WILLINGNESS TO PAY FOR DRINKING WATER CONNECTIONS:...

13
WILLINGNESS TO PAY FOR DRINKING WATER CONNECTIONS: THE CASE OF LARESTAN, IRAN MOHSEN MEHRARA University of Tehran, Iran [email protected] JAVAD PAKDIN University of Tehran, Iran AMIR NEJAD University of Tehran, Iran Abstract Water scarcity in Iran has reached a level that calls for the attention of all stakeholders including water consumers. While government as water distributor has made significant efforts in managing water at the supply side, an annual average rainfall of 251 mm (Iran Meteorological Organization, 2008) limits the capacity of this supply-side approach. As a result, policy efforts have increasingly turned towards demand management approaches. The objective of this paper is to estimate drinking tap water demand for the households in Larestan. We determine the willingness to pay (WTP) for drinking taps water connections by the Larestan’s households, using contingent valuation method (CVM). We use data from 320 randomly selected households in Larestan, Iran. Our findings show that, once drinking tap water connected, the households are willing to pay US$0.24 on average in addition to their monthly charge for per cubic meter water consumed. Key words: willingness to pay (WTP), contingent valuation method (CVM), tap water demand, Larestan, demand-side approach. JOURNAL OF ACADEMIC RESEARCH IN ECONOMICS VOLUME 1 NUMBER 2 OCTOBER 2009 191

Transcript of WILLINGNESS TO PAY FOR DRINKING WATER CONNECTIONS:...

Page 1: WILLINGNESS TO PAY FOR DRINKING WATER CONNECTIONS: …jare-sh.com/downloads/num_1_issue_2_2009/mohsen.pdf · WILLINGNESS TO PAY FOR DRINKING WATER CONNECTIONS: THE CASE OF LARESTAN,

WILLINGNESS TO PAY FOR DRINKING WATER CONNECTIONS:

THE CASE OF LARESTAN, IRAN

MOHSEN MEHRARA

University of Tehran, Iran [email protected]

JAVAD PAKDIN

University of Tehran, Iran

AMIR NEJAD

University of Tehran, Iran

Abstract

Water scarcity in Iran has reached a level that calls for the attention of all stakeholders including water consumers. While government as water distributor has made significant efforts in managing water at the supply side, an annual average rainfall of 251 mm (Iran Meteorological Organization, 2008) limits the capacity of this supply-side approach. As a result, policy efforts have increasingly turned towards demand management approaches. The objective of this paper is to estimate drinking tap water demand for the households in Larestan. We determine the willingness to pay (WTP) for drinking taps water connections by the Larestan’s households, using contingent valuation method (CVM). We use data from 320 randomly selected households in Larestan, Iran. Our findings show that, once drinking tap water connected, the households are willing to pay US$0.24 on average in addition to their monthly charge for per cubic meter water consumed.

Key words: willingness to pay (WTP), contingent valuation method (CVM), tap water demand, Larestan, demand-side approach.

JOURNAL OF ACADEMIC RESEARCH IN ECONOMICS

VOLUME 1 NUMBER 2 OCTOBER 2009 191

Page 2: WILLINGNESS TO PAY FOR DRINKING WATER CONNECTIONS: …jare-sh.com/downloads/num_1_issue_2_2009/mohsen.pdf · WILLINGNESS TO PAY FOR DRINKING WATER CONNECTIONS: THE CASE OF LARESTAN,

1. INTRODUCTION

The ability to put a value on natural resources like recreation, national parks, water, etc. is a difficult task; especially valuing water, which is the most crucial component of human life, often leads to controversies.

The use of non-market valuation has been proposed (Young, 1996; Hanemann, et al., 1991) as one method to value environmental goods. One of those valuation methods is contingent valuation and it has been applied to water-related studies in different parts of the world (Whittington et al., 1993; 2002 and Gnedenko et al., 1998). Whittington, et al., (1993) applied contingent valuation method (CVM) to estimate the WTP for improved sanitation services of 1200 randomly selected households in Kumasi, Ghana. The study found that the majority of households were willing to pay more for improved sanitation services than what they were currently paying for those services at that point in time.

Whittington et al., (2002) carried out a contingent valuation analysis to estimate the WTP for improved water supply in the Kathmandu Valley, Nepal. Among those households connected to the distribution channel, their study found a mean monthly WTP of $14.31 for the rich and $11.11 for the poor. For those households not connected to the distribution channel, the mean monthly WTP was $11.67 for a private connection and $3.19 for shared connection, while the mean monthly WTP was $8.61 for a private connection and $3.33 for a shared connection among the poor sub-sample of this group. Studies on water show that the urban poor face higher prices than the rich because they get their water from different sources including private vendors, who are likely to charge higher prices than the water utilities (Faruqui et al., 2001).

Also another study has carried out in Novgorod region (Russia) in February, 1998 (Gnedenko, E, et al., 1998). This study has shown that, on average, a household’s WTP for drinking water quality improvement in typical small Russian town makes up to 2% of household’s income. This estimate seems to be close to the analogous estimates of the World Bank for some developing countries.

Background of Drinking Water Provision to the household of the Water Market in Larestan

Larestan region is one of the most underprivileged regions of country in the field of drinking water resources and during the history has been suffered form water shortage. People of past ages have solved some of their problems related to annual water shortage, by using their inherent talents in pool construction, tap mouth and ghanat. But however they still have problem. Now using pools is an ordinary affair and although it is not a clean water but they have no other choice. However, Water Supply Company of city of Larestan has been under use since 1959, and developed in 1961, and completed with aid of General Department of Building and Urbanism of Fars province in 1971. But unfortunately despite all of performed actions, now this with a population more than 54688 peoples (Statistical

JOURNAL OF ACADEMIC RESEARCH IN ECONOMICS

192 VOLUME 1 NUMBER 2 OCTOBER 2009

Page 3: WILLINGNESS TO PAY FOR DRINKING WATER CONNECTIONS: …jare-sh.com/downloads/num_1_issue_2_2009/mohsen.pdf · WILLINGNESS TO PAY FOR DRINKING WATER CONNECTIONS: THE CASE OF LARESTAN,

Center of Iran, 2006) has not good water supply condition; people still suffer form water salinity and Water Organization with establishing drinking water stations in some districts of city has tried to solve citizen’s problems so that now people are going to these districts to secure water.

The objective of this paper is to estimate drinking tap water demand for the households in Larestan. We determine the willingness to pay (WTP) for drinking taps water connections by the Larestan’s households, using contingent valuation method (CVM).

We use data from 160 randomly selected households in Larestan, Iran. Our findings show that, once drinking water connected, the households are willing to pay US$0.24 on average in addition to their monthly charge for per cubic meter water consumed.

2. METHODOLOGY

The choice of method for valuing non-marketed goods depends on its computational ease and the problem to be studied. The CV method was originally proposed by Ciriacy-Wantrup (1947) who was of the opinion that the prevention of soil erosion generates some ‘extra market benefits’ that are public goods in nature, and therefore, one possible way of estimating these benefits is to elicit the individuals’ willingness to pay for these benefits through a survey method (see Portney, 1994; Hanemann, 1994). However, Davis (1963) was the first to use the CV method empirically when he estimated the benefits of goose hunting through a survey among the goose-hunters. This method gained popularity after the two major non-use values, namely, option and existence values have been recognized as important components of the total economic values in environmental economics literature, especially during the 1960s. While the conventional revealed preference methods such as travel cost method are not capable of capturing these non-use values (Smith, 1993), the only method that is identified for estimating these values is the contingent valuation method (CVM) (see, Desvousges et al., 1993).

The use of CVM for measuring WTP for social projects is well accepted and widely used in many different circumstances in developing countries. However, there is a very large part of the literature in CVM which discusses the "accuracy" of CVM.

There are various ways of classifying the nature of the biases that may be presented in the CVM. These include strategic bias (see Prince et al. 1992; Brookshire et al. 1976; Rowe et al. 1980; Hoehn and Randall 1987; Milon 1989; Bergstorm et al. 1989; Mitchell and Carson 1989; Evans and Harris 1982), design bias (see Boyle et al. 1986), vehicle bias (see OECD 1995), information bias (see Hoehn and Randall 1976; Boyle 1988; Bergstorm et al. 1989; Whitehead and Blomquist 1991; Hanley and Munro 1994), hypothetical bias (see Bishop et al.

JOURNAL OF ACADEMIC RESEARCH IN ECONOMICS

VOLUME 1 NUMBER 2 OCTOBER 2009 193

Page 4: WILLINGNESS TO PAY FOR DRINKING WATER CONNECTIONS: …jare-sh.com/downloads/num_1_issue_2_2009/mohsen.pdf · WILLINGNESS TO PAY FOR DRINKING WATER CONNECTIONS: THE CASE OF LARESTAN,

1983; Thayer 1981), starting point bias (see Boyle 1985; Randall et al. 1983), and operating bias (see Cummings et al. 1986).

Obviously, it is possible that some biases may exist when using the CVM. These biases are due to the hypothetical nature of the approach. Nevertheless, careful survey design is necessary to control these sources of bias. The study here attempted to control certain biases.

There are two bidding procedures used in CVM, known as the single-bounded and double-bounded dichotomous choice models respectively. The single-bounded model approach recovers the bid amount as a threshold by asking one dichotomous choice question, while the double bounded offers a second bid following the response to the first bid (Hanemann et al., 1991). Whether the single-bounded is the best method than the double-bounded remains an empirical question. Hanneman et al., (1991) applied both the single- and double-bounded CVM to compare their statistical efficiency. They estimated WTP for protecting wildlife and wetlands habitat in California and found that the double-bounded dichotomous CVM was statistically more efficient than the single-bounded model.

Herriges and Shogren (1996) used a double bounded DC model in which the respondents combined their prior WTP with the first bid amount to form a revised WTP. They compared their results with the initial single bounded DC model and concluded that a single bounded model is the best to estimate WTP in the presence of anchoring bias. However, once they controlled for the anchoring effect, there was little improvements in the results in terms of small efficiency gains.

According to Ready et al., (1996), analysts phrase the valuation question to generate information about the respondents' compensating variation for the increase in the level of provision. In the real world, consumers face prices with limited budget constraints, while contingent valuation makes use of a hypothetical market. It is therefore, important to accurately reflect the terms of the hypothetical market for the particular good being surveyed.

The model most appropriate to analyze the responses to our WTP bids is the conventional of obtaining a "no" or a "yes" response as presented in equation (1):single-bounded dichotomous CVM by Hanneman et al., (1991). This model states the probability:

{ }

{ }max

max

Pr);(1)(

Pr);()(

WTPBBGB

WTPBBGB

y

n

≤⇔−=

>⇔=

θπ

θπ (1)

Where )(Bnπ and )(Byπ is the probability of a "no" and a "yes" response

respectively, );( θBG is the cumulative distribution (CDF) of the individual's true

maximum WTP, with a parameter vector θ , B is the ultimate bid and maxWTP is

the true maximum WTP. Equation (1) implies that consumers are willing to pay a price if the bid is below the true maximum amount they are willing to pay and they are not willing to pay if the bid is higher. According to Hanneman et al., (1991),

JOURNAL OF ACADEMIC RESEARCH IN ECONOMICS

194 VOLUME 1 NUMBER 2 OCTOBER 2009

Page 5: WILLINGNESS TO PAY FOR DRINKING WATER CONNECTIONS: …jare-sh.com/downloads/num_1_issue_2_2009/mohsen.pdf · WILLINGNESS TO PAY FOR DRINKING WATER CONNECTIONS: THE CASE OF LARESTAN,

this statistical model can be interpreted as a utility maximization response, within a random utility context.

Theoretically, a logit model can be used to estimate the mean and median values of limited dependent variables (Mittelhammer, 2000; Maddalla, 1983). The logistic model can be presented as follows:

).exp(1

).exp()1(

β

β

i

i

X

XyP

+== (2)

Where P(Y =1) shows the probability of obtaining a yes, Xi is a row vector of exogenous variables, and β is a column vector of unknown coefficients. Li et

al., (2002) used the model given in equation (3) to estimate the WTP for genetically modified (GM) food products in China.

iiii ZBWTP ελρα ++−= ' (3)

Where WTP is the WTP function for GM foods, B is the ultimate bid offered to each respondent, Z is a vector of individual characteristics, and α , ρ ,

λ are vectors of unknown coefficients and iε is the identically, independently

distributed random variable with zero mean, with i representing the number of respondents.

3. STUDY DESIGN AND DATA

This study utilizes the DC questionnaire to measure the individual’s WTP in the CV surveys. It involves assigning a single bid from a range of predetermined bids that potentially reflect the maximum WTP amounts of the respondents for a particular good. The respondents are asked to state only “yes” or “no” to that bid on an all or nothing basis (Hadker et al., 1997; Venkatachalam, 2003).

The single-bounded dichotomous choice questionnaire, therefore, was designed for acquiring individual WTP to determine the existence value for drinking tap water in Larestan. This questionnaire for interviews was carefully designed to provide respondents with adequate and accurate information, making them fully aware of the hypothetical market situation. This information from the CV questionnaire was intended not only to help them reveal their true values as accurately as possible, but also to reduce the rate of rejection from the respondents (Hadker et al., 1997).

We ask respondents their willingness to pay for individual drinking tap water connections in a bidding game format, starting with the highest offer of 4000 RIALS per cubic meter followed by 3000 RIALS and finally 2000 RIALS. In our study, we use a starting value of 4000 RIALS based on the maximum value of 4000 RIALS paid by households at present (note that this procedure might lead to starting point bias in responses to the WTP question). From the questionnaire data,

JOURNAL OF ACADEMIC RESEARCH IN ECONOMICS

VOLUME 1 NUMBER 2 OCTOBER 2009 195

Page 6: WILLINGNESS TO PAY FOR DRINKING WATER CONNECTIONS: …jare-sh.com/downloads/num_1_issue_2_2009/mohsen.pdf · WILLINGNESS TO PAY FOR DRINKING WATER CONNECTIONS: THE CASE OF LARESTAN,

we know which of the following four WTP intervals each respondent would fall in: pay at least 4000 RIALS, pay 3000 RIALS but not 4000 RIALS, pay 2000 RIALS but not 3000 RIALS, and, unwilling to pay 2000 RIALS (no to all three bids). For our WTP estimation, we use this observed data to generate a synthetic data set by posing a hypothetical single bounded CV question to each respondent. We divide the sample into three equal sub-sets and determine whether each household would respond yes or no to a bid of 4000 RIALS, 3000 RIALS, or 2000 RIALS. Thus, a person in the second interval above would say no to 4000 RIALS, but yes to 3000 RIALS or 2000 RIALS.

The paper uses primary data on a sample of 320 randomly selected households in Larestan, collected between February and March of 2008. Data on all the variables used in the model are collected from the individual households in face-to-face interviews. Table 2 presents the variables used in the model.

Variable Name Description

WTP

A dummy variable indicating whether respondents are willing to pay to get tap water connections.

WTP = 1, if yes, = 0 if no The amount of money the consumer is willing to pay per month, in addition to his or her current monthly charges for water, once connected.

Bid

The amount of money the consumer is willing to pay per month, in addition to his current monthly charges for one cubic meter of water

Income per capita The respondent's level of income over family size (Iran

Rial)

Age Age of the respondent

Distance The distance respondent walk to the water point

(Kilometer)

Time Time consumed for water collection (minute)

Trip Number of trips for water provision in a month

education The level of respondent’s education (1 to 5)

House House size (m3)

Table 1: Description of Variables

JOURNAL OF ACADEMIC RESEARCH IN ECONOMICS

196 VOLUME 1 NUMBER 2 OCTOBER 2009

Page 7: WILLINGNESS TO PAY FOR DRINKING WATER CONNECTIONS: …jare-sh.com/downloads/num_1_issue_2_2009/mohsen.pdf · WILLINGNESS TO PAY FOR DRINKING WATER CONNECTIONS: THE CASE OF LARESTAN,

4. EMPIRICAL MODEL OF WATER DEMAND

There are three methods to compute the value of WTP: the first method, called mean WTP, is to calculate the expected value of WTP by numerical integration, ranging from 0 to + ∞ ; the second method, called overall mean WTP, is to calculate the expected value of WTP by numerical integration, ranging from -∞ to + ∞ and the third method, called truncated mean WTP, is to calculate the expected value of WTP by numerical integration, ranging from 0 to maximum bid. The last method however, is preferable because it satisfies consistency with theoretical constraints, statistical efficiency and ability to be aggregated (Duffield and Patterson, 1991). Thus, the truncated mean WTP is used in this research. The logit model is then estimated using the maximum likelihood (ML) estimation method, the most common technique for estimating the logit model. Once the parameters have been estimated using the ML method then the expected value of WTP can be calculated by numerical integration, ranging from 0 to maximum bid (B) as follows:

max max

0 0

exp( ) 1( )

1 exp( ) 1 exp[ ( )]

B BB

E WTP dB dBB B

α β

α β α β

′ += =

′ ′+ + + − +∫ ∫ (4)

Where E (WTP) is the expected value of WTP, and α ′ is the adjusted intercept which was added by the other term to the original intercept term of α ( iXα α δ′ = + ).

Logit models may be estimated with either linear or logarithmic functional forms in measuring both use and preservation values. However, the linear-logit model were employed in this study because the linear functional form was much easier to compute mean WTP.

The WTP model for water connections in Larestan is presented in equation (5).

i i i iWTP B X eα β δ= + + + (5)

Where WTPi is the WTP function for household i, B is the bid offered to

each household, Xi is the vector of individual attributes defined as Xi = {Age,

Income per capita, Distance, Trip, Time, education, House}, α , β , δ are vectors of unknown coefficients, ei is the identically, independently distributed random variable with zero mean and i represents the number of households.

Statistical analysis of variables, estimating parameters of logit model and mathematical calculations are carried out by SPSS, Eviews and Maple softwares, respectively.

JOURNAL OF ACADEMIC RESEARCH IN ECONOMICS

VOLUME 1 NUMBER 2 OCTOBER 2009 197

Page 8: WILLINGNESS TO PAY FOR DRINKING WATER CONNECTIONS: …jare-sh.com/downloads/num_1_issue_2_2009/mohsen.pdf · WILLINGNESS TO PAY FOR DRINKING WATER CONNECTIONS: THE CASE OF LARESTAN,

5. INTERPRETATIONS OF RESULTS

First we prepared 320 questionnaires and filled them through direct interviewing with the respondents. All of these questionnaires are filled during the period of February and March of 2008. 292 pieces of these questionnaires were accepted and what was remaining eliminated due to incorrect and unrelated answers.

Due to the hard condition of drinking water provision and also people cultural and religion characteristics, almost all the people who refer to tank are men and as a result all the respondents were men. 91.1 percent of respondents were caretaker of family. All the respondents are 23 years old or older and 16 of them were illiterate, 34 have primary education, 64 guidance education, 106 have diploma and 72 have bachelor and higher education.

Average of family dimension was 4.3 people and average of drinking water consumption of families under question was 75.27 liters per week.

Now for per two months 133 people of respondents are paying less than 50000RLS. 57 people between 50000 to 100000RLS. 57 people between 100000 to 1500000RLS, and finally 45 people are paying more than 1500000 RLS. According to questionnaires, 40 families have less than 40 liters water consumption per week. At the same time 142 families have water consumption between 40 to 80Li., 64 families between 80 to 100Li., and finally 46 families have more than 100Li. Water consumption.

Eq. (6) shows the expected value of mean WTP, which represents the existence value of the drinking tap water. It was calculated by numerical integration, ranging from 0 to maximum bid (Eq. (4)) after parameters from logit models were estimated using the ML method (Table 2). The socioeconomic term of δ was estimated and added to an adjusted intercept together with the original intercept term of α:

∫ ×+−+

4000

0 )]001.051.2(exp[1

1dB

B=2399.7 RIALS ≈ US$0.24 (6)

The median WTP of about 2399.7 RIALS indicates that, on average, water

consumers in Larestan are willing to pay 2399.7 RIALS for drinking tap water connections in addition to their monthly water consumption. Though this bid is supported by the data, and it falls within the interval of 2000 to 4000 RIALS offered as the bid. Table 2 presents the general results of the WTP function.

From the interview responses, 69.2% of the respondents were willing to pay a bid to get drinking tap water connections. The results from the model given in equation (6) are presented in table 2.

JOURNAL OF ACADEMIC RESEARCH IN ECONOMICS

198 VOLUME 1 NUMBER 2 OCTOBER 2009

Page 9: WILLINGNESS TO PAY FOR DRINKING WATER CONNECTIONS: …jare-sh.com/downloads/num_1_issue_2_2009/mohsen.pdf · WILLINGNESS TO PAY FOR DRINKING WATER CONNECTIONS: THE CASE OF LARESTAN,

Variable Coefficient Z-value P-value

Intercept 0.183 0.149 0.882

Bid -0.001 -4.345 0.000 Income per capita

0.000 5.130 0.000

education 0.700 4.933 0.000 Age -0.030 -1.907 0.057 Distance×Trip 0.015 2.682 0.007 Time 0.021 2.528 0.012 House 0.002 1.689 0.091 Log likelihood

-114.14

Percent of right prediction

75.88 McFadden R2

0.367

Probability(LR stat)

0.000

Table 2: WTP results

The results show that an increase in the bid reduces the consumers' WTP

for connections, which is consistent with theory and previous studies (Li, et al., 2002). All variables are significant at 90% significance level and the coefficients shows that increases in the level of income, level of literacy, the distance walked to collect water, and number of trips to collect water, and time takes to reach tank and decrease in respondent's age increase consumers' WTP for connections. The impacts of income and age on WTP is consistent with other studies (Li et al., 2002; Loureiro et al., 2001). WTP for connections increases with the difficulty of drinking water provision. The longer it takes to collect water (more distance, more number of trips to collect water and time takes to reach tank), the more the consumers are willing to pay for connections. This is in line with findings from the primary survey, where consumers indicated that they would rather pay for connections instead of walking a distance. The P-values shows that we have enough evidence to reject the hypothesis that all the coefficients are zero.

6. CONCLUSION

The paper estimates demand for drinking tap water in Larestan, Iran. Using CVM, we find that on average, consumers are willing to pay about 2399.7 RIALS in addition to their monthly water charge to get drinking water connected to their homes. This amount falls within the range of 2000 RIALS to 4000 RIALS offered as ultimate bids and it also falls within the range of 2100 RIALS to 3700 RIALS currently paid by most of the households.

An increase in the bid offered to households reduces the WTP for connections, which is consistent with theory and other findings (Li et al., 2002). Variables, such as income per capita, level of literacy, the distance walked to collect water, numbers of trips to collect water and time takes to reach tank have

JOURNAL OF ACADEMIC RESEARCH IN ECONOMICS

VOLUME 1 NUMBER 2 OCTOBER 2009 199

Page 10: WILLINGNESS TO PAY FOR DRINKING WATER CONNECTIONS: …jare-sh.com/downloads/num_1_issue_2_2009/mohsen.pdf · WILLINGNESS TO PAY FOR DRINKING WATER CONNECTIONS: THE CASE OF LARESTAN,

positive impacts on the households' WTP for drinking tap water connections. At the same time variable age has a negative impact on it. This is in line with previous findings and findings from the survey.

A median WTP of about 2399.7 RIALS in addition to monthly charges indicates that the households are willing to pay more than they are currently paying, to get individual drinking tap water connections. If the policy makers take affordability and demographic characteristics of the households into account, maybe an additional US$0.24 a month is not so cheap to the households, given their average reported income of 3756849 RIALS a month.

7. REFERENCES

Aprahamian F., O. Chanel and S. Luchini (2007). Starting point bias and unobserved heterogeneity in cv surveys: econometrics with and application to air pollution. American Journal of Agricultural Economics. Vol. 89, Issue 2, 533-547

Bishop. R., K. Boyle and M. Walsh (1983). The role of question order and respondent experience in contingent valuation studies. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 25(1), 80-99.

Bergstrom, J. et al. (1989). Information effects in contingent markets. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 71, 685-691.

Boyle K. J. and R. C. Bishop (1988). Welfare measurements using contingent valuation: a comparison of techniques. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 70, 20-28.

Boyle K. J. et al. (1986). Starting point bias in contingent valuation surveys, Land Economics, 61, 188-94.

Boyle K. (1985). Starting point bias in contingent valuation bidding games. Land Economics 61, 188-194.

Brookshire DS, Ives BC, Schulze WD (1976). The valuation of aesthetic preferences. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, vol 3, 325-346.

Chien Y., C. J. Huang and D. Shaw (2004). A general model of starting point bias in double bounded dichotomous contingent valuation surveys. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, vol. 50, 362-377

Cummings, R.R., Brookshire, D.S., and Schulze, W.D. (1986). Valuing environmental goods: An assessment of the “Contingent Valuation Method”.

Davis, R. K. (1963). Recreation planning as an economic problem. Natural Resources Journal 3(3), 239–249.

JOURNAL OF ACADEMIC RESEARCH IN ECONOMICS

200 VOLUME 1 NUMBER 2 OCTOBER 2009

Page 11: WILLINGNESS TO PAY FOR DRINKING WATER CONNECTIONS: …jare-sh.com/downloads/num_1_issue_2_2009/mohsen.pdf · WILLINGNESS TO PAY FOR DRINKING WATER CONNECTIONS: THE CASE OF LARESTAN,

Desvousges, W. H., J. F. Reed, R. W. Dunford, K. J. Boyle, S. P. Hudson, and K. N. Wilson (1993). Measuring natural resource damage with contingent valuation: A test of validity and reliability contingent valuation. In A Critical Assessment, 91–159. Amsterdam, The Netherlands: North-Holland.

Duffield, J. W.; Patterson, D. A. (1991). Inference and optimal design for a welfare measure in dichotomous choice contingent valuation. Land Economics, 67(2), 225-239

Evans R C and Harris R H D (1982). A bayesian analysis of the free rider meta game. Southern Economic Journal, vol 49, 137-149

Farugui N. L, A. K., Bisw and M. J. Bino (2001). Water management in Islam. United Nations University Press. New York, U.S.A.

Gnedenko, Ekaterina, Z. Gorbunova, G. Safonov (2000). Contingent Valuation of drinking water quality in Samara city. EERC Working Paper Series, number 98-263e.

Gnedenko E.D., Gorbunova Z.V. (1998). A contingent valuation study of projects improving drinking water quality. Modern Toxicological Problems, No. 3, Kiev.

Hadker, N., Sharma, S., David, A. and Muraleedharan, T.R. (1997). Willingness to pay for Borivili National Park: Evidence from a contingent valuation. Ecological Economics, 21, 105-122.

Hanemann, W. M. (1994). Valuing the environment through contingent valuation. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8, 19-43.

Hanneman, M., J. Loomisand and B. Kanninen, (1991). Statistical efficiency of double bounded dichotomous choice valuation. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 73, 1255-1263.

Hanley, N., C. Spash, L. Walker. (1994). Problems in valuing the benefits of biodiversity protection. Discussion Paper in Economics 94/8. Department of Economics, University of Stirling: Stirling, Scotland.

Herriges J. A., and J. F. Shogren (1996). Starting point bias in dichotomous choice valuation with follow-up questioning. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 30, 112-131.

Hoehn, J. P and Randall, A (1976). A satisfactory benefit cost indicator from contingent valuation.. Journal of Environmental Management, 14, 226-247.

Hoehn, J.P. and Randall, A. (1987). A satisfactory benefit cost indicator from contingent valuation. Journal of Environment, Economics and Management, 14, 226-47

Iran Meteorological Organization (2008), World Weather Records.

Li Q., K. R. Curtis, J. J. McCluskey and T. I. Wahl (2002). Consumer attitudes towards genetically modified foods in Beijing, China. AgBioForum, 5(4), 2002, 145-152.

JOURNAL OF ACADEMIC RESEARCH IN ECONOMICS

VOLUME 1 NUMBER 2 OCTOBER 2009 201

Page 12: WILLINGNESS TO PAY FOR DRINKING WATER CONNECTIONS: …jare-sh.com/downloads/num_1_issue_2_2009/mohsen.pdf · WILLINGNESS TO PAY FOR DRINKING WATER CONNECTIONS: THE CASE OF LARESTAN,

Loureiro M.L., J. J. McCluskey and R. C. Mittelhammer (2001). Assessing consumer preferences for organic, eco-labeled and regular apples. Journal of Agriculture and Resource Economics, 26, 404-413.

Maddalla G.S. (1983). Limited Dependent and Qualitative Variables in Econometrics. Econometric Society Monographs, Cambridge University Press, page 23.

Milon J. W. (1989). Contingent valuation experiments for strategic behaviour. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, vol 17, 293-308.

Mitchell, R. C., and R. T. Carson (1989). Using Surveys to Value Public Goods: The Contingent Valuation Method. Washington, DC: Resources for the Future.

Mittelhammer R. C., G. G. Judge and D. J. Miller (2000). Econometric foundations, Cambridge University Press, page 569.

OECD. (1995). The economic appraisal of environmental projects and policy: A practical guide, OECD, Paris.

Portney, P. R. (1994). The contingent valuation debate: Why economists should care. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8, 3-17.

Prince Prince, R., M. McKee, S. Ben-David, and M. Bagnoli, (1992). Improving the contingent valuation method: Implementing the contribution game“. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 23, 78-90.

Randall, A., Hoehn, J.P. and Brookshire, D.S. (1983). Contingent Valuation Surveys for Evaluating Environmental Assets. Natural Resources Journal, 23, 635-648.

Ready, R. C., J. C. Buzby and D. Hu (1996). Differences between Continuous and Discrete Contingent Value Estimates. Land Economics, 72, 397-411.

Rowe, R.D., R.C. d’Arge and D.S. Brookshire (1980). An experiment on the economic value of visibility. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 7, 1-19.

Smith VK (1993). Non-market valuation of natural resources: An interpretive appraisal. Land Economics, 69(1), 1–26.

Statistical Center of Iran (2006).

Thayer MA (1981). Contingent valuation techniques for assessing environmental impacts: Further evidence. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, vol 8, 27-44.

Venkatachalam, L. (2004). The contingent valuation method: A review. Environmental Impact Assessment Review, 24, 89–124.

Whittington D., Pattanayak S. K., Yang J., and Kumar K.C.B. (2002). Do Households Want Privatized Municipal Water Services? Evidence from Kathmandu, Nepal, Research Triangle Institute (RTI).

JOURNAL OF ACADEMIC RESEARCH IN ECONOMICS

202 VOLUME 1 NUMBER 2 OCTOBER 2009

Page 13: WILLINGNESS TO PAY FOR DRINKING WATER CONNECTIONS: …jare-sh.com/downloads/num_1_issue_2_2009/mohsen.pdf · WILLINGNESS TO PAY FOR DRINKING WATER CONNECTIONS: THE CASE OF LARESTAN,

Whitehead, John C., and Glenn C. Blomquist (1991). Measuring contingent values for wetlands: Effects of information about related environmental goods. Water Resources Research 27, no. 10, 2523-2531.

Whittington D., D. T. Lauria, A.M. Wright, K. Choe, J. A. Hughes and V. Swarna, (1993). Household Demand for Improved Sanitation Services in Kumasi, Ghana: A Contingent Valuation Study, Water Resources Research 29, 1539-1560.

Young R. A. (1996). Measuring Economic Benefits for Water Investments and Policies. The World Bank. World Bank Technical Paper No. 338. Washington D. C., U.S.A.

JOURNAL OF ACADEMIC RESEARCH IN ECONOMICS

VOLUME 1 NUMBER 2 OCTOBER 2009 203