Záchrana Itálie a EURA (dokument v AJ)

download Záchrana Itálie a EURA (dokument v AJ)

of 15

Transcript of Záchrana Itálie a EURA (dokument v AJ)

  • 8/3/2019 Zchrana Itlie a EURA (dokument v AJ)

    1/15

    ECONOMICS RESEARCH 24 November 20

    PLEASE SEE ANALYST CERTIFICATIONS AND IMPORTANT DISCLOSURES STARTING AFTER PAGE 12

    EURO THEMES

    What will it take to save Italy (and the euro)? We recently argued that Italian policy reforms alone would not suffice to bring

    Italy out of the crisis; the country is also likely to need an external financial

    shield to protect against destabilizing market dynamics. We now ask how large

    this shield may need to be, and whether it is plausible that the required funding

    can be mobilized.

    Italys potential demand for financial support cannot be taken in isolation, sinceother European sovereigns have already received substantial support from Europe

    and the IMF. Requirements to support Spain also need to be considered.

    We do not think that Italy or Spain need to be taken out of financial markets, asIreland, Portugal and Greece were. Neither country has lost access to markets;

    financial support should be designed to protect market access, not compensate

    for its loss. And the larger the potential source of contingent finance, the

    smaller the likelihood that this financial war chest will need to be used.

    While there is no scientifically precise way to estimate the contingent fundingrequired to protect market access, we think 18-24 months of public financing

    requirements is a reasonable benchmark. This amounts to a range of EUR 500

    billion to EUR 800 billion for Italy and Spain together.

    It is possible to come up with joint contributions from the EFSF, the IMF and theECB (via the SMP program) that add up to this amount. But the funding is not in

    place for now, and things may need to get (even) worse before it is catalyzed.

    The constraint that the ECB operate only in the secondary market does not

    eliminate, but does weaken the force of its contribution to the program.

    The odds of success in managing the euro area crisis depend to a large degreeon developing a more coherent vision of the post-crisis landscape. Both markets

    and policymakers need greater clarity on the institutional endgame of the

    European financial drama, without which markets are unlikely to settle.

    Figure 1: Italy At risk

    0

    25

    50

    75

    100

    125

    150

    175

    200

    2000 2005 2010 2015 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050

    0

    25

    50

    75

    100

    125

    150

    175

    200

    Italy

    Italy, strong policy action

    Spain

    Public debt-to-GDP (%)

    Source: Bloomberg, Barclays Capital

    Antonio Garcia Pascual

    +44 (0)20 3134 6225

    [email protected]

    Michael Gavin

    +1 212 412 5915

    [email protected]

    Piero Ghezzi

    +44 (0)20 3134 2190

    [email protected]

    Thomas Harjes

    +49 69 716 11825

    [email protected]

    www.barcap.com

  • 8/3/2019 Zchrana Itlie a EURA (dokument v AJ)

    2/15

    Barclays Capital | Euro Themes: What will it take to save Italy (and the euro)?

    24 November 2011 2

    WHAT WILL IT TAKE TO SAVE ITALY (AND THE EURO)?

    Italy Quo vadis?

    In the past week, market attention has been focused on political developments in southern

    Europe, as technocratic governments in Italy and Greece have been formed and have begun

    to organize themselves, and last weekends Spanish elections pave the way for a new

    government in that important part of the peripheral European story. These political

    developments are critical because, if successful, the new governments will revive the

    economic reforms and fiscal consolidations that are required to restore confidence.

    The major preoccupation of markets is now, of course, Italy, not because it is the only

    country that is perceived to be at risk, but because it is the biggest, and a bellwether for

    Europe. And there the new Monti government is certainly an important step in the right

    direction. Since confidence lies at the heart of the Italian debt problem, we cannot rule out

    the possibility that forceful policy actions by a new, reformist government may be enough

    to put the crisis behind us. Nonetheless, for reasons that we have recently discussed in

    some detail (Can Italy save itself?, 7 November 2011), as necessary as Italian economic

    reforms may be, we doubt that they alone will be sufficient to rehabilitate the Italian credit

    and eliminate the possibility of a confidence crisis that could overwhelm the positive effects

    of a reform agenda, however well conceived and implemented. Our read of the historical

    experience also supports the view that the self-reinforcing negative market dynamics that

    now threaten Italy are very difficult to break, and have generally required external financial

    support to provide a country that has lost market confidence with the time it needs to show

    financial markets that it is indeed solvent.

    Investors are focused on Italy for good reason; the countrys recent introduction into the

    equation raises the stakes dramatically for Europe and the world. Italy is the 7th largest

    national economy in the world and (at about EUR 1.7 trillion) its government debt

    comprises the worlds third largest bond market. An Italian credit event would have

    consequences for financial markets and the global economy that are almost literallyincalculable, because all we can know about the economic and financial costs of secondary

    and tertiary damage that would be done by an Italian default is that it would be devastating.

    This is true even if we set aside the EUR 0.7 billion in Spanish government debt that is also

    at risk, but it is hard to see an Italian event leaving the Spanish sovereign intact.

    While the danger has risen dramatically, so has the scale of the rescue operation that may

    be required to usher Italy and Spain into the safety zone. Certainly, the three previous

    EU/IMF programs cannot be replicated for Italy. Those programs were large enough to take

    the sovereigns completely out of the market for several years, while imposing tough

    conditionality. Simultaneously, the ECB has provided banks with unlimited liquidity and

    lends additional support with its securities markets programme (SMP). It would not be

    feasible to scale the financial commitments made to support Ireland, Portugal and Greeceup to Italian and Spanish size.

    Luckily, a program quite this massive is not likely to be necessary for Italy and Spain. In this

    report, we examine how much financial support may be required to assist Italy and Spain in

    the coming years of adjustment, and whether Europe (and the world) can muster the

    financial wherewithal to provide that support. The question is, in our view, pressing in part

    because pressure on French debt markets suggests to us that Europe is reaching limits in

    the capacity of fiscally stronger sovereigns to support fiscally weaker ones. Is Italy too big to

    be rescued? And if not, who has the balance sheet to save Italy?

    Italys government debt

    comprises the worlds third

    largest bond market

    Europe is reaching limits in the

    capacity of fiscally stronger

    sovereigns to support fiscally

    weaker ones

    https://live.barcap.com/go/publications/content?contentPubID=FC1763950https://live.barcap.com/go/publications/content?contentPubID=FC1763950
  • 8/3/2019 Zchrana Itlie a EURA (dokument v AJ)

    3/15

    Barclays Capital | Euro Themes: What will it take to save Italy (and the euro)?

    24 November 2011 3

    Our main concern is with Italy, but we need to put financial demands that may be

    associated with an Italian rescue operation into a broader European context that includes

    commitments already made to support Greece, Ireland and Portugal, and additional

    commitments that may be required to support Spain in the months to come. The financial

    burden associated with a rescue of Italy may be the largest to come from Europe, but the

    costs and policy risks associated with such a rescue are compounded by the fact that Italy is

    only one of the weak links in the European chain.

    What will it take?

    We briefly revisit Italys debt dynamics to understand the magnitude of the fiscal challenge

    that the government faces in light of the recent increase in bond yields, and to address once

    again the question whether a plausible adjustment effort can reverse the deterioration in the

    public debt dynamics. We also estimate potential financing needs for the next 3 years,

    which gives us some insight into the magnitude of the financing risks that confront Italy

    and Spain in the early stages of their adjustment and reform efforts, when weak market

    confidence poses the most acute risk to the reform program. In a subsequent section, we

    consider potential sources of funding, including the roles that may be played by the EFSF,

    the IMF, and the ECB.

    Italian debt dynamics redux

    We discussed Italys debt dynamics at length in June 2011 (Italy: the time to act, 21 June

    2011), before confidence in the Italian public credit began its abrupt slide. Before June 2011,

    Italy was in a good equilibrium in which market funding costs were low, consistent with a

    view that a credit event was very unlikely, making the debt sustainable. But in July, following

    the PSI decision for Greece, markets moved Italy to the bad equilibrium, in which anxiety

    about a potential credit event required interest rates that made the debt dynamics look

    unsustainable, thus justifying the anxiety about a potential credit event. With public debt at

    120% of GDP, Italy has become a victim of multiple equilibria.

    One question that arises in this context is whether the interest rates that Italy is now being

    required to pay on its public debt are high enough to put debt sustainability out of reach,

    given plausible fiscal efforts. To answer this question, and shed more general light on the

    new fiscal context, we have revised our debt sustainability analysis, assuming that interest

    rates remain at 6.5% for the foreseeable future. The highlights of the analysis are as follows:

    Figure 2: Public debt dynamics assuming a 6.5% financing rate

    0

    25

    50

    75

    100

    125

    150

    175

    200

    2000 2005 2010 2015 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050

    0

    25

    50

    75

    100

    125

    150

    175

    200

    Italy

    Italy, strong policy action

    Spain

    Public debt-to-GDP (%)

    Source: Barclays Capital

    With public debt at 120% of

    GDP, Italy has become a victim

    of multiple equilibria

    https://live.barcap.com/go/publications/content?contentPubID=FC1722988https://live.barcap.com/go/publications/content?contentPubID=FC1722988
  • 8/3/2019 Zchrana Itlie a EURA (dokument v AJ)

    4/15

  • 8/3/2019 Zchrana Itlie a EURA (dokument v AJ)

    5/15

    Barclays Capital | Euro Themes: What will it take to save Italy (and the euro)?

    24 November 2011 5

    So whats the problem?

    This brings us to the natural question: how much financial support might be necessary to

    help Italy and Spain over the hump? We begin with a few qualitative points, before delving

    into the numbers.

    First, neither Italy nor Spain has lost market access; with some help from the ECBs SMP,

    debt markets have been damaged but have remained open for business, and both countrieshave been able to issue new debt, though expensively, to private creditors. Unlike Greece,

    the rationale for official financial support to Italy and Spain is a precautionary one, not

    grounded in an imperative to substitute for private financing that has vanished. The goal of

    such support should be precisely to reduce the chance of a run by private creditors, not to

    accommodate one. As usual in such precautionary programs, a case can be made that the

    larger the potential source of contingent finance, the smaller the likelihood that it will need

    to be used.

    But why should contingent finance be necessary at all? At the risk of repeating elements of

    our earlier note (Can Italy save itself?, 7 November 2011), we outline some of the

    arguments that also bear upon the question of how much contingent support might be

    necessary. While we have argued that policy adjustments to consolidate fiscal positions andpromote growth are necessary, they take time. After months of turbulence, new

    governments with apparently strengthened inclinations and political mandates to act are in

    place in a number of the most affected countries, including Spain and Italy, but they have

    yet to formulate an economic program and enact it through normal parliamentary

    processes. Once approved, policy measures will then need to be implemented. And once

    they are implemented, investors will need to be reassured that the adjustment and reforms

    will not be so economically harmful in the short run that fiscal adjustment slips ever further

    off into some hypothetical long run, as has happened in some spectacular adjustment

    failures of the past. Investors are forward-looking, but they are not clairvoyant. Having seen

    examples of both successful and unsuccessful stabilization programs; they may be forgiven

    for adopting a wait and see approach to the ones that are underway in Europe.

    While this is going on, Italy and (to a lesser extent for now, because of its smaller debt

    stock) Spain will be subject to the intrinsic instability created by vicious circle dynamics and

    multiple equilibria that threaten highly levered sovereigns. We cannot rule out that investors

    will run simply because they are seized by a self-fulfilling fear that other investors will run.

    Moreover, there is every likelihood that holders of European government bonds will be

    shaken in the months to come by developments from elsewhere in the eurozone. Some

    measure of financial distress and at least a mild recession are pretty much baked into the

    outlook already. It cannot be ruled out that confidence in Italy or Spain may be undermined

    in the months to come by further unsettling developments in Greece, Portugal, Ireland, or

    some country that has yet to capture the headlines.

    These financial risks are enormously amplified by the structural change in the eurozone

    public debt market that has been caused by the eurozone public debt crisis, and which has

    created an overhang of this debt on the books of many traditional holders ( Euro area bank

    deleveraging: How much and how painful?, 22 November 2011). Most of the public debt

    that is now held by institutional investors was accumulated in a day when investors were

    encouraged to think that European government debt was largely without credit risk

    (remember the convergence trade?). This presumption was reflected in bank regulatory

    requirements which even now attach zero risk weightings to such debt. The presumption of

    those days is, of course, long gone. The Greek restructuring exploded the myth that

    eurozone sovereigns would not default. In fact, the structure of the private sector

    Neither Italy nor Spain has lost

    market access

    Investors may run simply

    because they are seized by a

    self-fulfilling fear that other

    investors will run

    The Greek restructuring

    exploded the myth that eurozone

    sovereigns would not default

    https://live.barcap.com/go/publications/content?contentPubID=FC1763950https://live.barcap.com/go/publications/content?contentPubID=FC1768707https://live.barcap.com/go/publications/content?contentPubID=FC1768707https://live.barcap.com/go/publications/content?contentPubID=FC1768707https://live.barcap.com/go/publications/content?contentPubID=FC1768707https://live.barcap.com/go/publications/content?contentPubID=FC1768707https://live.barcap.com/go/publications/content?contentPubID=FC1763950
  • 8/3/2019 Zchrana Itlie a EURA (dokument v AJ)

    6/15

    Barclays Capital | Euro Themes: What will it take to save Italy (and the euro)?

    24 November 2011 6

    involvement in Greece heightened perceptions of credit risk, because the losses were

    concentrated on private bondholders, and the value of the credit insurance that investors

    thought they held against the event was degraded by official efforts (so far successful) to

    achieve a restructuring without triggering CDS contracts. European banks are now being

    required to raise capital against their exposure to sovereign debt, in what may be

    interpreted as a tacit admission that market pricing of credit risk is not utterly without

    foundation. European governments have agreed eventually to include collective actionclauses in their bond contracts, the only plausible purpose of which is to facilitate sovereign

    debt restructurings in the future. In short, its a new world, and many European banks and

    other traditional holders of eurozone sovereign debt who owned it because it was

    considered to be safe, and was treated by regulators as such, now find themselves with

    much more of the paper on their hands than they can justify. This debt needs to migrate

    from traditional, relatively risk-averse holders to investors whose main job it is to assess and

    bear credit risk. But this process will take time, and in the meantime, fiscally stressed

    governments, including Italy and Spain, need to roll over their maturing debt and finance

    their still-substantial budget deficits.

    Financing requirements

    Italy and Spain have not lost access to debt markets, and there is no need for a program that

    takes them out of financial markets, as was done for Ireland, Portugal, and Greece.

    However, the possibility of a self-fulfilling run on the countries bonds poses a threat that

    can only be eliminated if policy implementation is strong, and a last-resort lender instils

    confidence among investors that they will have financing to ride out a period of market

    disruption. The benchmark for the required size of the contingent, last-resort lending is the

    public sector financing requirements that would need to be covered in the event of a bond-

    market strike.

    Figure 4: Public financing requirements for Italy and Spain (billion euros)

    2012 2013 2014 Total

    Italy 398 210 186 794

    Short-term debt 144 144

    Medium and long-term amortization 201 166 157 524

    Net issuance 53 44 29 126

    Spain (including regions) 191 106 100 397

    Short-term debt 84 84

    Medium and long-term amortization 60 71 73 204

    Net issuance 47 35 27 109

    Total 589 316 286 1191

    Amortization 261 237 230 728

    Net issuance 100 79 56 235

    Source: Barclays Capital

    Leaving short-term debt rollovers aside, the Italian governments gross funding

    requirements for 2012 are just above EUR 250 billion; over the three-year period 2012-14,

    they amount to roughly EUR 650 billion, with about 125 billion reflecting government cash

    deficits. (The estimates in Figure 4 are based upon deficit projections consistent with the

    debt-dynamics exercise discussed above, in which the primary budget surplus gradually

    What are the public sector

    financing requirements that

    would need to be covered in the

    event of a bond-market strike?

    The Italian governments gross

    funding requirements for

    2012-14 amount to roughly

    EUR 650 billion

  • 8/3/2019 Zchrana Itlie a EURA (dokument v AJ)

    7/15

    Barclays Capital | Euro Themes: What will it take to save Italy (and the euro)?

    24 November 2011 7

    rises to about 4% of GDP in 2014, consistent with an overall deficit slightly below 2% of

    GDP in that year, before falling to 3% in the steady-state. We make no explicit allowance for

    potential privatization proceeds in the projections.)

    Moreover, bank bond redemptions are very large as well, about EUR 80 billion in 2012 alone,

    and like substantial parts of the European banking system, the Italian system is likely to

    need official liquidity support for the foreseeable future. There are no material risks to theItalian banking system beyond the stressed sovereign. Since the Italian banking system is

    fundamentally solvent, the ECB through the extended fixed rate full allotment is likely to

    continue to meet the Italian bank funding needs.

    In Spain, the public financing needs are about half the size of Italys, amounting to EUR 107

    billion in 2012, if once again we exclude the rollover of short-term bills. Over the 2012-2014

    period, the gross financing requirement is about EUR 313 billion if short-term debt is

    excluded, and just under EUR 400 billion if it is included.

    How much of these financing requirements might need to be covered to reduce the risk of a

    cash squeeze associated with a run on these sovereigns bonds? Here we have to admit

    that we are leaving the realm of the scientific and entering the realm of market psychology.

    The short, but not so useful, answer is that the financial war chest needs to be big enough

    to convince market participants that the sovereign is insulated from a run. A more

    operational answer is that the contingent support should be large enough so that the

    endangered sovereign would have time to either allow the external source of an attack to

    run its course, and/or to take the corrective action required to re-establish market access.

    For the sake of concreteness, let us work with 18-24 months of financing requirements.

    For Italy and Spain, this gives a range of about EUR 500 billion (18 months of financing,

    excluding short-term bill rollovers) to EUR 800 billion (24 months, assuming that roughly

    half of the outstanding stock of short-term bills would need to be covered as well).

    Potential sources of funding

    The EFSF alone will not suffice

    As we wrote previously (EFSF 2.0: Nearly there, 6 October 2011), the EFSF is not sufficiently

    funded to deal with the larger countries such as Italy on its own. Under the current

    programmes for Greece, Ireland and Portugal, the EFSF would cover about EUR 143 billion

    of funding needs, leaving EUR 297 billion for all the rest. If every remaining euro were

    committed to support for Spain and Italy, the EFSF could cover something like 35-60% of

    the financing needs that we identify above. But this would leave no reserve for unforeseen

    (but not unthinkable) contingencies in the other programs, and would crowd out entirely

    other uses for the EFSF, such as assisting in the bank capitalization effort, or coping with

    another country that may fall into financial difficulties.

    It is by now clear that the EFSF cannot be increased meaningfully, in part because ofpolitical resistance, but more fundamentally because the contingent liabilities associated

    with the support program have already undermined confidence in some guarantor

    countries. France, in particular, has come under market scrutiny in a way that most likely

    prevents the country from undertaking additional contingent fiscal commitments on behalf

    of financially weaker countries in the eurozone.

    European policymakers floated some options to leverage these EFSF resources, including

    credit enhancements to new debt issued by member states (probably in the form of first-

    loss credit insurance) and new funding arrangements of the EFSF with a combination of

    In Spain, they amount to

    EUR 313 billion over the

    2012-2014 period

    For Italy and Spain, this gives a

    range of EUR 500 billion to

    EUR 800 billion for the next 18-24

    months

    https://live.barcap.com/go/publications/content?contentPubID=FC1752779https://live.barcap.com/go/publications/content?contentPubID=FC1752779
  • 8/3/2019 Zchrana Itlie a EURA (dokument v AJ)

    8/15

    Barclays Capital | Euro Themes: What will it take to save Italy (and the euro)?

    24 November 2011 8

    resources from private and public financial institutions (including IMF) and investors, which

    could be arranged through Special Purpose Vehicles.

    As we explained in a previous piece (Leveraging the EFSF: Uses and Limits, 25 October

    2011), we thought that these schemes to leverage EFSF resources had some positive

    elements, but would have a more limited impact on debt-servicing costs than headline

    leverage ratios may have suggested. The initiatives seem to have lost momentum, and wethink that the best estimate of support for Italy and Spain from the EFSF is the EUR 200 to

    300 billion in unlevered resources that is left after previous commitments and potential

    contingencies are accounted for. Financial engineering could conceivably increase the

    headline number, while offering relatively little in the way of additional financial support.

    IMF support likely limited in size as well

    A complementary option is to bring in the IMF. Augmenting resources with funds from the

    IMF could certainly help but with important caveats. The most important of these is that the

    IMF only lends with seniority. It provides cash, but not credit, in effect concentrating the

    credit risk on outstanding, privately-held debt. The reduction in the recovery value of

    privately-held debt is reflected in the credit risk of newly issued debt, thus making it harder

    for the beleaguered sovereign to return to markets than would be the case if the liquiditysupport were not senior to private creditors. Senior support of this sort has proven effective

    in past IMF programs, but may require a more extended period of official financing than

    might otherwise be likely.

    The IMF has about EUR 290 billion left in uncommitted resources (its current forward

    commitment balance) that could, in principle, be lent in the months to come. Among the

    IMFs existing commitments are very large commitments to Greece, Ireland, and Portugal

    that were extended in support of the eurozone rescue program for these countries. These

    commitments amount, in aggregate, to roughly EUR 79 billion (Greece EUR 30 billion,

    Ireland EUR 22.5 billion and Portugal EUR 26 billion), almost 20 times the three countries

    IMF quota. This illustrates, on the one hand, that previously applicable constraints on

    lending programs relative to borrowers IMF quota have been broken by the Europeanimbroglio. But it also demonstrates how exposed the IMF already is to Europe, which is

    likely to pose the main constraint on the financial support that the IMF could lend to Italy

    and Spain. If, for example, the IMF were to make EUR 150 billion available as a contribution

    to a rescue effort for Italy and Spain (about 11 times their current quotas and about 6 times

    their new IMF quotas approved in December 2010 and likely becoming effective in the next

    months), it would be left with only EUR 140 billion of lending capacity to cope with potential

    demands for IMF resources from the rest of the world.

    The IMF could raise the resources available to it for lending, and just did so very significantly

    and rapidly. But we very much doubt that there would be any appetite for a generalized

    increase in IMF quota contributions after the doubling in quotas that was so recently

    approved. China and other surplus emerging market economies do have funds, and might

    be induced to lend them to the Fund in exchange for a higher IMF quota and the associated

    geopolitical clout. Even then, however, the domestic political atmospherics of still relatively

    poor Chinese workers and taxpayers being tapped to rescue over-dimensioned welfare

    states in some of the wealthiest corners of the world could be problematic. In addition, the

    concentration of IMF exposure to Europe that would be created by a massive extension of

    credit could give the IMFs shareholders pause.

    The IMF has about

    EUR 290 billion left in

    uncommitted resources

    https://live.barcap.com/go/publications/content?contentPubID=FC1758486https://live.barcap.com/go/publications/content?contentPubID=FC1758486
  • 8/3/2019 Zchrana Itlie a EURA (dokument v AJ)

    9/15

    Barclays Capital | Euro Themes: What will it take to save Italy (and the euro)?

    24 November 2011 9

    On balance, it seems to us that a plausible scenario for IMF support for Italy and Spain is in the

    range of EUR 100-150 billion. The EUR 150 billion is roughly 5-6 times the two countries new

    quota. The estimate of about EUR 100-150 billion for possible IMF support for Italy and Spain

    is about half the EFSF contribution, consistent with the precedent established in the programs

    for Ireland, Portugal, and Greece, where the IMF also contributed roughly 1 euro for every 2

    euros the European authorities contributed to the program.

    All of this is necessarily speculative, of course, but it seems to us that the best estimate of

    the financial support for Italy and Spain that could be mustered by the EFSF and the IMF

    together is something like EUR 300-450 billion. This falls EUR 200-500 billion short of the

    program that we calculated above.

    ECB: The last-resort lender of last resort

    This brings us, finally, to the ECB. In our view, the ECB has the balance sheet capacity to

    support stressed European sovereigns substantially in excess of our (admittedly very rough)

    estimates of what might be called for to complement sovereign adjustment and reform

    programs. And the ECB has been offering support, although with some reluctance, and in

    limited amounts. Although the new ECB President, Mario Draghi, emphasized in his first

    press conference the limited and temporary nature of the SMP, in recent weeks, the ECB hasbroadly continued in size and frequency the sovereign bond purchases under the SMP

    policy that was revived in August in response to increased pressure on Italian and Spanish

    government bond markets. However, ECB leadership and important elements of the political

    leadership in Europe have been anxious to discount a more explicit role for the ECB as

    lender of last resort.

    This reluctance is not justified by balance-sheet constraints. The ECBs accounting capital is

    small by comparison with the hypothetical lending operations, and with theoretical credit

    losses that could emerge if the ECB were exposed to a sovereign debt restructuring. But

    these potential (or even actual) credit losses are essentially irrelevant for the ECBs core task

    of conducting monetary policy. The ECBs capacity to absorb loss is not limited to its

    accounting capital, but also includes the value of future seigniorage earnings, whose netpresent value amounts to something in the order of EUR 2-5 trillion.1

    In the event of a large sovereign credit event, the ECB might have to operate for some years

    with negative capital on an accounting basis. But this would have no necessary impact on

    the ECBs capacity to conduct future monetary policy. A vivid illustration of this is given by

    Chile, whose central bank was rendered insolvent (to the tune of something like 15% of

    GDP) by the 1982 financial crisis, and operated very effectively with negative net worth for

    decades thereafter.

    The ECBs reluctance to establish itself as an explicit lender of last resort to European

    sovereigns is grounded not in balance-sheet constraints, but rather in tactical,

    legal/constitutional/doctrinal, and conventional policy inhibitions.

    The tactical constraint pertains to moral hazard, which in this case is grounded in theperception that market pressure is required to force governments to address their policy

    deficiencies. The ECBs SMP operations therefore seem calibrated to prevent a

    meltdown of peripheral sovereign markets, while permitting enough market pressure to

    induce prompt policy action. This may be a risky policy, in light of the potentially

    1 The eurosystems profits are about EUR 30 billion. If these grow at 3.5% per year and are discounted at an interestrate of 4.5% per year, the net present value of the earnings would total EUR 3,000 billion. Even if the relevant numberis half this, it is large by comparison with the size of operations that the ECB has been willing to make so far.

    A plausible scenario for IMF

    support for Italy and Spain is in

    the range of EUR100-150 billion

  • 8/3/2019 Zchrana Itlie a EURA (dokument v AJ)

    10/15

    Barclays Capital | Euro Themes: What will it take to save Italy (and the euro)?

    24 November 2011 10

    unstable vicious circle dynamics that can affect bond markets, but until stronger

    policies are in place, an adherent to this point of view would argue that there is no

    realistic alternative.

    The legal and constitutional issues are serious constraints on the form that ECB supportmight take, though not obviously on the magnitude. The ECB is prohibited from

    (directly) financing governments, a prohibition that is grounded in the horrific interwarexperience with monetary finance, particularly in Germany. However, secondary market

    operations have not been prohibited by this constraint, although the ECB is careful to

    rationalize these operations on monetary-policy grounds.

    Finally, there is a concern that engaging in very large lender-of-last resort operationsmay be inconsistent with the ECBs mandate to maintain inflation at low levels. We

    should not forget that, until recently, the ECB was beginning to tighten policy to fend off

    a perceived inflationary threat. Certainly, heedless, unlimited, unsterilized balance sheet

    expansions would pose an eventual inflationary threat.

    Given these capabilities and constraints, what can be expected of the ECB in the months

    and years to come?

    We now believe that further interest-rate cuts will follow the surprise cut announced atthe last monetary-policy meeting, justified by the darkening outlook for economic

    activity and associated decline in perceived inflationary risks.

    We also see a good chance that the ECB will announce more non-conventionalmeasures. It is even possible that the ECB will finally follow the U.S. Fed and Bank of

    England and revert to quantitative easing, or credit easing if the policy rate reached its

    lower, near-zero bound. This could involve a much bigger SMP, and possibly even an

    announcement of the targeted intervention levels in advance. This should certainly lend

    support to the Italian public debt market and others under stress, but it would be

    communicated as part of the ECBs strategy to maintain price stability in the face of

    deflationary risks or systemic stress in the banking sector.

    More decisive ECB interventions in euro area bond markets are likely to be politically moreacceptable once the new governments in Italy and Spain make headway in their policy

    agendas. (In this context, we find it significant that the Dutch Prime Minister and Finance

    Minister recently stated that they would support the ECB stepping up its unconventional

    tools, as long as affected countries carry out the required policy reforms.)

    That said, we consider any unlimited commitment to intervene, or an explicit target levelfor government yields or spreads, to be highly unlikely. It is also hard to imagine the ECB

    surmounting the legal prohibition against direct finance of governments. ECB support is

    likely to take the form of an increase in the scale of intervention in secondary markets

    or, more likely, communication to the market that such interventions may be in place for

    the foreseeable future. In this context we note that the recently-floated cap of EUR 20billion per week on SMP operations allows for very consequential cumulative support,

    although it would be spread over an extended period of time.

    In short, we think there are grounds for optimism that reluctance to use the ECB balance

    sheet to support sovereign debt markets more forcefully will ease, as inflationary

    considerations give way to a need to support a weakening economy and manage the bank

    de-leveraging that is underway in Europe, and as governments in the affected economies

    establish a more reassuring track record of reform implementation. However, the de facto

    Reluctance to use the ECB

    balance sheet to support

    sovereign debt markets more

    forcefully may ease

  • 8/3/2019 Zchrana Itlie a EURA (dokument v AJ)

    11/15

    Barclays Capital | Euro Themes: What will it take to save Italy (and the euro)?

    24 November 2011 11

    lender-of-last resort operations will continue to coexist uneasily with the ECBs institutional

    mandate, and institutional distaste for the operations is not likely to fade entirely. The ECB is

    very likely to continue to confine its intervention to secondary markets.

    Final thoughts on the endgame

    There is an optimistic way to read our assessment of the state of play. Combined withplausible support from the EFSF and the IMF, the ECBs contribution via the SMP could

    plausibly be sufficient, on paper, to provide a financial war chest commensurate with the

    scale of the contingent financing risks that might sensibly be addressed as part of the policy

    package to restore Europe to financial health.

    But doing so requires a patchwork of support from a variety of sources, none of them

    actually operative at the moment, except the ECBs SMP, which is now being implemented

    with some considerable reluctance, controversy, and arguably even distaste in European

    policy circles. We see little room for doubt that contributions from the EFSF and the IMF can

    be mobilized, but progress may need to be catalyzed by adverse developments. In other

    words, it may (still) need to get (even) worse before it gets better.

    The question arises whether the constraint on the ECB to operate in the secondary marketweakens significantly the value of the ECBs potential contribution. Here is how we think

    about this. As long as markets are functioning and governments remain able to tap private

    financing, there is an important degree of fungibility, and ECB operations in the secondary

    market should catalyze private participation in private markets, by making room in private-

    sector balance sheets and by providing some reassurance that the bond market is not on

    the verge of a free fall. Secondary market interventions operate indirectly, and they may be

    less efficient than participation in primary markets would be, but they should be effective.

    When it comes to the tail risk of managing a buyers strike in which the sovereign loses

    access to private finance, like Greece, Portugal, and Ireland have done, it is another matter.

    Under these circumstances, investors are in a corner solution; they simply want out of their

    exposure at essentially any price. In circumstances like these, secondary marketinterventions may simply take private investors out of their exposure, without promoting

    any meaningful private support for primary market issuance. In this sense, secondary

    market operations are a far less effective mechanism to help a beleaguered sovereign

    manage a loss of market access.

    In short, while it is not too difficult to identify plausible financial contributions from the

    EFSF, the IMF, and the ECB that add up to a program that adds up on paper, the whole may

    be somewhat less convincing to markets than the sum of its parts, and it may once again

    come late enough in the game that it will fail to prevent economic fallout that could

    plausibly have been prevented by a more pre-emptive approach. The patchwork of support

    that is very probably available, but not yet in place, seems very likely to fall short of the show

    of force that could induce financial markets to turn the page on the problem.

    Another missing element is a clear sense of the end game of the European drama. It is

    certainly to be hoped that the emergency policy adjustments and support programs are

    transition mechanisms but transition to what? One possibility is to creditworthiness; call

    this the Brazil scenario in which policy adjustments alone eventually transform

    precariously-positioned European sovereigns into strong economic and credit stories. But

    this scenario is, to us, unrealistic for a country like Italy, except perhaps on a 10-20 year

    time frame. Brazil was able to de-dollarize its public (and much of its private) debt at the

    same time that it engineered a fiscal consolidation and strengthened its monetary policy

  • 8/3/2019 Zchrana Itlie a EURA (dokument v AJ)

    12/15

    Barclays Capital | Euro Themes: What will it take to save Italy (and the euro)?

    24 November 2011 12

    framework. And when all was said and done, the public debt was closer to 50% of GDP than

    100%. This is not an option for Italy, as long as it remains in the euro area, as we think it

    should and will. After it has fixed its budget and implemented pro-growth reforms, it will for

    many years have a public debt in excess of 100% of GDP, issued in foreign currency, and

    without a true lender of last resort. Two or three years from now, investors may not view

    Italy as dancing on the brink of insolvency but the sovereign will remain in an intrinsically

    precarious financial position as long as this is the case.

    Thus, without a reasonably specific and credible agenda at the euro-area level on what

    EMU2.0 will be, markets are unlikely fully to settle. International investors are no longer

    viewing many of the euro area sovereigns as risk free, including Italy and Spain. And they are

    unlikely to return to these markets unless a structural change happens in Europe that involves

    not only corrective policies in Italy and Spain, but also a reasonably clear path towards a less

    precarious institutional framework, including for example more euro-area integration and

    perhaps the issuance of Eurobonds. The ECB, too, and perhaps also the IMF, are also unlikely

    to feel fully at ease assisting the euro areas transition if they have no clear sense of the

    endgame. This is one crisis where the odds of success in managing the crisis depend to a

    substantial degree on developing a more coherent vision of the post-crisis landscape.

  • 8/3/2019 Zchrana Itlie a EURA (dokument v AJ)

    13/15

    Analyst Certification(s)We, Antonio Garcia Pascual, Michael Gavin, Piero Ghezzi and Thomas Harjes, hereby certify (1) that the views expressed in this research report accuratelyreflect our personal views about any or all of the subject securities or issuers referred to in this research report and (2) no part of our compensation was, is orwill be directly or indirectly related to the specific recommendations or views expressed in this research report.

    Important DisclosuresFor current important disclosures regarding companies that are the subject of this research report, please send a written request to: Barclays Capital ResearchCompliance, 745 Seventh Avenue, 17th Floor, New York, NY 10019 or refer to https://ecommerce.barcap.com/research/cgi-bin/all/disclosuresSearch.pl orcall 212-526-1072.

    Barclays Capital does and seeks to do business with companies covered in its research reports. As a result, investors should be aware that Barclays Capitalmay have a conflict of interest that could affect the objectivity of this report. Any reference to Barclays Capital includes its affiliates. Barclays Capital and/or anaffiliate thereof (the "firm") regularly trades, generally deals as principal and generally provides liquidity (as market maker or otherwise) in the debt securitiesthat are the subject of this research report (and related derivatives thereof). The firm's proprietary trading accounts may have either a long and / or shortposition in such securities and / or derivative instruments, which may pose a conflict with the interests of investing customers. Where permitted and subjectto appropriate information barrier restrictions, the firm's fixed income research analysts regularly interact with its trading desk personnel to determine currentprices of fixed income securities. The firm's fixed income research analyst(s) receive compensation based on various factors including, but not limited to, thequality of their work, the overall performance of the firm (including the profitability of the investment banking department), the profitability and revenues ofthe Fixed Income Division and the outstanding principal amount and trading value of, the profitability of, and the potential interest of the firms investingclients in research with respect to, the asset class covered by the analyst. To the extent that any historical pricing information was obtained from BarclaysCapital trading desks, the firm makes no representation that it is accurate or complete. All levels, prices and spreads are historical and do not representcurrent market levels, prices or spreads, some or all of which may have changed since the publication of this document. Barclays Capital produces a variety ofresearch products including, but not limited to, fundamental analysis, equity-linked analysis, quantitative analysis, and trade ideas. Recommendationscontained in one type of research product may differ from recommendations contained in other types of research products, whether as a result of differingtime horizons, methodologies, or otherwise.

    DisclaimerThis publication has been prepared by Barclays Capital, the investment banking division of Barclays Bank PLC, and/or one or more of its affiliates as providedbelow. It is provided to our clients for information purposes only, and Barclays Capital makes no express or implied warranties, and expressly disclaims allwarranties of merchantability or fitness for a particular purpose or use with respect to any data included in this publication. Barclays Capital will not treatunauthorized recipients of this report as its clients. Prices shown are indicative and Barclays Capital is not offering to buy or sell or soliciting offers to buy orsell any financial instrument. Without limiting any of the foregoing and to the extent permitted by law, in no event shall Barclays Capital, nor any affiliate, norany of their respective officers, directors, partners, or employees have any liability for (a) any special, punitive, indirect, or consequential damages; or (b) anylost profits, lost revenue, loss of anticipated savings or loss of opportunity or other financial loss, even if notified of the possibility of such damages, arisingfrom any use of this publication or its contents. Other than disclosures relating to Barclays Capital, the information contained in this publication has beenobtained from sources that Barclays Capital believes to be reliable, but Barclays Capital does not represent or warrant that it is accurate or complete. Theviews in this publication are those of Barclays Capital and are subject to change, and Barclays Capital has no obligation to update its opinions or theinformation in this publication.The analyst recommendations in this publication reflect solely and exclusively those of the author(s), and such opinions were prepared independently of anyother interests, including those of Barclays Capital and/or its affiliates. This publication does not constitute personal investment advice or take into accountthe individual financial circumstances or objectives of the clients who receive it. The securities discussed herein may not be suitable for all investors. BarclaysCapital recommends that investors independently evaluate each issuer, security or instrument discussed herein and consult any independent advisors theybelieve necessary. The value of and income from any investment may fluctuate from day to day as a result of changes in relevant economic markets(including changes in market liquidity). The information herein is not intended to predict actual results, which may differ substantially from those reflected.Past performance is not necessarily indicative of future results.This communication is being made available in the UK and Europe primarily to persons who are investment professionals as that term is defined in Article 19of the Financial Services and Markets Act 2000 (Financial Promotion Order) 2005. It is directed at, and therefore should only be relied upon by, persons whohave professional experience in matters relating to investments. The investments to which it relates are available only to such persons and will be entered intoonly with such persons. Barclays Capital is authorized and regulated by the Financial Services Authority ('FSA') and member of the London Stock Exchange.Barclays Capital Inc., U.S. registered broker/dealer and member of FINRA (www.finra.org), is distributing this material in the United States and, in connectiontherewith accepts responsibility for its contents. Any U.S. person wishing to effect a transaction in any security discussed herein should do so only bycontacting a representative of Barclays Capital Inc. in the U.S. at 745 Seventh Avenue, New York, New York 10019. Non-U.S. persons should contact andexecute transactions through a Barclays Bank PLC branch or affiliate in their home jurisdiction unless local regulations permit otherwise. This material isdistributed in Canada by Barclays Capital Canada Inc., a registered investment dealer and member of IIROC (www.iiroc.ca). To access Barclays Capital policy

    on the dissemination of research reports, please go to http://www.barcap.com/Client+offering/Research/Research+Policy. Subject to the conditions of thispublication as set out above, Absa Capital, the Investment Banking Division of Absa Bank Limited, an authorised financial services provider (Registration No.:1986/004794/06), is distributing this material in South Africa. Absa Bank Limited is regulated by the South African Reserve Bank. This publication is not, noris it intended to be, advice as defined and/or contemplated in the (South African) Financial Advisory and Intermediary Services Act, 37 of 2002, or any otherfinancial, investment, trading, tax, legal, accounting, retirement, actuarial or other professional advice or service whatsoever. Any South African person orentity wishing to effect a transaction in any security discussed herein should do so only by contacting a representative of Absa Capital in South Africa, 15Alice Lane, Sandton, Johannesburg, Gauteng 2196. Absa Capital is an affiliate of Barclays Capital. In Japan, foreign exchange research reports are preparedand distributed by Barclays Bank PLC Tokyo Branch. Other research reports are distributed to institutional investors in Japan by Barclays Capital Japan Limited.Barclays Capital Japan Limited is a joint-stock company incorporated in Japan with registered office of 6-10-1 Roppongi, Minato-ku, Tokyo 106-6131, Japan.It is a subsidiary of Barclays Bank PLC and a registered financial instruments firm regulated by the Financial Services Agency of Japan. Registered Number:Kanto Zaimukyokucho (kinsho) No. 143. Barclays Bank PLC, Hong Kong Branch is distributing this material in Hong Kong as an authorised institutionregulated by the Hong Kong Monetary Authority. Registered Office: 41/F, Cheung Kong Center, 2 Queen's Road Central, Hong Kong. This material is issued inTaiwan by Barclays Capital Securities Taiwan Limited. This material on securities not traded in Taiwan is not to be construed as 'recommendation' in Taiwan.

  • 8/3/2019 Zchrana Itlie a EURA (dokument v AJ)

    14/15

    Barclays Capital Securities Taiwan Limited does not accept orders from clients to trade in such securities. This material may not be distributed to the publicmedia or used by the public media without prior written consent of Barclays Capital. This material is distributed in South Korea by Barclays Capital SecuritiesLimited, Seoul Branch. All equity research material is distributed in India by Barclays Securities (India) Private Limited (SEBI Registration No: INB/INF231292732 (NSE), INB/INF 011292738 (BSE), Registered Office: 208 | Ceejay House | Dr. Annie Besant Road | Shivsagar Estate | Worli | Mumbai - 400 018 |India, Phone: + 91 22 67196363). Other research reports are distributed in India by Barclays Bank PLC, India Branch. Barclays Bank PLC Frankfurt Branchdistributes this material in Germany under the supervision of Bundesanstalt fr Finanzdienstleistungsaufsicht (BaFin). This material is distributed in Malaysiaby Barclays Capital Markets Malaysia Sdn Bhd. This material is distributed in Brazil by Banco Barclays S.A. This material is distributed in Mexico by BarclaysBank Mexico, S.A. Barclays Bank PLC in the Dubai International Financial Centre (Registered No. 0060) is regulated by the Dubai Financial Services Authorit y(DFSA). Barclays Bank PLC-DIFC Branch, may only undertake the financial services activities that fall within the scope of its existing DFSA licence. Barclays

    Bank PLC in the UAE is regulated by the Central Bank of the UAE and is licensed to conduct business activities as a branch of a commercial bank incorporatedoutside the UAE in Dubai (Licence No.: 13/1844/2008, Registered Office: Building No. 6, Burj Dubai Business Hub, Sheikh Zayed Road, Dubai City) and AbuDhabi (Licence No.: 13/952/2008, Registered Office: Al Jazira Towers, Hamdan Street, PO Box 2734, Abu Dhabi). Barclays Bank PLC in the Qatar FinancialCentre (Registered No. 00018) is authorised by the Qatar Financial Centre Regulatory Authority (QFCRA). Barclays Bank PLC-QFC Branch may only undertakethe regulated activities that fall within the scope of its existing QFCRA licence. Principal place of business in Qatar: Qatar Financial Centre, Office 1002, 10thFloor, QFC Tower, Diplomatic Area, West Bay, PO Box 15891, Doha, Qatar. This material is distributed in Dubai, the UAE and Qatar by Barclays Bank PLC.Related financial products or services are only available to Professional Clients as defined by the DFSA, and Business Customers as defined by the QFCRA.This material is distributed in Saudi Arabia by Barclays Saudi Arabia ('BSA'). It is not the intention of the Publication to be used or deemed asrecommendation, option or advice for any action (s) that may take place in future. Barclays Saudi Arabia is a Closed Joint Stock Company, (CMA License No.09141-37). Registered office Al Faisaliah Tower | Level 18 | Riyadh 11311 | Kingdom of Saudi Arabia. Authorised and regulated by the Capital MarketAuthority, Commercial Registration Number: 1010283024. This material is distributed in Russia by OOO Barclays Capital, affiliated company of Barclays BankPLC, registered and regulated in Russia by the FSFM. Broker License #177-11850-100000; Dealer License #177-11855-010000. Registered address in Russia:125047 Moscow, 1st Tverskaya-Yamskaya str. 21. This material is distributed in Singapore by the Singapore branch of Barclays Bank PLC, a bank licensed inSingapore by the Monetary Authority of Singapore. For matters in connection with this report, recipients in Singapore may contact the Singapore branch ofBarclays Bank PLC, whose registered address is One Raffles Quay Level 28, South Tower, Singapore 048583. Barclays Bank PLC, Australia Branch (ARBN 062449 585, AFSL 246617) is distributing this material in Australia. It is directed at 'wholesale clients' as defined by Australian Corporations Act 2001.

    IRS Circular 230 Prepared Materials Disclaimer: Barclays Capital and its affiliates do not provide tax advice and nothing contained herein should be construedto be tax advice. Please be advised that any discussion of U.S. tax matters contained herein (including any attachments) (i) is not intended or written to beused, and cannot be used, by you for the purpose of avoiding U.S. tax-related penalties; and (ii) was written to support the promotion or marketing of thetransactions or other matters addressed herein. Accordingly, you should seek advice based on your particular circumstances from an independent taxadvisor.Barclays Capital is not responsible for, and makes no warranties whatsoever as to, the content of any third-party web site accessed via a hyperlink in thispublication and such information is not incorporated by reference. Copyright Barclays Bank PLC (2011). All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced in any manner without the prior written permissionof Barclays Capital or any of its affiliates. Barclays Bank PLC is registered in England No. 1026167. Registered office 1 Churchill Place, London, E14 5HP.Additional information regarding this publication will be furnished upon request.

  • 8/3/2019 Zchrana Itlie a EURA (dokument v AJ)

    15/15

    US20043