LEM, 36, 4.

250 E. W.. CASTLE

Here the ship is represented as belonging to a wealthy individual, and while the document is a panegyric rather than an administrative

document, it may be argued that the scribe is obliged to paint his

complimentary picture within the limits of what was socially possible. No office is attributed to him although this might be expected in a

panegyric if he were understood to hold some official position. Even

so, there would be no need to assume that the holding of office and the exercise of trade or manufacture for private enrichment were

mutually exclusive activities in ancient Egypt. While nmhyw were

private individuals outside the bureaucracy, holders of official posi- tions may well have carried on private trading activities with their own vessels, retaining iwtyw for this purpose. Some evidence for this will be presented below.

While private ownership of boats is attested, capital is also attested in the hands of private individuals (nm4yw) in the form of gold. Given

this, it is only a small step to a degree of private enterprise.

The Role of Traders

Traders attached to temples are well attested. pHarris I. 46, 2 mentions "innumerable traders" attached to the temple of Ptah built

by Ramesses III. As mentioned above, the Nauri inscription, line 40 refers to Iwtyw n b3st, "foreign traders" in the service of the temple of Osiris. Notwithstanding the edicts of the Nauri decree, Ramesses

II, visiting Abydos, finds his father's temple unfinished and its endowments violated57). His re-endowment provides for the welfare of the temple, iwtyw hr irt s'wyt hr hnt.sn b3kw.sn zry m nbw hd hmt, "while traders trade with their consignments, their revenue therof58)

57) Great Abydos inscription, lines 34-35, in K. Kitchen, Ramesside Inscrtptzons II, 325ff.

58) It would be possible to translate b3kw as "products" or "workmanship", in which case the reference could be to the selling of objects made of gold, silver and copper However, I have taken the suffix of b3kw. sn to refer to the traders and

try to hnt.sn in order to avoid a possible redundancy in the use of try This passage appears in a list of endowments providing income to the temple. It seems clear therefore from context that the metals should be understood as temple revenue.

SHIPPING AND TRADE IN RAMESSIDE EGYPT 251

being gold, silver and copper." 59) pTurin 2008 + 2016

demonstrates, in Janssen's view, that traders attached to the temple provided an indirect way for people to obtain goods manufactured in

temple workshops60). The title hry iwtyw appears in connection with traders belonging to temples. One of these is attached to a temple of the Aten, demonstrating that the temples built during the Amarna

period functioned similarly in this respect61). However, traders are also attested as belonging to individuals.

pBM 1005362) cites 16 traders as recipients of property stolen from tombs. Eight of these come from the town of Mi-wer, modern Kom Medinet Ghurob situated on the Bahr Yusuf at the entrance to the

Faiyum where it would have been well situated for trading with that area. Three, and perhaps a fourth, of the other traders appear also in pBM 10068. These are described as belonging to the army com-

mander, chief of the Twhr troops Amen-nufer63). Of the other traders in pBM 10068, rt. 4, another four are listed as belonging to the same

army commander, one to a troop-captain of the temple of Re, and two to a singer of the temple of Sobek in Crocodilopolis, daughter of a former commander. One belongs to another officer of Twhr troops, while two belong to temples. Altogether then, two belong directly to

temple estates, three are attached to temple functionaries and thus

perhaps (or perhaps not) indirectly to temple estates, while nine

belong to military officers. The exact status of these traders is unclear, but one of them is said

to have possessed a slave64). pBM 1006865), rt. 4,2 refers to "traders

59) Spiegelberg, Rechnungen aus der Zeit Setis I. Strassbourg: Triibner, 1896, 61, n. 1 Mariette, Abydos 1/8, 84 (= KRI II, 333, 1-2).

60) Ship's Logs, 101

61) Mariette, Monuments divers recueillis en Egypte et en Nubie, P1. 56. See also Mariette, Cat. d'Abydos, 410, #1115

62) pBM 10053, rt. passim. Peet, The Great Tomb Robberies of the Twentzeth Egyp- tian Dynasty Oxford: OUP, 1930

63) Rt. 4,4. 64) pBM 10052, rt. 8,2 (Peet, Tomb Robberies): "There was brought S. the slave

of the merchant Pesienwese" So already Janssen, Ship's Logs, 102. 65) pBM 10068, rt. 4,2 (Peet, Tomb Robberies).

252 E. W. CASTLE

of every house" in connection with these traders. Janssen 66) is uncon- vinced that this refers to private commercial firms as Peet suggests, since pr, "house" could refer to "estates" in this and other similar

statements67). However, as noted, pBM 10052 68) refers to a slave

belonging to one of the traders involved in these proceedings. Since

ownership of a slave suggests a degree of independence, perhaps more weight could be given to the possibility than Janssen is prepared to concede. At the least the "houses" to which these traders belonged could well include the private estates of titled individuals such as the above-mentioned for whom they conducted profitable private ven- tures.

Traders are otherwise attested as dealing in slaves in pCairo 6573969), where the purchases result in litigation. Payment in this case is in commodities. James70) speculates persuasively that even traders attached to temples may have had some degree of

independence, reflecting the fact "that the national autocracy, the

all-pervading authority of the king and, by a kind of devolved, unspecified proxy, of the temples, was modified to the point of being ignored" in other aspects of Egyptian life. In support of this, he cites two documents described as ship's logs published by Janssen71). Kemp rightly considers that the internal mobility provided by shipp- ing "provides, in fact, a weighty argument against the view that per- sonal economic transactions were so often cosy reciprocal exchanges between relations and neighbours as to form the only serious alter- native to redistribution" 72), but he is incorrect in stating that iowtyw "appear always in the employ of someone else, either a temple or an

66) Janssen, Ship's Logs, 103. 67) E.g. pLansing 4, 10 = Gardiner, LEM, 103, where Caminos (LEM, 384)

translates, "ship's crews of every (commercial) house" 68) pBM 10052, rt. 8,2 (Peet, Great Tomb Robberies). 69) pCairo 65739 Gardiner, JEA 21 (1935), 140ff. 70) Pharaoh's People, 249 71) J Janssen, Two Ancient Egypttan Ship's Logs. Leiden: 1961. 72) Barry J Kemp, Ancient Egypt: Anatomy of a Civilization. London: Routledge,

1989, 257

SHIPPING AND TRADE IN RAMESSIDE EGYPT 253

official." 73) The statement is repudiated by many references to i!tyw in the tomb robbery papyri where the scribes are otherwise particular in referring to the affiliations of witnesses for purposes of

identification7"). Further, any affiliations of the swtyw of pBoulaq 11 remain unstated. On the other hand, many iotyw were certainly attached to institutions and individuals. Because he doubts the existence of free traders in this period, Reineke prefers to translate

Jwty as "Handelsagent" 75). Nevertheless, some doubt still attaches to the status of the swtyw, and Kemp's preference for the more neutral

"trader" 76) remains acceptable since its semantic range is exclusive of neither dependent nor independent status. Their status may never- theless turn out to be somewhat more complex77).

Foreign Traders and Exchange The tomb of Qenamun contains a scene depicting Syrian traders

landing at a quay, probably at Thebes78). At least three Egyptian traders are shown on the quay, one of these being a woman. From the nature of the stalls in which they sit, it seems reasonable to assume that these Egyptians are acting in a private capacity, as James suggests79). On whether they are acting as private individuals or

agents of a temple, Kemp reserves judgement, but nevertheless believes that this scene represents "the very kind of mechanism that is required for an economic model which allows greater scope to

private enterprise" 80). The two male traders are shown holding hand

73) Kemp, Ancient Egypt, 257 74) E.g. pBM 10053 rt. 3,1, 3,2; 4,5 and passim; pBM 10052, 8,2. 75) Walter F. Reineke, "Waren die gwtyw wirklich Kaufleute?", Altorsentalische

Forschungen 6 (1979), 13 76) Kemp, Ancient Egypt, 257 77) I intend to treat this subject more fully in a future paper 78) N de Garis Davies and R. O Faulkner, in JEA 33 (1949), 40ff. 79) T G H. James, Pharaoh's People. London: The Bodley Head, 1984, 254. Cf.

the local market scene in the tomb of Ipuy, in N de G Davies, Two Ramesstde Tombs at Thebes. New York: 1927, plates XXX, XXXI, reproduced m James, Pharaoh's People, fig. 25

80) Kemp, Ancient Egypt, 255

254 E. W. CASTLE

scales. Davies and Faulkner had suggested that the purpose of these scales might be to weigh out precious metal used in transactions.

Kemp too considers that the presence of these scales implies "that metals were part of the transaction" 81). James, on the other hand, considers it "unlikely that any of the goods offered for sale in these booths could have been worth bargaining for in gold or silver." Nevertheless, he accurately describes the only identifiable transaction in the scene where "a Syrian offers a large stoppered jar, probably of oil ... while the trader makes his bargain using his balance" 82). In this case, the object being traded could well be an expensive item, especially if the jar contained some valuable oil or imported wine. International trade during this period seems to have been restricted to luxury goods, exceptions probably arising only out of special circumstances83). In any case, the object in question should probably be interpreted as representing only a sample of a larger quantity being offered for sale: following the well-dressed Syrian is a stream of labourers bearing more vessels, some of the latter being of the same kind as that being shown to the Egyptian. Documentary evidence for the import of Syrian wine is provided by a Ugaritic document which refers to "20 (jars of) hsp-wine for Ql, who is setting out for

Egypt""84). The stated quantity would be excessive for personal con-

sumption, and must be considered as part of a cargo destined for

Egypt. It should be pointed out that whereas much of the silver which

reached Egypt seems to have been imported via Syria, Egypt was the main exporter of gold. Gold was therefore considerably cheaper in

Egypt. During the 14th to 13th centuries, the price of one shekel of

gold in Ugarit was three to four shekels of silver85), whereas in Egypt

81) Kemp, Ancient Egypt, 253 82) James, Pharaoh's People, 256. 83) Cf. I. Singer, Tel Aviv 10 (1983), 4. 84) PRU II 84 (= RS 16.127):27 85) Peter C. Craigie, Ugant and the Old Testament. Grand Rapids: Eerdmans,

1983, 41. M. Heltzer, "The Metal Trade of Ugarit and the Problem of Transpor- tation of Commercial Goods", in Iraq 39 (1977), 205.

SHIPPING AND TRADE IN RAMESSIDE EGYPT 255

during the New Kingdom up to as late as the 17th year of Ramesses

IX86) the price was only about two shekels of silver. Clearly, any astute

Syrian trader would have been keen to acquire gold at the Egyptian price.

Ugaritic texts attest to the fact that state employees were paid in

silver, and that in fact silver was widely used as currency there during the same period87). Weigall believes that until supplanted by the kite

owing to the gradual depreciation of this standard, the sct of about 7.6 to 8 grams functioned as the equivalent of the Assyrian shekel88), an equivalence which would have been desirable in commercial ven- tures such as that shown in this representation, which also depicts the kind of conditions under which silver exchange could have reached the Egyptian marketplace. It is of interest that the Tell el Amarna hoard includes a figurine which has been identified as Hittite89), and which must have reached Egypt through Levantine trade.

The scene from the tomb of Qenamun, which dates from the reign of Amenhotep III, may find a Syrian correlative in a Ugaritic docu- ment referring to Amenhotep III, a merchant, ships and silver,

although the precise purport of the text is uncertain90). The activity of Syrian merchants operating in Egypt is further

reflected in a text recording the allotment of a quantity of oil to one "Abrm of Egypt" 91). Another text possibly refers to a ship-owner of the same name92). Yet another fragmentary text contains the isolated

86) Cerny, "Prices and Wages in Egypt in the Ramesside Period", in Cahzers d'Histozre Mondiale I (1954), 905f.

87) M. Heltzer, "Royal Economy in Ancient Ugant", in E. Lipinski, State and

Temple Eonomy, vol. II. Orientalia Lovantensia Analecta 6. Leuven, 1979, 471f. and

passim. 88) A. Weigall, Weights and Balances. Catalogue gendral des antzquztls igyptiennes du

Musie du Caire, 1908, pp. 10, 11-12, 13 He does not discuss the 9ct of the so-called

Hauskaufurkunde of the Old Kingdom (Urk. 1. 157f.). 89) Martha R. Bell, "A Hittite Pendant from Amarna", in American Journal of

Archaeology 90 (1986), 145ff.

90) KTU 2.42 (= RS 18.113A = PRU V 8). D Pardee, "Epigraphic and

Philological Notes", in Ugarzt-Forschungen, 19 (1987), 204ff.

91) RS 18.42 (= PRU V 95): 3-4.

92) RS 19 126 (= PRU V 123): 7

256 E. W. CASTLE

words myrm, "Egypt" and mkr[m(?)], "merchant[s"(?)]93), the latter

appearing as a borrowing in Egyptian94). Apart from shipping, Ugaritic sources suggest that overland trade

was conducted between Syria and Egypt95).

Precious Metal as a Means of Exchange It has been generally accepted by Egyptologists that all commercial

exchange in Egypt was conducted by means of barter, the com-

parative values of goods for exchange being expressed for the sake of convenience in terms of quantities of standard commodities such as metal or grain 96). While such a barter system certainly existed at the local level it should be considered but part of a larger system in which

precious metal was employed as a form of currency. Reference has already been made to a passage in the great Abydos

inscription referring to traders belonging to a temple who "trade with their consignments, their revenue thereof being gold, silver and

copper" 97).

pLansing 4, 8 ff. portrays traders carrying goods from town to town up and down the Nile. Caminos98) found this passage puzzling. The difficulty lies in the phrase which he evidently understood as iw. w shnt mi hmty and translated "and are as busy as brass" 99). In fact

hmty is not "brass" but "copper" though this hardly helps the sense. To satisfy sense and context & should be understood as a

writing of the preposition m, a writing not unknown to these texts 100). We may then translate the relevant passage:

93) RS 18.285[A] (= PRU V 126): 4-5 94) Gardiner, Anczent Egyptzan Onomastica, vol. 1, 95*. 95) Jesus-Luis Cunchillos, Textes Ougarntques, tome II. Correspondence. Littiratures

Anciennes du Proche-Ortent. Parts: Editions du Cerf, 1989, 405, and n. 183 96) Cf. Jac. J Janssen, "Prolegomena to the Study of Egypt's Economic

History during the New Kingdom", in SAK 3 (1975), 177 97) KRI II, 333, if. 98) Cammnos, LEM, 386, n. (4, 10). 99) Caminos, LEM, 384. 100) Caminos, LEM, 551.

SHIPPING AND TRADE IN RAMESSIDE EGYPT 257

"The traders fare downstream and upstream as they do business with copper, carrying goods <from > one town to another as they supply him who has not, although the tax-people carry gold, the most precious of all minerals."

The passage occurs in a tendentious school text in which the scribe is attempting to show to disadvantage all professions other than his own. He attempts to demonstrate the meanness of the traders' condi- tion by contrasting the relative values of the metals in which they are said to deal with that handled by the htriw.

But this is mere hyperbole since traders were not restricted to the

use of copper. On the contrary, they are specifically recorded as pay-

ing in gold for purchases. pBoulaq 11101) contains accounts of the sale

of small quantities of goods, principally beef and wine. The majority of the transactions appear to be debits entered against the names of

various traders, but one of the transactions clearly shows a trader

paying for his purchases with gold:

6. 3bd 2-nw 3bt sw 25 isp m-c iwty B3kz 7. nbw Sct 2 1/2 r swnt iwf

6. Second month of Inundation, day 25, received from the trader

Baki: 7. gold 2 1/2 sct in payment for meat102).

While admitting that this entry involves payment in gold•03),

James prefers to argue from the silence of the entries where com-

modities are valued in terms of their equivalent in metal that "we

should not conclude that payments were actually made in metal as

specified. If they were so made, it would suggest that metals, in par- ticular gold and silver, were commonly used as 'currency' in the

truest sense; from which it should follow that substantial quantities

101) T E. Peet, The Unit of Value iCty, 185ff. 102) pBoulaq 11 3, 6-7 See also James, Pharaoh's People, 248. 103) James, Pharaoh's People, 249

258 E. W. CASTLE

of these metals were in circulation, available for trading, and

regularly passed from hand to hand" 104).

As Peet notes, these transactions seem to involve retailers making purchases from a wholesaler. The trader's method of payment might be understood to suggest private status. Deliveries are made in some cases 105) to the same trader on consecutive days, so that the sphere of activity appears to be strictly local unless they happen to be acting as buyers or agents for other dealers.

The two Brooklyn account papyri published by Condon106) are

thought by Janssen to resemble texts such as pBoulaq 11 "in which an institution, probably a temple, settles its accounts with retail dealers" 07). While the wholesaler may well be a temple, there seems no inherent reason why these texts could not originate from private commercial concerns, if only we could be sure of their existence. In

any case, the possibility should not be prejudiced. Regarding pValengay I, Gardiner'08) questions the expressionf3y

nbw in connection with payments to the Crown of rents or taxes by nm4yw engaged in cultivation, indicating that he would have expected to find hd, "silver" instead of gold, as in pHarris I 46,1, and understands it simply to indicate payment. However, the same

expression is used of htrznw (tax-collectors?) in pLansing 4, 9 f. fol- lowed by the phrase p3 sbq n znr nb, "the most precious of all minerals". The expression is suggested by Cerny as a restoration of the traces in pTurin 1887, vs. 1, 9109) to which Gardiner somewhat

reluctantly acquiesces. In the light of pBoulaq 11, where a trader

specifically pays in gold and where commodities are valued in terms of the same metal, there seems no reason to exclude the use of gold in domestic commercial exchange, at least at the upper levels. As

104) James, Pharaoh's People, 260 105) E.g. Col. 3, 8 & 11. 106) V Condon, "Two Account Papyri of the Late 18th Dynasty (Brooklyn

35.1453 A and B)", in Revue d'Egyptologze 35, 57ff 107) Jac. J Janssen, "Two Variant Accounts", in Vara Aegyptzaca 1(1985), 109 108) Gardiner, RdE 6, 121 n. (o). 109) Gardiner, RAD, 79a, n. 6a-b.

SHIPPING AND TRADE IN RAMESSIDE EGYPT 259

noted above, the great Abydos inscription refers to traders dealing in

gold, silver and copper. If private individuals were able to pay tax or rent in gold rather

than in kind we may reasonably assume this gold to have been obtained from the sale of grain. That silver might be obtained in this

way is demonstrated by the legal defence offered by a woman being questioned in connection with silver stolen from tombs. Asked to

explain the source of silver in her possession, she explains that it was obtained from the sale of barley 10). The veracity of her testimony is

irrelevant; it was intended to be plausible. As stated, pBoulaq 11 attests a trader paying for his purchases with

gold. Wenamun, 1,10; 2,10 and 2,40 show that gold and silver might be used for foreign exchange"'). That a temple might employ the

same means of exchange domestically is shown in a text originally cited by Peet 2) where a temple provides gold, silver and copper "for the rations of the Necropolis."

Kees is of the opinion that gold production was a royal monopoly. He presents no evidence for his statement, but some support might be provided by the admonitions against pilfering addressed to the men involved in gold production in the Redesiyeh inscription of Sety I:

"Was das Gold betrifft, das Flezsch der Gitter, so ist es nzcht Eure Sache. Seine (Amun's) Augen [wachen] iiber seine Sachen. Sie lieben nwcht Unrecht an ihrem Besztz'" 13).

Further documentary evidence of temple involvement in the pro- duction of gold is provided by Koenig' 14).

110) pBM 10052, 11,4ff. 111) Some of this is in the form of metal vessels. 112) pTurin Cat. 1881, recto, line above cols. I-II. Quoted by Peet, Griffith

Studies, 124f. Now published in Kitchen, Ramesside Inscriptions VI, 612. 113) Transl. S. Schott, Kanais. Der Tempel Sethos' I in Wadi Mia. Nachrichten der

Akademie der Wissenschaften in Goettingen (1961), Nr 6, 150 Lepsius, Denkmaeler, 140, 3-4.

114) Yvan Koenlg, "Livraisons d'or et de galene au tr6sor du temple d'Amon sous la XXe dynastle: document A, partie inf6reure", in BIFAO 83, 249ff.

260 E. W. CASTLE

On the question of monopoly in general, Kemp is of the opinion that no monopolies of natural resources were held by the Crown or

Temple. To support this, he points to the fact that there was no shor-

tage of alabaster for the vase makers of Middle Egypt in the First Intermediate Period. He means to demonstrate that it would have been possible for private individuals to exploit the quarries at Hatnub without expeditions organized under royal control. Royal monopoly is ipso facto precluded in a period of collapse of royal authority, but who can say that any pre-existing royal monopoly had not been assumed by a local ruler? In point of fact, just such opportunities are the fuel of secessionism.

How gold found its way into public circulation becomes a point of interest. There is certain evidence for one of the sources in the tomb

robbery papyri where even the names, affiliations and origin of traders receiving stolen tomb furniture are recorded, and the

Redesiyeh inscription above implies that pilfering occurred in the course of production. However, there must have been legitimate sources for gold also, otherwise the mere possession of it would have been incriminating. Another source of gold appears in the Nauri

inscription where we learn by implication that fortress commanders were wont to exact imposts in gold from vessels coming from Nubia. An examination of the tax lists in Rekhmire's inscriptions115) shows that while the amount of gold paid as tax on offices ranges from about 5 to 6 deben, the commandant of the fortress of Elephantine pays no less than 40, the commandant of the fortress of Bigeh 20, while the next highest amount of gold is a mere 8 deben paid by the mayor of Edfu. Clearly officials of the southern frontier were in the best posi- tion to obtain gold. It is clear from the Semnah inscription of Sesostris

III16) that a trading post existed north of the Second Cataract during the Middle Kingdom. Another market existed at Aswan, and it is not

difficult to see Egyptian traders obtaining gold directly or indirectly

115) Breasted, Ancient Records II. 717ff. 116) Berlin 14753 = Sethe, Lesestiicke, 84f.

SHIPPING AND TRADE IN RAMESSIDE EGYPT 261

from officials at markets such as these in exchange for luxury items from the north. Although this information pertains to the Middle

Kingdom and the Eighteenth Dynasty, it seems safe to conclude that

trading remained intense in the south during the Ramesside period. Officials stationed in Nubian outposts such as Nauri would have been

eager customers for luxuries from home, and as we have seen, had

access to the gold with which to pay for them. As noted above, a passage from pTurin 188111") concerns gold,

silver and copper provided by a temple for the rations of the

Necropolis:

"Receipt of the hd from the deputy Minkhau of the temple of Isis for the rations of the Necropolis: good gold 1 kite, equivalent to 5 khar (of corn); silver 4 kite, equivalent to 6 khar; a kerchief18), equivalent to 2 khar; and 20 deben of copper, equivalent to 5 khar."

These metals, together with a garment, are classified as hd which, apart from its primary meaning of "silver", has acquired the extended meaning of "payment", all sorts of commodities being capable of inclusion under this term "9). While otherwise it is com- mon for commodities to be valued in terms of metal for purposes of

barter, here the metals are curiously valued in equivalents of khar of

grain. Cerny, in contradiction of his previous statement that the workmen of the Necropolis "were all paid entirely in kind"•120)

quotes this passage as evidence that the workmen received metal in lieu of the usual form of payment 121). However, it is not necessary to assume that the metal actually reached the men. In view of the fact

that grain equivalents are given for the quantities of metal, it may well be that the metal was provided for the purpose of purchasing the usual grain rations from some third party, more likely a private

117) Peet, Griffith Studies, 124f. Now published in Kitchen, Ramesstde Inscriptions VI, 612.

118) On zdg, see Janssen, Commodity Prices, 282ff.

119) Cf. Janssen, Commodity Prices, 499ff.

120) Prices and Wages, 916.

121) Prices and Wages, 905.

262 E. W. CASTLE

individual or trader than another temple. On the other hand, the

grain equivalents may indicate the usual amounts of grain payments which are being supplanted by payments in metal for some reason, perhaps on account of a temporary shortage of grain. In any case, the metal must be seen as a form of currency.

. By itself, the fact that hd came to acquire the extended meaning of

"payment" suggests that the exchange of silver in commercial tran- sactions was or had been general practice.

While a barter system is everywhere in evidence in the Deir el Medinah ostraca, it seems clear that elsewhere trade was also con- ducted by means of metal exchange. Kemp too concludes that "we should accept that a substantial amount of gold and silver was always in circulation" 122).

The large quantity of ostraca dealing with the economic activities of the inhabitants of Deir el Medinah has survived as a result of the

unique convergence of a number of factors. Because of the skills

required for the decoration of Royal tombs, the inhabitants of the

village enjoyed an abnormally high literacy rate. The location of the

village within the Theban necropolis provided access to an ample supply of limestone flakes suitable for writing, while the dry condi- tions encouraged preservation of their inscriptions. Ostraca are not common in Egypt outside the Theban necropolis.

This volume of evidence from Deir el Medinah, however, may not

speak accurately for the rest of the country. While the necropolis area was heavily policed, the village itself was surrounded by a wall and accessed by way of a single, guarded gate. Although there is no direct evidence for it, it might well have been thought prudent for the authorities to discourage commerce in precious metal on the part of the workmen as a security measure so that any trade in precious metal became ipso facto evidence of tomb robbery. While the tomb

robbery papyri show that trade in stolen metal did indeed occur, they also constitute evidence of its detection.

122) Kemp, Ancrent Egypt, 259

SHIPPING AND TRADE IN RAMESSIDE EGYPT 263

If metal was used as a means of exchange, there arises the question of how this exchange was carried out in practice.

Exchange: Standards and Practice

The basic unit of weight by which metals were measured was the deben. Another unit frequently encountered in the New Kingdom was

variously called sct, snc(t), or snzw, which has been shown to be

equivalent in value to 1/12 of the deben'23). This unit has been conven-

tionally translated as "piece" to avoid any suggestion as to its actual form 124). James 125) prefers the even more neutral translation "unit".

It appears that precious metals were frequently handled in the con- venient form of rings. Representations of gold and silver in this form

appear in the tombs of Rekhmire126) and Sobekhotep 27), where the

rings often appear to be open and linked in the form of chains. Actual finds of treasure show that silver was also handled in this form"28).

Weigall has produced evidence of an Old Kingdom writing of the word deben in the context of weights where it is written with a circular

determinative, which may also stand as an abbreviated form of the word in other examples. In at least one instance this is more

specifically depicted as an open ring"29). Since the primary lexical value of dbn appears to involve

circularity"30), it appears that originally in the context of metals the

123) Gardiner, "Four Account Papyri of the 18th Dynasty from Kahun", in Zeitschrift fiir Aegyptische Sprache und Altertumskunde 43 (1906), 45

124) Peet, The Unit of Value sCty, 199

125) James, Pharaoh's People, 268, n. 20 126) Percy E. Newberry, The Life of Rekhmzra. Westminster- Constable, 1900,

Plate V

127) British Museum No. 921 See James, Pharaoh's People, Plate 10 128) The Tod treasure is published in F Bisson de la Rocque, Le Trisor de Tod.

Cairo, 1953 Also in Centenaire de l'Institut FranCats d'Archeologze Orientale. Service des Antiquites de l'Egypte. Le Caire: 1981, 104ff. Also in Un Sikcle de Fouilles Franfaises en Egypte, 1880-1980 l'Ecole du Caire (IFAO), 1981, 144ff. The Tell el Amarna treasure trove is published in H. Frankfort and J D S. Pendlebury, City of Akhenaten II: London, 1933 See particularly Plate XLIII, 4.

129) Weigall, Weights and Balances, iii. 130) Wb. 5 436, 6ff.

264 E. W. CASTLE

word deben indicated one of these rings, perhaps acquiring a fixed

weight which later became a standard. Peet 131) rejects Weigall's conclusions out of hand, but the evidence

is not so easily disposed of. In fact, Peet himself vacillates on this

question in a footnote 132). Certainly a stone weight inscribed # , "belonging to a sem-priest named Ammpy (sic) and also

Ptahenkau" 33) can hardly be dismissed out of hand as "a suppose (sic) writing of the word deben" 34). Weigall's conclusions require the existence of an Old Kingdom deben weighing 13-14 grams as opposed to that of the New Kingdom which weighed about 91 grams.

James has commented on the fact that the 11th Dynasty farmer Hekanakhte proposed payment of rent for land using "24 copper debens"135). Baer136) translates without comment "24 deben of cop- per", but as James points out '37), this would have been written hmty dbn 24, not, as we have here, dbn hmty 24. In this case it seems clear that what are to be understood are not merely units of weight, but concrete objects. The implications of this cannot be easily dismissed. Consideration has to be given to the possibility that what we have here may be the coincidence of original and derived meaning in the form of copper rings perhaps weighing one deben each138). Peet 139) has

suggested that ~ct originally referred to a metal object rather than to an abstract measure of value.

131) The Unit of Value SCty, 199 132) Note 2. 133) Weigall, Wezghts and Balances, iv

134) Peet, The Unit of Value Isty, 199 135) T G. H. James, The Hekanakhte Papers and Other Early Middle Kingdom

Documents. New York, 1962, 44, n. 57 It is to be noted that Helck (Altaegyptzsche Aktenkunde des 3. und 2. Jahrtausends vor Christus. Muenchner Aegyptologische Studien 31, p. 139f.), misrepresents James' position here. The sign that James reads for hmty, "copper", Helck incorrectly understands him to read as a second determinative for dbn.

136) JAOS 83 (1963), 9 137) James, Hekanakhte, 44, n. 57

138) Cf. James, Hekanakhte, 118. 139) Peet, "The Egyptian Words for 'Money', 'Buy' and 'Sell', in Studies

Presented to F Ll. Griffith, 122, n. 1.a.

SHIPPING AND TRADE IN RAMESSIDE EGYPT 265

The word ict has been discussed at some length. This word seems to have existed alongside a synonym Inc/t, in addition to another writ- ten sniw 140). inC appears with Ict as a synonym in two versions of Spell 129 of the Book of the Dead141). In the Hekanakhte letters, the

writing of ict appears to have been twice emended to sn ct by the addi- tion of n, in one case written inside the S of ~ct42). The words seem

to have been so closely identified that vct has been claimed by Drioton to have arisen from a graphically abbreviated spelling of snCt through the elision of n, to which he compares the writing of rmt, "man" with-

out m. Wente also comments on "the close association, if not iden-

tity, of nnct

and Ct'" 43), but rejects Drioton's hypothesis, tentatively suggesting instead a possible dialectical variation.

Wente cites occurrences of inC, sct and sCty determined with the seal

sign, but notes another example in the hieratic where the circular car- touche sign is possible. Any relationship of the seal sign to "ring" has been rejected by Peet '44) on the grounds that the seal sign originally represented a cylinder seal attached to a cord 145). However, it is ques- tionable whether this distinction was scrupulously maintained by the Egyptians of the later periods.

The word _dbct, "seal"146), having clear lexical association with "finger" is determined variously with the (cylinder) seal, the circular cartouche and the "block" sign, the last of which, as Wente notes, is used as a second determinative of inC in Spell 129 of the Book of the Dead in the Tomb of Ramesses VI, and which he suggests "may also be related to the metal lump sign used to determine the Old

140) Jac. J Janssen, Commodity Prices from the Ramesside Period. Leiden: E. J Brill, 1975, 102ff.

141) Etienne Drioton, "Un document sur la vie chere ' Thebes au debut de la

XVIII dynastle", in Bulletin de la Societi Franpaise d'Egyptologze, No. 12 (February 1953), 15-17

142) James, Hekanakhte, 113

143) Edward F Wente, "A Note on the Eloquent Peasant, B I, 13-15", in JNES 24 (1965), 106.

144) Peet's position is misrepresented by Janssen (Commodity Prices, 102). 145) Peet, The Unit of Value Fty, 198.

146) Wb. 5.566,6.

266 E. W. CASTLE

Kingdom ict, regarded as a concrete unit of value" 147). Wente148) believes with Piankoff that the in c of Spell 129 of the Book of the Dead means "ring" or "seal". As 6ern? has noted, a word written vCt

"occurs several times in an 18th dynasty magical text, where it seems to designate the flat "seal" of a signet ring"149).

The Wb. gives only the translation "seal" for dbct. However, Gar- diner translates it as "signet-ring" ''150) which translation is supported by a Ptolemaic writing W of the verb dbc'51), "to seal". The related Hebrew tbCtl52) also carries the meaning of "signet ring" 15s) as well as of rings designed to attach various objects for suspension from rods or chains.

Apart from this, even the cylinder seal may be found mounted on a circular metal bracelet to be worn on the arm, possibly complicating the later understanding of the original significance of the sign as a

cylinder seal hanging from a cord. Such a mounted cylinder seal was found on the arm of Sheshonq 11154).

The Hebrew .tbct

further indicates one of the forms in which gold is presented to the temple in Numbers 31:50, where it appears in association with )sCdh, "armlet", smyd, "bracelet" 155), Cgyl, "ring",

147) Wente, JNES 24, 107

148) Wente, JNES, 106. 149) Cerny, Prices and Wages, 912.

150) Gardiner, Sign-list S20, in Gardiner, Grammar, 3rd. ed., 506.

151) Wb. 5.566.

152) BDB, 371, b. The word is probably an Egyptian loan word rather than a derivative of Hebrew tbc, "to seal" which is best explained as another loan from

Egyptian dbc (Wb. 5.566,12). The Egyptian dbct is attested from the Old Kingdom. Cf. Thomas O Lambdin, "Egyptian Loan Words in the Old Testament", in

JAOS 73 (1953), 151.

153) Gen. 41:41-42: "Pharaoh said to Joseph, "Behold, I have set you over the whole land of Egypt." Pharaoh took his ring (tbCt) from his hand, and put it upon Joseph's hand.. "

154) Colin A. Hope, Gold of the Pharaohs. Melbourne: Museum of Victoria, 1988, Plate 80. The seal itself is mounted on a spindle so that it might be used, but it is not Egyptian and is to be considered decorative rather than functional.

155) For this and the preceding see K. Galling, Biblisches Reallexikon. Tiibingen: J C.B. Mohr (Paul Siebeck), 1977, 285; Abb. 75, 1-3

SHIPPING AND TRADE IN RAMESSIDE EGYPT 267

as well as kwmx, a word of unclear meaning and derivation. This seems to suggest that, as far as precious metals were concerned, the distinction between bullion and personal adornment was slightS56). The large assemblage of silver coils in the Oriental Institute Museum '57) suggests that this was also true of Mesopotamia. One of these is a coiled bar weighing sixty shekels•58). Others have smaller

pieces of wire attached as though to make up a particular weight "59). The open rings could have been cut from such spiral forms.

It appears that there existed a unit of value equivalent to 1/12 of a deben of silver, and variously called sct, vnct and snzw. Janssen has

produced strong evidence for a writing snzw applied to the same unit of value 160). However, this does not dispose of the various plene writings of s'Ct and znct. Given the sound evidence for the variant

writings, they can hardly be mutually exclusive. It seems necessary therefore to accept the existence of three competing readings.

Peet'61) puzzles at some length over the fact that 'ct, although "beyond all doubt ... a perfectly concrete unit, and in fact a fixed

weight" should be accompanied by the "abstract determinative"

.-w . In point of fact, .-

does not always determine abstract

concepts. In ..

)c, "Schriftstuck" (Wb. 4.418,9) the determinative represents a concrete papyrus roll. Its use in

~ ct, "knife" (Wb. 4.417,8) is perhaps analogous. The analogy is clear enough if we consider that what 0

V ,, iVct represents is a piece of silver bar cut from a parent coil of bar stock,

156) The necklaces of gold beads represented in the tomb of Rekhmire point in the same direction. See Percy E. Newberry, The Life of Rekhmzra. Westminster- Constable, 1900, Plate V

157) Oriental Institute, A 9507, A 9509-A 9518, A 9527-A 9530, A 9540, A 9543-A 9632, A 9637 These objects were pointed out to me by Richard H. Beal.

158) A 9543 159) A 9571, A 9574. 160) Janssen, Commodity Prices, 102ff. Helck's characterisation of Janssen's

reading as "kaum wahrscheznlich" (Lexikon der Aegyptologie III.1207, n. 35) is unjustified. Janssen's reading is sound. Helck's reading (ibid) of hnct in the Haus- kaufurkunde (Urk. 1.157) should be corrected to fct.

161) The Unit of Value iCty, 197

268 E. W. CASTLE

in the same way that a letter is cut from a roll of papyrus. By this

interpretation, s't, deriving from sc , "to cut", would refer to its being cut from a parent roll of metal. Vycichl 162) translates as "coupure".

According to Janssen's observations, the writing svCtls'nct is sup- planted after the Eighteenth Dynasty by sniw, and he believes that all

writings of .ic-" in ostraca and papyri of the Nineteenth and Twentieth Dynasties should be read as sniw. He states: "it has to be stressed that nowhere in the ostraca and account papyri of the Nine- teenth and Twentieth Dynasty I have (sic) come across even the faintest trace of a reading 'cty or incty'' 63).

It would appear then, that after the Eighteenth Dynasty, ict is sup- planted by another word also potentially derived from a verb mean-

ing "to cut", namely sn (Wb. 3.456,15), This is supported by the observation of Wb. 4.415,13 that the verb Sc, ",to cut" was in the pro- cess of dropping out of usage during the New Kingdom, to be sup- planted by s'Cd (Wb. 4.422). It is of considerable importance to this

study that it is therefore indicated that the connection between s~, "to cut" and ict was never lost sight of in the minds of the Egyptians, and that whatever standard of weight may have applied to this word, its connection with some tangible metal object or coupure was always maintained.

As stated above, the ctl/inct or sniw was equivalent to 1/12th of a deben. However, no silver rings of this weight are found in the Tell el Amarna hoard. Those in the Tod treasure hoard have unfor-

tunately been weighed in their connected groups rather than as

separate objects. Nevertheless, no discernible system is apparent there either.

During the development of coinage, it became necessary to secure the integrity of coins from dishonest paring of the metal. For this

reason, coins of valuable metals came to be milled around the edge.

162) W Vycichl, "La shat, etalon mon6taire de I'Egypte Pharaonlque", in Bulletin de la Socziti d'Egyptologie, Genave, vol. 3, 1980, 27ff.

163) Janssen, Commodity Prices, 103-104.

SHIPPING AND TRADE IN RAMESSIDE EGYPT 269

The application of such a device to protect the integrity of a metal bar of fixed weight would probably be less successful, and consequently metal used in exchange would certainly have been weighed in the course of transactions. It is not difficult to see that any rings or bars of fixed weight, if they ever existed in anything but theory, would have been subjected to considerable cutting in the course of commer- cial exchange.

The existence of attempts to protect the integrity of rings or twisted bars of fixed weight should perhaps not be rejected out of hand. Three of the metal rings in the Tell el Amarna hoard are reported to have incised designs on the ends'64). Unfortunately the publication does not give the weights of these pieces separately.

Metal hoards containing open rings and scrap similar to those from Tell el Amarna and Tod have been found at Ugarit 65). One of these consists of rings and scrap of electrum166).

In assessing the evidence, Cerny came to the conclusion that the

sct "was a flat, round piece of metal 1/12 deben, that is about 7.6 grams, in weight, possibly with an inscription to indicate this

weight or the name of the issuing authority", adding "If so, the

'piece' was practically a coin"1 67). However, if this were correct, it would be strange, as Janssen '68) observes, that no such objects have been found.

The evidence seems to suggest the existence at some point of open rings of silver having a weight fixed at 1/12 deben which was employed as a standard unit of weight equivalent to the Assyrian shekel169), the words sct and sniw being descriptive of their physical nature. Since,

164) H. Frankfort and J D S. Pendlebury, The City of Akhenaten, Part III, 60, and Plate XLIII, 4. It can best be seen in the photograph reproduced by James in Pharaoh's People, Plate 11.

165) F.-A. Claude Schaeffer, in Syria 13 (1932), Iff., pl. IX, lower right, and pl. XVI.

166) F.-A. Claude Schaeffer, in Syria 16 (1935), 144f. and fig. 6. 167) 6ern', Prices and Wages, 912. 168) Janssen, Commodity Prices, 105 169) The Old Kingdom sct of Urk. 1.157 may have been of different value.

270 E. W. CASTLE

however, the integrity of these rings would have been difficult to maintain against dishonesty and the need for fractional values in

practice, and would consequently have been subject to much

weighing, it would no longer have been either possible or necessary to maintain the fixed weight of the rings. Nevertheless, the standard would have been maintained by weighing. Weigall cites several inscribed examples of weights of this standard 170).

Conclusions

The impression gained from this examination of shipping and trade is of an economy highly centralized around the great institu- tions of Temple and Crown. In terms of administration, the distinc- tion between the institutions remain unclear. We find officials of the Crown responsible for the collection of Temple income, and Temple institutions cooperating between themselves and the Crown to obtain efficient use of resources. An overall impression is gained of a highly stratified administrative structure separated vertically into con-

tiguous departments of Temple and Crown with lateral movement of officials common. The situation is compounded by the changing political relationship between the Crown, the military and the High Priesthood of Amun during this period.

An efficient redistribution system seems to have functioned both

through and outside the great institutions through the agency of traders, attached to temples and private. Gold, silver and copper were used by these as a means of exchange, as well as barter in other

commodities, as for example in the sale of slaves in pCairo 65739. Private ownership of boats is certain, and private ownership of vessels

plying trade with Syria probable, though subject to official imposts. In terms of the relationship between officials and populace, the

various royal decrees attest considerable power to commandeer or

requisition on the part of the bureaucracy and the army which was

170) Weigall, Weights and Balances, xii.

SHIPPING AND TRADE IN RAMESSIDE EGYPT 271

sometimes abused, leading to frequent disputes. Official policy seems to have encouraged private ownership of boats and made use of such

private vessels. While evidently subject to occasional requisitioning, private owners seem to have been remunerated for use of their

vessels, and fishermen are seen taking advantage of an official when an opportunity presented itself. It appears certain that a considerable

degree of private enterprise existed alongside an extensive

bureaucracy, the latter differentiated mainly nominally according to divine or royal affiliation.

ADDENDUM

Having read a draft of this paper, Professor John A. Brinkman advises me that the Mesopotamian silver coils in the Oriental Institute Museum have been published by Marvin A. Powell: A Con- tribution to the History of Money in Mesopotamia przor to the Invention of Coinage, in Festschrift Lubor Matous', vol. II, eds. B. Hru'ka and G. Ko-

mor6czy = Assyriologia V, Budapest, 1978 (appeared 1981), 211-243. Powell's observations, working with the Mesopotamian evidence, support conclusions reached in this paper from the Egyptian evidence.

Powell (p. 234) notes that E. Sollberger, discussing the use of silver

rings in Ur III texts, had already suggested that "the rings in ques- tion would be similar to those helicoidal rings well known from

North-European tombs of the Early Middle Ages. Payments or gifts could be made by cutting off pieces equivalent to the desired amount" (JCS 10 (1956), 23). Powell's conclusions were arrived at

independently. His attention was drawn to Sollberger's remarks by W.W. Hallo along with the latter's own note (BiOr 20 (1963), 138) on the subject subsequent to the preparation of his manuscript.

Powell notes that, as is well known, metals were traded in

Mesopotamia in a form denoted in texts by Sumerian HAR, corre-

sponding to Akkadian .ewirum (semerum, semerum). He proposes that

these words, indicating a circular object, do not mean simply "ring"

272 E. W. CASTLE

in the usual sense, but may refer to a coil of metal, this being the con- venient form in which metals were handled and used for monetary purposes. This corresponds closely to what has been proposed for the

Egyptian dbn, as to both etymology and usage. The earliest textual references to HAR known to Powell are from the

Old Akkadian period. It is unclear, as he says, whether currency or

jewellery is intended in the texts cited. However, an Old Akkadian text cited by CAD seems clear enough:

"Paid 5 (silver) coils, the price of 20 sheep" (CAD, vol. 15, p. 224, semeru, 2c: Met. Mus. 86.11.134 r. iii 11).

References to silver, gold, bronze and copper IAR are common in the Ur III period. In the texts, their nominal value may not corre-

spond exactly to their actual weight as given in the same text (Powell, p. 215). As Powell agrees, this caused no real difficulty in practice since they would have been weighed in handling (p. 217).

On the wearing of precious metals, he notes that he is not able to discover any clear-cut evidence after the Old Babylonian period where these "rings" function primarily as money as opposed to ornamentation (p. 219).

In discussing a passage from the Cruciform Monument of Mani'tu'u:

"1 talent en anneaux d'argent, 30 mines en anneaux d'or, a Shamash mon maitre, certes, je pr'sentai" (transl. Limet, Metal, p. 145: CT XXXII, no. 91022 (pl. 4), XI, 1. 5-8 and 25-28),

Powell describes this monument as "apparently an Old Babylonian forgery" (p. 219). Sollberger, while concurring in its characterization as a pious fraud, has argued convincingly for a Neo-Babylonian date for this inscription (E. Sollberger, The Cruciform Monument, in

Jaarbercht ex Oriente Lux 20 (1968), 50 ff.). Powell points out that the term for "one-eighth of a shekel", bitqu,

attested from the Middle Babylonian period on, translates literally as

"a cutting" (p. 222). This corresponds to the meaning proposed for

the Egyptian .ct or sniw, if not to its weight.

SHIPPING AND TRADE IN RAMESSIDE EGYPT 273

He postulates that amounts smaller than this were paid in

fragments or scrap silver called .ibirtu which he derives from the verb

lebiru, "to break to pieces", "to shatter". The Egyptian equivalent would be hd m qnqn, "silver scrap" (Wb. 5.56,6), the verb qnqn mean-

ing "to strike", "to beat". Such scrap is found in both the Tod and Amarna hoards together with the clipped rings and, as Powell has

shown, silver was handled in the same form at Megiddo where the

published hoard consists in part of pieces which appear to have been struck from coils or rings (Powell, p. 243, pl. IIIc: OIP 62 (1948), pl. 229: Oriental Institute cat. A 18925). It becomes increasingly clear that precious metals were handled as both scrap and in the form of helicoidal rings throughout the Fertile Crescent, and that they were used as a form of currency quite early in Mesopotamia, and in Egypt certainly by the New Kingdom, and probably earlier.

On the other hand, it should be pointed out that Powell's tentative

speculations on early coinage (p. 223 ff.) are not supported by

(erny's statement which he cites (p. 226 and n. 36). This was based

on Egyptian evidence which better supports the conclusion that

precious metals in Egypt were frequently handled and used as a means of exchange in the form of rings cut from a parent coil, as Powell has successfully shown for Mesopotamia.

ABBRE VIA TIONS

AR Breasted, J H., Ancient Records of Egypt. 5 vols. New York: Russell and Russell, 1962.

BDB Francis Brown, S. R. Driver and Charles A. Briggs, A Hebrew and English Lexicon of the Old Testament Based on the Lexicon of William Gesenius. Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1972.

BiOr Bibliotheca Orientalis. Leiden: 1943- CAD The Assyrian Dictionary of the Oriental Institute of the University of Chicago.

Chicago and Glfickstadt: 1956- CT Cuneiform Text from Babylonian Tablets, etc., in the Brztish Museum. London:

1896- JCS Journal of Cuneiform Studies. New Haven and Cambridge, Mass.. 1947- KRI Kitchen, K. A., Ramesside Inscriptions. Oxford: Blackwell (1975-). KTU M. Dietrich, O Loretz, J Sanmartin, Die Keilalphabetischen Texte aus Ugarit,

I. Neukirchen-Vluyn, 1976.

274 E. W. CASTLE

LEM Gardiner, A. H., Late-Egyptian Miscellanies. Bibliotheca Aegyptiaca VII. Brussels: Fondation Egyptologique Reine Elisabeth, 1937 Caminos, Ricardo A., Late-Egyptzan Miscellanies. Brown Egyptologzcal Studies I. London: Oxford University Press, 1954.

LRL Cerny J., Late Ramesside Letters. Bibliotheca Aegyptiaca IX. Brussels: Fonda- tion Egyptologique Reine Elisabeth, 1939

OIP Oriental Institute Publicatzons. Chicago: 1924- PRU Le Palais Royal d'Ugarat (vols. II, V, VI). Publ. sous la direction de Claude

F -A., Schaeffer RAD Gardiner, A. H., Ramesside Administratzve Documents. London: Oxford

University Press, 1948. Wb. Erman, A., und Grapow, H., Wdrterbuch der Aegyptischen Sprache. Berlin:

Akademie-Verlag, 1982.

BIBLIOGRAPHY

The Assyrian Dictionary of the Oriental Institute of the Universzty of Chicago. Chicago and Gliickstadt: 1956-

Baer, K., "The Low Price of Land in Ancient Egypt", inJARCE I (1962), 25 ff. Bisson de la Rocque, F., Le Trisor de Tod. Cairo: 1953 Breasted, J H., Ancient Records of Egypt. 5 vols. New York: Russell and Russell,

1962. Caminos, R. A., Late-Egyptian Miscellanies. Brown Egyptological Studies I. Lon-

don: 1954. Centenaire de l'lInstitut Franfais d'Archiologie Ortentale. Service des Antiquit's de l'Egypte. Le

Caire: 1981, p. 104 ff. 6erny, J., Late Ramesside Letters. Bibliotheca Aegyptiaca IX. Brussels: Fondation

Egyptologique Reme Elisabeth, 1939 -, "Prices and Wages in Egypt in the Ramesside Period", in Cahzers d'histozre mon-

diale I (1954), 903 ff. Cunchillos, J -L., Textes Ougaritiques, tome II. Correspondence. Lettirature Anciennes du

Proche-Orzent. Paris: Editions du Cerf, 1989 Condon, V., "Two Account Papyn of the Late 18th Dynasty (Brooklyn 35 1453

A and B)", in Revue d'Egyptologze 35, 57 ff. Craigie, Peter C., Ugarit and the Old Testament. Grand Rapids: Eerdmans, 1983,

p. 41. Dairaines, S., Un socialisme d'itat quinze sidcles avant J Chr L 'Egypte iconomique sous

la XVIIIe dynastie pharaonzque. Pans: 1934. Davies, N de G., Two Ramesside Tombs at Thebes. New York: 1927 Drioton, Etienne, "Un document sur la vie

chore '

Thebes au debut de la XVIII dynastie", in Bulletin de la Sociiti Franfaise d'Egyptologie, No. 12 (February 1953), pp. 15-17

Edgerton, W F., "The Government and the Governed in the Egyptian Empire", in JNES 6 (1947), 152f.

Edwards, I. E. S., The Pyramids of Egypt. New York: Viking Penguin, 1986.

SHIPPING AND TRADE IN RAMESSIDE EGYPT 275

Erichsen, W., Papyrus Harrms I. Bibliotheca Aegyptiaca V Brussels: Fondation Egyptologique Reine Elisabeth, 1933

Faulkner, R. 0., A Conczse Dictionary of Middle Egyptian. Oxford: Griffith Institute, 1981.

Frankfort, H., and Pendlebury, J D S., City ofAkhenaten (3 vols.). London, 1933. Gardiner, A. H., Ancient Egyptian Onomastica (2 vols.). Oxford: Oxford University

Press, 1947 -, Egypt of the Pharaohs. Oxford University Press: 1964. -, Egyptian Grammar Oxford University Press: Third Edition, 1957 -, "Four Account Papyri of the Eighteenth Dynasty from Kahun", in Zeitschrift

fiir Aegyptische Sprache und Altertumskunde (1906), 27ff. -, Late-Egyptzan Miscellanies. Bibliotheca Aegyptiaca VII. Brussels: Fondation

Egyptologique Reine Elisabeth, 1937 -, Ramesszde Admintstrative Documents. London: Oxford University Press, 1948. -, "Ramesside Texts Relating to the Taxation and Transport of Corn", JEA 27

(1941), pp. 19-73 -, The Wilbour Papyrus (4 vols.). London: Oxford University Press, 1952. Hallo, William W., Review of: Henri Limet, Le travail du

mrtal au pays de Sumer au

temps de la IIIe dynastie d'Ur, in Bibliotheca Orentalis XX, No. 3/4, Mai/Juli 1963, 136ff.

Heichelheim, F M., An Ancient Economic History from the Palaeolithic Age to the Migra- ttons of the Germanzc, Slavic and Arabic Natwns, Vol. I. Leiden, 1958.

-, "Recent Discoveries In Ancient Economic History The Wilbour Papyrus" Historza 2 (1953), 129f.

Helck, H. W., Zur Verwaltung des Mittleren und Neuen Rezchs. Regzster. Probleme der Aegyptologie, 1975

-, Materzalien zur Wirtschaftsgeschichte des Neuen Reichs. Wiesbaden: Akademie der Wissenschaften und der Literatur in Mainz, 1961

-, Wirtschaftsgeschichte des Alten Aegypten im 3. und 2. Jahrtausend vor Chr , 1975 Heltzer, M., "Royal Economy in Ancient Ugarit", in E. Lipinski, State and Temple

Economy, vol. II. Orientalia Lovaniensta Analecta 6, Leuven, 1979 -, "The Metal Trade of Ugarit and the Problem of Transportation of Commer-

cial Goods", in Iraq 39 (1977), 205ff. Hope, Colin A., Gold of the Pharaohs. Melbourne: Museum of Victoria, 1988. James, T G H., Pharaoh's People. London: The Bodley Head, 1984. -, The Hekanakhte Papers and Other Early Middle Kingdom Documents. New York, 1962. Janssen, Jac. J., "The R61e of the Temple in the Egyptian Economy during the

New Kingdom", in E. Lipinski, State and Temple Economy in the Ancient Near East, vol. II. Orientalia Lovantensta Analecta 6. Leuven, 1979

-, "Two Variant Accounts", in Varia Aegyptiaca I (1985), 109 -, "Agrarian Admintstration in Egypt During the Twentieth Dynasty ", in Bibliotheca Orien-

talis XLIII, 3/4 (1986), 351ff. -, Commodity Prices from the Ramesside Period. Leiden: E. J Brill, 1975

-, Prolegomena to the Study of Egypt's Economic History during the New Kingdom. Studien zur Altaegyptischen Kultur Band 3 ed. Altenmueller u. Wildung, 1975, 127ff.

-, Two Ancient Egyptian Ship's Logs. Leiden: E. J Brill, 1961. Kees, H., Aegypten, Kulturgeschzchte des alten Orzents I. Mfinchen: 1933

276 E. W. CASTLE

-, Ancient Egypt: A Cultural Topography. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1961.

Kemp, Barry J., Anczent Egypt: Anatomy of a Civilization. London: Routledge, 1989. Kitchen, K. A., Ramesside Inscriptions. Oxford: Blackwell (1975-). Koenig, Yvan, "Livraisons d'or et de galene au tresor du temple d'Amon sous la

XXe dynastie: document A, partie inf6rieure", in BIFAO 83, 249ff. Kruchten, J -M., Le Dicret d'Horemheb Brussels: Editions de l'Universite de Brux-

elles, 1981. Lambdin, Thomas O., "Egyptian Loan Words in the Old Testament", inm JAOS

73 (1953), 145ff. Lichtheim, M., "The Naucratis Stela Once Again", in Studies in Honor of George

H. Hughes. Studies tn Ancient Oriental Civilizattons 39 (1976), 139ff. Limet, H., Le Travail du Mital au Pays de Sumer au Temps de la IIIe Dynastie d'Ur

Paris: Societe d'Edition "Les Belles Lettres", 1960. Mariette, A., Catalogue Giniral des Monuments d'Abydos, Paris: 1880. Reprinted by

Ltr-Verlag, Wiesbaden, 1982. -, Monuments divers recueillis en Egypte et en Nubze, with text by G Maspero. Paris:

1872-1889 Megally, Mounir, "A Propos du Papyrus CGC 58070 (Papyrus Boulaq XI)", in

Bulletin de l'institut francais d'archiologie ornentale 74 (1974), 161ff.

-, Constdirattons sur les variations et la transformations desformes des signes hIeratiques dans le Papyrus E. 3226 du Louvre. Bibliotheque d'Etude, tome 49 Paris: S.I.D.A.B., 1969

-, "Le Papyrus CGC 58081 Suite du Papyrus CGC 58070 (Papyrus Boulaq XI)", in Bulletin de l'institut franfazs d'archiologie orzentale 75 (1975), 165ff.

-, Le papyrus hiiratzque comptable E. 3226 du Louvre. Bibliotheque d'Etude, tome 53. Paris: S.I.D.A.B., 1969

', Notions de comptabiliti propos du Papyrus E. 3226 du Musie du Louvre. Bibliotheque d'Etude, tome 72. Paris: Institut frangais d'archeologie orientale du Caire, 1977

-, Recherches sur l'iconomze, I'admmnstratzon et la comptabiliti igyptienne. Bibliotheque d'Etude, tome 71. Paris: Institut frangais d'arch6ologie orentale du Caire 1977

Menu, Bernadette, Le rigzme jurdique des terres et du personnel attachie'i la terre dans le Papyrus Wilbour Lille: 1970, 139ff.

Moran, William L., Les Lettres d'el-Amarna: Correspondence diplomatique du pharaon. Paris: Les Editions du Cerf, 1987

Morenz, S., Prestige und Wirtschaften im Alten Aegypten. Munich, 1969 Newberry, Percy E., The Life of Rekhmira. Westminster- Constable, 1900. Peet, T E., "The Egyptian Words for 'Money', 'Buy', and 'Sell' ", in Studies

Presented to F Ll. Griffith. -, The Great Tomb Robberies of the Twentieth Egyptian Dynasty, 2 vols. Oxford Univer-

sity Press, 1930 -, The Unit of Value sCty in Papyrus Bulaq 11, in Melanges Maspero I (Mimoires de

S'institut franfats d'archiologie orientale 66/1), 185ff. Pflueger, K., "The Edict of King Horemhab", in JNES 5 (1946), 260f. Pleyte, W and Rossi, F., Papyrus de Turin. Leiden: 1869-1876.

SHIPPING AND TRADE IN RAMESSIDE EGYPT 277

Powell, M. A., "A Contribution to the History of Money in Mesopotamia prior to the Invention of Money", in Festschrift Lubor Matous', eds. B. Hru'ka and G. Komor6czy = Assyriologia V, Budapest, 1978 (appeared 1981), 211-243

Relneke, Walter F., "Waren die gwtyw wtrklich Kaufleute?" Altorientalische Forschungen 6 (1979), 5ff.

Roeder, G., Urkunden zur Religion des alien Aegypten, Jena, 1915 Schaedel, H. D., Die Listen des grossen Papyrus Harris. Aegyptische Abhandlung 6 (1936),

Leipzig. Schaeffer, F -A. Claude, "Les Fouilles de Minet-el-Beida et de Ras-Shamra:

Troisieme Campagne", in Syria XIII (1932), Iff. -, "Les Fouilles de Ras Shamra-Ugarit: Sixieme Campagne", in Syria XVI

(1935), 141ff. Sethe, K., Aegyptische Lesestiicke. Leipzig: J C. Heinrichs'sche Buchhandlung,

1928.

-, Urkunden des Alten Rezchs, Band I. Leipzig, 1933 Un Sidcle de Fouilles Franpaises en Egypte, 1880-1980. l'Ecole du Caire (IFAO), 1981,

p. 144ff.

Sollberger, E., "The Cruciform Monument", inJaarberzcht ex Oriente Lux 20 (1968), 50ff.

-,"Selected Texts from American Collections", in Journal of Cuneiform Studies 10 (1956), 11ff.

Spiegelberg, W., Rechnungen aus der Zeit Setts I. Strassbourg: K. J Truebner, 1896. Stuchevsky, I. A., Zemledel'tsy gosudarstvennogo khozyazstva drevnego Egzpta epokhi

Ramessidov (The Cultivators of the State Economy in Ancient Egypt durnng the Ramesside Period). Moskva: Izdatel'stvo "Nauka", 1982. Review- Janssen, Agrarian Administratzon in Egypt during the Twentieth Dynasty, in Bibliotheca Orientalis XLIII, 3/4 (1986), 351ff.

Studies Presented to F Ll. Griffith. London: Egypt Exploration Society, 1932. Vycichl, W., "La shat, etalon monetaire de l'Egypte Pharaonique", in Bulletin de

la Sociiti d'Egyptologze, Geneve, vol. 3, 1980, p. 27ff. Weigall, A., Weights and Balances. Catalogue gindral des antzquitis igyptiennes du Musie

du Caire, 1908. Wente, Edward F., "A Note on the Eloquent Peasant, B I, 13-15", in JNES 24

(1965), p. 105ff.