ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian...

106
Tackling the Monster Bank: Andrew Jackson, Nicholas Biddle, and the Bank War

Transcript of ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian...

Page 1: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

Tackling the Monster Bank:Andrew Jackson, Nicholas Biddle,

and the Bank War

Anthony Ciardiello

Senior Thesis

April 20, 2010

Page 2: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

Acknowledgements

I would like to sincerely thank Professor Sean Adams, who has served as my advisor over the

course of this past year. His advice, guidance, and wisdom have been truly invaluable as I em-

barked on this academic pursuit. Additionally, his courses on the Early Republic, as well as the

History of American Capitalism, were taught with aplomb and served to catalyze my interest in

the Bank War and the Jacksonian Era. Without his tutelage, this thesis would not have been pos-

sible.

I would also like to extend my gratitude towards a former colleague of mine, Matthew Winters.

Mr. Winters was the first person to introduce me to Andrew Jackson and all of his eccentricities.

Our initial discussions regarding America’s seventh president first piqued my interest in Andrew

Jackson, and led me to pursue the topic further.

Finally, it is imperative that I acknowledge the supportive role my parents, David and Susan,

played in the process of writing this thesis. My father, as a small business owner, instilled the

ideas of capitalism, democracy, and the American spirit ever since my youth, which subse-

quently led me to pursue topics in political economy. Additionally, my mother inculcated a love

of reading and books, a passion which continues to this day. Their love and support has been a

constant source of inspiration for me, and this thesis is dedicated to them.

Page 3: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

Table of Contents

Section Name Page Number

Introduction 1

Beginnings

Andrew Jackson 3

Nicholas Biddle 7

Central Banking

First Bank of the United States 11

Henry Clay and the American System 13

Second Bank of the United States 14

The Bank War Begins

Clay’s Machinations 18

Arguments Against, and the Veto 21

Clay, Webster, and Arguments For 28

The Election of 1832 33

The War Rages On

Removing the Deposits 35

End Game 40

Examining the Bank War Historiographically

Arthur Schlesinger 42

Murray Rothbard 44

Bray Hammond 46

Susan Hoffman 48

Conclusions 50

Epilogue: The Monster Bank Today 53

Bibliography 57

Page 4: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

Introduction

Throughout the history of mankind, politics and the economy are two factors that always

play a role in the shaping of a nation; one invariably affects the other. So it was the case in the

nascent United States of America, a nation conceived in liberty, yet still struggling with its iden-

tity in the early nineteenth century.

During the 1830s, the United States faced many new movements, both religious and po-

litical, and was struggling with the incompatibility of slavery with the ideals set forth in the Dec-

laration of Independence. Yet attention at the highest levels of government was not focused on

these events in particular, but another situation entirely. The Second Bank of the United States

had been an integral part of the nation’s economy for over fifteen years, yet with the election of

the nation’s first populist president, the role and privileges of the Bank were put into question.

In this thesis, the role and function of the Second Bank of the United States will be ex-

plored, as well as the characters that both supported and opposed its role during the Early Repub-

lic. The two primary actors (in what would become known to history as the Bank War) are the

seventh president of the United States, Andrew Jackson, and his counterpart, the President of the

Second Bank of the United States, Nicholas Biddle, although the actions of others, such as the

statesman Henry Clay, will not be neglected. After analyzing opinions of the time from newspa-

pers and other publications, the Bank War will be examined historiographically. One hundred

and seventy years after the end of the events of the 1830s, there are still differing schools of

thought regarding the Bank War. Certain historians fault the actions of Andrew Jackson, who, in

an attempt to act as a president of the people, instead crushed an institution benefitting them.

Others place the blame not on the President, but the Bank itself. If Biddle had not been as arro-

1

Page 5: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

gant and vengeful, he very well could have spared the American people from an economic con-

traction and recession.

This thesis does not set out to examine the entire Jacksonian Era; indeed, entire volumes

of work have been dedicated that topic. During what can be called the Age of Jackson, the

United States had to address many growing pains, such as tariffs, Indian removal, internal im-

provements, nullification, and emerging social movements. Instead, the focus of this paper will

be on the Bank War and the nascent U.S. economy. When appropriate, these other movements

may be mentioned in order to highlight or augment the point at hand.

Although the Bank War occurred almost two centuries ago, important lessons can still be

gleaned from it. The Bank War greatly increased the power and role of the presidency; it estab-

lished the President of the United States as the dominant figure in American politics. It concurred

with the rise of democracy in America; for the first time, the electorate, not the eastern bankers

or the political class, had a say in the direction of the American economy. As such, Jackson used

his power as the president to implement policies conducive to the will of the people. As was the

case then, the United States today still struggles with and argues about the proper role of the cur-

rent central bank, the Federal Reserve, in contemporary society. With the current economic melt-

down still fresh in the minds of the public, the argument over what is to be done now versus what

has been done previously takes on a new historical significance. The characters of Andrew Jack-

son and Nicholas Biddle live on.

2

Page 6: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

Beginnings

Andrew Jackson

Born in the Waxhaws, a frontier region between North Carolina and South Carolina, An-

drew Jackson was the third child (and third son) of Andrew Jackson, Sr. and Elizabeth Hutchin-

son Jackson. However, Jackson’s mother was widowed when her husband injured himself chop-

ping wood for the family. Andrew Jackson was born a few weeks later, and named after his de-

ceased father.

The environment in which the president was raised would shape much of his future per-

sona. Personal violence was quite common on the Carolina frontier, and “young Andrew Jackson

grew up certain that a well-known willingness to repay violence with more violence was essen-

tial to a respected man’s reputation.”1 Young Andrew Jackson was wild and reckless, engaging

in fights with children two or three times his own size.2 One anecdote that has survived history

has Jackson firing an overly-loaded musket to prove his strength. He was thrown to the ground

by the blast, and as he got up off the floor, he yelled to the boys around him, “By God, if one of

you laughs, I’ll kill him!”3 No one had the gall to challenge him; Jackson’s threats were often

quite credible.

The British invaded the Carolina highlands in 1780, and Jackson enlisted in the Revolu-

tionary Army as a courier, joining his elder brothers who were serving as soldiers. His eldest

brother died in battle, and both he and his younger brother were captured. It is during his captiv-

ity where one of the stories regarding Jackson’s resilience and toughness emerges. When ordered

1 Henry L. Watson, Andrew Jackson vs. Henry Clay: Democracy and Development in Antebellum America (Boston: Bedford/St. Martin’s, 1998), 23.2 Robert Remini, Andrew Jackson (New York: Twayne Publishers, Inc., 1966), 16.3 Ibid.

3

Page 7: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

by a British officer to clean his boots, Jackson responded, “Sir, I am a prisoner of war, and I

claim to be treated as such.”4 Angered by the young American’s impetuousness, the British offi-

cer raised his saber and slashed Jackson across his face and outstretched hand, giving him scars

that he would carry with him for the rest of his life.

When Andrew and his surviving brother contracted smallpox, his mother was able to se-

cure their release from captivity. With her boys’ safety ensured, Mrs. Jackson traveled to

Charleston to nurse some of her other relatives back to health. It was on this ship she contracted

cholera and died. Andrew’s brother, Robert, took a turn for the worse, and he, too, perished.

Now, Andrew Jackson was an orphan in the world at the age of fourteen, the British taking away

his entire family from him in one way or another. It was from this point on he developed a deep

antipathy towards anything and everything British.

It speaks to Jackson’s tenacity that rather than giving up at this point in his life, he forged

ahead. Moving to Salisbury, North Carolina in 1783, he entered the law office of Spruce McCay

to learn what he decided would be his future profession.5 Three years later, he was admitted to

the bar. Although he did not have any formal legal education, he was not, as many future genera-

tions would paint him, unintelligent by any means. He subsequently moved out to the western

frontier, in to the area that would become Tennessee, and practiced small claims law and cases

involving assault and battery. He rose quickly, becoming a delegate to the Tennessee constitu-

tional convention in 1796. When Tennessee became a state later that year, he was elected as the

state’s at-large Representative. The following year, he became one of the state’s Senators, but re-

signed that post to sit on the bench of the Tennessee Supreme Court, where he served until 1804.

4 Ibid., 18.5 Ibid., 21.

4

Page 8: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

By his thirtieth birthday, Jackson had served in both branches of Congress and on the

Supreme Court of the state of Tennessee, but his greatest claim to fame was yet to come. In

1801, Jackson had been appointed to the rank of Colonel in the Tennessee militia. During the

War of 1812, Jackson was first charged with attacking the “Red Stick” Creeks. He attacked and

defeated about eight hundred Creeks at the Battle of Horseshoe Bend. As a reward for his brav-

ery, he was appointed to the position of Major General, and placed in charge of the seventh mili-

tary district, which covered Tennessee, Louisiana, and the Mississippi Territory.6

Upon hearing that the British were preparing to mount an attack on New Orleans, Jack-

son headed there to take control of the city’s defenses. He assembled a hodgepodge of men will-

ing to fight, including pirates, Frenchmen, Creoles, and free Negroes alongside his militia regu-

lars. On January 8, 1815, Jackson’s forces easily held off a numerically superior British force,

suffering 71 casualties to Britain’s 2,037. As Robert Remini notes, “It was an unbelievable vic-

tory. Never had American arms sustained so overwhelming, so complete a victory as this. Never

by force of arms had Americans proved so convincingly their right to independence.”7 This vic-

tory greatly enhanced Jackson’s character and made him a legend in the United States. Alexis de

Tocqueville, writing Democracy in America two decades later, remarked, that Jackson “was

raised to the Presidency, and has been maintained there, solely by the recollection of a victory

which he gained, twenty years ago, under the walls of New Orleans.”8

Over the course of the next decade, Jackson continued his military career, serving in the

First Seminole War and subsequently acting as the military governor of Florida. His home state

of Tennessee appointed him to the Senate once again, and he was a candidate for the presidency

in the election of 1824. By this time, the Republican Party was the only national party, and it

6 Ibid., 61.7 Ibid., 72.8 Alexis de Tocqueville. Democracy in America (New York: The Century Company, 1898), 369.

5

Page 9: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

fielded four candidates: General Jackson; John Quincy Adams, the Secretary of State; William

Crawford, the Secretary of the Treasury; and Henry Clay, the Speaker of the House. After the

election results came in, Jackson had received a plurality of both the popular and electoral vote,

but not an outright majority as required by the United States Constitution. As per the Twelfth

Amendment, the election was thrown to the House of Representatives, where only the top candi-

dates were to be voted on. This excluded Henry Clay, the Speaker. As Adams’s political views

were closer to Clay’s, the Speaker threw his support to the Secretary of State; Adams won on the

first vote. Jackson was furious; he had received a plurality of the votes, so clearly the will of the

American people was his. He was further enraged when Henry Clay was appointed by Adams to

be his Secretary of State. Jackson and his supporters accused Adams and Clay of striking a “cor-

rupt bargain.” The entrenched elites had acted out of their own interests, not those of the people

of the United States, continuing the common Jacksonian theme.

After the election of 1824 had been decided, Jackson and his supporters almost immedi-

ately went on the offensive, preparing for the next presidential election to be held four years

later. Their message was simple enough: “Jackson and Reform.” They attacked the Adams-Clay

coalition for acting without the backing of the American people. The Adams Administration, ac-

cording to the Jacksonians, from the beginning had engaged in a “giant act of fraud – one that, to

succeed, required shifting as much power as possible to Washington, where the corrupt few

might more easily oppress the virtuous many…”9 The veracity of such claims is debatable, but

nonetheless, they were effective, as Jackson easily won the presidency, carrying fifteen of

twenty-four states and fifty-six percent of the popular vote. The Man of the People had made it to

the White House.

9 Sean Wilentz, The Rise of American Democracy (New York: W.W. Norton & Company, 2005), 178.

6

Page 10: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

Even though Jackson had served

as a Congressman, Senator, Judge, and

now President, he never truly felt as if

he were a part of the system. Rather, he

prided himself on being apart from the

system. Furthermore, his small govern-

ment philosophy came from his own

personal experiences. Orphaned at a

young age, he was able to succeed in

the world without the aid or assistance

of government. He was a self-made man, and firmly believed that all Americans should be able

to succeed as he had. That philosophy directly conflicted with the one held by the President of

the Second Bank of the United States, Nicholas Biddle.

Nicholas Biddle

Nicholas Biddle, born January 8, 1786, was nineteen years Jackson’s junior. A member

of the prominent Biddle family, the young Nicholas was incredibly gifted, enrolling at the Uni-

versity of Pennsylvania at the age of ten. When the University refused to confer a degree due to

his young age, Biddle transferred to Princeton. Like most of his classmates, Biddle was a Feder-

alist, and in his writings, he accused Jefferson’s Republicans of “seeking to impose an absolute

and tyrannical government upon the country.”10 Another one of his compositions illustrated his

skepticism of republics, insofar as they “were in constant danger from demagogues…The fires of

10 Thomas Payne Govan, Nicholas Biddle: Nationalist and Public Banker (1786 – 1844), (Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 1959), 7.

7

This painting depicts Andrew Jackson’s inauguration on March 4, 1829. Due to campaigning as the “people’s president,” a large crowd descended onto the Executive Mansion, and would only be dispersed when large bowls of punch and liquor were placed on the lawn.

Picture courtesy The Library of Congress

Page 11: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

discord rage with dreadful fury and unless extinguished by the wisdom of citizens may involve

our country in one great conflagration.”11

After graduating as valedictorian of his class at Princeton at the age of fifteen, Biddle be-

gan to study law. He quickly grew tired of the profession, and yearned to travel. Thanks to the

influence of his father, Biddle was hired as a secretary for the United States Minister to France,

John Armstrong. During this time, he also served as secretary for James Monroe, who was the

Minister to Great Britain. Monroe took a liking to the young Biddle, and the professional rela-

tionship that developed between the two men would be crucial later in Biddle’s life.

Returning to the United States at the end of the decade, Biddle practiced law and wrote

for various newspapers. His bid for Congress failed, so he took an increasing interest in com-

merce and finance. The Second Bank of the United States was chartered in 1816, and the follow-

ing year, James Monroe, now the President of the United States, appointed Biddle as one of the

federal government directors. In his letter of acceptance, he told the President: “The truth is, that

with all its faults, the Bank is of vital importance to the finances of the government and an object

of great interest to the community.”12 This appointment would define Biddle’s career for the next

twenty years, and even Biddle himself could not have possibly imagined where it would take

him.

While under the tutelage of then-Bank President Langdon Cheves, he learned the positive

value the Bank could have if managed correctly. The previous Bank President, William Jones,

was a terrible administrator and had almost brought the Bank to ruin (as will be explained in fur-

ther below), and Cheves brought it back from the brink by strongly contracting the money sup-

11 Ibid., 8.12 Ibid., 59.

8

Page 12: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

ply. This proved to be a highly unpopular move, for although the Second Bank survived, it threw

the national economy into a tailspin, and played a role in causing the Panic of 1819.

Biddle’s own philosophy was strongly influenced by the time he spent at the bank. His

study of political economy had led him to reject the classical liberalism as preached by Thomas

Malthus, David Ricardo, and James Mill (the father of the even more famous John Stuart Mill).

According to historian Thomas Govan, Biddle “had seen too clearly during the course of the War

of 1812 and its aftermath how business activity responded to the expansion and contraction of

the money supply to believe that economic activity was governed by natural laws with which

men interfered at their peril.”13 Thus, Biddle was not an advocate of the type of laissez-fair eco-

nomics first preached by Adam Smith a half century hence; he firmly believed that enlightened

civil servants, such as himself, with the nation’s best interest in mind, were in the best position to

manage and direct the American economy.

When Langdon Cheves retired as Bank President in the summer of 1822, Biddle was

elected to the position. Biddle set out immediately to grow and strengthen the Bank, but to do so

amicably, without antagonizing the state banks. He was somewhat successful in this regard;

working together, the National Bank and state banks were able to collaborate in providing credit

for an expanding economy. With the economy now growing, the Bank was able to expand the

money supply to further this growth, and by 1828, “a surplus of $1,500,000 had been accumu-

lated, and in the later half of that year the Bank began paying dividends at the rate of 7 percent

per annum.”14

Biddle was quite pleased with himself; he had accomplished what he had set out to do.

When Andrew Jackson was elected to the presidency in 1828, Biddle did not display the level of

13 Ibid., 70.14 George Rogers Taylor, Jackson Versus Biddle: The Struggle over the Second Bank of the United States (Boston: D.C. Heath and Company, 1949), 4.

9

Page 13: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

animosity towards the incoming president as many of his colleagues did. A learned man himself,

he believed that once Jackson knew the importance of the Bank, he would not actively interfere

with it. Besides, the Bank’s charter was not set to expire for another eight years, and the Bank

was not a contentious issue in the 1828 election; Biddle saw no need to worry.

Biddle himself was loath to get involved in politics; he preferred that the Bank stay above

the political fray. It was of his opinion that the Bank was superior to the normal political pro-

cesses of a democracy and that his Bank should not be responsive to the will of the people. He

decried the “‘violence of the party,’ and said he felt ‘no disposition to become the follower of

any sect, or to mingle political animosities with the intercourse of society.’”15 His disdain of pop-

ular democracy combined with a fervent belief in his Bank led him to certain arrogance regard-

ing the position of the Bank in the American Republic. In an interview with Alexis de Toc-

queville, who was in Philadelphia doing research for what would become Democracy in Amer-

ica, Biddle showed his contempt for political parties by remarking,

The party standard has really been knocked down for good and all....Since then there have been people who support the administration and people who attack it; people who extol a measure and people who abuse it. But there are no parties properly so called, op-posed one to the other and adopting a contrary political faith. The fact is that there are not two practicable ways of governing this people now, and political emotions have scope only over the details of this administration and not over its principles.16

Thus, in Biddle’s mind, there was no further need for debate. He and his patrons at the Bank

would decide what policy to implement, what policies would be best for the country. The more

years he spent at the Bank, the more arrogant he became, and this pride would be detrimental in

the fight to come.

15 H.W. Brands, Andrew Jackson, (New York: Anchor Books), 458.16 Ibid., 457.

10

Page 14: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

Central Banking

First Bank of the United States

Central Banking had always been a contentious issue in the early years of the United

States, and the conception of one, monolithic bank operating at the behest of business interests

over the will of the people was a view held by many Americans. A central bank controlling the

nation’s finances by manipulating credit and the flow of reserves directly conflicted with the

constitutional view held by many of a limited government. However, there were others who

viewed the idea of a central bank essential to the future growth and prosperity of the United

States of America.

The nation’s first attempt at central banking came in the form of the First Bank of the

United States (First B.U.S.). Proposed by Alexander Hamilton, the Secretary of the Treasury, the

Bank was officially chartered on February 25, 1791. The Charter, lasting twenty years, estab-

lished a mint and an excise tax. Additionally, according the Hamilton, the Bank would serve to

establish credit for the new nation, resolve the fiat currency issue (that is, the “Continentals” is-

sued by the Continental Congress during the Revolutionary War), and also ensure financial or-

der. The bank was to be private, and could not buy government bonds. Interestingly, although a

private institution, the Bank acted as the official bank of deposit for the United States govern-

ment, and as such, the Secretary of the Treasury would be free to remove deposits and inspect

the Bank’s books.17

Unfortunately for Hamilton, while he intended for the Bank to be national in character, in

actuality it benefitted Northern commercial interests much more than Southern planters and

17 That is, all revenues (i.e. taxes and tariffs) collected by the government of the United States of America were put into the Bank.

11

Page 15: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

landowners. Chief among those who spoke out in opposition were Thomas Jefferson and James

Madison. Jefferson, a strict constructionist, claimed that the establishment of the Bank violated

the Constitution, stating, “I consider the foundation of the Constitution as laid on this ground:

That ‘all powers not delegated to the United States, by the Constitution, nor prohibited by it to

the States, are reserved to the States or to the people.’…The incorporation of a bank, and the

powers assumed by this bill, have not, in my opinion, been delegated to the United States, by the

Constitution.”18

Whereas the Federalists allied themselves with bankers and merchants along the East

Coast, Jefferson believed in the American planter and farmer. Jefferson preached a small govern-

ment ideology, where the states would be co-equal partners with the Federal Government, and,

as stated above, a strict interpretation of the Constitution. If the Constitution did explicitly grant

the Federal Government a certain power, than that power was reserved to the states. After Jeffer-

son was elected to the presidency, he did not actively attack the bank, but was content to allow

its charter to expire when the time came. That is exactly what occurred in 1811, when James

Madison held the office. Similar in ideology to his predecessor, Madison, a Virginian, believed

that the South did not benefit from a bank, and that it was unnecessary. However, circumstances

in the near future would force Madison to change course and establish the Second Bank of the

United States, an institution even larger than its predecessor.

This begs the question: why should the same political party, and even many of the same

individuals, who had opposed the Bank’s rechartering and demonized the institution, suddenly

have an about-face a mere five years later? According to historian George Rogers Taylor, the

chief reason was the War of 1812: “By the beginning of 1815 the credit of the United States had

18 Thomas Jefferson, “Opinion against the Constitutionality of a National Bank” from Volume III of The Writings of Thomas Jefferson, Wikisource, http://en.wikisource.org/wiki/Opinion_against_the_Constitutionality_of_a_Na-tional_Bank (accessed April 9, 2010).

12

Page 16: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

fallen to its lowest ebb since the founding of the federal government….Banks had multiplied

during the war and greatly extended their note issues. By the fall of 1814 most banks outside

New England had been forced to suspend specie payments, and…prices had risen to the highest

point for the whole nineteenth century.”19 Congress had not passed appropriation taxes in time

for the war either, compounding the problem.

Henry Clay and the American System

Thankfully for the United States, the war ended in 1815, and a more severe crisis had

been averted. But faced with the specter of mounting debts and crippling inflation, Madison’s

Republicans set about establishing a second national bank. Chief among the advocates for the

Second Bank of the United States was a Congressman from the State of Kentucky, Henry Clay.

Also serving as the Speaker of the House, Clay brought the Western perspective into a debate

that had, prior to then, been exclusively North-South. Clay’s background was similar to Jack-

son’s, but there were some marked similarities. Although both had training in law and had come

of age in the American West, Clay’s education went much further, studying at William and Mary

under the prominent judge and law scholar George Wythe (whose pupils at one time included

Thomas Jefferson, James Monroe, and John Marshall).

By 1811, Clay was elected to the House of Representatives as well as to the Speakership.

As Speaker, he led the “War Hawk” faction of the House, who advocated war with Great Britain

due to her violation of American shipping rights. After the War of 1812 had ended, he, along

with fellow Congressman John C. Calhoun, passed the Tariff of 1816, which served as part of

Clay’s new “American System.” According to historian Merrill Peterson, “Viewed as a theory of

political economy, the American System disputed the fundamental ‘free market’ premises of the

19 George Rogers Taylor, Jackson Versus Biddle, 1.

13

Page 17: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

classical school. It believed that a youthful economy, like the American, required the fostering

hand of government; it believed a republican government responsive to the interests of the peo-

ple ought to promote employment, productivity, and wealth…”20

This concept of government directly conflicted with the Jacksonian ideal of limited gov-

ernment and self-subsistence of the individual. Although both Clay and Jackson were members

of the same political party, the Republican Party, their vision of the future of the country could

not have been more markedly different.

The American System advanced by Clay advocated the subsidizing of roads to connect

the West to the East. The western states would ship raw goods to the east via these roads, which

would then be turned into goods to be sold by eastern manufacturers. Construction of these roads

would be funded by the sale of federal lands out West and by the Tariff mentioned above. This

Tariff would also serve as a protectionist measure to advance American interests and goods over

those produced overseas. Finally, the capstone of the American System was the Bank, which

would stabilize currency and keep the risky state banks in check.

The Second Bank of the United States

Thus, Clay firmly sided with the Madison Administration when the chartering of a Sec-

ond Bank was presented to Congress. After the War of 1812, the state banks, which had stepped

into the role of lender to the Federal Government, issued paper money as currency. The problem

with this situation lay in the fact that different state banks had different exchange rates with other

state banks. For example, New York banks might accept notes from Boston banks, but Boston

banks might not accept notes from banks in New York. Pennsylvania banks would offer a dis-

20 Merrill D. Peterson, The Great Triumvirate: Webster, Clay, and Calhoun (New York: Oxford University Press, 1987), 69.

14

Page 18: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

count on New York notes, but New York would not accept notes from Philadelphia. In other

words, there was no uniform standard of currency throughout the rapidly growing nation. “With

the state banks still refusing to pay specie on their notes, each bank’s notes were depreciated at

different rates in different places, and the Treasury was hard to move its funds from places of

collection to places of payment.”21

Additionally, liquidity had dried up, as state banks refused to pay specie (that is, gold

and silver) for certain notes. George Taylor explains, “Although earlier proponents had looked

upon it mainly as a means for aiding the treasury in financing the war, the chief objects sought

by the Bank’s sponsors in 1816 were to force the state banks to resume specie payments and to

establish a satisfactory national currency.”22

Thus, the Second Bank of the United States was chartered out of a perceived necessity,

rather than some type of ideological goal. With its headquarters in Philadelphia, near the old

headquarters of the First Bank, the Second Bank could establish branch banks anywhere in the

nation. It was a public-private joint venture, as the Federal Government appointed five of its

twenty-five directors, ascribed for a fifth of the stock in the bank, and acted as the government’s

official bank of deposit.23 William Jones, the former Secretary of the Navy and Acting Secretary

of the Treasury was selected as the Bank’s first president.

What followed next would have strong implications for the future of the Bank. While a

shrewd politician, Jones made for a terrible Bank president. During his tenure, the branch banks

established were subjected to little or no control by the parent institution. In one particularly

egregious example, the operators of the Baltimore Branch “easily robbed it of more than a mil-

21 Charles Sellers, The Market Revolution (New York: Oxford University Press, 1991), 71.22 George Rogers Taylor, Jackson Versus Biddle, 2.23 Charles Sellers, The Market Revolution, 72.

15

Page 19: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

lion dollars before they were exposed and the branch forced into the hands of a receiver.”24

Malfeasance and incompetence were rampant from the smallest of branch banks all the way up

to the primary bank in Philadelphia. Under these conditions, in January 1819, Jones was allowed

to resign.

These events subsequently led to the Panic of 1819. Because the Bank had been so lax

with credit and the distribution of fiat currency, a huge economic bubble had been created. State

banks were allowed to pursue inflationary policies, without any type of reprimand or correction

from the central bank. By late 1818, the Bank knew it was in trouble, and started contracting the

money supply: total notes and deposits fell from $21.9 million in June 1818 to $11.5 million one

year later, a contraction in the money supply of almost fifty percent. As a result, prices fell pre-

cipitously. From this, businesses could no longer pay their debts or their employees, and many

went bankrupt. An estimated $100 million dollars in mercantile debt to Europe was liquidated,

and some areas out West reverted to using a barter system for transactions.25 Hard money econo-

mist and historian William Gould summed up the Panic as such: “the Bank was saved, and the

people were ruined.”26

The spectacular failure of Jones, combined with the Panic of 1819, proved in Jackson's

mind that banks were nothing but corrupt institutions incapable of managing an economy. The

Bank had done nothing to stem the Panic, and might have in fact contributed to it. From this

point on, Jackson stood firmly against the Second Bank of the United States. A war hero and

self-made man of the West, he positioned himself as a man of the people against the entrenched

interests of the Eastern elite.

24 George Rogers Taylor, Jackson Versus Biddle, 2-3.25 Facts and figures courtesy Murray Rothbard, A History of Money and Banking in the United States: The Colonial Era to World War II (Auburn, AL: Ludwig Vin Mises Institute, 2002), 89-90.26 William M. Gouge, A Short History of Paper Money and Banking in the United States (Philadelphia: T.W. Ustick, 1833), 110.

16

Page 20: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

Faced with the first real economic depression the country’s short history, many Ameri-

cans turned against the Bank. The perceived failure of the financial institutions to prevent and

address the Panic of 1819 laid the foundation for what would become known as Jacksonian

Democracy. As would be the case in the future (and as is the case currently after this most recent

fiscal crisis), anti-establishment (and by extension, anti-Bank) sentiments were very high.

The Panic of 1819 also converted to Jackson's thinking many of those who would be-

come part of Jackson's inner circle, including Thomas Hart Benton, James K. Polk, and Jackso-

nian economists Amos Kendall and Condy Raguet. All of these men were “converted to hard

money and 100-percent reserve banking…[and] pinned the blame for boom-bust cycles on infla-

tionary expansions followed by contractions of bank credit.”27

Unfortunately for the Jacksonians, their ideology hit a constitutional snag that same year.

State banks were growing more and more tired of the National Bank establishing branch banks in

what they considered their operational territory. Two states, Indiana and Illinois, prohibited in

their constitutions the establishment of any bank other than state banks. Additionally, Maryland,

Tennessee, Georgia, North Carolina, Kentucky, and Ohio “levied taxes upon the branches of the

Bank of the United States which would have driven the Bank from the states imposing them.”28

However, James McCulloch, head of the Baltimore Branch of the Second Bank of the United

States, refused to pay the tax. The case was eventually appealed to the Supreme Court.

In McCulloch v. Maryland, the state of Maryland essentially argued that since chartering

a bank was not one of Congress’s enumerated powers, the Bank of the United States was uncon-

stitutional. Furthermore, Maryland had the Tenth Amendment on their side as well, as it states

that any powers not delegated to the Federal Government by the Constitution are reserved to the

27 Murray Rothbard, A History of Money and Banking, 91.28 George Rogers Taylor, Jackson Versus, 3.

17

Page 21: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

states, and to the people. Chief Justice John Marshall disagreed with Maryland’s assertions; the

Court instead found unanimously in McCulloch’s favor.

Marshall justified his decision by invoking the Necessary and Proper Clause of the Con-

stitution (Article I, Section 8, Clause 18). While the Constitution does not explicitly give Con-

gress the right to charter a bank, it can do so in order to fulfill its enumerated powers, in this in-

stance the right to collect and expand revenue. Using Hamiltonian language, the Court con-

cluded: “Let the end be legitimate, let it be within the scope of the constitution, and all means

which are appropriate, which are plainly adapted to that end, which are not prohibited, but con-

sist with the letter and spirit of the constitution, are constitutional.”29 Famously declaring that

“the power to tax involves the power to destroy,” Marshall wrote that were a state were permit-

ted to tax the Federal Government, they may “tax all the means employed by the government, to

an excess which would defeat all the ends of government. This was not intended by the Ameri-

can people. They did not design to make their government dependent on the states.”30 Thus, in all

instances, Federal law would trump state law. The Bank, being a Federal institution, was thus

constitutional.

The Bank War Begins

Clay’s Machinations

Although Jackson was not fond of the Bank, he did not intend to make it a major point of

contention during his presidency. In Jackson’s First Annual Message to Congress (what today

would be called the State of the Union) on December 8, 1829, the president barely mentioned the

29 McCulloch v. Maryland, 17 U.S. 316 (1819), accessed online at http://laws.findlaw.com/us/17/316.html.30 Ibid.

18

Page 22: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

Bank at all, only saying near the end of the speech that, “Both the constitutionality and the expe-

diency of the law creating this bank are well questioned by a large portion of our fellow citizens,

and it must be admitted by all that it has failed in the great end of establishing an uniform and

sound currency.”31 Indeed, the previous election had not focused on the issue of the Second Bank

of the United States, but instead the tariff, partially because mentioning a contentious issue like

the Bank may have upset Jackson’s delicately balanced coalition.32

Jackson and Biddle finally had the opportunity to meet during Jackson’s first year in of-

fice; this would be the first and last time the two men would talk to each other face-to-face. Bid-

dle had sent Jackson a plan to pay off the federal debt, for which Jackson thanked him. During

this meeting, the two men also discussed banking, and Jackson shared his opinion of the Bank

with its president, telling Biddle that he still believed that Congress did not have the power to

charter a bank outside the borders of Washington D.C. He then added, “I do not dislike your

bank any more than all banks. But ever since I read the history of the South Sea bubble I have

been afraid of banks.”33

After this meeting, Biddle felt fairly certain that while Jackson had a personal animus

against banks, this would not necessarily translate into public policy. Biddle sincerely believed

that Jackson would, in his mind, put aside his personal prejudges against the Bank and do what

was in the best interest of the nation. Jackson’s conception of what was best for the nation,

though, was much different than Biddle’s. He would certainly not support a rechartering of the

bank; however, this did not mean he would be actively hostile towards it. Indeed, had not the

Bank issue come up, he very well may have let the Second Bank run the same course as the First,

31 Andrew Jackson, "First Annual Message to Congress," The American Presidency Project, http://www.presiden-cy.ucsb.edu/ws/index.php?pid=29471.32 Sean Wilentz, The Rise of American Democracy, 252.33 H.W. Brands, Andrew Jackson, 460.

19

Page 23: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

allowing its charter to simply expire without making much of a fuss. According to H.W. Brands,

“Jackson hadn’t intended to fight the 1832 election on the Bank issue. In his annual message of

December 1831 he had barely mentioned the subject.”34 Thus, for the first three years of his pres-

idency, the Bank was a non-issue.

Henry Clay, now a Senator, had different ideas. He knew that Jackson remained a popu-

lar president with the American people, and that, barring any major improprieties, he would eas-

ily win re-election. Clay thus needed a wedge issue, an issue which to embarrass Jackson and

dampen his popularity, an issue he, as a presidential candidate, could win on. Clay thus ap-

proached Biddle, suggesting that they push the Bank’s recharter date four years early. In a letter

to Biddle, Clay wrote, “If, as I suppose, [Jackson] would reject it, the question would be immedi-

ately, in consequence, referred to the people, and would inevitably mix itself with our elec-

tions.”35 Yet this is exactly what Biddle did not want: for his Bank to become part of a partisan,

political battle. As previously mentioned, he believed that his precious institution should be

above common politics, and was not initially well-disposed towards Clay’s entreaties.

As time wore on, however, Biddle became increasingly alarmed at the fact that Jackson

was not coming over to his side. Biddle sincerely believed that Jackson’s antipathy towards

banks was a simple misunderstanding; once Jackson was in a position of power for an extended

period of time, surely he would see the positive role the Bank played in American society. Alas,

that was not the case; with each passing year, the President showed no signs of relenting or

changing his mind. When, in a speech, Jackson called for changes to allow state banks a larger

say in the system, Biddle flew into a rage, telling a colleague, “In respect to General Jackson and

Martin Van Buren, I have not the slightest fear of either of them, or both of them. Our country-

34 Ibid., 468.35 Ibid., 461.

20

Page 24: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

men are not naturally disposed to cut their own throats to please anybody, and I have so perfect a

reliance on the spirit and sense of the nation that I think we can defend the institution from much

stronger enemies than they are.”36 Now fully believing in the American people, Biddle gave his

full support to pushing for a recharter four years early. Surely the people of the United States

would side with him.

Arguments Against, and the Veto

Jackson had intended the Second Bank of the United States to go quietly into the night,

similar to the way its predecessor had. Now that Biddle had decided to make an issue out of it,

Jackson was determined to fight for what he believed was right. In Jackson’s mind, the presi-

dency was the only position in the nation that represented the true will of the people. Congress-

men were elected to represent their districts; Senators were elected by state legislatures to repre-

sent their states; only the President, the Chief Executive, was elected by the whole of the people.

Thus so chosen by the electorate, and he was determined to execute their will (or at least his in-

terpretation thereof).

Jackson’s oppositions to the bank were primarily political and constitutional in nature. He

firmly believed that the Bank as an institution corrupted both the people in it and the country at

large. According to historian Sean Wilentz, “Jackson perceived that the Bank, by its very design,

undermined popular sovereignty and majority rule.”37 Additionally, the Bank concentrated power

in the hands of a few, small, unelected elite at the detriment to the masses. Even if, hypotheti -

cally, the Bank were well administered, such an enormity allowed, “‘a few Moneyed Capitalists’

to trade upon the public revenue ‘and enjoy the benefit of it, to the exclusion of many.’” 38 Con-

36 Ibid., 462.37 Sean Wilentz, Democracy in America, 253.38 Ibid., 253.

21

Page 25: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

stitutionally, Jackson was Jeffersonian in his approach, advocating for a smaller, decentralized

government and a strict reading of the Constitution. That document granted no power to Con-

gress to charter a Bank, and as such, the Bank was invalid.

In a letter to John Randolph, one of his allies, Jackson thanked the aging statesman for his

support. Appealing to Randolph’s “Old Republican” mentality, Jackson wrote that the Bank “has

failed to answer the ends for which it was created, and besides being unconstitutional, in which

point of view, no measure of utility could ever procure for it my official sanction, it is on the

score of mere expediency dangerous to liberty, and therefore, worthy of the denunciation which

it has received from the desciples [sic] of the old republican school.”39 Here again, Jackson illus-

trates his concept of the Constitution; although the Bank might be useful overall to the Republic,

it is not constitutional, so it cannot be allowed to stand.

Some historians and economists claim that Jackson was simply appealing to the igno-

rance of the masses in attacking the bank; they claim that Jackson played on the anti-elitist fears

of the populace in order to further his own personal power and popularity. Others make the as-

sertion that Jackson simply did not know what he was doing and could not comprehend the im-

plications of his actions. Such statements reflect contemporary biases and cynicism towards

politicians rather than containing any revolutionary historical insight. Indeed, the historical

record belies these assertions. In an internal memorandum written in Jackson’s own handwriting

(an interesting document, as most writings for both internal and external dissemination were

composed by Andrew Jackson Donelson, Jackson’s nephew and private secretary), he elucidated

his reasons for opposing the Bank. Claiming the sovereignty for the Federal Government came

from the states and the people, Jackson asks rhetorically, “Is the sovereign power to grant corpo-

39 Andrew Jackson, Correspondence of Andrew Jackson (Volume IV), ed. John Spenser Basset (Washington D.C: Carnegie Institution of Washington, 1929), 387.

22

Page 26: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

rations expressly given to the general Government to be found in the constitution [sic], I answer

no….all powers not delegated are retained to the states and to the people…”40

Although, as discussed previously, the constitutionality of the Second Bank of the United

States had been established in the 1819 case McCullough v. Maryland, Jackson still held that the

Bank was unconstitutional. Addressing the Court’s statement that the Bank was a necessary ex-

tension of the function of government, Jackson wrote, “The powers of the Government are gen-

eral and national, not local. it [sic] must follow then that if necessity creates the power, then the

Bank must be exclusively national having no concern with corporations. it [sic] must be an ap-

pendage of the Treasury, a Bank merely of deposit and exchange.”41 Thus, although Jackson had

a personal antipathy towards the Second Bank of the United States, he would allow a national

bank to exist as long as it stayed within its constitutional boundaries as enumerated in Article I,

Section 8.

Jackson’s allies and associates rushed to his side. Thomas Hart Benton, Senator from

Missouri and one of the President’s right-hand-men, made an impassioned speech on the Senate

floor. After several attempts to silence him via parliamentary technicalities by the Bank’s allies,

Benton finally rose, and loudly stated, “Mr. President, I object to the renewal of the charter…be-

cause its tendencies are dangerous and pernicious to the Government and the people….It tends to

aggravate the inequality of fortunes; to make the rich richer and the poor poorer…”42 The Bank

benefitted the East at the expense of South and West; the bankers were enriching themselves on

the back of the honest, hard-working American: “Every body in the South and West knows that

the hard money of the country is disappearing; but only those who have observed the machinery

40 Ibid., 388.41 Ibid.42 Arthur Schlesinger, The Age of Jackson (Boston: Little, Brown, and Company, 1946), 81.

23

Page 27: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

of the Bank of the United States can tell where all this hard money is gone.” 43 Benton then fin-

ished with a crescendo:

In these mock sales of towns and cities may be laid the foundation for the titles and es-tates of our future nobility – Duke of Cincinnati! Earl of Lexington! Marquis of Nash-ville! Count of St. Louis! Prince of New Orleans! Such may be the titles of the bank no-bility to whom the next generation of American farmers must ‘crook the pregnant hinges of the knee!’44

Such rhetoric revealed the passions surrounding the Bank more than the workings and functions

of the Bank itself.

Newspapers inclined to favor the Administration’s policies also started writing editorials

criticizing the Bank. The Washington Globe, the official mouthpiece of the Administration, ex-

pressed anger at the corruption endemic to the institution: “We call the attention of our readers to

the article from the Washington Globe, on the first page of this paper, on the subject of the late

outrage committed by the United States Bank, in seizing a portion of the dividends on the gov-

ernment stock to cover the pretended damages claimed by it…This claim, amounting to 158,842

dollars and 77 cents has never been recognized by Congress, or by the Treasury Department.”45

According to the newspaper, this was not the first time such an event had occurred, noting, “We

must add this to the swelling list of unwarrantable acts committed by the Bank.”46 The Globe

dedicated several issues trying to galvanize public opinion, making several (not unwarranted)

claims that certain members of Congress were actually on the Bank’s payroll.

Despite the best efforts of Jackson’s allies in Congress, Henry Clay and Daniel Webster

were able to guide the Bank recharter Bill through, passing the Senate 28 to 20 and the House

107 to 85 about a month later on July 3. According to Jacksonian historian Robert Remini, the

vote to recharter the Bank, “reflected solid support for the Bank in New England and the Middle

43 H.W. Brands, Andrew Jackson, 466.44 Ibid., 467.45 The Globe, (Washington, DC) Monday, August 11, 1834; Issue 51; col E.46 Ibid.

24

Page 28: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

Atlantic states, strong opposition in the South, and almost divided opinion in the Northwest and

Southwest.”47 Biddle couldn’t help himself; moments after the House passed the Bill, he made an

appearance on the floor, where “members crowded round to shake his hand. A riotous party in

his lodgings celebrated the victory late into the night.”48

Jackson was tremendously displeased at the news that the Bank’s proponents had suc-

ceeded in passing the bill to recharter the Bank; he had hoped it would simply die in Congress.

Martin Van Buren returned from England to find Jackson ill and in bed. Grabbing his friend’s

hand firmly, the President exclaimed, “The Bank, Mr. Van Buren, is trying to kill me, but I will

kill it!”49 But Jackson would not stay ill for long. Within a few days, he gathered his closest advi-

sors (Van Buren, Amos Kendall, Roger Taney, and Andrew Jackson Donelson) together to work

on a draft of the message that would accompany the veto. After three days of work, the President

issued his veto on July 10, 1832.

The veto message “burst like a thunderclap over the nation.”50 The message, directed

more at the people of the United States than to the Congress to whom it was addressed, outlined

the Jacksonian interpretation of the Bank issue. The constitutionality of the Bank was once again

brought into question. Although the Supreme Court had already spoken to the Bank’s legitimacy,

the President disagreed with their assertions. For one, although McCulloch was the most famous

of the cases regarding the Bank, the Court had shifted a tad in their interpretation, twice support-

ing the Bank and twice opposing it. Additionally, the crux of the Court’s argument was that the

Bank was “necessary and proper” extension of the Federal Government. “It can not be ‘neces-

sary’ or ‘proper’ for Congress to barter away or divest themselves of any of the powers vested in

47 Robert Remini, Andrew Jackson and the Bank War (New York: W.W. Norton & Co., 1967), 80.48 Arthur Schlesinger, The Age of Jackson, 87.49 Martin Van Buren, The Autobiography of Martin Van Buren, ed. John C. Fitzpatrick (Washington: Government Printing Office, 1920), 625.50 Arthur Schlesinger, The Age of Jackson, 90.

25

Page 29: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

them by the Constitution to be exercised for the public good,” Jackson argued; Congress had

done exactly this when they gave the Bank control over the currency, a power granted only to

Congress itself.51

Furthermore, the President did not believe that the Executive Branch was bound by the

decisions rendered by the Supreme Court. To later generations, such sentiments seem, well, bla-

tantly unconstitutional. Although Marbury v. Madison had established the precedent of judicial

review, such an idea was not universally held during Jackson’s time. Thus, “if the opinion of the

Supreme Court covered the whole ground of this act, it ought not to control the coordinate au-

thorities of this Government. The Congress, the Executive, and the Court must each for itself be

guided by its own opinion of the Constitution. Each public officer who takes an oath to support

the Constitution swears that he will support it as he understands it, and not as it is understood by

others.”52 Since Jackson believed, according to his interpretation of the Constitution, that the bill

presented before him violated it, it was his job, and his duty, as Chief Executive to veto it.

The President also appealed to populist sentiments in his veto message. Congress had

granted the Bank monopoly status, which it used for its own advantage to the detriment of the

people. The government appointed only five of the twenty-five directors of the Bank; how could

such an institution, with a responsibility to is shareholders, be expected to put the nation ahead of

its own interests? Worst of all, a large portion of the Bank’s stock was in the hands of foreign in-

vestors, the consequences of which could be dire: “will there not be cause to tremble for the pu-

rity of our elections in peace and for the independence of our country in war? Their power would

be great whenever they might choose to exert it.”53 Jackson believed he would be violating his

51 Andrew Jackson, “Veto Message Regarding the Bank of the United States.” The Avalon Project, Yale Law School. http://avalon.law.yale.edu/19th_century/ajveto01.asp.52 Ibid.53 Ibid.

26

Page 30: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

oath of office if he were to put the national security of the United States in the hands of non-

Americans.

The veto ended with Jackson’s larger vision for democracy: “It is to be regretted that the

rich and powerful too often bend the acts of government to their selfish purposes,” Jackson

wrote. However, he would not use that same government to level the playing field. “Distinctions

in society will always exist under every just government. Equality of talents, of education, or of

wealth can not be produced by human institutions.”54 All men are entitled to equal protection un-

der the law but, “when the laws undertake to add to these natural and just advantages artificial

distinctions,…to make the rich richer and the potent more powerful, the humble members of so-

ciety–the farmers, mechanics, and laborers–…have a right to complain of the injustice of their

Government.”55

Businessmen, members of Congress, and others who supported the Bank were shocked

by the Bill’s tone and language. Interestingly, Biddle was actually delighted at the veto message,

for he believed that the American people would be appalled by Jackson’s arrogance. In a letter to

Henry Clay, Biddle called the veto message, “A manifestation of anarchy, such as Marat or

Robespierre might have issued to the mob of the faubourg Saint Antoine.”56 Although attempting

to maintain an air of neutrality as the Bank’s President, privately, he now donated to Clay’s cam-

paign and wrote to the presidential candidate, saying, “You are destined to be the instrument

of…deliverance, and at no period of your life has the country ever had a deeper stake in you. I

wish you success most cordially, because I believe the institutions of the union are involved in

it.”57

54 Ibid.55 Ibid.56 Nicholas Biddle, The Correspondence of Nicholas Biddle dealing with National Affairs, ed. Reginald D. McGrane (New York: Houghton Mifflin Company, 1919), 196.57 Ibid.

27

Page 31: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

But the veto served the exact purpose Jackson intended; in addition to explaining his rea-

sons for opposing the Bank, it unified the various factions of the Jacksonian coalition. For work-

ing men and the West, there were passages that tore into the Bank’s monopoly privileges. For the

moderates, Jackson left the door open for future debate when he stated that a National Bank

could be useful for the people. For the state banks and the states-rights Southerners, there was

Jackson’s claim that he would not allow a bank to subvert the rights of the states or the people. 58

In the words of historian Arthur Schlesinger, “The war against the Bank thus enlisted the enthu-

siastic support of two basically antagonistic groups: on one hand, debtor interests of the West

and local banking interests of the East; on the other, Eastern workingmen and champions of the

radical Jeffersonian tradition.”59 When Congress failed to override the veto, Jackson could finally

claim success.

Clay, Webster, and Arguments for the Bank

The two men who had led the debate in Congress for the Bank’s rechartering were two

political giants: Henry Clay, Senator from Kentucky, former Speaker of the House, and current

candidate for the presidency; and Daniel Webster, the current Senator from Massachusetts.

A wave of popular democracy was sweeping the country, but there still existed a class of

individuals and politicians steeped in Hamiltonian ideas and tradition. These politicians, led by

Henry Clay and the National Republicans (later the Whigs) still believed firmly in Clay’s Ameri-

can System, of which the Bank was a part. The Bank, Clay argued, allowed for credit to be more

easily accessible to those who needed it. By providing a uniform national currency rather than a

58 Sean Wilentz, The Rise of American Democracy, 264.59 Arthur Schlesinger, The Age of Jackson, 79.

28

Page 32: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

haphazard amalgamation of state currencies, the Bank also acted a guarantor of financial stabil-

ity; citizens would no longer have to worry whether the notes at their bank would be accepted by

those of another state, or how heavily those same notes might be discounted. The Bank, having a

much greater amount of capital in reserves, was able to loan out larger sums of money to corpo-

rations and businesses, which in turn spurred further growth. The institution also acted as the

government’s official bank of deposit, which kept the government’s funds safer than they would

have been if they were placed in dozens of state banks. Although the Bank had the unintended

consequence of concentrating wealth in certain areas, overall, it would be serving the best inter-

ests of the American people by providing them with sound currency, easy credit, and financial

stability.

After Clay had convinced Biddle to push for the Bank’s recharter, Daniel Webster led off

for its supporters in the Senate. “A disordered currency is one of the greatest of political evils,”

he claimed. “Of all the contrivances for cheating the laboring classes of mankind, none has been

more effectual than that which deludes them with paper money.”60 Seizing on the spirit of the

times, Webster made the democratic case for the Bank. If each state bank were permitted to print

their own currency, the rich could manipulate the lack of a consistent discount to their advantage.

Said Webster, “Ordinary tyranny, oppression, excessive taxation: these bear lightly the happiness

of the mass of the community, compared with the fraudulent currencies and the robberies com-

mitted by depreciated paper.”61 The lack of a sound currency hurt the poor much more than the

rich, and only a central bank could provide the sound, uniform currency the country needed.

The interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that

the exact same argument, word for word, could be used by the opponents of the Bank.62 The crux

60 H.W. Brands, Andrew Jackson, 465. 61 Ibid., 465.62 Ibid., 464.

29

Page 33: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

of Webster’s argument was that the Bank of the United States served as a check on state banks,

which, lacking coordination, produced run-away inflation. This was indeed true. However, the

Jacksonians pushed this argument further: if paper money was the culprit, why not just eliminate

all banks? Hard money (gold and silver) could check inflation just as well as a central bank

could, perhaps even better. Why not use gold and silver instead of a corruptible institution?

But Webster was not done. The day after Jackson issued his veto message, Webster made

an impassioned speech from the Senate Floor. Decrying the veto, Webster declared that the end

of the Bank would spell the end of a prosperous economy. “Thirty millions of the capital of the

bank are now out on loans and discounts,” Webster stated. “Now, Sir, how is it possible that this

vast amount can be collected in so short a period of time without suffering, by any management

whatever?” the Senator inquired.63 He called many of the President’s arguments baseless, stating

that taken to their logical conclusion, they could be used to attack any legal corporation. The

President was also disregarding decades of precedent by declaring himself on equal footing with

the Supreme Court as arbiter of the nation’s laws, thus turning the United States into a govern-

ment of men, not of laws. “If the opinions of the President be maintained,” the Senator argued,

“there is an end of all law and all judicial authority.”64 It appealed to the worst in men, stirring up

class antagonisms unnecessarily. The veto message appealed to public freedom, but in the eyes

of Webster, “nothing endangers that so much as its unparalleled pretenses.”65 Should Jackson’s

veto message be accepted by the majority of Americans, it would mean the end of the Republic.

Webster’s opponents accused him of engaging in an act of duplicity; after all, he had op-

posed the recharter of the First Bank of the United States back in 1816 when he was a Congress-

man. Many sensed that something more sinister was at hand; after all, until recently, Webster had

63 George Rogers Taylor, Jackson Versus Biddle, 22.64 Merrill D. Peterson, The Great Triumvirate, 211.65 George Rogers Taylor, Jackson Versus Biddle, 30.

30

Page 34: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

been on relatively friendly terms with the Administration. Unfortunately for Biddle, such accusa-

tions were more true than false. Webster had written a letter to the Bank President in December

1833 politely reminding Biddle that, “my retainer has not been renewed or refreshed as usual. If

it be wished that my relation to the Bank should be continued, it may be well to send me the

usual retainers.”66 When the Globe learned of this revelation, the editors quickly published it.

Webster was portrayed as Biddle’s little errand boy: “He had, it was reported, hurried from Phil-

adelphia upon the adjournment of Congress and received from the B.U.S. an easy loan of $10-

$15,000 for his services.”67 Although Webster had made salient points on the Senate floor in fa-

vor of recharter, his words were now dismissed as nothing more than mere rhetoric; one of the

Bank’s most ardent supporters had been effectively sidelined.

While The Globe, the official newspaper of the Administration, spoke highly of the con-

tent of Jackson’s veto message, the vast majority of newspapers around the country lambasted

the President. An editorial from the Portland Daily Advertiser, reprinted in the National Intelli-

gencer, reproached Jackson for the language used in the veto message. “There is no part more

deservedly reprobated and more reprehensible, than that part which attempts to array the poor

against the rich.”68 The Boston Daily Atlas called it the most radical document that had ever em-

anated from any Administration in any country, finding it incredulous that the President “un-

blushingly denies [that] the Supreme Court is proper tribunal to decide upon the constitutionality

of the laws!!”69 The Boston Daily Advertiser and Patriot screamed, “The spirit of Jacksonianism

is JACOBINISM….It’s Alpha is ANARCHY and its Omega is DESPOTISM.”70 The Lynchburg

Virginian accused Amos Kendall, one of Jackson’s closest advisors, of spreading lies about the

66 Nicholas Biddle, The Correspondence of Nicholas Biddle, 218.67 Merrill D. Peterson, The Great Triumvirate, 211.68 George Rogers Taylor, Jackson Versus Biddle, 32.69 Ibid., 31.70 Sean Wilentz, The Rise of American Democracy, 268.

31

Page 35: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

Bank’s supporters: “Those who see the Washington Globe, are aware that Amos Kendall has

been for some past writing a series of Essays against the U.S. Bank, in the course of which he

has charged almost every distinguished advocate of that institution with having been bribed to

support it….Venal and corrupt himself, he cannot believe that other men are honest – and hence

he uniformly attributed the best actions to the basest motives...”71 While the Virginian acted gen-

uinely shocked that such accusations could be thrown around by the Administration, there was a

certain truth in Kendall’s statements: as many as two-thirds of the newspapers publishing pro-

Bank editorials were on the Bank’s payroll.

Some newspapers even attacked The Globe for supporting the President. The Daily Na-

tional Intelligencer, a newspaper that had supported the Republican Party of Jefferson, Madison,

and Monroe in years past now openly attacked the mouthpiece of the Administration. A few days

earlier, The Globe had run an editorial suggesting that should the Bank of the United States con-

tinue to function and be successfully rechartered, the nation would forever be beholden to Euro-

pean interests, as one of the members of the British Cabinet held stock in the Bank. In an edito-

rial on June 19, 1832, the Intelligencer mocked the editorial staff at The Globe for even suggest-

ing such a notion, saying, in part, “Such remarks are degrading to the government paper, and can

only be tolerated on the consideration that although they may disgrace the administration, they

will not be taken as conveying the sentiments of the American people.”72

Although ostensibly Biddle wanted the Bank to remain apolitical, he, by this point, enthu-

siastically supported Henry Clay, and many newspapers and politicians were on the Bank's pay-

roll. He had written articles in support of the Bank, and offered many newspapers monetary con-

tributions for publishing them. In a letter to a newspaper publisher, Biddle wrote, “For the inser-

71 Lynchburg Virginian. Thursday, November 1, 1832; Issue 22; Col A.72 Daily National Intelligencer, (Washington, DC) Tuesday, June 19, 1832; Issue 6042; col A.

32

Page 36: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

tion of these I will pay either as they appear or in advance. Thus, for instance, if you will cause

the articles I have indicated and others which I may prepare to be inserted in the newspaper in

question, I will at once pay to you one thousand dollars.”73 Not wishing to be accused of any in-

discretions with the Bank’s money in the future, he also requested that the letter be returned to

him, “as it might be misconstrued.”74

The Election of 1832

Jackson’s supporters came together in May 1832 for the first ever Democratic National

Convention. The Convention nominated the sitting president unanimously and selected Martin

Van Buren as his Vice-President. The National Republican Party had already convened the pre-

vious December and nominated Henry Clay as their candidate for the Presidency. A third party,

the Anti-Masonic Party, also fielded a candidate: William Wirt. Andrew Jackson was indeed a

Mason, but many in the Anti-Masonic Party opposed Jackson for the same reasons the National

Republicans did.

The future status of the Second Bank of the United States (and by extension, Jackson’s

handling of the situation) was the issue of this presidential election. The only other point of con-

tention for the United States at this time was the Nullification Crisis; South Carolina, upset with

the new tariff passed by Congress, passed its own Orders of Nullification declaring that the tariff

was null and void in the state of South Carolina. However, both Jackson and Clay stood with the

Union and against the nullifiers, so this point was rendered moot.

The supporters of Jackson staged huge parades, raised hickory poles, and sang campaign

songs in support of their hero, General Jackson. Many threw barbeques, a few of which the Pres-

73 H.W. Brands, Andrew Jackson, 462.74 Ibid.

33

Page 37: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

ident himself attended. Francis Blair oversaw massive printings and the nation-wide distribution

of The Globe, while Amos Kendall, de facto campaign manager, organized Hickory Clubs

around the nation in support of his candidate.75 Some of Jackson’s supporters were put on the de-

fensive in certain sections of the country (primarily New York and Pennsylvania, where the

Bank was most popular), much to Clay’s delight. However, in much of the rest of the nation,

Jackson’s stand against the Bank reaffirmed to the American people his support of the common

man over the rich and privileged. The Globe ran with this theme throughout the campaign,

declaring, “It is the final decision of the President – between the Aristocracy and the People – he

stands squarely by the People.”76

And the people stood squarely

with him. Jackson easily won re-elec-

tion, carrying sixteen of twenty-four

states and 219 electoral votes. Al-

though over 100,000 more votes were

cast in 1832 than in 1828, “Clay actu-

ally received 35,000 fewer votes than

John Quincy Adams had four years

earlier, a decline of nearly 7 per-

cent.”77 Jackson also broke the Na-

tional Republicans’ lock on New Eng-

land by winning both Maine and New Hampshire. Clay only carried his home state of Kentucky,

as well as Massachusetts, Connecticut, Rhode Island, Maryland and Delaware; he could not even 75 Sean Wilentz, The Rise of American Democracy, 268.76 Ibid., 269.77 Ibid.

34

The results of the 1832 Presidential Election. Jackson won 55% of the popular vote and 219 electoral votes out of the 286 cast, easily winning re-election to a second term.

Image courtesy NationalAtlas.gov™

Page 38: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

win the heavily pro-Bank states of Pennsylvania and New York. Clay and Biddle had thought

that the American people would clearly side with an institution both men believed served the

best interests of the nation; instead, they voted for their hero and against the “moneyed aristoc-

racy.” The vote vindicated Jackson and gave him the mandate he wanted against the Bank. His

overwhelming popularity and support led the defeated Anti-Masonic candidate, William Wirt, to

note “that he [Jackson] may be President for life if he chooses.”78

The War Rages On

Removing the Deposits

With his re-election secured, Jackson believed the American people had given him a

mandate to do what was necessary in regards to the Bank. Biddle, thoroughly shocked that Clay

had lost the election, assumed the same. With the Bank’s charter set to expire in 1836, there was

still one presidential election, one more opportunity for the Bank to survive. Both men assumed

the other would engage in some sort of chicanery to guarantee that their side emerged from the

Bank War victorious. Both were right.

Almost immediately after the election, Jackson began mulling over the decision to re-

move the Federal Government’s deposits from the Bank and place them in state banks. In the

words of historian Robert Remini, “His reasons for taking the action were obvious. To begin

with, he feared the Bank’s ability to utilize the three remaining years of the charter to upset the

verdict of the election and he wanted to reduce its power by denying it government funds.” 79 The

Bank received most of its operating revenue from using the Federal Government’s deposits, and

denying the Bank this money would severely impair its day-to-day functions and effectively

78 Robert Remini, Andrew Jackson and the Bank War, 107.79 Ibid., 111.

35

Page 39: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

cripple it. When Francis Blair, one of Jackson’s advisors, told the President that Biddle would

actively be spending public funds to “frustrate the people’s will” by “using the money of govern-

ment for the purpose of breaking down the government,” Jackson became visibly irate, shouting,

“He shan’t have the public money! I’ll remove the deposits! Blair, talk with our friends about

this, and let me know what they think of it.”80

Over the summer of 1833, Jackson toured New York and New England. The heart of old

Federalist territory, Jackson was nonetheless greeted by the thunder of cannon, the roaring of

crowds, pompous reception committees and banquets galore. This reception confirmed to the

President his enduring popularity with the people, and provided him with the impetuous to do

what he considered necessary for the general welfare of Americans. Thus, when he returned to

Washington, he was committed to removing the Federal Government’s deposits. Unfortunately

for Jackson, the only individual who could initiate a removal of the government’s deposits was

the Secretary of the Treasury, William Duane, who refused. Additionally, Duane felt slighted by

Jackson, whom he felt did not respect his opinion, so he refused to resign. Jackson was a man

used to getting his way by now, so after a few days of terse negotiations, the President removed

Duane from his position and instilled one of his closet allies, the Attorney General, Roger Taney,

to the vacancy.

As soon as Taney assumed his new position, he appointed Amos Kendall as his agent to

identify which state banks would be the new depositories of government funds; Kendall picked

seven.81 On September 25, 1833, the order was issued from the Treasury Department: “com-

mencing October 1, 1833, all future government deposits would be placed in the state banks…

and that for operating expenses the government would draw on its remaining funds from the 80 Ibid.81 The seven banks were: the Union Bank of Maryland in Baltimore, the Girand Bank in Philadelphia, the Mechanics Bank of New York, the Manhattan Company of New York, the Bank of America in New York, the Commonwealth Bank of Boston, and the Merchant Bank of Boston.

36

Page 40: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

BUS until they were exhausted.”82 These

seven “pet banks,” as they were dubbed by

the Administration’s opponents, increased to

twenty-two by year-end and to almost one

hundred within three years. By December 13,

1833, the public funds held by the Bank were

virtually gone.83 The Boston Post declared

the Bank, “BIDDLED, DIDDLED, AND

UNDONE.”84

But Biddle refused to sit by idly

while the President mercilessly tore apart his

beloved Bank. To keep his Bank alive, historian Robert Remini writes, “Biddle wielded every

weapon in his arsenal, with little regard for the economic suffering or catastrophe he might pro-

voke by using them.”85 Biddle would cause an economic panic if that would prove to the public

that the Bank needed to be rechartered. “My course is decided,” the Bank President wrote to a

friend, “All the other Banks and all the other merchants may break, but the Bank of the United

States shall not break.”86

Biddle then began to call in loans from the various state banks that the Second Bank had

lent to, and demanded they be paid in full and in specie; no paper bills could be used to pay back

their debt. This had the effect of draining the reserves of many banks out West, causing bank

runs, and ultimately resulted in many banks shutting their doors permanently. He also tightened

82 Robert Remini, Andrew Jackson and the Bank War, 125.83 Ibid.84 Arthur Schlesinger, The Age of Jackson, 102.85 Robert Remini, Andrew Jackson and the Bank War, 26.86 Nicholas Biddle, The Correspondence of Nicholas Biddle, 221.

37

This political cartoon, created by Henry R. Robinson, depicts President Jackson attacking the Bank with sword labeled “veto,” represented here as a many headed-hydra. Each of the heads represents a different branch of the bank, with the largest head representing Nicholas Biddle. Here, Jackson is aided by his Vice President, Martin Van Buren.

Image courtesy the Brown University Library

Page 41: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

the money supply and restricted credit to borrowers and investors. All of this could not have

come at a worst possible time. The economy was rapidly expanding, credit was needed, and the

demand for liquid assets – specie and cash – was the highest it had been in decades. Within a few

months, what had been a bourgeoning economy was brought to its knees. Said Biddle, “The ties

of party allegiance can only be broken by the actual conviction of existing distress in the commu-

nity. Nothing but the evidence of suffering abroad” – in other words, suffering across the entire

nation – “will produce any effect in Congress.”87

All Americans felt the pinch; many lost their jobs, investments, and occasionally, sav-

ings. Business leaders implored their Congressmen to recharter the Bank, lest it ruin them all.

But Jackson was unmoved. He would see this event to its finish; he would not allow Biddle to

win. When a delegation of merchants from New York came with a petition signed by six thou-

sand individuals, Jackson immediately assumed Biddle had put them up to it. When they started

pleading for relief, the President thundered, “Relief, sir! Come not to me…go to the Monster!…

Go to Nicholas Biddle! We have no money here….Biddle has all the money. He has millions of

specie in his vaults at this moment, laying idle, and yet you come to me to save you from break-

ing.”88

When an economic disruption or panic occurs that affects the lives of most Americans,

normally the American people respond by voting the party in power out of office. Such was the

fear of many of the Democrats. These fears were heightened when the Whig Party was formed in

1833. Taking their name from the British Whigs who opposed the monarchy, this new political

party coalesced around their common antipathy towards Andrew Jackson and their conception of

87 Ibid., 219.88 H.W. Brands, Andrew Jackson, 502.

38

Page 42: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

him as an executive tyrant. As such, they favored the supremacy of the Legislative Branch over

that of the Executive.

The winter of 1833-1834 was a long one for Jacksonian Democrats. Events were occur-

ring that could spell their undoing. The Senate, now under de facto Whig control due to the de-

fections of National Republicans and anti-Jackson Democrats, voted to censure President Jack-

son for removing the deposits from the Second Bank of the United States without Congressional

approval. Although the censure was just a reprimand from the Senate and had no affect on the

presidency, it was nonetheless a stain on Jackson’s record. In the words of Robert Remini, “The

removal of the deposits, Biddle’s squeeze, the economic panic, the rumors of conspiracy, the

party desertions, the talk of a new national bank, the political fumbling of the Democrats, the

censure of the President, the emergence of the Whig Party – all gravely threatened the future of

the Jacksonian Party.”89 Ultimately however, Jackson would outmaneuver all of his opponents

and emerge victorious.

89 Robert Remini, Andrew Jackson and the Bank War, 153.

39

Page 43: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

End Game

By the time the 1834 midterm elections came around, the liquidity crisis had started to

ease; federal deposits now went into the state banks, and from the state banks, into the econ-

omy.90 The Democrats had also successfully managed to place the blame of the economic crisis

on Biddle; the President simply had to react to the conditions presented to him. The voters ate it

up; the Democrats crushed the Whigs in 1834. When the calendar turned to the year 1835, the

White House had more good news: the United States had officially paid off its debt. This was the

first, and so far only, time the Federal Government has paid off the entire federal debt. The

Whigs, seeing that the Bank had been a losing issue not once, but twice, started to unchain them-

selves from Biddle. His Bank was set to expire in two years, and Jackson’s Democrats, the Party

that had voted against recharter, were on the ascendency. Biddle’s power base had been shat-

tered. In 1836, a few weeks before his bank was set to expire, he sought to keep the Philadelphia

Branch in operation by applying for incorporation in the state of Pennsylvania. Although op-

posed by some Democrats, the state legislature granted Biddle’s request, and the Second Bank of

the United States was rechartered as a private, Pennsylvania Bank.91

Jackson left office as popular as ever, and his anointed successor, Martin Van Buren, was

easily elected to the presidency in 1836. Van Buren, however, would not be celebrating for long.

Less than five weeks into his term, the nation suffered a devastating financial meltdown that

would last almost five years. Land prices out West had been expanding rapidly, and, after several

years of unsustainable and unrealistic growth, the bubble finally burst. Individuals stopped pay-

ing for land, and various state banks, unable to meet their financial obligations, starting declaring

bankruptcy. Out of the 850 banks across the country, 343 closed down permanently.

90 H.W. Brands, Andrew Jackson, 502.91Reginald Charles McGrane, The Panic of 1837 (Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 1924), 70.

40

Page 44: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

Each political party blamed the other for the crisis. The Democrats blamed the paper

money the state banks had issued; if they had simply used specie, this crisis could have been

averted. The Whigs turned that argument against the Democrats. Indeed, it was the fault of the

state banks; they had issued an excess amount of paper money and thus caused rapid inflation

and overvaluation. However, the Whigs argued, this never would have occurred had there been a

central bank issuing a common, stable currency. The Party of Jackson, said the Whigs, was

clearly the guilty party.

Unfortunately for the Democrats, Van Buren was not the exciting, patriotic war hero

Jackson was; he could not keep the Party together and count on the support of the American peo-

ple simply by force of will alone. As the crisis carried on into each year of his Administration,

the American people grew more and more impatient; unemployment reached its highest levels in

decades. The Whigs nicknamed him “Martin Van Ruin.” When the Panic of 1837 had not ended

by the 1840 presidential election, Americans had had enough, and threw Van Buren out of office.

Biddle, seemingly vindicated, smiled upon hearing the election returns.

But Jackson would have the last laugh. Biddle’s private Pennsylvania Bank did not have

the same fiscal tools at its disposal that it did as the National Bank, and it too ran into trouble.

The Panic of 1837 affected all banks, and Biddle’s was no exception. In 1841, faced with rising

defaults on its loans and a lack of reserves, the Bank finally declared bankruptcy. Biddle’s

“Monster Bank” was no more.

41

Page 45: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

Examining the Bank War Historiographically

Arthur Schlesinger

The common consensus amongst historians for the first century after the Bank War

placed the blame for the trials and tribulations of the 1830s and the Panic of 1837 squarely on

Jackson’s shoulders. However, in 1945, historian Arthur Schlesinger published his Pulitzer Prize

winning account of the Jacksonian era appropriately entitled The Age of Jackson. He differs from

his predecessors by acknowledging Biddle’s antagonist role during the Bank War. Biddle was

not a just a victim of Jackson’s aggressive populism; he was an active participant in the crisis.

As a historian whose formative years were spent in 1930s Depression America,

Schlesinger’s sympathies were not with banks or banking in general, as he blamed their corrup-

tion for precipitating the Depression. Additionally, his father, as a social historian at both Ohio

State University and Harvard, surely influenced his mindset. Thus, unlike previous historians, he

did not exonerate Biddle. According to Schlesinger, it was Biddle’s arrogance that cost him the

Bank War. After contracting the money supply after Jackson issued the Bank Veto, Biddle once

again expanded the money supply to pre-panic levels. In other words, his haphazard attempts to

squeeze the nation’s economy were contradictory and antithetical to the field of banking. Biddle

was trying to save the village by burning it down. “Somewhere along the way, Biddle had lost

his grip on reality,” Schlesinger explains. “Ambition, vanity, and love of power had crossed the

thin line to megalomania. So little had he understood the American people that he ordered the

circulation of thirty thousand copies of the Bank veto as a campaign document for Henry

Clay.”92 Jackson was able to understand and connect with the American people in a way Biddle

never could. This was due, in part, to the upbringings of both men. Growing up in the West in -

culcated in Jackson a sense of the travails ordinary Americans faced, whereas Biddle was a child 92 Arthur Schlesinger, Age of Jackson, 113.

42

Page 46: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

of privilege and excellence from the very beginning, never leaving the bubble of security the

Biddle family provided him. His radical Hamiltonian vision of the unelected civil servant and

democracy placed him on the edges of American political thought, something he could truly

never reconcile himself with.

Although critical of Biddle, Schlesinger does not assuage Jackson of his guilt and com-

plicity in the Bank War either. Although Jackson used anti-government rhetoric in the debate, he

was not above using the government for his own devices: “Both parties [Whig and Democrat]

would concede that enterprise should be free, would claim always to be acting to protect this

freedom, and each, when in possession of the state, would unhesitatingly intervene in business,

on its own behalf and in the name of ‘freedom,’ by destroying United States Banks or establish-

ing protective tariffs.”93 Schlesinger thus disputes the notion, held by Jackson and many of his

supporters, that his actions were motivated by a true desire for limited government that returned

power to the people, as quite a few of his actions actually contributed to the growth of the Execu-

tive Branch.

The Jacksonian Democrats were thus, in Schlesinger’s interpretation, populists, and Jack-

son pursued a populist policy more than a strict anti-government one. Although Jackson spoke of

the evils of the powerful at the Bank who manipulated the system for their own advantage, he

was mum on politicians in his own party who did the same. Jackson wanted to protect the work-

ers from their employers, but to do so required the Federal Government to take a much more ac-

tive role in everyday life. Thus, in Schlesinger’s view, Jacksonian democracy used Hamiltonian

means to achieve Jeffersonian ends. The Bank War illustrated this contradiction perfectly. Jack-

son used a strong Executive Branch and his conception of the presidency as the arbiter of the

people’s will to destroy the Bank; Andrew Jackson used Hamilton’s conception of a strong cen-

93 Ibid., 515.

43

Page 47: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

tral government to achieve Jefferson’s vision of a small government America. Schlesinger notes

this phenomenon in his epilogue: “Thus, the Jacksonians, under the banner of antistatism, could

carry on a vigorous program of government intervention, and Jackson, ruling in the name of

weak government, ended up by leaving the presidency stronger than it ever had been before.”94

Murray Rothbard

Murray Rothbard, famous economist of the Austrian School and notable libertarian,

views Jackson's actions in the Bank War as positive. He differs from Schlesinger, however, in

that he claims that Jacksonians were not populist per se, but in fact libertarians. In Rothbard's

opinion, no movement in American political history has been as misunderstood by historians as

the Jacksonians. His explanation is worth quoting in full:

They were emphatically not...either “ignorant anti-capitalist agrarians,” or “tools of the inflationary state banks”…Their program and ideology were libertarian; they strongly fa-vored free enterprise and free markets, but they just as strongly opposed special subsidies and monopoly privileges conveyed by government to business or to any other group. They favored absolutely minimal government, certainly at the federal level, but also at the state level. They believed that government should be confined to upholding the rights of private property. In the monetary sphere, this meant the separation of government from the banking system and a shift from inflationary paper money and fractional reserve banking to pure specie and banks confined to 100-percent reserves.95

Rothbard, unlike Schlesinger, claims that Jackson and those around him had a coherent program,

and not one simply based around Jackson’s cult of personality. While Schlesinger asserts that

Jackson’s moves were haphazard, Rothbard states that the attack on the Second Bank of the

United States and the subsequent deposits into the state banks were all part of a carefully precon-

ceived plan.

Rothbard, in his analysis, cites a study by Peter Temin. Wholesale prices increased fifty-

two percent between April 1834 and February 1837; wasn’t this increase caused by the abolition

94 Ibid, 513.95 Murray Rothbard, A History of Money and Banking in the United States, 91.

44

Page 48: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

of the Bank? Rothbard, with Temin, argues no. Foremost, the Second Bank of the United States

did not keep inflation in check as many of her contemporaries thought. Additionally, although

Biddle contracted the supply of bills, there was now there was more specie – gold and silver – in

the country’s banks. The state banks are not to blame either. If they had simply been lending out

money as previous historians have claimed, their reserve ratio – the ratio of the minimum re-

serves to customer deposits and notes – would have fallen sharply. Yet, at this time, their reserve

ratio did not change.

Thus, in Rothbard's opinion, “the Jackson Administration is absolved from blame for the

1833-37 inflation….Of course, the basic fractional reserve banking system is scarcely absolved

from responsibility, since otherwise the monetary expansion in absolute terms would not have

been as great.”96 The crisis could have been completely averted had Jackson more quickly moved

to a one hundred percent specie basis, as they could have used the specie to ease the monetary

contradiction that Biddle was causing.97

His analysis is a bit contradictory. In one paragraph, he states that there was more specie

in the vaults of the state banks, and that this increased specie increased inflation. Fair enough;

when the supply of money increases, so does inflation. Only a few pages later though, he states

that the crisis of the mid-1830s could have been avoided if Jackson had moved to a one percent

specie basis sooner. In this way, he would be injecting liquidity into the market. That statement

is true on its own merits as well. But when the two are combined, they contradict one another.

How can an increase in the money supply, particularly hard money, both simultaneously be the

cause of and solution to the problem at hand? Rothbard never makes that clear.

96 Ibid, 97.97 Ibid.

45

Page 49: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

While Rothbard presents an interesting and novel approach to the Bank War, it is impor-

tant not to read one's own political philosophy into events of the past. As a prominent libertarian

of his era, Rothbard seeks to examine the events of the past through the eyes of the Austrian

School of economic thinking. Economists from the Austrian School generally advocate for lais-

sez-faire thinking and a hard money system (that is, a currency backed by silver or gold). At the

same time, Rothbard should be careful not to let his own personal biases affect his historical

analysis.

Bray Hammond

Bray Hammond presents a different perspective on the Bank of the United States and the

Bank War. An Assistant Secretary of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

from 1944 to 1950, he presents a banker’s perspective to the events of the 1830s. As such, he

faults Andrew Jackson and the Democrats for many of the events and fiscal crises of the Jackso-

nian era.

Hammond views the Jacksonian perspective on the economy as fundamentally naïve. The

Jacksonians advocated hard money as a solution to the nation’s ills. In an expanding country

with plentiful swaths of land and an energetic populace, there could not have been an idea more

unsuited to the American setting. In Hammond’s words, “Nowhere on earth was the spirit of en-

terprise to be more fierce, the urge for exploration more restless, the demand for credit more im-

portunate.”98 An expanding nation needed access to easy credit, something a central bank can

provide. Specie, the hard money the Jacksonians spoke of, contracts the economy. Thus, if they

truly wanted the economy to grow, they should have rethought their own policy. They preached

98 George Rogers Taylor, Jackson Versus Biddle, 59.

46

Page 50: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

small government and limited regulation, but according to Hammond, that would not have suited

their needs: “The Jacksonians gloried in what was a triumph was lassier faire [sic] in a field

where laisser faire [sic] had no place. Sovereign and unified control of the monetary system is

needed in any economy, whatever freedoms may be proper otherwise.” 99 Contrary to the claims

made by Rothbard, a coherent and consistent monetary policy is exactly what the Jacksonians

lacked. Monetary policy must be national in scope, but Jackson instead delegated that power to

the states, with disastrous consequences.

Jackson is remembered as great President by history simply because he escaped a crisis

of his own making by a mere two months. The Panic of 1837 occurred five weeks into Van Bu-

ren’s presidency, had it occurred during Jackson’s, the people may very well have turned against

him, Hammond argues. In his opinion, they should have turned on the Democrats much sooner,

for although the Party declared that it supported the common man, they were much more con-

cerned with obtaining and subsequently maintaining power: “Their rebellion was a popular and

democratic one but not agrarian. It accomplished the antithesis of agrarian aims. It was led by

men whose skill in propaganda…and in demagogy was supported by envy and an uncritical be-

lief that the divine blessing was on their efforts.”100

He is also very critical of Arthur Schlesinger’s book, The Age of Jackson. He accuses

Schlesinger of subtly using vocabulary to advance his own personal biases. Words such as “mas-

terly,” “thoughtful,” and “intelligent” are used to describe Jackson and his allies, while using

words such as “phony” and “roar” to describe supporters of the Bank. Schlesinger does not dis-

cuss the Bank as a functioning financial institution, but instead, “he makes the Bank a dim sort of

moneyed monstrosity and Biddle a vague, sinister figure, ‘drunk with power’ whose career is a

99 Bray Hammond, Banks and politics in America: from the Revolution to the Civil War (Princeton: Princeton Uni-versity Press, 1957), 741.100 Ibid.

47

Page 51: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

darkened background for Jackson’s gleaming achievements.”101 Hammond also contends that

Schlesinger does not emphasize the positive role Biddle played as President of the Bank. Under

Biddle, the Bank “performed its depository services efficiently, furnished a sound and uniform

currency, and regulated the state banks.”102

Hammond must tread lightly here. By vehemently attacking Schlesinger’s opinion, Ham-

mond reveals his own biases and opinion in favor of banks. The way some of his criticisms are

worded, it appears as if he is taking Schlesinger’s analysis of the Bank War personally. Letting

his emotions cloud his judgment of historical events does not shed any new historical insight or

advance his arguments for the validity of the Second Bank of the United States. Targeted,

poignant criticism would be much more effective than simple grandstanding.

Susan Hoffman

Susan Hoffman, a public servant turned political economist, also disagrees with

Schlesinger’s narrative. In the preface to her book, she expresses with full disclosure her admira-

tion for the positive role of banks and what the banking industry can do for society, so it is of no

surprise that she sides with Biddle in her analysis of the Bank War. But she differs from Bray

Hammond in one important regard. Hammond claims that Jackson’s fight against the Bank was

motivated by his belief in laissez-faire capitalism. In the end, though, Jackson’s actions were ul-

timately counter-productive as power simply shifted away from a Washington Central Bank to

New York private banks. Hoffman, however, makes the following supposition: “Jackson could

not see that a publicly designed banking regulator helped individuals – whether farmers, work-

ers, or entrepreneurs – because he could not accept institutional design that violated his ideologi-

101 George Rogers Taylor, Jackson Versus Biddle, 113.102 Ibid., 114.

48

Page 52: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

cal insistence on a clear separation between the economy and the (very limited) government.”103

She argues that Jackson was an ideologue in the strictest sense: he believed that there was a de-

lineation between the public and private spheres, and one sphere should not trespass into the af-

fairs of the other. Additional, she claims his personal animus towards the banking industry and

banks in general led him on crusade in which he deluded himself into thinking he had the best in-

terests of the nation in mind.

Her analysis, however, falls a bit short. As proof of her argument, she cites Jean Alexan-

der Wilburn’s book, Biddle’s Bank. In the book, Mr. Wilburn gathered data to investigate sup-

port for the Bank amongst Congressmen, Senators, state legislatures, and the citizenry during the

Bank War. According to Ms. Hoffman, Mr. Wilburn found that the majority of state legislatures,

Congressmen, and the public supported the Second Bank. However, the historical record belies

such a statement. The rechartering of the Second Bank of the United States was the issue facing

the country in the presidential election of 1832. (As an aside, there was one other issue in the

1832 Presidential Election, the nullification crisis occurring in South Carolina. But both Jackson

and Clay stood with the Union against the nullifiers, so this point was rendered moot for the elec-

tion). As such, when the election came around, the public had a clear choice: Clay and the Bank,

or Jackson and his veto. As noted above, the people resoundingly supported Jackson; he even

carried the state of Pennsylvania, the Bank’s headquarters. If the majority of the people indeed

supported the Bank, then they would have supported Clay over Jackson. Such was not the case.

She is right in asserting that a majority of Congressmen and Senators supported recharter-

ing the Bank, but that should already be implicit in the argument. The only way the bill to rechar-

ter the Bank could reach the President’s desk was for it to be supported by a majority in both

103 Susan Hoffman, Politics and Banking: Ideas, Public Policy, and the Creation of Financial Institutions (Balti-more, MD: The Johns Hopkins University Press, 2001), 257.

49

Page 53: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

Houses of Congress. Jackson would not have been able to veto the Bill if such an opinion were

in the minority.

The Bank, in Hoffman’s mind, was a constructive institution, and Andrew Jackson could

never fully appreciate it, for whatever reason. Simply because policymakers claim to act in the

public’s best interest does not necessarily make the policy “good.” Says Hoffman, “Ideas can be

destructive of institutions and policy directions that have served well from other points of view,

as well as constructive.”104 In his pursuit for limited government, Jackson rode roughshod over

an institution that was a positive force for all Americans.

Conclusions

The Bank War left a lasting legacy on the United States, a legacy which continues to this

day. The Second Bank of the United States did serve as a vehicle for the powerful, but Clay and

Webster were correct in addressing its fundamental purpose. After the War of 1812, the United

States needed a National Bank; it could not, in the future, simply rely on state banks and the

goodwill of the wealthy to fund a war effort. Additionally, under Biddle’s guidance, the United

States enjoyed a decade and a half of stable prices, small levels of inflation, sound currency, and

ample credit. But Jackson was correct in asserting that the Bank concentrated far too much

power in the hands of a few individuals. Instead of being at the mercy of state banks and private

citizens, the Federal Government was now beholden to twenty-five bank directors. All are

equally corruptible.

Thus, it can be concluded that while the Bank was far too powerful, the best course of ac-

tion would be for it to be reformed, not destroyed. Unfortunately for the United States, that was

not an option for either Andrew Jackson or Nicholas Biddle. Both men let their personal ani-104 Ibid., 248.

50

Page 54: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

mosities and hatred permeate their thought process; rather than doing what was best for the

United States, they simply did what was best for them. And that in itself is an important lesson.

The English historian Lord Acton famously declared, “Power tends to corrupt, and absolute

power corrupts absolutely. Great men are almost always bad men, even when they exercise influ-

ence and not authority.”105 Jackson used his power as the President to inflict harm upon the Bank,

and Biddle responded by causing great harm to the U.S. economy. Only by inflicting suffering

onto the American people would they realize how truly important the Bank was.

In that regard, although both men were insanely stubborn and arrogant, the blame for the

crippling of the United States economy in the years 1834-36 lies with Biddle. His hubris clouded

his judgment, and he willingly and deliberately damaged the lives of thousands of Americans

simply to see his Bank survive. Such actions are inexcusable and clearly indicate that Biddle

wielded far too much power for an unelected official.

Although it is apparent that Jackson hated the National Bank, it is to be debated how sin-

cerely he believed in small government. He certainly wasn’t above using the power of the presi-

dency to achieve his own goals. To define Jackson as a libertarian, as Rothbard suggests, or pop-

ulist, as suggested by Schlesinger, is to apply contemporary labels to a nineteenth century phe-

nomenon. While Jackson did believe in greater freedom and hard money, he also styled himself

as a man of the people. Was he simply enforcing the people’s will or his own? Perhaps that will

never be known. What can be understood and analyzed is how Jackson got it done.

Thus, most importantly, the Bank War forever reshaped the dynamic of the presidency.

Ignoring for the moment whether or not Jackson’s actions were justified, he enlarged authority of

America’s Chief Executive in several ways. Presidents before Jackson rarely vetoed legislation;

if Congress passed a bill, the President signed it. Jackson stopped this practice, using the veto as

105 John Emerich Edward Dalberg-Acton, Essays on Freedom and Power (Boston: Beacon Press, 1949), 364.

51

Page 55: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

an expression of policy in addition to constitutionality. Now the House of Representatives and

the Senate had to fully consider the President’s will when considering legislation. Furthermore,

by taking the Bank issue directly to the people and defeating the opposition in the 1832 presiden-

tial election, he greatly expanded the president’s political power base: “Thereafter Jackson did

not hesitate to claim an augmentation of executive authority by virtue of this victory at the

polls.”106 He also advanced the idea that the president was the sole and direct representative of all

the American people; thus he, and only he, was able to act in full accordance with the American

electorate. Finally, by removing William Duane from his post at the Secretary of the Treasury

without the consent of Duane himself, he established the presidential prerogative of removing

executive officers at will.107 Jackson contributed to many of the features of the modern presi-

dency, and he did so primarily through his actions during the Bank War.

106 Robert Remini, Andrew Jackson and the Bank War, 178.107 Ibid., 177-178.

52

Page 56: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

Epilogue: The Monster Bank Today

Over one hundred and seventy years have passed since the Bank War ended, and yet to-

day, Americans still confront many of the same issues and questions raised by the War: what is

the proper role of a central bank, and how much power, leeway, influence, and independence

should it have? The recent financial meltdown, including the collapse of the housing bubble, and

bailouts of certain corporations, has only served to heighten the public’s awareness and distrust

of the current central bank, the Federal Reserve.

Interestingly, both Ben Bernanke, the current chairman of the Federal Reserve, and

Nicholas Biddle believe in a type of benign paternalism – a belief that they, as educated civil ser-

vants, should be above the system and all its trappings. In an interview with Jim Lehrer last year,

the PBS newsman had the Fed Chief field some questions from the crowd. One individual asked

Bernanke if the Federal Reserve should be “audited,” that is, should the actions taken by the

Governing Board of the Federal Reserve become more transparent? Bernanke was adamant in

his response: “Bernanke expressed particular opposition to a proposal in Congress for the Gov-

ernment Accounting Office to be able to ‘audit’ the Fed's interest rate decisions. ‘I don't think

that's consistent with independence. I don't think the American people want Congress running

monetary policy. That's exactly what (the bill) would do,’” he said.108

Bernanke, like Biddle, has nothing but contempt for those who would seek to interfere

with what he considers to be crucial to the underpinnings of the economy; it is, after all, the Fed-

eral Reserve that sets monetary policy. Yet, at the same time, the American public is becoming

more and more suspicious of the Federal Reserve; the arbitrary nature under which the Fed has

recently conducted business seems, to many, unfair. In March 2008, Bear Sterns, an investment

108 PBS Newshour, “Bernanke Reflects on Fed's Actions in Forum,” Online Newshour. http://www.pbs.org/new-shour/updates/business/july-dec09/bernanke_07-26.html.

53

Page 57: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

bank, was on the verse of bankruptcy due the losses they suffered as a result of the decline in the

market for subprime mortgages. To prevent Bear Sterns from collapsing, Ben Bernanke offered

to give $25 billion dollars to the firm after a run on the company wiped out its cash reserves in

two days. Of course, Bernanke justified his actions in a hearing before a Joint Economic Com-

mittee of Congress by stating that the results would have been “catastrophic” had the Fed not

acted. Said Bernanke, “With financial conditions fragile, the sudden failure of Bear Stearns

likely would have led to a chaotic unwinding of positions in those markets and could have se-

verely shaken confidence.”109

The public might have been more receptive if they hadn’t heard this meme before, and

again afterwards. Bernanke used similar justification when the Fed intervened in the cases of

Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac, Goldman Sachs, American International Group (AIG) (multiple

times), and so on. It is thus quite understandable for Americans to be angry at the Federal Re-

serve, a body not accountable to them and only indirectly accountable to Congress, for spending

their tax dollars to aid failing corporations. They, like their counterparts in the 1830s, see the

“Bank” as enriching the elites and those in positions of power whilst contributing nothing to the

well-being of the public at large.

In response to such criticisms, both Biddle and Bernanke would state that the central

bank is indeed helping the American economy and the general public by preventing greater

calamity from befalling the economy. They both believe that an agency, independent of the polit-

ical whims that befall Washington, is in the best position to manage and direct the economy. In

addition, Bernanke can point to a study done in 1993 by Alberto Alesina and Lawrence H. Sum-

mers, a political economist and former Secretary of the Treasury, respectively. As one can see on

109 Yalman Onaran, “Fed Aided Bear Stearns as Firm Faced Chapter 11, Bernanke Says,” Bloomberg, L.P. Written April 2, 2008. http://www.bloomberg.com/apps/news?pid=20601087&refer=worldwide&sid=a7coicThgaEE.

54

Page 58: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

the chart on the right, a strong cor-

relation exists between the indepen-

dence of the central bank and the

degree of average annual inflation.

In nations such as Spain and Italy,

which do not allow their central

bank large degrees of latitude, the

average annual inflation for the

thirty-three year period examined in

the study was over seven percent per

annum for both nations. In contrast, nations such as the United States and Germany, which grant

their central banks a tremendous amount of freedom, have some the lowest inflation rates in the

world.

Some would argue that such sentiments run against the capitalist spirit that has made the

United States what it is today. Sure, inflation is low, but at what price? How much control is the

nation willing to relinquish to institutions that are independent of the checks and balances of the

system? Are the American people willing to give the Federal Reserve the amount of latitude it

asks for to function properly, or has this recent financial crisis dampened support?

Ultimately, the study of the Bank War and Second Bank of the United States raises more

questions than it answers. The mere fact that historians, even those with backgrounds in econom-

ics, cannot agree on a consensus is proof that the proper role of a central bank, by extension the

government, has yet to be determined. Americans in the year 2010 are still arguing over the

proper role of the Federal Government in society. Is it the obligation of the government to take

55

In their study, Alesina and Summers plotted the degree of Central Bank independence against average annual inflation rates. Their study showed a negative coloration between the two.

Graph courtesy the Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking

Page 59: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

care of its citizenry, or does the impetus for success still lay with the individual? As the United

States enters the second decade of the new century, these questions are as pertinent as they were

one century and four score ago.

56

Page 60: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

Bibliography

Primary Sources

Biddle, Nicholas. The Correspondence of Nicholas Biddle dealing with National Affairs, ed. Reginald D. McGrane. New York: Houghton Mifflin Company, 1919.

Cruikshank, Robert. “President's Levee, or all Creation going to the White House, Washington.” The Library of Congress. http://memory.loc.gov/cgi-bin/query/r?ammem/pin:@field%28NUMBER+pin1104%29%29 (accessed April 9, 2010).

Daily National Intelligencer, (Washington, DC) Tuesday, June 19, 1832; Issue 6042; col A. Via Infotrac Database at the University of Florida. http://callisto10.ggimg.com/doc/NCNP/WrapPDF=contentSet=NCNP=recordID=5DXC-1832-JUN19-002-F.pdf (accessed April 9, 2010).

Jackson, Andrew. The Correspondence of Andrew Jackson (Volume IV), ed. John Spencer Bas-set. Washington D.C: Carnegie Institution of Washington, 1929.

-----. "First Annual Message to Congress," The American Presidency Project. http://www.presi-dency.ucsb.edu/ws/index.php?pid=29471 (accessed April 8, 2010).

-----. The Correspondence of Andrew Jackson (Volume V), ed. John Spencer Basset. Washington D.C: Carnegie Institution of Washington, 1929.

-----. The Papers of Andrew Jackson (Volume VII, 1829), eds. Daniel Feller, Harold D. Moser, Laura-Eve Moss, Thomas Coens. Knoxville: The University of Tennessee Press, 2007.

-----. “Veto Message Regarding the Bank of the United States.” The Avalon Project, Yale Law School. http://avalon.law.yale.edu/19th_century/ajveto01.asp (accessed April 9, 2010).

Jefferson, Thomas. “Opinion against the Constitutionality of a National Bank” from Volume III of The Writings of Thomas Jefferson. Wikisource. http://en.wikisource.org/wiki/Opinion_against_the_Constitutionality_of_a_National_Bank (accessed April 9, 2010).

Lynchburg Virginian, (Lynchburg, VA). Thursday, November 1, 1832; Issue 22; Col A. Via In-fotrac Database at the University of Florida. http://callisto10.ggimg.com/doc/NCNP/WrapPDF=contentSet=NCNP=recordID=5AJO-1832-NOV01-003-F.pdf (accessed April 10, 2010).

McCulloch v. Maryland, 17 U.S. 316 (1819), accessed online at http://laws.findlaw.com/us/17/316.html.

57

Page 61: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

Onaran, Yalman. “Fed Aided Bear Stearns as Firm Faced Chapter 11, Bernanke Says.” Bloomberg, L.P. Written April 2, 2008. http://www.bloomberg.com/apps/news?pid=20601087&refer=worldwide&sid=a7coicThgaEE (accessed April 9, 2010).

PBS Newshour. “Bernanke Reflects on Fed's Actions in Forum.” Online Newshour. http://www.pbs.org/newshour/updates/business/july-dec09/bernanke_07-26.html (accessed April 8, 2010).

Robinson, H.R. “General Jackson Slaying the Many Headed Monster.” Brown University Li-brary, Center for Digital Scholarship, Digital Collections. http://dl.lib.brown.edu/reposi-tory2/repoman.php?verb=render&id=119817787962500 (accessed April 9, 2010).

The Globe, (Washington, DC) Monday, August 11, 1834; Issue 51; col E. Via Infotrac Database at the University of Florida. http://infotrac.galegroup.com.lp.hscl.ufl.edu/itw/infomark/613/470/103313920w16/purl=rc1_NCNP_0_GT3012210206&dyn=31!xrn_20_0_GT3012210206&hst_1?sw_aep=gain40375 (accessed April 10, 2010).

Van Buren, Martin. The Autobiography of Martin Van Buren. Edited by John C. Fitzpatrick. Washington: Government Printing Office, 1920.

Secondary Sources

Alesina, Alberto and Lawrence H. Summers “Central Bank Independence and Macroeconomic Performance: Some Comparative Evidence.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 25, No. 2 (May, 1993), 151-162.

Brands, H.W. Andrew Jackson. New York: Anchor Books, 2005.

Colbert, David. Eyewitnesses to Wall Street: 400 Years of Dreamers, Schemers, Busts, and Booms. New York: Broadway Books, 2001.

Cole, Donald B. The Presidency of Andrew Jackson. Lawrence, KS: University Press of Kansas, 1993.

Dalberg-Acton, John Emerich Edward. Essays on Freedom and Power. Boston: Beacon Press, 1949.

Gouge, William M. A Short History of Paper Money and Banking in the United States. Philadel-phia: T.W. Ustick, 1833.

Govan, Thomas Payne. Nicholas Biddle: Nationalist and Public Banker 1786 – 1844). Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 1959.

Hammond, Bray. Banks and Politics in America: from the Revolution to the Civil War. Prince-ton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1957.

58

Page 62: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

Hoffman, Susan. Politics and Banking: Ideas, Public Policy, and the Creation of Financial In-stitutions. Baltimore, MD: The Johns Hopkins University Press, 2001.

McGrane, Reginald Charles. The Panic of 1837. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 1924.

NationalAtlas.gov. “Presidential Elections 1828 – 1840: Electoral Votes” The National Atlas of the United States of America. http://www.nationalatlas.gov/printable/images/pdf/elec-tions/elect03.pdf (accessed April 10, 2010).

Nevins, Allan, and Frank Weitenkampf. A Century of Political Cartoons from 1800 to 1900. New York: Charles Scribner’s Sons, 1944.

Peterson, Merrill D. The Great Triumverate: Webster, Clay, and Calhoun. New York: Oxford University Press, 1987.

Remini, Robert V. Andrew Jackson. New York: Twayne Publishers, Inc., 1966.

-----. Andrew Jackson and the Bank War. New York: W.W. Norton & Co., 1967.

-----. Andrew Jackson: The Course of American Freedom, 1822 – 1832. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1981.

-----. Andrew Jackson: The Course of American Democracy, 1833 – 1845. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1984.

-----. The Age of Jackson. Columbia, SC: University of South Carolina Press, 1972.

-----. The Jacksonian Era. Arlington Heights, IL: Harlan Davidson, Inc., 1989.

Reynolds, David S. Waking Giant: America in the Age of Jackson. New York: HarperCollins Publishers, 2008.

Rothbard, Murray N. A History of Money and Banking in the United States: The Colonial Era to World War II. Auburn, AL: Ludwig Von Mises Institute, 2002.

Schlesinger, Arthur M. The Age of Jackson. Boston: Little, Brown, and Company, 1946.

Sellers, Charles. The Market Revolution. New York: Oxford University Press, 1991.

Sharp, James Roger. The Jacksonians versus the Banks: Politics in the States after the Panic of 1837. New York: Columbia University Press, 1970.

Taylor, George Rogers. Jackson Versus Biddle: The Struggle over the Second Bank of The United States. Boston: D.C. Heath and Company, 1949.

59

Page 63: ufdcimages.uflib.ufl.edu · Web viewThe interesting aspect about Webster’s argument, as historian H.W. Brands notes, is that the exact same argument, word for word, could be used

Temlin, Peter. The Jacksonian Economy. New York: W.W. Norton & Company, 1969.

Timberlake Jr., Richard H. The Origins of Central Banking in the United States. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1978.

Tocqueville, Alexis de. Democracy in America. New York: The Century Company, 1898.

Van Deusen, Glyndon G. The Jacksonian Era. New York: Harper & Row, Publishers, Inc., 1959.

Watson, Harry L. Andrew Jackson vs. Henry Clay: Democracy and Development in Antebellum America. Boston: Bedford/St. Martin’s, 1998.

Widmer, Ted. Martin Van Buren. New York: Times Books, Henry Holt and Company LLC, 2005.

Wilentz, Sean. The Rise of American Democracy: Democracy Ascendant, 1815 – 1840. New York: W.W. Norton & Company, 2005.

-----. Andrew Jackson. New York: Times Books, Henry Holt and Company LLC, 2005.

Womack, Roy Douglas. An Analysis of the Credit Controls of the Second Bank of the United States. New York: Arno Press, 1978.

60