Yanbo Goldhedging

download Yanbo Goldhedging

of 31

Transcript of Yanbo Goldhedging

  • 8/11/2019 Yanbo Goldhedging

    1/31

    Does Hedging Increase Firm Value?

    Evidence from the Gold Mining Industry

    YANBO JIN*and

    PHILIPPE JORION**

    This version: July 2007

    * Corresponding author, Department of Finance, Real Estate and Insurance, California StateUniversity, Northridge** Paul Merage School of Business, University of California at Irvine

    Philippe Jorion Yanbo Jin

    Paul Merage School of Business Department of Finance, Real Estate and InsuranceUniversity of California at Irvine California State University, NorthridgeIrvine, CA 92697-3125 Northridge, CA 91330-8379Phone: (949) 824-5245 Phone: (949) 285-4166Fax: (949) 824-8469 Fax: (818) 677-6079E-mail:[email protected] E-mail: [email protected]

  • 8/11/2019 Yanbo Goldhedging

    2/31

    1

    Does Hedging Increase Firm Value?Evidence from the Gold Mining Industry

    ABSTRACT

    This paper studies the relationship between risk management practices and firm value for a

    sample of 44 North American gold mining firms from 1991 to 2000. We first show that

    hedging activities are recognized by the market, as hedging variables do have an impact on

    stock price exposure to gold prices. Controlling for other variables, however, we cannot find

    a positive relationship between hedging activities and firm values, as measured by Tobins Q

    ratio. If anything, the relationship is negative. This result is inconsistent with theories

    implying that hedging increases firm value. In this industry, commodity price exposure is

    transparent and easy to hedge by investors, so there is no reason to expect that gold mining

    firms hedging their gold price risk should have higher market values.

  • 8/11/2019 Yanbo Goldhedging

    3/31

    2

    North American gold mining companies have vastly different hedging practices. At one

    end of the hedging spectrum, companies like American Barrick have been hedging extensively

    their gold production. At the other end, firms like Homestake Mining choose not to hedge their

    gold production at all.

    This raises a number of questions. First, what could justify such different hedging

    practices given that all of these companies have similar exposure to gold prices? Second, how

    do these hedging policies affect company valuations, if at all?

    Financial theories attempt to answer the first question by following one of two groups of

    explanations. The first group assumes that managers hedge to maximize firm value. In this

    context, hedging can achieve this goal by reducing the cost of financial distress, by reducing

    expected taxes, or by relieving the under-investment problem.1 The second group assumes that

    managers hedge for personal diversification purposes, or to maximize their personal utility.2

    These two classes of explanation have very different implications for the effect of hedging on

    firm value. In one case, hedging should be associated with higher firm value, unlike in the other.

    Earlier empirical studies have focused on the first question, with mixed results. For

    example, Tufano (1996) studies the derivatives hedging activities of the gold mining industry in

    1990-1993 and finds little support for the firm value maximization theory. On the contrary, his

    evidence is consistent with manager utility maximization. Managers who hold more stocks tend

    to hedge more, while managers who hold more options tend to hedge less. Focusing on a broad

    sample of firms exposed to interest rate and exchange rate risk, Graham and Rogers (2002) also

    find that derivatives use is related to managers equity positions. They also report that firms

    1See, for example, Smith and Stulz (1985) and Froot, Sharfstein and Stein (1993).2See, for example, Stulz (1984).

  • 8/11/2019 Yanbo Goldhedging

    4/31

    3

    hedge to increase debt capacity, which is consistent with the firm value maximization theory;

    they report tax benefits that amount to an average of 1.1 percent of firm value.

    Recently, more attention has been focused on the second question, testing directly

    whether hedging is related to firm value. The first evidence is provided by Allayannis and

    Weston (2001). Using a sample of 720 large U.S. firms over a six-year time period, they claim

    that firms using foreign currency derivatives enjoy a 5 percent hedging premium relative to

    others. Given that the median firm has a market value of $4 billion, this corresponds to a

    premium of $200 million, which is significant. More recently, Carter et al. (2005) report that US

    airlines enjoy a 14 percent premium from hedging fuel cost, which is an even larger effect.

    These results have stimulated more research along this line. In particular, Guay and

    Kothari (2003) claim that the potential gains from typical derivatives positions are small

    compared to economic exposures. Their interpretation is that the observed increase in market

    values is driven by other risk management activities, such as operational hedges, that are value-

    enhancing and are positively correlated with derivatives positions, or is spurious.

    To shed more light on these issues, the natural resource industry provides a set of ideal

    controlled experiments. Gold mining is a very homogeneous industry group, with high exposure

    to gold prices. In addition, it does not offer much scope for vertical integration and

    diversification, unlike the oil and gas industry. Gold price risk can be easily hedged by investors

    if they so choose, using for instance exchange-listed futures. This raises the classic Modigliani

    and Miller (M&M) question of why hedging with derivatives should add any value. Perhaps

    value added is created because derivatives carry an unrecognized risk premium. Alternatively,

    the firm may have expertise such that active trading activities create a profit.

  • 8/11/2019 Yanbo Goldhedging

    5/31

    4

    In the U.S. oil and gas industry, Jin and Jorion (2006) found no relationship between

    derivatives activities and firm value. The gold mining industry, however, provides a rich sector

    for risk management studies. Petersen and Thiagarajan (2000) provide a detailed comparison of

    the risk management practices of two gold mining firms. American Barrick hedges most of its

    price risk using derivatives; Homestake Mining does not use derivatives. The authors, however,

    also argue that risk management can take other forms than using derivatives. Homestake Mining

    manages its risk using a combination of operational and accounting decisions. The firm manages

    its extraction costs in line with the price of gold and reduces the volatility of its accounting

    income through discretionary choices. The authors indicate that the equity exposure to gold

    prices is almost identical for the two firms. Whether this result extends to the entire industry,

    however, is an open question.

    Adam and Fernando (2006) show that firms with gold hedging programs have

    consistently realized economically significant cash flow gains over the period 1990 to 2000.

    This is because the term structure of gold forward or futures prices is typically in contango,

    meaning that forward prices are systematically higher than spot prices. Thus gold producers are

    selling at a forward price that is on average higher than the spot price, locking in a typical profit

    of 3%.3 They report that their typical firm realized an average gain of $11 million, or $24 per

    ounce of gold hedged per year, as compared to an annual net income of $3.5 million only.

    Whether this translates into higher market value has not been tested. This is not obvious,

    however. If a risk premium exists in this market, it can be captured easily by buying gold

    futures, which are now trading on the New York mercantile exchange and have been offered

    since 1974.

    3This is based on 1-year forward contract. This number implies is that spot prices did not rise, on average, by theamount embedded in the forward premium over this period. In other words, there was a bias in the forward rate.Whether this bias is a risk premium is another issue.

  • 8/11/2019 Yanbo Goldhedging

    6/31

    5

    In this paper, we study the hedging activities of 44 North American gold mining firms

    from 1991 to 2000, and evaluate their impact on equity exposure and firm value. We show that,

    although hedging with derivatives reduces gold price exposure of most firms, hedging does not

    seem to increase firm value. If anything, hedging seems to be associated with lower firm value.

    Our result offers further evidence that hedging commodity price does not automatically

    increase firm value. This is consistent with Jin and Jorion (2006). In the gold mining industry,

    similar to the oil and gas industry, gold price risk is an operating risk. Investors most likely

    choose to invest in this industry simply to gain exposure to gold prices, which implies that firms

    hedging this operating risk will not be valued more by its investors.

    As an intermediate step, we also test if hedging reduces gold mining firms stock price

    sensitivity to gold prices. We offer evidence that hedging effectively dampens the gold price

    exposure of gold mining firms, consistent with Tufano (1998). This shows that financial markets

    do recognize the gold hedging activities taken by the firms. This result is important, as it

    establishes a necessary condition to test the relation between hedging and firm value.

    The remainder of the paper proceeds as follows. Section I summarizes risk management

    theories and related empirical evidence. In Section II, we describe the sample and explain

    measures of hedging and firm value. Section III examines the effect of hedging on gold mining

    stock exposure. Section IV examines the relation between firm value and hedging. Finally,

    Section V provides some conclusions.

  • 8/11/2019 Yanbo Goldhedging

    7/31

    6

    I. Risk Management Theories and Empirical Evidence

    Two strands of theory attempt to explain the motives of risk management. One is based

    on firm value maximization theories. The other is based on managers utility maximization.

    A. Firm Value Maximization Theories

    Firm value maximization theories states that firms can hedge to reduce certain costs or

    capital market imperfections related to volatile cash flows. There are typically three lines of

    explanations. First, hedging can reduce deadweight costs of financial distress (Mayers and

    Smith (1982), Smith and Stulz (1985)). Second, hedging may also be motivated by tax

    incentives. When firms face a convex tax function, hedging should help reduce expected taxes

    (Mayers and Smith (1982), Smith and Stulz (1985)). Hedging can also increase a firmss debt

    capacity, therefore generating greater tax advantages from greater leverage (Leland (1998)).

    These two explanations imply that corporate hedging can add value when firms face

    convex costs such as progressive taxation and bankruptcy costs. Similarly, MacKay and Moeller

    (2007) argue that hedging can add value if revenues are concave in product prices.

    The third line of argument is that hedging may also help relieve the problem of

    underinvestment, that is, when firms have many growth opportunities and external financing is

    more expensive than internally generated funds (Froot, Scharfstein, and Stein (1993)). This

    underinvestment problem arises when investment opportunities are negatively correlated with

    cash flows. For instance, airlines suffer from underinvestment when opportunities to buy

    distressed assets at a good price occur during a down cycle for the industry. The present value of

    these saved costs should be reflected in a higher market valuation.

  • 8/11/2019 Yanbo Goldhedging

    8/31

    7

    B. Manager Utility Maximization Theory

    Another strand of theory claims that hedging stems from the incentive of managers to

    maximize their personal utility functions. Risk-averse managers may engage in hedging if their

    wealth and human capital are concentrated in the firm they manage and if they find the cost of

    hedging on their own account is higher than the cost of hedging at the firm level (Stulz (1984),

    Smith and Stulz (1985)). According to this second group of theories, hedging should not affect

    market values.

    C. Empirical Evidence

    Earlier empirical literature focused on the relation between firm characteristics and

    hedging, trying to identify which theory best explains actual hedging activities. Results have

    been mixed. For instance, risk management activities are found to be more prevalent in large

    firms. One would expect to find that small firms, which are more likely to experience financial

    distress, would be more likely to hedge. Instead, hedging seems to be driven by economies of

    scale, reflecting the high fixed costs of establishing risk management programs.4

    On the other hand, Dolde (1995) and Haushalter (2000) report a positive and significant

    relation between hedging and leverage, consistent with the theory that hedging helps reduce

    financial distress. Graham and Rogers (2002) provide evidence that tax convexity does not seem

    to be a factor in the hedging decision but do find that firms hedge to increase debt capacity. This

    evidence is in line with the second explanation above. Finally, both Nance, Smith, and Smithson

    (1993) and Geczy, Minton, and Schrand (1997) find that hedging firms have greater growth

    4These costs include hiring risk management professionals and purchasing computer equipment and software forrisk management. See, for example, Nance et al. (1993), Mian (1996), Geczy et al. (1997), Haushalter (2000), andGraham and Rogers (2002). Brown (2001) estimates annual costs at about $4 million for a large multinational with$3 billion in derivatives positions.

  • 8/11/2019 Yanbo Goldhedging

    9/31

    8

    opportunities, which is consistent with the argument that hedging mitigates the potential

    underinvestment problems.

    On the whole, however, there is mixed support for value maximization theories. Mian

    (1996) surveys their implications and reports that the only reliable observation is that hedging

    firms tend to be larger. Similarly, Tufano (1996) examines the hedging activities of gold mining

    firms and finds no empirical support for the value maximization theory. Instead, he finds strong

    evidence that supports the managerial risk-aversion theory, according to which managers who

    hold more stock tend to undertake more hedging activities.

    In recent years, researchers have started to examine the direct relation between firm value

    and hedging. Allayannis and Weston (2001) report that the market value of firms using foreign

    currency derivatives is 5% higher than for nonusers, on average. This result is economically

    important, but puzzling in view of the mixed empirical evidence on hedging theories. Graham

    and Rogers (2002) argue that derivatives-induced debt capacity should increase firm value by

    1.1% on average. However, as mentioned previously, the validity of these results is questioned

    by Guay and Kothari (2003). More recently, Bartram, Brown, and Conrad (2007) examine a

    large sample of 6,888 firms from 47 countries and find hardly any relationship between

    derivatives hedging and firm value.

    More recently, Jin and Jorion (2006) examine a sample of U.S. oil and gas producers, and

    document no association between hedging and firm value. In this industry, commodity

    exposures are disclosed and easy to hedge by individual investors, so it is not clear why hedging

    should be related to firm value. Likewise, commodity exposure in the gold mining industry is

    fairly transparent and easy to hedge. The advantage of focusing on one industry is that this

    automatically controls for endogeneity, or differences in the hedging propensity of firms across

  • 8/11/2019 Yanbo Goldhedging

    10/31

    9

    industries. The question is whether hedging should be associated with differences in firm value

    for gold mining companies.

    Callahan (2002) also looks at the effect of hedging but in a time series framework. He

    first computes the alpha in a regression of mining firms stock returns on a market index. Second,

    he regresses the alpha on a hedging variable and does not find much relationship. Such setup has

    little statistical power, however, and does not directly addresses the relationship between the

    levelof firm value and hedging activities. With constant hedging, a firm could be worth a fixed

    proportion more than a non-hedger, which implies that the relative rate of change in the price, or

    alpha, would be no different. Instead, our paper looks directly at the price level embodied in the

    Q ratio, which is a better measure of value added.

    II. Sample Description

    Our analysis is based on a sample of 44 gold mining firms in the United States and

    Canada, over the time period of 1991 to 2000. This consists of the majority of gold mining firms

    in North America over this period.

    A. Hedging Variables

    Our measure of the extent of hedging activities comes from two sources. The hedging

    variable from 1991 to 1998 is computed from quarterly surveys of hedging activities of North

    American gold mining firms.5 These quarterly surveys document all the hedging activities that

    gold mining firms undertake at the end of each quarter. They are summarized into a measure

    called delta. The hedging activities include not only outstanding derivatives positions such as

    5We would like to thank Georges Dionne for providing us with the hedging data. For detailed description of thedata, please see Dionne and Garand (2003).

  • 8/11/2019 Yanbo Goldhedging

    11/31

    10

    forward sales of gold, put and call options, but also other hedges such as the gold loans with

    reimbursement in gold over a number of years.

    A delta is calculated for each position at the end of each quarter. Delta equals 1 for

    linear contracts such as forward sales or gold loans. For non-linear contracts such as put and call

    options, delta is calculated using the Black-Scholes formula. The sum of deltas is then divided

    by the estimated production for the rest of the year and the next two calendar years.6 This gives

    us , which measures the extent of hedging of gold price risk. As in Tufano (1996), we calculate

    the annual by averaging the quarterly over a year, as most of the firm data are available only

    on an annual basis.

    The hedging variable for year 1999 and 2000 comes from the data in Callahan (2002),

    which is derived from annual reports. Similar to the delta documented above, this represents the

    total gold hedging positions for each firm. As before, delta equals 1 for linear contracts such as

    forward sales or gold loans, and is calculated by the Black-Scholes formula for options and

    collars. Here, however, delta is computed on an annual basis, at fiscal year-end., dividing by the

    estimated next three-year production.

    Table 1 displays the distribution of annual . Out of 257 firm-year observations, 30 firm-

    year observations (or 11.7% of the sample) have no hedging activity. On the other hand, 54

    firm-years (or 21% of the sample) hedge more than 40% of the next three years production. 7

    On average, each firm appears 5.8 times (or 257 observations divided by 44 firms) in the sample.

    B. Tobins Q Ratio

    6This is because most of the hedging activities are designed to cover the production for the same time period.7These firm-year observations are not independent, however, because firms typically adopt similar hedgingprograms over time.

  • 8/11/2019 Yanbo Goldhedging

    12/31

    11

    We measure firm value by Tobins Q ratio, defined as the market value (MV) of assets

    over the book value (BV) of assets. The market value of assets is measured as the market value

    of common equity plus the book value of other assets. Hence, the Q ratio is defined as:

    assetstotalBV

    equitycommonMVequitycommonBV-assetstotalBV +=Q (1)

    Table 2 provides summary statistics on firm size and Tobins Q ratios. Panel A shows

    summary statistics for the entire sample. The average gold mining firm has $676 million in book

    value of total assets, $991 million in market value of common equity, and 9.29 million ounces of

    proven and probable gold reserves. The average Tobins Q ratio is 1.72. Panel B and C display

    summary statistics for subsamples of firms with and without gold hedging activities. Out of 257

    observations, 30 have no hedging activities and 227 have some hedging activity. Hedging firms

    tend to be larger (average BV assets is $739m, MV equity is $1080m), compared to firms with

    no hedging (average BV assets is $200m, MV equity is $322m). This matches evidence in other

    markets that hedging is concentrated in larger firms. Because larger firms have lower default

    risk, this contradicts the bankruptcy cost explanation of hedging. Instead, hedging programs are

    probably explained by their fixed costs, which are more easily absorbed by larger firms.

    In terms of Tobins Q, hedging firms tend to have lower Q ratios (mean=1.69,

    median=1.52), compared to non-hedging firms (mean=1.96, median=1.74). This observation is

    not consistent with firm maximization theories of hedging.

    Before we proceed, we need to confirm that financial markets recognize firms hedging

    activities. This can be tested by examining the effect of hedging on the firms stock price

    exposure to gold price movements. Normally, firms with more extensive hedging should

    experience lower sensitivity of their stock prices to gold price swings. The following section

    tests this hypothesis.

  • 8/11/2019 Yanbo Goldhedging

    13/31

    12

    III. Stock Return Sensitivity and Hedging

    Stock returns of gold mining firms are positively related to gold price changes. For

    example, Tufano (1998) shows that for each 1% change in gold prices, gold mining stocks move

    by 2% on average. We would expect that firms hedging with derivatives should experience

    dampened exposure to gold prices. Similarly, a gold mining firms exposure to gold price should

    be positively related to the amount of its gold reserves, scaled by its market value of equity.

    During the sample period of 1991 to 2000, gold price moved between $250 and to over

    $400. In the first half of the 1990s, gold price was relatively stable, moving around $350 to

    $400. However, the second half of 1990s saw big drop in gold prices, from $350 to $250 in less

    than two years. Figure 1 shows the daily spot gold price between 1991 and 2002. Thus, this

    sample period experienced substantial variations in prices, which is required for meaningful

    tests.

    In this section, we first describe gold mining firms exposure to gold price movement,

    and then test whether hedging reduces such exposure.

    A. Exposure of Gold Mining Firms

    We estimate gold price exposures from a two-factor time-series model:

    titgoldigoldtmktimiti RRR ,,,,,, ** +++= (2)

    where

    tiR , is the total stock rate of return for firm i in month t

    ,mkt t R is the monthly rate of change in the stock market index, taken as the CRSP

    NYSE/AMEX/NASDAQ value-weighted monthly return

    tgoldR , is the monthly rate of change in the spot price of gold

  • 8/11/2019 Yanbo Goldhedging

    14/31

    13

    Table 3 displays the cross-sectional distribution of estimated betas, using firms with

    complete monthly data over the entire sample period of 1991-2000 (Panel C), and the two sub-

    sample periods of 1991-1995 (Panel A) and 1996-2000 (Panel B). Gold beta is almost always

    positive and significant across all sample periods, confirming that gold mining firms have

    significant exposure to gold price movements. For example, for 16 firms with complete monthly

    data between 1991 and 2000, the average mining stock moves by 2.67% for each 1% change in

    gold price. Between 1991 and 1995, the average mining stock moves by 2.40% for each 1%

    change in gold price. In the second half of 1990s, the average mining stock moves by 2.79% for

    each 1% change in gold price. These numbers are remarkably consistent across subperiods.

    B. Effect of Hedging on Gold Exposure

    Next, we test whether hedging reduces gold beta. The following equation is used for the

    estimation

    titgoldtigoldtmktmti RRR ,,1-ti,

    1-ti,

    31,,21,1, )MVE

    reservegold(* +++++= (3)

    where

    1,, tigold is the annual for firm i, representing the percentage of next three years gold

    production effectively hedged at the end of each year

    gold reservei,t-1/MVEi,t-1is the dollar value of reserves divided by the total market value of

    equity8

    8For increased precision, both the numerator and denominator are updated each month using changes in gold andstock prices. The ratio is reset to the number reported at the end of each year.

  • 8/11/2019 Yanbo Goldhedging

    15/31

    14

    Our main hypothesis is that hedging reduces gold beta. Therefore, we expect a negative

    sign for 2. In addition, the amount of gold reserves should increase a firms gold beta.

    Therefore, we expect a positive sign for 3. This equation is estimated for firm-years with

    hedging activities only. Data were available for 24 firms for a total of 110 firm-years after

    excluding certain outliers.9

    Table 4 displays the results of the estimation. Model A uses pooled cross-section time-

    series regression, with standard errors corrected for correlation at the firm level and for

    heteroscedasticity with the Huber-White-Sandwich estimator. Model B reports results using

    fixed-effect regression. The results confirm our hypothesis. First, 2 is negative and significant,

    consistent with our conjecture that gold mining firms stock exposure to gold prices is effectively

    reduced by hedging. Tufano (1998) also found that hedging reduces gold beta. Second, 3is

    positive and significant, showing that a firm with larger gold reserves has greater exposure to

    gold prices.

    These results confirm that markets do recognize the effect of hedging activities on the

    stock exposure to gold prices. The results do not generalize the claim by Petersen and

    Thiagarajan (2000) that gold price risk can be managed as effectively by other means than

    derivatives contracts. In the next section, we test whether hedging firms are valued differently

    from non-hedging firms.

    9A firm-year observation is included if we have at least 3 consecutive monthly stock returns for the year. Weexcluded firms with gold reserves of less than 1 million ounces. These are smaller firms with less frequent trading,which unduly reduces the gold price exposure of the stocks. We also excluded outlier observations where the annualgold beta on monthly returns is less than 0.5 (3 observations), or the gold beta is greater than 9 (2 observations), orthe gold reserve/MVE ratio greater than 30 (1 observation).

  • 8/11/2019 Yanbo Goldhedging

    16/31

    15

    IV. Firm Value and Hedging

    A. Univariate Analysis

    In this section, we test whether hedging firms have higher Tobins Q ratios than non-

    hedging firms, using univariate analysis. Panel A in Table 5 presents the results of this

    comparison. We find that hedging firms actually have lower Q ratios than non-hedging firms.

    The difference between the median Tobins Q of hedging firms and non-hedging firms is 0.22,

    with a p-value of 0.03 using Wilcoxons rank-sum Z-test. In addition, we find that hedging firms

    are much larger than non-hedging firms. The median value of assets for hedging firms is twice

    that of non-hedging firms.

    Table 1 reports the distributions of hedging activities. There seems to be a natural

    grouping in terms of extent of hedging in the gold mining industry. At the low end of the

    spectrum, there are 30 firm-years (out of 257 observations, or 11.7%) with no hedging

    whatsoever. At the high end of the spectrum, there are 54 firm-years (or 21%) that hedge more

    than 40% of their next three year projected production. Following Tufano (1996), we group the

    observations into three categories: no hedging are firm-years with =0; modest hedging are

    firm-years with 040%.

    Panel B and Panel C of Table 5 compare firm size and Tobins Q ratios for different

    groups partitioned by the extent of hedging. Panel B compares firms with modest hedging

    activities to firms with no hedging activities. Panel C compares firms with extensive hedging

    activities to firms with modest hedging activities. Across the two panels, firm size seems to be

    monotonically increasing with the extent of hedging, while Tobins Q ratio seems to be

    monotonically decreasing with the extent of hedging. For example, extensive hedgers, modest

    hedgers, and non-hedgers have average asset value of $1,140 million, $614 million, and $200

  • 8/11/2019 Yanbo Goldhedging

    17/31

  • 8/11/2019 Yanbo Goldhedging

    18/31

    17

    percent. According to firm value maximization theories, if hedging has a positive effect on firm

    value, we should observe that firms derive more benefits from greater hedging, unless, of course

    hedging is irrelevant.

    We use the natural log of Tobins Q ratio as the dependent variable, as the raw Qs are

    skewed to the right. We include the following control variables following Allayannis and

    Weston (2001):

    1)Firm size: Previous empirical evidence on the relationship between firm size and firm

    value is ambiguous. However, it is important to control for size because large firms are more

    likely to hedge than small firms. The proxy is the log of total assets.

    2)

    Profitability: Profitable firms are more likely to have higher Qs than less profitable ones.

    The variable is taken as the ROA, defined as the ratio of net income to total assets. We expect a

    positive coefficient on this variable.

    3)Investment growth: Firm value may also depend on future investment opportunities. We

    use capital expenditure over total assets as a proxy. We expect a positive coefficient on this

    variable.

    4)Access to financial markets: If hedgers have limited access to financial markets, their Q

    ratios may be high because they are constrained to take only the projects with the highest net

    present values. To proxy for a firms ability to access financial markets, we use a dividend

    dummy that equals one if the firm paid dividend on common equity in the current year. In this

    interpretation, the coefficient should be negative. On the other hand, dividends can be viewed as

    a positive signal coming from management for growth prospects, which should imply a positive

    coefficient.

  • 8/11/2019 Yanbo Goldhedging

    19/31

    18

    5)Leverage: A firms capital structure may be related to its value. If the benefits of debt tax

    shields outweigh the expected costs of financial distress, then leverage can increase the firm

    value. On the other hand, if the costs of financial distress are perceived to be higher than the

    potential tax benefit coming from debt, firm value can become lower with leverage. We use a

    leverage variable defined as the book value of long-term debt over the book value of equity.

    Next, we add a new variable that is specific to this industry:

    6) Cash costs: Gold mining firms profitability is closely related to the cost of producing

    gold. Cash cost refers to the dollar cost of producing one ounce of gold. This includes all direct

    and indirect costs of mining, crushing, processing and general and administrative expenses of the

    mine, including royalties and mining taxes.10 Cash costs vary with the quality of ore deposits

    and operating efficiencies. Therefore, we expect that firms with lower average cash cost would

    enjoy higher firm value. Thus, we expect a negative coefficient on this variable.11 However,

    because of significant numbers of missing observations for this variable, Table 6 reports results

    with and without this control variable.

    Table 6 reports the results of the regressions. It displays the results for all firm-year

    observations, which include 43 firms. Similar to the results in univariate analysis, we see that

    hedging is still negatively related to firm value, even after controlling for other firm

    characteristics. All the coefficients on the hedging dummy and delta are negative. The

    coefficient on the hedging dummy is significant at the 10% level in Model 1.12

    10Cash costs exclude noncash items, such as depreciation, depleting and amortization, as well as interest expense,corporate SG&A, exploration, and extraordinary costs.11Gold mining firms report cash cost either at a per mine bases or for the company as a whole. If the figures are foreach mine, we compute a weighted-average cash cost for that year. However, because of significant numbers ofmissing observations on this data, we report in Table 6 the regression results with and without this control variable.12Apparently, American Barrick is an outlier, with 100 percent of its 3-year production fully hedged. As in Tufano(1996), we also estimate the regressions without this firm. The coefficients on delta are still negative and are nowsignificant at the 1% level.

  • 8/11/2019 Yanbo Goldhedging

    20/31

    19

    Several control variables also show a significant relationship to Tobins Q ratio. As

    expected, firms profitability (ROA) and investment growth are positively related to the Q ratio,

    indicating that firms with higher profitability and higher growth potentials are rewarded with

    higher Q ratios. In addition, Q ratios seem to be positively related to firm size among gold

    mining firms. We also see that cash cost is negatively related to the Q ratio, as expected,

    although the relationship is not significant.

    V. Conclusions

    This paper studies the hedging activities of 44 gold mining firms between 1991 and 2000,

    and examines the relationship between gold hedging and firm value. We first show that gold

    hedging reduces mining firms stock exposures to gold prices. However, contrary to the

    argument that hedging increases firm value, we do not find a positive association between

    hedging and firm value, as measured by Tobins Q ratio. In fact, the relationship appears

    negative.

    Our study is in line with the findings in Jin and Jorion (2006), who find no association

    between derivatives hedging and firm value for a sample of oil and gas producers. Within the

    gold industry, these results support the conclusions in Tufano (1996), who finds little empirical

    support for theories claiming that hedging stems from firm value maximization motives. Instead,

    he shows that hedging appears to be driven primarily by managerial risk aversion. If so, there

    should be no association between hedging and firm value, which is confirmed by our empirical

    analysis over an extended sample period.

    As in the oil and gas industry, the commodity price risk of gold mining firms is easy to

    identify and hedge. Hedging at the firm level does not confer special advantages. Even if there

  • 8/11/2019 Yanbo Goldhedging

    21/31

    20

    was a risk premium in gold forward contracts, such premium can be captured easily by investors.

    The firm environment is closer to that described by Modigliani and Miller irrelevance conditions.

    Under such conditions, it is hard to understand how hedging commodity price risk could increase

    firm value. This is confirmed by the empirical analysis in this paper.

  • 8/11/2019 Yanbo Goldhedging

    22/31

    21

    REFERENCES

    Adam, Tim and Chitru S. Fernando. 2006. Hedging, Speculation and Shareholder Value. Journal of

    Financial Economics81, pp. 283-309.

    Allayannis, George and James P. Weston. 2001. The Use of Foreign Currency Derivatives and Firm

    Market Value.Review of Financial Studies14:1, pp. 243-76.

    Bartram, Sohnke, Gregory Brown, and Jennifer Conrad. 2007. The Effects of Derivatives on Firm

    Risk and Value. Working Paper, Lancaster University.

    Callahan, Matthew. 2002. To Hedge or Not to Hedge...That Is the Question: Empirical Evidence from

    the North American Gold Mining Industry 19962000. Financial Markets, Institutions &

    Instruments11:4, pp. 271-88.

    Carter, David A., Daniel A. Rogers, and Betty J. Simkins. 2006. Does Hedging Affect Firm Value?

    Evidence from the US Airline Industry.Financial Management35:1, pp. 53-86.

    DeMarzo, Peter, and Darrell Duffie. 1995. Corporate incentives for hedging and hedge accounting.

    Review of Financial Studies8, pp. 743-771.

    Dolde, Walter, 1995. Hedging, leverage, and primitive risk.Journal of Financial Engineering4, pp.

    187-216.

    Dionne, Georges and Martin Garand, 2003. Risk management determinants affecting firms values in

    the gold mining industry: new empirical results.Economic Letters79, pp. 43-52.Froot, Kenneth A., David S. Scharfstein, and Jeremy C. Stein. 1993. Risk Management: Coordinating

    Corporate Investment and Financing Policies.Journal of Finance48:5, pp. 1629-58.

    Geczy, Christopher, Bernadette A. Minton, and Catherine Schrand. 1997. Why Firms Use Currency

    Derivatives?Journal of Finance52:4, pp. 1323-54.

    Graham, John R. and Daniel A. Rogers. 2002. Do Firms Hedge in Response to Tax Incentives?

    Journal of Finance57:2, pp. 815-39.

    Guay, W. and S.P. Kothari. 2003. How much do firms hedge with derivatives?Journal of Financial

    Economics80:3, pp. 423-461.

    Haushalter, David. 2000. Financing policy, basis risk, and corporate hedging: Evidence from oil and

    gas producers.Journal of Finance55, pp. 107-52.

    Jin, Yanbo and Philippe Jorion. 2006. Firm Value and Hedging: Evidence from the U.S. Oil and Gas

    Producers.Journal of Finance61:2, pp. 893-919.

  • 8/11/2019 Yanbo Goldhedging

    23/31

    22

    Leland, Hayne. 1998. Agency cost, risk management, and capital structure.Journal of Finance53, pp.

    1213-43.

    MacKay, Peter and Sara B. Moeller. 2007. The Value of Corporate Risk Management. Journal of

    Finance, Forthcoming.

    Mayers, David, and Clifford Smith. 1982. On the corporate demand for insurance. Journal of

    Business55, 281-296.

    Mian, Shehzad. 1996, Evidence on corporate hedging policy.Journal of Financial and Quantitative

    Analysis31, pp. 419-39.

    Nance, Deana, Clifford Smith, and Charles Smithson, 1993. On the determinants of corporate

    hedging.Journal of Finance48, pp. 267-84.

    Petersen, Mitchell A. and S. Ramu Thiagarajan. 2000. Risk Measurement and Hedging: With and

    Without Derivatives.Financial Management29:4, pp. 5-30.

    Rajgopal, Shivaram. 1999. Early evidence on the in formativeness of the SEC's market risk disclosures

    The case of commodity price risk exposure of oil and gas producers. Accounting Review74:3, pp.

    251-80.

    Simkins, Betty J. and Charles W. Smithson. 2005. Does Risk Management Add Value? A Survey of

    the Evidence. Journal of Applied Corporate Finance17:3, pp. 8-17.

    Smith, Clifford W. and Rene M. Stulz. 1985. The Determinants of Firm's Hedging Policies.Journal

    of Financial and Quantitative Analysis20:4, pp. 391-405.

    Stulz, Rene M. 1984. Optimal Hedging Policies.Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis,

    19:2, pp. 127-40.

    Tufano, Peter. 1996. Who Manages Risk? An Empirical Examination of Risk Management Practices in

    the Gold Mining Industry.Journal of Finance51:4, pp. 1097-137.

    Tufano, Peter. 1998. The Determinants of Stock Price Exposure: Financial Engineering and the Gold

    Mining Industry.Journal of Finance53:3, pp. 1015-52.

  • 8/11/2019 Yanbo Goldhedging

    24/31

    23

    Table 1: Distribution of Hedging Activity in the Gold Mining Industry

    This table displays the distribution of hedging activity measured by the delta-percentage. Delta-percentagemeasures the fraction of gold production hedged by each firm for the next three years. From 1991 to 1998, data aretaken from quarterly surveys, averaging over the year. For the years 1999 and 2000, data are taken from annualreports.

    Delta-Percentage(Firm-year observations)

    Number of firm-yearobservations

    Percentage oftotal observations

    Exactly 0 30 11.7%0.1-10 59 23.0%10-20 52 20.2%20-30 39 15.2%30-40 23 8.9%40-50 15 5.8%50-60 11 4.3%60-70 9 3.5%70-80 3 1.2%

    80-90 3 1.2%90-100 8 3.1%>100 5 1.9%Total 257 100%

    Mean 25.0Median 16.4Standard Deviation 25.9Minimum 0.0Maximum 122.7

  • 8/11/2019 Yanbo Goldhedging

    25/31

    24

    Table 2: Summary Statistics for Firm Characteristics

    Panel A describes the sample of 44 gold mining firms from 1991 to 2000, with a total of 257 firm-year observations.A subsample of firm-years with gold hedging activities is reported in Panel B. Firm-years without gold hedgingactivities are displayed in Panel C. Total assets are measured as the book value (BV) of assets. Also shown is themarket value (MV) of equity. Gold reserves are reported in millions of ounces. Gold production hedged is the

    annual average of quarterly delta-percentage from 1991 to 1998, and the end-of-year delta percentage for year 1999and 2000. Tobins Q ratio is measured as the BV of total assets BV of common equity + MV of common equitydivided by the BV of total assets.

    Panel A: All Firm-Years

    Obs. Mean Median Std. Dev. 10thPerc. 90thPerc.

    Total Assets ($m) 257 676 280 950 49 1801Market Value of equity ($m) 257 991 331 1734 36 3073Gold Reserves (million oz) 174 9.29 3.34 14.03 0.60 26.52Tobins Q 257 1.72 1.54 0.89 0.81 2.82

    Panel B: Firm-Years with Gold Hedging Activities

    Obs. Mean Median Std. Dev. 10thPerc. 90thPerc.

    Total Assets ($m) 227 739 332 991 52 2081Market Value of equity ($m) 227 1080 340 1822 35 3395Gold Reserves (million oz) 156 10.07 14.03 14.56 0.60 26.52Gold production hedged (%) 227 28 21 26 3 63Tobins Q 227 1.69 1.52 0.89 0.81 2.81

    Panel C: Firm-Years without Gold Hedging Activities

    Obs. Mean Median Std. Dev. 10th

    Perc. 90th

    Perc.Total Assets ($m) 30 200 157 188 41 393Market Value of equity($m) 30 322 240 385 51 531Gold Reserves (million oz) 18 2.57 1.04 4.19 0.33 4.30Tobins Q 30 1.96 1.74 0.88 0.89 3.35

  • 8/11/2019 Yanbo Goldhedging

    26/31

    25

    Table 3: Statistical Properties of Stock Price Exposures

    This table presents the statistical properties of the cross-sectional exposure coefficients from the time-series model

    titgoldigoldtmktimiti RRR ,,,,,, ** +++=

    Monthly stock returns from 1991 to 1995, 1996 to 2000 and 1991 to 2000 are used for firms with complete monthly dataduring the period. tmktR , and tgoldR , are the CRSP NYSE/AMEX/NASDAQ value-weighted monthly return and the

    monthly change in the spot price of gold. Statistical significance is assessed for a one-sided hypothesis.

    Panel A: 1991-1995 (25 firms)

    Beta_mkt Beta_gold

    Mean 0.46 2.40Median 0.42 2.28Standard deviation 0.40 0.67Minimum -0.43 1.26Maximum 1.29 4.15

    %>0 88% 100%%>0 and significant at p

  • 8/11/2019 Yanbo Goldhedging

    27/31

    26

    Table 4: Effect of Hedging on Gold Beta

    This table displays the regressions of monthly stock returns on the market and gold price changes, with coefficients adjustedfor the effect of hedging and reserves. The model setup is

    titgoldigoldtmktmti RRR ,,1-ti,

    1-ti,

    3,21,1, )MVE

    reservegold(* +++++=

    Data includes 24 firms (110 firm-year observations) over the calendar year 1992 to 2001. Model A uses pooled cross-sectiontime-series regression, with standard errors corrected for correlation at the firm level and for heteroscedasticity with Huber-White-Sandwich estimator; model B reports results using fixed-effect regression. T-statistics are reported in parentheses. *, **and *** denote significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% level respectively.

    Independent variable A: Pooled B: Fixed-effect

    R_mkt 0.446(4.72)***

    0.456(5.59)***

    R_gold 3.081(9.06)*** 3.100(16.61)***Delta*R_gold -1.094

    (-2.26)**-1.145(-3.27)***

    [Reserve_(gold)/MVE]*R_gold 0.057(1.41)

    0.054(2.71)***

    R-square 38.89% 40.67%Number of observations 1312 1312

  • 8/11/2019 Yanbo Goldhedging

    28/31

  • 8/11/2019 Yanbo Goldhedging

    29/31

    28

    Panel D: Gold Hedging vs. Non-Gold Hedging Firm-Years

    Best Matched with Firm Size (Total Assets)

    VariableHedgers(30obs.)

    Nonhedgers(30 obs.) Difference

    t-stat (mean)Z-score (median) p-value

    Tobins Q (mean) 1.78 1.96 -0.18 -0.68 0.50Tobins Q (median) 1.45 1.74 -0.29 -1.44 0.15Total assets ($m, mean) 200 200 0 0.00 0.99Total assets ($m, median) 156 157 -1 0.01 0.99Delta_production (mean) 31% 0Delta_production (median) 24% 0

  • 8/11/2019 Yanbo Goldhedging

    30/31

    29

    Table 6: Hedging and Firm Value

    This table presents pooled time-series cross-sectional regressions of firm value on hedging variables. The models used are:

    Q ratio = + * Dummy (=1 if hedging) + ii * control variables

    Q ratio = + * Delta_production + ii * control variables

    Q ratios are measured by the natural log of Tobins Q, defined as the market value of assets divided by the book value ofassets. The sample includes 43 firms over calendar years of 1991 to 2000, or a total of 254 firm-years. Deltais the annualaverage of quarterly delta from survey for 1991 to 1998, or the end-of-year delta from annual report for year 1999 to 2000.

    Log(asset)is the natural log of BV of total assets. ROAis defined as the ratio of net income over the previous year to totalassets. Inv_growthis measured by capital expenditure over total assets. Leverageis defined as the BV of long-term debt overthe BV of equity. Dividenddummyequals one if the firm paid dividend on its common equity in the current year. Cash costis the dollar cost of producing one ounce of gold. Year dummies are included in the regressions but are not reported here.Standard errors are corrected for correlation on a firm level and for heteroskedasticity using the Huber-White-Sandwichestimator. T-statistics are reported in the parentheses. *, ** and *** denote significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% levelrespectively.

    Model 1 2 3 4

    Observations 254 254 205 205R2 0.409 0.414 0.427 0.430Hedging dummy -0.210

    (-1.82)*-0.148(-1.09)

    Delta -0.292(-1.27)

    -0.207(-0.95)

    Log(asset) 0.057(1.69)*

    0.060(1.92)*

    0.049(1.34)

    0.055(1.49)

    ROA 0.446(3.33)***

    0.411(3.40)***

    0.355(2.15)**

    0.327(2.13)**

    Inv_growth 2.014(4.18)***

    2.119(4.42)***

    1.927(3.00)***

    1.954(3.08)***

    Leverage -0.004(-0.15)

    -0.007(-0.28)

    -0.066(-0.95)

    -0.079(-1.11)

    Dividend dummy 0.110(1.12)

    0.138(1.53)*

    0.057(0.46)

    0.077(0.69)

    Cash cost -0.002(-1.45)

    -0.002(-1.39)

  • 8/11/2019 Yanbo Goldhedging

    31/31

    Figure 1: Daily Gold Spot Price between 1991 and 2002

    200

    250

    300

    350

    400

    450

    Dec-90 Dec-91 Dec-92 Dec-93 Dec-94 Dec-95 Dec-96 Dec-97 Dec-98 Dec-99 Dec-00 Dec-01 Dec-02

    date

    Price_

    gold