unpan024226

download unpan024226

of 28

Transcript of unpan024226

  • 8/8/2019 unpan024226

    1/28

    BANKING SECTOR REFORMS IN INDIA AND CHINA A COMPARATIVE PERSPECTIVE

    Christian Roland*

    This version: 8 August 2006

    Paper prepared for the "Harvard Project for Asian and

    International Relations" 2006 Conference in Singapore

    ABSTRACT

    India and China have both started banking sector reforms after decades of heavy state

    involvement. This paper takes a comparative perspective on the reforms in the two countries

    by analyzing the reform progress made since the early 1990s along the lines of the policy

    recommendations of transformation studies, evaluating the results using the CAMELframework, and discussing political-economy factors that may have contributed to the

    respective reform outcomes.

    The key findings are: (1) India and China have followed most of the policy recommendations

    in the areas of liberalization, institution building and structural change, while privatization of

    state-owned banks has lagged in both countries; (2) India has generally proceeded faster with

    banking sector reforms and outperforms China on most indicators; (3) from a political-

    economy perspective, a common restraining factor on the reforms are the ailing state-owned

    enterprises that lack hard-budget constraints, and the influence of interest groups in areas such

    as privatization and directed credit, while the political system appears to be less important

    than commonly assumed.

    JEL-Classification: O53, O57, P52.

    Key words: Banking sector reforms, CAMEL, China, India, transformation.

    * European Business School, Oestrich-Winkel Germany; E-Mail: [email protected]

  • 8/8/2019 unpan024226

    2/28

    -1-

    1 INTRODUCTION

    China and India have managed an impressive economic take-off since the opening of their

    economies in 1978 and 1991 respectively. Both countries have attempted to liberalize andmodernize their economies by for example lowering trade barriers, opening their countries for

    foreign investments and deregulating industries.

    Despite the impressive progress made in many parts of the economy, the banking sectors of

    both countries are not fully liberalized yet and continue to be state-dominated. In addition,

    both banking sectors still suffer from years of state-intervention as can be seen for example by

    the comparatively high level of non-performing loans (NPLs) or the overstaffing of state-

    owned banks. This can have significant implications for the overall economic performance of

    the two countries since studies have shown that a well-developed banking sector positively

    influences growth through the mobilization of savings and the allocation of capital to the

    highest value use.1 While the benefits of a well-functioning banking sector are apparent,

    pursuing the necessary reforms towards this goal is not without pitfalls. From a political-

    economy perspective the reform of a banking sector poses major challenges due to special

    interest groups, the repercussions on the enterprise sector, and the linkage with a country's

    fiscal situation.

    How to manage the transition from a state-directed to a market-based system is the main focus

    of transformation studies. The recommendations along the process elements of transformation

    studies can provide a framework to evaluate the progress of banking sector reforms in China

    and India. Knowing how the reforms have proceeded is however only the first step in an

    overall evaluation since reforms are no means by themselves, but should contribute to an

    improvement of the economics of the banking sector. This is evaluated along the lines of the

    CAMEL framework.2 To provide possible explanations for the results, relevant political-

    economy factors that have shaped the reforms and their outcomes are discussed.

    This paper contributes to the scarce comparative literature on banking sector reforms in India

    and China in three ways: (1) it provides an evaluation along the lines of transformation studies

    on the reform process in the two countries, (2) performance indicators are used to provide a

    1See Levine (1997), p. 720f.

    2 The acronym CAMEL stands for Capital adequacy, Asset quality, Management soundness, Earnings andprofitability, and Liquidity

  • 8/8/2019 unpan024226

    3/28

    -2-

    holistic view on the relative performance of the two banking sectors, and (3) political-

    economy factors affecting reform outcomes are evaluated in a systematic manner.

    The rest of the paper is organized as follows: section 2 provides an overview of the mainelements and recommendations of transformation studies as the theoretical basis for the

    evaluation of the reforms. The influence of political-economy factors on the reform process in

    the banking sector is discussed in section 3. In section 4 the development and major reforms

    in the banking sectors in India and China are presented. This is followed by a discussion in

    section 5 of how the recommendations of transformation studies were followed in the reform

    process of both countries and which performance effects the reforms had. In section 6, the

    influence of political-economy factors on the reform process and results is discussed. Section

    7 concludes.

    2 OVERVIEW OF TRANSFORMATION STUDIES

    Transformation studies3 attempt to explain the trigger, process and result of long-run systemic

    changes. A transformation is frequently triggered by a political or economic crisis and

    involves a fundamental change of the underlying economic, political or cultural order, which

    often entails a redistribution of relative power and wealth.4

    A frequently used early blueprint for the transformation from a state-directed to a market-

    based system was the Washington Consensus that emphasized liberalization, stabilization and

    privatization. It was at the beginning of the 1990s widely adopted in Latin America and in

    Central and Eastern Europe (CEE).5 However, soon after the start of the transition in the CEE

    countries, the Washington Consensus came under increasing scrutiny for offering an overly

    simplistic model of transformation. The experiences in the transition countries have shown

    that especially two factors have to receive more attention. First, institutions are needed to

    ensure the functioning of the market system. Second, in most transition countries the

    3 There is disagreement in the literature whether a general "transformation theory" exists. Because of thecontroversy, the more neutral term "transformation studies" is used in this paper to refer to a set of hypothesis

    describing the process of transition from a state-directed to a market-based system.4 See Kloten (1991), p. 9; Wagener (1996), p. 9. According to Wagener (1996) the main difference between a

    transformation and a reform is the depth of the changes. While in a reform, the underlying economic order is

    preserved, a transformation involves the substitution of the underlying economic order with a new one.

    Despite these conceptual differences the terms transformation, transition and reform are used interchangeablyin this paper.

    5 See Rodrik (2000), p. 86; Williamson (2004), pp. 1-10.

  • 8/8/2019 unpan024226

    4/28

    -3-

    economic structure was distorted through state interventions, which make significant

    structural changes necessary. Thus, the main policy recommendations of liberalization,

    stabilization and privatization have to be complemented by institution building and structural

    change.6 These five elements as well as issues that relate to the timing and sequencing of

    reforms are now briefly described in the context of banking sector reforms.

    Liberalization of the banking sector is a part of the internal liberalization of an economy. As

    for the overall economy, liberalization refers to the establishment of a market-determined

    price and allocation mechanism.7 An extensive literature starting with the seminal works of

    McKinnon (1973) and Shaw (1973) argues for the reduction of repressionist policies such as

    interest rate restrictions, reserve requirements and directed credit programs.8

    The rationale for sequencing the liberalization of interest rates is that more sophisticated

    economic agents need a shorter adjustment period, as well as to reduce overly fierce

    competition for deposits at the start of liberalization. Thus, interest rate liberalization should

    start with wholesale interest rates, followed by lending rates and finally deposit rates. For

    interest rate liberalization to be successful, economic agents should be subject to hard-budget

    constraints to ensure sound borrowing and lending, and banks should have a certain degree of

    stability to avoid break-downs due to price competitions in liberalized markets.9

    Reserve requirements are a tool of monetary policy. They can however become an instrument

    of financial repression, if they are used as a source of cheap funds for the budget deficit since

    they then constitute a distortionary tax on the banking sector. The policy recommendation

    consequently is to only employ reserve requirements for monetary policy.10

    Under a directed credit program banks have to channel credit to certain priority sectors due to

    perceived market failures or development objectives. Should market failures exist that limit

    the access to credit of certain parts of the population or the enterprise sector, measures to

    ensure access to credit should be implemented before liberalization. For the abolishment of a

    6 See Kolodko (2004), p. 1.7 The removal of entry and exit barriers can be regarded as part of the liberalization of an economy as well.

    Here, these points are regarded as enablers for structural changes in a sector.8

    See for example Fry (1997), McKinnon (1991), or Roubini and Sala-i-Martin (1992).9 See Caprio, Atiyas and Hanson (1994), p. 435; Mehran and Laurens (1997), p. 33f.10 See Joshi and Little (1997), p. 125.

  • 8/8/2019 unpan024226

    5/28

    -4-

    directed credit program, a dual-track approach with nominal credit targets should be used so

    that economic agents have time to adjust and potential reform losers are compensated.11

    Stabilization of the banking sector is another important reform element. In the context ofbanking sector reforms, stabilization refers especially to the recapitalization of banks that are

    likely to be burdened by a legacy of non-performing loans (NPLs) and low levels of capital.

    To avoid moral hazard, this should be done through a "once-and-for-all" program. Pre-

    conditions for a successful recapitalization of banks are the correct measurement and

    classification of NPLs to be able to determine the capital need, a stable macroeconomic

    environment, transparent accounting standards and a legal framework to enforce claims.12

    One of the main levers to create a market-based banking system is the privatization of state-

    owned banks (SOBs). In light of the often inadequate systems of governance under state

    ownership, privatization is regarded as a way to enhance the performance of SOBs and avoid

    costly bailouts. A successful program of bank privatization should lead to entities that are

    both independent of the state and of insider control. Pre-conditions towards this goal are a

    disengagement of the state from direct governance of banks and the build-up of a regulatory

    framework as a means of indirect control. For the disengagement of the state to be credible,

    banks must be able to operate independently which may make a recapitalization beforeprivatization necessary. The main policy recommendation for bank privatization is to sell

    state-owned banks through a transparent bidding process to strategic partners. This should

    help to quickly upgrade banks' operations to best practice levels, and to fully divest the

    government's holding to avoid continued interference. This view is however not undisputed

    since large-scale sales to foreign investors might lead to a popular backlash against reforms.13

    The experience of the transition countries made it clear that the incentives created by

    privatization and liberalization of the economy would not work in the absence of proper

    institutions. In terms of necessary institutions for the banking sector, countries at least need to

    have the following in place. First, accounting and disclosure rules to promote transparency for

    outside stakeholders and supervisors. Second, a regulatory system to supervise market

    participants so that consumers are protected, competition is promoted, and risk-taking is not

    11 For a discussion of dual-track liberalization in China see Lau, Qian and Roland (2000).12

    See Balcerowicz and Gelb (1994), p. 37f.; Sheng (1996), p. 46.13 See Bonin, Hasan and Wachtel (2005), p. 2172; Hawkins and Mihaljek (2001), p. 9; Otchere (2005), p.

    2090f.; Parker and Kirkpatrick (2005), p. 531.

  • 8/8/2019 unpan024226

    6/28

    -5-

    threatening the stability of the overall system. Third, capital adequacy standards following the

    Basel capital accord to have a cushion against losses and reduce risk-taking. These institutions

    have to be embedded in the overall institutional and legal structure that includes for example

    commercial and business laws.14

    Managing structural changes constitutes one of the central tasks of transition. In the context

    of a banking sector, a key lever for structural changes is the entry of domestic and foreign

    banks. Before new banks and especially more sophisticated foreign banks can enter the

    market, it is important to have a bank supervisory agency in place. In addition, it is important

    that the incumbent banks have sufficient net worth to avoid undue risk taking in a more

    competitive environment. If these conditions are met, the general policy recommendation is to

    allow entry of new banks into the market. Experience has shown that the threat of entry alone

    can force incumbent banks to improve and upgrade their operations, which ultimately

    enhances consumer welfare.15

    The successful management of the transformation process does not simply depend on

    executing the five previously described process steps, but also on managing the interaction

    between these elements. Since a transformation strategy will almost inevitably contain

    gradual reforms, the sequencing of the policy reforms as well as the timing of theirimplementation become important considerations. Since the sequence depends at least

    partially on country specific initial conditions, it is difficult to draw general conclusions from

    the experiences of other countries. There are however some generally applicable

    recommendations.16 First steps in a banking sector reform program should be the creation of

    market-based institutions and if needed the stabilization of banks. From this basis, interest

    rates can be liberalized in the sequence described above. The next steps are the lowering of

    statutory pre-emptions and the step-wise removal of directed credit. When the necessary

    regulatory structure has been established and domestic banks are accustomed to market

    mechanisms, entry barriers for domestic and foreign players can be lifted, and the

    privatization of state-owned banks can start.17

    14 See Joshi and Little (1997), p. 115; Kormendi and Snyder (1996), p. 11; Rajan and Zingales (2003), p. 18;Rybczinski (1991), p. 34.

    15

    See Caprio, Atiyas and Hanson (1994), p. 435; World Bank (2001), p. 169.16 See Dhanji (1991), p. 323; Funke (1993), p. 337.17 See Gibson and Tsakalotos (1994), p. 579; McKinnon (1991), pp. 6-8; Mehran and Laurens (1997), p. 34.

  • 8/8/2019 unpan024226

    7/28

    -6-

    3 POLITICAL-ECONOMY CONSIDERATIONS FOR BANKING

    SECTOR REFORMS

    Banking sector reforms do not occur in isolation: the transformation of the banking sector

    affects other parts of the economy, and developments in the rest of the economy in turn have a

    profound influence on banking sector reforms. A further complication is that the reforms in

    the banking sector affect different interest groups such as savers, borrowers, or bank

    employees. Consequently, political-economy considerations are important for the successful

    management of banking sector reforms. Two important factors, the inter-connection of

    banking sector reforms with the enterprise sector and the fiscal situation, as well as the role of

    interest groups, are discussed in more detail.

    The banking sector serves as an intermediary between providers and users of capital in an

    economy. In a market-oriented banking system, banks will try to channel capital to the

    ventures with the best risk-return trade-off in order to minimize credit losses and maximize

    profits, which will ensure an efficient allocation of capital in the economy. This may however

    change in a system where the state has an important influence over the credit allocation of the

    banking sector and enterprises face soft-budget constraints.18 If enterprises face soft-budget

    constraints, losses can either be covered by subsidies from the government budget or withfurther loans from the banking sector. The extension of loans to loss-making enterprises

    adversely affects the profitability and capital base of the banking sector, which may make a

    bailout of banks with government funds necessary. To avoid costly recapitalizations of banks

    due to unsustainable lending practices, enterprises have to abide to hard budget constraints.

    There are two implications from these arguments for banking sector reforms. First, banking

    sector reforms need to be complemented by reforms in the enterprise sector if soft budget

    constraints are present. Second, the financial capability and resources of the government

    affect the pace of banking sector reforms.

    While the introduction of hard-budget constraints is an important complementary element for

    banking sector reforms, the extent of available financial resources has direct implications on

    the transformation process in the banking sector. First, low or moderate public debt may slow

    down the privatization process, because with funds available for subsidies for loss-making

    18 For a discussion of the soft-budget constraint see for example Kornai (1986).

  • 8/8/2019 unpan024226

    8/28

    -7-

    public enterprises and banks, there is no urgent pressure to privatize.19 Second, high budget

    deficits are likely to lead to a persistence of repressive policies in the form of interest rate

    controls and statutory pre-emptions since they constitute sources of cheap funds for the

    government, and thus lower its financing costs. Third, higher public debt and deficits may

    result in a slower reform pace if compensation transfers have to be made. 20 Fourth, high

    public debt and deficits make a "once-and-for-all" recapitalization less likely because the

    necessary resources are lacking. Thus ceteris paribus, the higher the public debt and deficits,

    the slower the pace of banking sector reforms will be.

    The speed of reforms is not only influenced by the fiscal position of the government, but to a

    major extent by the existence of interest groups that are affected by the reform process. Since

    the seminal work by Olson (1965) the effects of interest groups have been a recurrent topic in

    the political-economy literature. The analysis of interest groups is also important in the

    context of banking sector reforms since they may profoundly affect the liberalization process.

    Without going into an in-depth discussion, interest groups may have ceteris paribus the

    following effects on the transition process. First, the higher the number of veto players such as

    in a coalition government or with well-organized trade unions, the less likely is

    privatization.21 Second, interest rate restrictions and directed credit program provide rents to

    certain interest groups, which will oppose the abolition and try to delay a full liberalization.22

    Third, the opening of the market for new entrants depends on the strength of incumbents to

    block new entrants vis--vis the existence and degree of organization of outsiders that would

    benefit from the reform. In general it can be assumed that incumbents are better organized and

    have closer ties to relevant decision-makers, which will delay reforms.23 Fourth, interest

    groups may also affect the speed of reforms. A "war of attrition" between different interest

    groups, in which the group that gives in first loses more, will lead to a delay of reforms.24 In

    19 See Opper (2004), p. 571.20 See Roland (2002), p. 45.21 See Opper (2004), p. 569f.22 This can however be solved by using a dual-track liberalization approach in which pre-existing rents are

    preserved. For a discussion see Lau, Qian and Roland (2000).23 See Abiad and Mody (2002), p. 12; Rajan and Zingales (2003), p. 20f.24 See Alesina and Drazen (1991), p. 1171.

  • 8/8/2019 unpan024226

    9/28

    -8-

    addition, uncertainty about the distribution of gains and losses from the reforms will induce

    economic agents to prefer the status quo, which may also lead to a delay of reforms.25

    It can be concluded that political-economy factors can have a profound influence on thereform process in the banking sector, and therefore can help to explain reform outcomes.

    Before these factors are applied to explain the reform progress in India and China, an

    overview of banking sector reforms in the two countries is given.

    4 DEVELOPMENT OF THE BANKING SECTORS IN INDIA AND

    CHINA

    4.1 India

    At the time of Independence in 1947, the banking system in India was fairly well developed

    with over 600 commercial banks operating in the country. However, soon after Independence,

    the view that the banks from the colonial heritage were biased against extending credit to

    small-scale enterprises, agriculture and commoners gained prominence. To ensure better

    coverage of the banking needs of larger parts of the economy and the rural constituencies, the

    Government of India created the State Bank of India (SBI) in 1955. Despite the progress in

    the 1950s and 1960s, it was felt that the creation of the SBI was not far reaching enough since

    the banking needs of small scale industries and the agricultural sector were still not covered

    sufficiently. Additionally, there was a perception that banks should play a more prominent

    role in India's development strategy by mobilizing resources for sectors that were seen as

    crucial for economic expansion. As a consequence, in 1967 the policy of social control over

    banks was announced, which aimed to cause changes in the management and distribution of

    credit by commercial banks.26

    In 1969 the 14 largest public banks were nationalized which raised the Public Sector Banks'

    (SOB) share of deposits from 31% to 86%. The two main objectives of the nationalizations

    were rapid branch expansion and the channeling of credit in line with the priorities of the five-

    year plans. To achieve these goals, the newly nationalized banks received quantitative targets

    for the expansion of their branch network and for the percentage of credit they had to extend

    25See Fernandez and Rodrik (1992).

    26 See Cygnus (2004), p. 5; ICRA (2004), p. 5; Joshi and Little (1997), p. 110f.; Kumbhakar and Sarkar (2003),p. 406f.; Reddy (2002b), p. 337f.; Shirai (2002b), p. 8.

  • 8/8/2019 unpan024226

    10/28

    -9-

    to the so-called priority sectors, which initially stood at 33.3%. Six more banks were

    nationalized in 1980, which raised the public sector's share of deposits to 92%. The second

    wave of nationalizations occurred because control over the banking system became

    increasingly important as a means to ensure priority sector lending, reach the poor through a

    widening branch network and to fund rising public deficits. In addition to the nationalization

    of banks, the priority sector lending targets were raised to 40%. Besides the establishment of

    priority sector credits and the nationalization of banks, the government took further control

    over banks' funds by raising the statutory liquidity ratio (SLR) and the cash reserve ratio

    (CRR). From a level of 2% for the CRR and 25% for the SLR in 1960, both increased steeply

    until 1991 to 15% and 38.5% respectively.27

    However, the policies that were supposed to promote a more equal distribution of funds, also

    led to inefficiencies in the Indian banking system. To alleviate the negative effects, some

    reforms were enacted in the second half of the 1980s. The main policy changes were the

    introduction of Treasury Bills, the creation of money markets, and a partial deregulation of

    interest rates.28

    Despite the reform attempts, the Indian banking sector had like the overall

    economy severe structural problems by the end of the 1980s. By international standards,

    Indian banks were even despite a rapid growth of deposits extremely unprofitable. In the

    second half of the 1980s, the average return on assets was about 0.15%. The capital and

    reserves of Indian banks stood at about 1.5% of assets, which was significantly below other

    Asian countries that reached about 4-6%.29

    The 1991 report of the Narasimham Committee served as the basis for the subsequent banking

    sector reforms. The objective of banking sector reforms was in line with the overall goals of

    the 1991 economic reforms of opening the economy, giving a greater role to markets in

    setting prices and allocating resources, and increasing the role of the private sector.30 In the

    following years, reforms covered the areas of (1) liberalization including interest rate

    deregulation, the reduction of statutory pre-emptions, and the easing of directed credit rules;

    (2) stabilization of banks; (3) partial privatization of state-owned banks; (4) changes in the

    27 See Arun and Turner (2002a), p. 184; Bhide, Prasad and Ghosh (2001), p. 4; Ganesan (2003), p. 14; Hanson(2001), p. 2f.; Joshi and Little (1997), p. 111f.; Kumbhakar and Sarkar (2003), p. 407; Reddy (2002b), p. 338.

    The SLR refers to funds that have to be kept in cash or government bonds, the CRR is a percentage of funds

    that have to be deposited with the RBI. See Joshi and Little (1997), p. 112.28

    See Bhide, Prasad and Ghosh (2001), p. 5; Shirai (2002b), p. 9.29 See Joshi and Little (1997), p. 111.30 See Government of India (1991); Hanson (2001), pp. 5-7.

  • 8/8/2019 unpan024226

    11/28

    -10-

    institutional framework, and (5) entry deregulation for both domestic and foreign banks. The

    main reforms are now briefly described.

    Interest rate liberalizationPrior to the reforms, interest rates were a tool of cross-subsidization between different sectors

    of the economy. As a result the interest rate structure had grown increasingly complex with

    both lending and deposit rates set by the Reserve Bank of India (RBI). The lending rate for

    loans in excess of Rs200,000 which account for over 90% of total advances was abolished in

    October 1994. Banks were at the same time required to announce a prime lending rate (PLR)

    which according to RBI guidelines had to take the cost of funds and transaction costs into

    account. For the remaining advances up to Rs200,000 interest rates can be set freely as long

    as they do not exceed the PLR. On the deposit side, there has been a complete liberalization

    for the rates of all term deposits, which account for 70% of total deposits. From October 1995,

    interest rates for term deposits with a maturity of two years were liberalized. The minimum

    maturity was subsequently lowered from two years to 15 days in 1998. The term deposit rates

    were fully liberalized in 1997. As of 2004, the RBI is only setting the savings and the non-

    resident Indian deposit rate. For all other deposits above 15 days banks are free to set their

    own interest rates.31

    Statutory pre-emptions

    Until 1991 the CRR had increased to its maximum legal limit of 15% from a level of around

    5% in the 1960s and 1970s. From its peak in 1991, it has declined gradually to a low of 4.5%

    in June 2003. In October 2004 it was slightly increased to 5% to counter inflationary

    pressures, but the RBI remains committed to decrease the CRR to its statutory minimum of

    3%. The SLR has seen a similar development. The peak rate of the the SLR stood at 38.5% in

    February 1992, just short of the upper legal limit of 40%. Since then it has been gradually

    lowered to the statutory minimum of 25% in October 1997.32

    Priority sector lending

    Besides the high level of statutory pre-emptions, the priority sector advances were identified

    as one of the major reasons for the below average profitability of Indian banks. The

    Narasimham Committee therefore recommended a reduction from 40% to 10%. However, this

    31See Arun and Turner (2002b), p. 437; Reserve Bank of India (2004), p. 11 and 15; Shirai (2002b), p. 13f.;Singh (2005), p. 18; Varma (2002), p. 10.

    32 See Ghose (2000), p. 199; Reserve Bank of India (2004), p. 10.

  • 8/8/2019 unpan024226

    12/28

    -11-

    recommendation has not been implemented and the targets of 40% of net bank credit for

    domestic banks and 32% for foreign banks have remained the same. While the nominal

    targets have remained unchanged, the effective burden of priority sector advances has been

    reduced by expanding the definition of priority sector lending to include for example

    information technology companies.33

    Stabilization

    Due to directed lending practices and poor risk management skills, India's banks had accrued

    a significant level of NPLs. Prior to any privatization, the balance sheets of SOBs had to be

    cleaned up through capital injections. In the fiscal years 1991/92 and 1992/93 alone, the

    Indian government provided almost Rs40 billion to clean up the balance sheets of SOBs.

    Between 1993 and 1999 another Rs120 billion were injected in the nationalized banks. In

    total, the recapitalization amounted to 2% of GDP.34

    Privatization

    Despite the suggestion of the Narasimham Committee to rationalize SOBs, the Government of

    India decided against liquidation, which would have involved significant losses accruing to

    either the government or depositors. It opted instead to maintain and improve operations to

    allow banks to create a starting basis before a possible privatization. In 1993 partial privateshareholding of the SBI was allowed, which made it the first SOB to raise equity in the capital

    markets. After the 1994 amendment of the Banking Regulation Act, SOBs were allowed to

    offer up to 49% of their equity to the public. This led to the partial privatization of an

    additional eleven SOBs. Despite those partial privatizations, the government is committed to

    keep the public character of these banks by for exampling maintaining strong administrative

    controls.35

    Institution building

    The report of the Narasimham Committee was the basis for the strengthening of prudential

    norms and the supervisory framework. Starting with the guidelines on income recognition,

    asset classification, provisioning and capital adequacy the RBI issued in 1992/93, there have

    been continuous efforts to enhance the transparency and accountability of the banking sector.

    33 See Ganesan (2003), p. 15; Hanson (2001), p. 8; Reserve Bank of India (2004), p. 16.34

    See Deolalkar (1999), p. 66f.; Reddy (2002a), p. 359; Reserve Bank of India (2001), p. 26.35 See Ahluwalia (2002), p. 82; Arun and Turner (2002b), pp. 436-442; CASI (2004), p. 33; Reddy (2002a), p.

    358f.; Shirai (2002b), p. 26.

  • 8/8/2019 unpan024226

    13/28

    -12-

    The improvements of the prudential and supervisory framework were accompanied by a

    paradigm shift from micro-regulation of the banking sector to a strategy of macro-

    management.36

    The Basle Accord capital standards were adopted in April 1992. The 8% capital adequacy

    ratio had to be met by foreign banks operating in India by the end of March 1993, Indian

    banks with a foreign presence had to reach the 8% by the end of March 1994 while purely

    domestically operating banks had until the end of March 1996 to implement the requirement.

    Significant changes where also made concerning NPLs since banks can no longer treat the

    putative 'income' from them as income. Additionally, the rules guiding their recognition were

    tightened. Even though these changes mark a significant improvement, the accounting norms

    for recognizing NPLs are less stringent than in developed countries where a loan is considered

    nonperforming after one quarter of outstanding interest payments compared to two quarters in

    India.37

    Structural changes

    Before the start of the 1991 reforms, there was little effective competition in the Indian

    banking system due to strict entry restrictions for new banks, which effectively shielded the

    incumbents from competition. Over 30 new banks both domestic and foreign have enteredthe market since 1994. By March 2005, the new private sector banks and the foreign banks

    had a combined share of almost 20% of total assets.38

    4.2 China

    Like in other countries the development of the banking sector in China has been strongly

    influenced by the pre-dominant political philosophies. Since the foundation of the People's

    Republic of China (PRC) the Chinese banking sector has undergone several distinct policy

    changes. Before the reforms conducted after 1994 are described in more detail, the earlier

    developments in the banking sector are briefly described.

    The banking system of the Soviet Union in the 1930s served as a blueprint for the Chinese

    system after the declaration of the PRC in 1949. The People's Bank of China (PBC) stood at

    36

    See Reserve Bank of India (2004), p. 24f; Shirai (2002b), p. 21.37 See Joshi and Little (1997), p. 117; Madgavkar, Puri and Sengupta (2001), p. 114; Shirai (2002b), p. 21f.38 See Reserve Bank of India (2005b), pp. 231-233 and p. 258f.

  • 8/8/2019 unpan024226

    14/28

    -13-

    the center of a virtual mono-banking system since it had the main responsibility for cash,

    credit and settlements. Even though at the beginning of the 1950s other banks and rural

    cooperatives existed, they de-facto functioned as extensions of the PBC, and were eventually

    merged into the PBC system in 1955. As the de-facto mono-bank, the PBC combined central

    banking and commercial banking functions, and served as a tool for the implementation of the

    Five-Year Plans. As such, the PBC did not have any degrees of freedom in its lending

    decision size, term and interest rates of loans were all administratively set.39

    In 1979 China established a two-tier banking system with the foundation of three state-owned

    banks. These were the Agricultural Bank of China (ABC), the Bank of China (BOC) and the

    People's Construction Bank of China (PCBC). The ABC was charged with the task of

    providing banking services to rural areas and townships, the BOC which was separated from

    the PBC was supposed to act as an urban bank providing different banking services, while the

    PCBC took responsibility for financing large capital intensive projects. This was an important

    first step in creating a more diversified and specialized banking system. In 1984, the Industrial

    and Commercial Bank of China (ICBC) was established and complemented the three other

    state-owned commercial banks by taking over the commercial banking functions and the vast

    branch network of the PBC. In 1984 the PBC became the official central bank after ICBC had

    taken over its commercial banking functions.40

    Several important steps were taken to further commercialize the banking system between

    1985 and 1994. Among them was the replacement of direct grants with interest-bearing loans

    to harden the budget constraints of state-owned enterprises (SOEs), the granting of formal

    responsibility for the PBC in 1986 over monetary policy and the supervision of the financial

    system, and the formulation of a credit plan that instituted an aggregate credit ceiling for each

    PBC branch. Within those credit ceilings, the branches gained increasing autonomy to make

    credit decisions. In 1993 the State Council initiated further reform steps that included the

    transformation of the PBC into a modern central bank with responsibility for monetary policy

    and financial system supervision, and the decision to separate policy and commercial lending

    39 See Lo (2001), p. 16; Nanto and Sinha (2002), p. 472; Wolken (1990), p. 54; Yang (2004), p. 2. Under thecentral planning system, enterprises had two sources of funds: the state budget and the banking system.

    Companies received most of their funds through the official state budget. The remainder of the funds

    primarily for working capital was provided by the PBC based on a national credit plan that was prepared by

    the State Planning Commission of the State Council. See Wolken (1990), p. 55.40 See Chen and Thomas (1999), p. 17; Lardy (1998), p. 64; Lowinski and Terberger (2001), p. 5f.; Nanto and

    Sinha (2002), p. 472; Wolken (1990), p. 57.

  • 8/8/2019 unpan024226

    15/28

    -14-

    which was the basis for the transformation of the state banks into commercial banks. In

    addition to the foundation of the policy banks, major reforms in the areas of reserve

    requirements, interest rate deregulation, reduction of directed lending, entry deregulation,

    improvement of prudential regulation, and NPL management have been started since 1994.41

    These reforms are now described in more detail.

    Interest rate liberalization

    The initial attempts to liberalize interest rates started in the late 1980s, when Chinese banks

    received the flexibility to adjust interest rates for lending within a certain range around the

    administered rate. Further progress was made in 1998 and 1999 when attempts were made to

    increase the flow of credit to SMEs by first increasing the interest ceiling on loans to SMEs to

    20% in 1998 and then to 30% in the following year. From 2002, banks received more

    flexibility in setting their interest rates on loans since they could charge up to 1.3 times the

    central lending rate. This was in 2004 raised to 1.7 times the central lending rate. Despite the

    progress made on the lending side, deposit rates continue to be largely set by the state.42

    Statutory pre-emptions

    Attempts have been made to ease the burden of statutory pre-emptions. After an increase of

    reserve requirements from 13% to 20% in 1992, they were lowered to 8% in 1998 and to 6%in 1999. The statutory reserves are remunerated by the PBC.43

    Priority sector lending

    The main instrument for directed lending in China has been the credit plan. An important step

    towards a more market-based allocation of credit came with the Commercial Banking Law of

    1995, in which the four SOBs were given responsibility to operate as commercial entities with

    accountability for profits and losses. Besides the establishment of the policy banks, this

    marked an important step to ensure the extension of loans based on economic and not political

    criteria. The credit plan for working capital loans and fixed investment loans was in 1998

    replaced with an indicative, non-binding target. Today, even though banks are in general able

    41

    See Shirai (2002a), p. 21f.; Lo (2001), p. 20; World Bank (1996), p. 27.42 See Garcia-Herrero and Santabarbara (2004), p. 19; Shirai (2002a), p. 23; The Economist (2004), p. 18.43 See Garcia-Herrero and Santabarbara (2004), p. 19; Shirai (2002a), p. 23.

  • 8/8/2019 unpan024226

    16/28

    -15-

    to extend loans based on commercial considerations within the framework of the existing

    regulations, the government is still able to intervene to some extent in credit decisions.44

    StabilizationStabilization of state-owned banks is one of the foremost issues in the Chinese banking

    system. The need to stabilize the SOBs arises from a combination of a large stock of NPLs

    and low equity capital that could serve as a cushion for loan losses. Despite rapid credit

    growth over recent years, the stock of NPLs has not declined sufficiently so that even today

    NPLs stand at around 15-20% of total loans, which implies that the banking sector is

    technically insolvent. The Chinese government has tried to solve the problem by

    recapitalizing the Big Four banks with almost USD 260 bn in three successive rounds of

    recapitalization since the late 1990s and by shifting NPLs to asset management companies.45

    Privatization

    Privatization of state-owned banks in China has not proceeded beyond the selling of minority

    stakes. The first partial privatization of a Big Four bank was the global initial public offering

    of China Construction Bank in October 2005, which was followed by the listing of Bank of

    China in June 2006. Besides that foreign investors have taken ownership stakes in second-tier

    banks starting in December 2001 with HSBC's purchase of an 8% stake of the Bank ofShanghai, a local joint-stock commercial bank.46

    Institution building

    Important upgrades to the institutional infrastructure of the Chinese banking sector were made

    between 1995 and 2002. The Commercial Banking Law included provisions that required

    banks to focus on efficiency and liquidity in their operations, as well as to make inquiries into

    the creditworthiness of their customers. In addition, the Commercial Banking Law required

    banks to maintain an 8% equity cushion and to adopt a classification system for NPLs. The

    loan classification system was further upgraded in 2002 with the introduction of a five-tier

    system which all banks had to adopt by the end of 2005. Important progress in the area of

    regulation and supervision was made in 2003 with the establishment of the China Banking

    Regulatory Commission (CBRC) that took over these responsibilities from the PBC. The

    44 See Mo (1999), p. 99; Shirai (2002a), p. 24. For example according to the Commercial Banking Law state

    banks have to provide credit for projects approved by the state council. See Shirai (2002a), p. 2445 See Bremner (2005), p. 24; Garcia-Herrero and Santabarbara (2004), p. 17; The Economist (2004), p. 18f.46 See Bremner (2005), p. 26; Bremner (2006), p. 1.

  • 8/8/2019 unpan024226

    17/28

    -16-

    current main priorities of the CBRC are the reduction of NPLs, ensuring sufficient levels of

    bank capital and the upgrading of banks' internal indicators to international standards.47

    Structural changesStarting in the second half of the 1990s, the SOBs saw an increase in competition through the

    establishment of new commercial banks whose shares were owned by public authorities, and

    at times by individuals. These new commercial banks include for example Shenzhen

    Development Bank, Guangdong Development Bank and Everbright Bank. Under China's

    WTO commitment, the banking sector has to be opened successively between 2002 and 2006

    in terms of business reach and geography. Until 2002 foreign banks were only allowed to

    serve foreign companies and foreign individuals. This was extended to Chinese domestic

    companies in 2005, with the commitment to lift all restrictions in 2006, so that services can be

    offered to Chinese individuals as well. In geographic terms, the liberalization also proceeds in

    a phased manner with 2006 being the deadline for lifting all geographic restrictions for

    foreign banks' business in China.48

    5 COMPARATIVE PERSPECTIVE ON BANKING SECTOR

    REFORMS

    As the overview of the reform progress in table 1 shows, there is a remarkably high degree of

    similarity between India and China despite the different starting points for both countries and

    different reform environments. Both countries have followed the general recommendations

    for interest rate liberalization, the lowering of reserve requirements, and the enabling of

    structural changes through the entry of new players. Institution-building is a somewhat special

    case, because both countries have upgraded their institutions and relevant regulations.

    However, the enforcement of these rules seems to have been particularly in China, at least

    until recently, an issue. In the areas of directed credit and privatization both countries have

    made relatively little progress towards a market-oriented banking system. In the area of

    stabilization both countries have not followed the recommendation of a "one-time"

    recapitalization of banks. It is interesting to note that in all areas with the exception of

    47See Chen (2003), p. 321; Deutsche Bank Research (2004), p. 8; Garcia-Herrero and Santabarbara (2004), p.22f.; Lardy (2000), p. 8f.; Lowinski and Terberger (2001), p. 10; Nanto and Sinha (2002), p. 472f.

    48 See Deutsche Bank Research (2004), p. 2; Nanto and Sinha (2002), p. 473f.; Wong and Wong (2001), p. 19.

  • 8/8/2019 unpan024226

    18/28

    -17-

    directed credit, India has started in general 5-10 years earlier with reforms than China. While

    this can to a certain extent be attributed to China's mono-bank legacy and fragility of its

    banking sector, this marks an important deviation to the overall reforms where China is in

    general perceived to be the first-mover.

    Concerning the timing and sequencing of reforms, both countries have followed like for the

    rest of their reforms a gradual reform path. The generally proposed sequence of reforms has

    been followed quite well by both countries with only some smaller deviations. For example

    the initial partial privatizations were conducted quite early in the reform process in India. The

    selling of minority stakes should however be interpreted more as a means to generate funds,

    and not to cede control. China started with institution building relatively late, which again can

    be attributed to the legacy of the mono-banking system, which first required the build up of a

    two-tier banking system. It is interesting to note that both countries have despite their gradual

    and cautious reform not always had all the necessary pre-conditions in place.

    Overall it can be concluded that India and China followed the policy recommendations fairly

    well. It is noteworthy that reform progress has been limited in the contentious areas of

    directed credit, privatization and stabilization, which would be expected from a political-

    economy standpoint since these are the reforms that most likely affect various interest groups,

    and are intricately linked to enterprise reforms and the fiscal situation of the government.

    Banking sector reforms are no means by themselves, but should contribute to a better

    functioning of the sector. Therefore, it is necessary not only to evaluate the reform process,

    but also the performance effects of banking sector liberalization. This is done with the

    indicators of the CAMEL framework that analyzes capital adequacy, asset quality,

    management soundness, earnings and profitability, and liquidity.49 To provide a more holistic

    view of the reforms, indicators for financial development and sectoral concentration are

    included in the analysis.

    49 See International Monetary Fund (2000), p. 4. Sensitivity to market risks is sometimes used as an additionalfactor. Due to lack of data it is however not included here.

  • 8/8/2019 unpan024226

    19/28

    -18-

    Table 1: Reform progress in India and China

    Status

    Process step Pre-conditions Policy recommendation India China

    Liberalization

    Interest rates (1) Hard-budget constraints in

    the enterprise sector(2) Stability in the banking

    sector

    Liberalize wholesale rates first,

    followed by lending rates anddeposit rates

    Pre-conditions only partially fulfilled

    Wholesale rates liberalized in the late1980s, lending rate liberalization started

    in 1994; deposit rate liberalization

    started in 1995

    Pre-conditions only partially fulfilled

    Wholesale rates liberalized first,widening corridor for the setting of

    lending rates (starting in 1998), deposit

    rates largely set by the state

    Directed credit Ensure access of broad

    population groups to credit

    Directed credit should be

    abolished via a dual-track

    liberalization

    Directed credit program remains in

    place

    De-jure abolishment of directed credit;

    de-facto government retains some

    influence over credit distribution

    Reserve

    requirements

    Control over budget deficits Only use reserve and liquidity

    requirements for monetary

    policy

    From peak in 1991, SLR lowered to

    statutory minimum of 25% (1997); CRR

    with 5% slightly above minimum of 3%

    Reserve requirements were lowered

    from a peak of 20% in the early 1990s

    to 6% (1999). Effective reserves

    however above this level

    Stabilization (1) Correct measurement and

    classification of NPLs

    (2) Transparent accounting

    standards

    (3) Legal framework for

    claim enforcement

    (4) Stable macro-economic

    environment

    Recapitalize banks with a "once-

    and-for-all" program

    Pre-conditions not fulfilled at start of

    reforms

    Several round s of recapitalization

    between 1991 and 1999

    Pre-conditions except for stable macro

    environment not fulfilled

    Big Four banks received three rounds

    of capital injections between 1998 and

    2005

    Privatization (1) Disengagement of state

    from direct governance

    of banks

    (2) Build up of regulatory

    framework for indirect

    control

    (3) Recapitalize banks if

    needed

    Fully divest government's

    holding by selling state-owned

    banks to strategic partners

    Minority stakes in SOBs sold starting

    with the SBI in 1993; government

    however committed to keep public

    character of banks, other pre-conditions

    fulfilled

    Pre-conditions except for the

    disengagement of the state largely

    fulfilled

    Selling of stakes in Big Four banks to

    strategic foreign investors; listing of

    China Construction Bank in Oct 2005

    and Bank of China in June 2006

    Institution bu ilding - - - (1) Accountin g an d disclosu re

    rules

    (2) Regulatory and supervisory

    system

    (3) Capital adequacy

    standards in line with

    Basel capital accord

    Upgrading of rules and regulations

    started in 1992/93, with further

    tightening in the mid-1990s

    Rules have been upgraded in the mid-

    1990s; full enforcement is however still

    questionable

    Structural change (1) Supervisory agency

    (2) Sufficient net worth of

    incumbents

    Allow entry of domestic and

    foreign players

    Entry of new domestic and foreign

    banks started in 1994

    Net worth of incumbent banks however

    relatively low at the beginning of reforms

    Phased opening following the WTO

    agreements

    Capital Adequacy: India's banking sector has on average a higher capital basis than the

    Chinese as measured by the ratio of capital to risk-adjusted assets and the equity share (Figure

    1). The Chinese banking sector has however shown some improvements in recent years

    following the recapitalization of the SOBs.50

    Asset Quality: Both countries have started the reform process with a huge burden of NPLs.

    India has however so far more successfully managed to gradually reduce the burden of NPLs

    and to introduce hard-budget constraints. In China the ratio of NPLs has despite capital

    injections and strong loan growth not declined significantly (Figure 2).

    Management Soundness: The cost-income ratio is lower in China. India has since 1992 shown

    a steady improvement and has lowered the CIR from 90% to 70% (Figure 3)

    50 The aggregate capital adequacy ratio in India has since 1996 exceeded 10%. For China, data is not availablefor all years, but the level is likely significantly below the 8% threshold of the Basel capital standards.

  • 8/8/2019 unpan024226

    20/28

    -19-

    Earnings and Profitability: With the exception of the immediate aftermath of the balance-of-

    payment crisis, India's banks have been consistently more profitable than China's banks as

    measured by the return on assets (Figure 4). While the profitability of China's banks has

    improved somewhat, it remains low by international standards.

    Liquidity: Credit from monetary authorities to deposit money banks was not of great

    importance in India (Figure 5). However in China it was an important tool for refinancing and

    capitalization of banks. The importance has however declined in the last years as well. One

    possible reason for the high share is the former mono-bank system were no distinction

    between the central bank and commercial banks was made.

    Other indicators: Two further indicators to evaluate the reforms are liquid liabilities to GDP

    and the M-4 concentration ratio. Liquid liabilities to GDP is an indicator of the depth of the

    financial system. China by far exceeds India in this respect (Figure 6).The M-4 concentration

    ratio is the sum of the market shares of the four largest banks in the market. Due to the larger

    institutional diversity in the Indian banking sector in the pre-reform period, the concentration

    of the banking sector is significantly lower compared to China, which should result in more

    intense competition that benefits banks' customers (Figure 7).

    Thus, it can be concluded that on a sectoral level the Indian banking sector outperforms the

    Chinese with the exception of the cost-income ratio. The relatively weak performance of the

    Chinese banking sector as measured for example by the equity share or NPLs is exacerbated

    by the great importance of the Chinese banking sector for the overall economy as indicated by

    the high ratio of liquid liabilities to GDP.

    Possible factors that may explain the better performance of the Indian banking sector are an

    earlier start of reforms, a less difficult institutional legacy since India had no mono-banking

    system, and a lower concentration, which may lead to a higher degree of competition.

  • 8/8/2019 unpan024226

    21/28

    -20-

    Figure 1: Equity share

    0%

    1%

    2%

    3%

    4%

    5%

    6%

    7%

    19 90 1 991 1 992 1 993 19 94 19 95 19 96 199 7 1998 1999 2 000 2 001 2 002 2 003 20 04

    Equity Share India Equity Share China

    Source: BankScope (2006); Garcia-Herrero and Santabarbara (2004),

    p. 42; Reserve Bank of India (2005a).

    Figure 2: Non-performing loans as % of total loans

    0%

    5%

    10%

    15%

    20%

    25%

    30%

    35%

    199 0 199 1 199 2 199 3 199 4 199 5 199 6 19 97 19 98 19 99 20 00 20 01 20 02 20 03 20 04

    NPL India NPL China

    Source: International Monetary Fund (2005a), p. 196;

    Muniappan (2002), p. 2f.; Pei and Shirai (2004), p. 7.

    Figure 3: Co

    0%

    10%

    20%

    30%

    40%

    50%

    60%

    70%

    80%

    90%

    100%

    19 90 19 91 19 92 19 93 1 994 1995 19

    C

    Source: Garcia-Herrero a

    Reserve Bank

    Figure 4: R

    -1.5%

    -1.0%

    -0.5%

    0.0%

    0.5%

    1.0%

    1.5%

    1990 199 1 19 92 19 93 19 94 1 995 1

    RO

    Source: BankScope (2006); Garc

    p. 42; Reserve B

  • 8/8/2019 unpan024226

    22/28

    -21-

    Figure 5: Credit from monetary authorities to

    banks as % of total credit

    0%

    5%

    10%

    15%

    20%

    25%

    30%

    35%

    40%

    1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004

    Credit from monetary authorities to banks/domestic credit India

    Credit from monetary authorities to banks/domestic credit China

    Source: International Monetary Fund (2005b).

    Figure 6: Liquid liabilities to GDP

    0%

    20%

    40%

    60%

    80%

    100%

    120%

    140%

    160%

    180%

    200%

    1980

    1981

    1982

    1983

    1984

    1985

    1986

    1987

    1988

    1989

    1990

    1991

    1992

    1993

    1994

    1995

    1996

    1997

    1998

    1999

    2000

    2001

    2002

    2003

    2004

    Liquid liabilities (%of GDP) India Liquid liabilities (%of GDP) China

    Source: International Monetary Fund (2005b).

    Figure 7: M-4 con

    0%

    10%

    20%

    30%

    40%

    50%

    60%

    70%

    80%

    90%

    1 990 1991 1 992 1993 1994 1995 19

    m

    Source: Reserve Bank of Ind

    p. 6; Wong and

  • 8/8/2019 unpan024226

    23/28

    -22-

    The comparison of the reform experiences has shown that India and China have largely followed

    the same reform path, with India being ahead in most reform areas. This has also led to an overall

    better performance of the Indian banking sector. Looking at the reforms, it appears that both

    countries followed the general policy recommendations where they found little opposition from

    interest groups such as the lowering of reserve requirements or the introduction of capital

    adequacy standards, while reforms in areas that could likely affected larger constituencies such as

    privatization, credible stabilization or directed credit where not implemented as suggested by the

    general policy recommendations. Possible reasons for these outcomes are discussed in the next

    section.

    6 DISCUSSION OF REFORM RESULTS

    The political-economy factors discussed in section 3 are now used to interpret and explain the

    experiences of India and China with banking sector reforms. In both countries the reform outcomes

    have been influenced by the interaction of fiscal constraints, the performance in the enterprise

    sector and the influence of interest groups.

    Contrary to expectations the relatively weak fiscal situation in both countries appears to have had

    no major influence on the reform process: despite the relatively high debt levels in both countries,privatization of state-owned banks has not proceeded far, while statutory pre-emptions as well as

    interest rate restrictions have been lowered more than expected.51 In these areas interest groups

    appear to have played a more influential role. The same is true for stabilization of banks. The

    inability to pursue a "once-and-for-all" stabilization program appears to have been influenced more

    by the lack of political will to do so than by the budgetary situation.52

    The pace of reform in the enterprise sector appears to have had some influence on the reform

    process in the banking sector, especially due to the linkage between state-owned banks and state-

    owned enterprises. In both countries, banks were and to some extent still are burdened by

    legacy NPLs from SOEs. Since it was politically not feasible to directly introduce hard budget

    constraints in the enterprise sector at the start of the reforms due to the likelihood of large job

    51 India has annual budget deficits of around 10% of GDP and government debt of around 80% of GDP. China has a

    relatively moderate official deficit and debt levels of 3-4% of GDP and about 40% of GDP respectively. However,

    China has relatively high contingent liabilities from the bad loans that are accumulated in the banking sector, which

    are estimated to stand at 30% of GDP. See Mukherji (2005), p. 64f.; The Economist (2004), p. 18f.52 As discussed above, India's bank recapitalization program in the 1990s for example amounted to a relatively modest

    2% of GDP; China appears to have sufficient foreign currency reserves to pay for a recapitalization.

  • 8/8/2019 unpan024226

    24/28

    -23-

    losses, banks had to extend further loans to non-viable SOEs, which in turn adversely affected the

    quality of banks' loan portfolios.53 Since the respective governments were not prepared to let large

    SOEs and SOBs go bankrupt, credible stabilization of banks was not possible, and privatization

    difficult at best since banks did not fully operate according to commercial principles.

    While the fiscal situation has not had the expected effect in shaping reform outcomes, interest

    groups had a major influence. Especially in India, there has been strong opposition by interest

    groups against privatization of SOBs and the reduction of directed credit; a situation that has been

    exacerbated by relatively weak coalition governments that are particularly vulnerable to a loss of

    voters' support. An important interest group against the opening of the banking sector to new

    competitors in both India and China were the ailing SOBs themselves, which at least at the

    beginning of the reform process were not in a position to compete with best-practice players.These factors are more likely to have slowed down the reform process than a "war of attrition"

    between different interest groups, or uncertainty about the distribution of gains and losses from

    banking sector reforms.

    A surprising feature of the banking sector reforms in both countries is the similarity of the reform

    process despite a different political, economic and institutional situation in both countries. This is

    especially striking in terms of the political system since the general assumption is that China as a

    one-party authoritarian system is in a position to pursue faster reforms than the Indian multi-party

    democracy. The comparison of the reforms in the banking sector and the faster reform pace in

    India provide some evidence that the political system has less importance on the reform process

    and outcome than commonly assumed.54

    7 CONCLUSION

    The goal of this paper was to evaluate the recent banking sector reforms in India and China along

    the lines of transformation studies and to discuss political-economy factors that have shaped

    reform outcomes. The analysis showed that the reforms in both countries have proceeded quite far

    and that many of the general policy recommendations have been followed. There were however

    important deviations in areas such as stabilization, directed credit and privatization. A likely reason

    53 The distribution of bank loans in China shows that this pattern continues: private enterprises received only 27% of

    bank loans in 2003, but accounted for 52% of GDP. See McKinsey Global Institute (2006), p. 11.54 As reported by Saez and Yang (2001) this not only appears to be the case in the banking sector, but also in the

    electricity and telecommunications sector. See Saez and Yang (2001), p. 90.

  • 8/8/2019 unpan024226

    25/28

    -24-

    is higher pressure from interest groups in these areas, and the close connections between the ailing

    SOEs and state-owned banks. In terms of performance, the Indian banking sector is on most

    indicators ahead of the Chinese banking sector.

    Several implications for policy makers arise from the reform experiences in India and China. First,

    banking sector reforms are closely intertwined with the real sector of an economy. Therefore, hard-

    budget constraints in the enterprise sector are an important pre-condition for further reforms in the

    banking sector in India and China. Second, interest groups can have a profound influence on the

    reform process especially in "visible" areas such as privatization and directed credit. Thus going

    forward it is necessary to either incorporate the concerns of diverse stakeholder groups in the

    reform strategies, or to design compensation mechanisms for potential reform losers to ensure their

    buy in. The dual-track approach for price liberalization in China for example is a mechanism thatcould also be applied in the banking sector. Third, the political system of a country is likely less

    important for successful reforms than the management of interest groups.

    There are two areas that warrant further research. First, political-economy factors have only been

    discussed qualitatively in this paper. An econometric analysis would help to yield further insights

    into which factors have a significant influence on the reform process. Second, the timing of the

    banking sector reforms showed that most reforms started in the mid-1990s after the growth

    acceleration in the two countries. The relationship between banking sector reforms and economic

    growth in the two countries is therefore a topic that deserves further investigation.

    REFERENCES

    Abiad, Abdul/ Mody, Ashoka (2002): Status Quo

    Bias in Financial Reform, in: IMF Working Paper, pp.1-38.

    Ahluwalia, Montek S. (2002): Economic reforms inIndia since 1991: Has Gradualism worked?, in:

    Journal of Economic Perspectives, 16 (3), pp. 67-88.

    Alesina, Alberto/ Drazen, Allan (1991): Why areStabilizations Delayed?, in: The American Economic

    Review, 81 (5), pp. 1170-1188.

    Arun, T.G./ Turner, J.D. (2002a): Financial

    liberalisation in India, in: Journal of InternationalBanking Regulation, 4 (2), pp. 183-188.

    Arun, T.G./ Turner, J.D. (2002b): Financial Sector

    Reforms in Developing Countries: The IndianExperience, in: World Economy, 25 (3), pp. 429-445.

    Balcerowicz, Leszek/ Gelb, Alan (1994):Macropolicies in Transition to a Market Economy: A

    Three-Year Perspective, in: Bruno, Michael/

    Pleskovic, Boris (ed.), Paper prepared for the AnnualWorld Bank Conference on Development Economics

    1994, Washington D.C., pp. 21-44.

    BankScope (2006): Accessed: July 2006.

    Bhide, M. G./ Prasad, A./ Ghosh, Saibal (2001):Emerging Challenges in Indian Banking, in: Working

    Paper Stanford University, No. 103, pp. 1-61.

  • 8/8/2019 unpan024226

    26/28

    -25-

    Bonin, John P./ Hasan, Iftekhar/ Wachtel, Paul(2005): Privatization matters: Bank efficiency intransition countries, in: Journal of Banking & Finance,

    29 (8-9), pp. 2155-2178.

    Bremner, Brian (2005): Betting on China's Banks, in:

    Business Week.

    Bremner, Brian (2006): A Golden Age for China'sBanks, in: Business Week Online Edition (May 31,

    2006).

    Caprio, Gerard Jr./ Atiyas, Izak/ Hanson, James A.(1994): Policy issues in reforming finance: Lessonsand strategies, in: Caprio, Gerard Jr./ Atiyas, Izak/

    Hanson, James A. (ed.): Financial reform - theory and

    experience, Cambridge, pp. 413-440.

    CASI (2004): Doing Business in India - Ideology,

    Politics and Economic Reforms: The NationalDemocratic Alliance 1999-2004.

    Chen, Ji (2003): Capital adequacy of Chinese banks:Evaluation and enhancement, in: Journal of

    International Banking Regulation, 4 (4), pp. 320-327.

    Chen, Ji/ Thomas, Stephen C. (1999): Banking onChina, in: The China Business Review, Nov/Dec

    1999, pp. 16-22.

    Cygnus (2004): Indian Banking, Hyderabad.

    Deolalkar, G.H. (1999): The Indian Banking Sector:On the Road to Progress, in: (ed.): Rising to the

    Challenge in Asia: A Study of Financial Markets -

    India, Manila, pp. 59-109.

    Deutsche Bank Research (2004): China's financialsector: Institutional framework and main challenges,

    Frankfurt am Main.

    Dhanji, Farid (1991): Transformation Programs:Content and Sequencing, in: The American Economic

    Review, 81 (2), pp. 323-328.

    Fernandez, Raquel/ Rodrik, Dani (1992): Resistanceto Reform: Status Quo Bias in the Presence of

    Individual-Specific Uncertainty, in: The AmericanEconomic Review, 81 (5), pp. 1146-1155.

    Fry, Maxwell E. (1997): In Favour of FinancialLiberalisation, in: The Economic Journal, 107, pp.

    754-770.

    Funke, Norbert (1993): Timing and Sequencing ofReforms: Competing Views and the Role of

    Credibility, in: Kyklos, 46, pp. 337-362.

    Ganesan, P. (2003): Impact of Priority SectorAdvances on Profitability of Public Sector Banks in

    India, in: Journal of Financial Management and

    Analysis, 16 (2), pp. 14-27.

    Garcia-Herrero, Alicia/ Santabarbara, Daniel(2004): Where is the Chinese Banking System Going

    with the Ongoing Reform?, in: Documentos

    Ocasionales Banco de Espana, No. 0406, pp. 1-44.

    Ghose, Udoy Michael (2000): Die Transformation derIndischen Union - Eine empirische und theoretische

    Analyse der Wirtschaftsreformen 1991-96 und ihrer

    Implikationen fr die "Mainstream"-

    Transformationstheorie, Diss., Frankfurt am Main.

    Gibson, H./ Tsakalotos, E. (1994): The Scope andLimits of Financial Liberalization in Developing

    Countries, in: Journal of Development Studies, 30 (3),

    pp. 578-628.

    Government of India (1991): Report of TheCommittee on the Financial System, New Delhi.

    Hanson, James A. (2001): Indian Banking: MarketLiberalization and the Pressures for Institutional and

    Market Framework Reform, in: Working Paper

    Stanford University, No. 104, pp. 1-37.

    Hawkins, J./ Mihaljek, D. (2001): The banking

    industry in the emerging market economies:

    competition, consolidation and systemic stability, in:

    Overview Paper BIS, No. 4.

    ICRA (2004): The Indian Banking Industry, NewDelhi.

    International Monetary Fund (2000):Macroprudential Indicators of Financial System

    Soundness, in: IMF Occasional Paper, No. 192, pp. 1-

    49.

    International Monetary Fund (2005a): GlobalFinancial Stability Report - Market Developments andIssues, Washington, D.C.

    International Monetary Fund (2005b): International

    Financial Statistics (electronic version).

    Joshi, Vijay/ Little, I.M.D (1997): India's EconomicReforms 1991-2001, Delhi et al.

    Kloten, Norbert (1991): Die Transformation vonWirtschaftsordnungen: theoretische, phnotypische

    und politische Aspekte, Tbingen.

    Kolodko, Grzegorz W. (2004): Transition to aMarket System: Gradualism versus Radicalism, in:

    TIGER Working Paper Series, No. 60, pp. 1-11.

  • 8/8/2019 unpan024226

    27/28

    -26-

    Kormendi, Roger C./ Snyder, Edward A. (1996):

    Bank Privatizations in Transitional Economies, in:William Davidson Working Paper, No. 1, pp. 1-23.

    Kornai, Janos (1986): The Soft Budget Constraint, in:Kyklos, 39, pp. 3-30.

    Kumbhakar, Subal C./ Sarkar, Subrata (2003):Deregulation, Ownership, and Productivity Growth in

    the Banking Industry: Evidence from India, in: Journal

    of Money, Banking, and Credit, 35 (3), pp. 403-424.

    Lardy, Nicholas R. (1998): China's Unfinished

    Economic Revolution, Washington, D.C.

    Lardy, Nicholas R. (2000): When Will China's

    Financial System Meet China's Needs?, in: Working

    Paper Stanford University, No. 54, pp. 1-48.

    Lau, Lawrence J./ Qian, Yingyi/ Roland, Grard(2000): Reform Without Losers: An Interpretation of

    China's Dual-Track Approach to Reforms, in: Journal

    of Political Economy, 108 (1), pp. 120-143.

    Levine, Ross (1997): Financial Development andEconomic Growth: Views and Agenda, in: Journal of

    Economic Literature, 25, pp. 688-726.

    Lo, Wai Chung (2001): A Retrospect on China'sBanking Reform, in: The Chinese Economy, 34 (1),

    pp. 15-28.

    Lowinski, Felix/ Terberger, Eva (2001):Transformation im chinesischen Finanzsektor: Die

    Reform der staatlichen Banken zwischen Anspruch

    und Wirklichkeit, in: Wittener Diskussionspapiere,

    No. 86, pp. 1-35.

    Madgavkar, Anu/ Puri, Leo/ Sengupta, Joydeep(2001): Revitalizing India's banks, in: The McKinsey

    Quarterly, No. 4, pp. 113-116.

    McKinnon, Ronald (1973): Money and Capital in

    Economic Development, Washington D.C.

    McKinnon, Ronald (1991): The Order of EconomicLiberalization - Financial Control in the Transition to a

    Market Economy, Baltimore and London.

    McKinsey Global Institute (2006): Putting China'sCapital to Work: The Value of Financial System

    Reform, San Francisco.

    Mehran, Hassanali/ Laurens, Bernard (1997):Interest Rates: An Approach to Liberalization, in:

    Finance & Development, June 1997, pp. 33-35.

    Mo, YK (1999): A review of recent banking reforms

    in China, in: Bank for International Settlements (ed.):Strengthening the Banking System in China: Issues

    and Experiences (BIS Policy Papers No. 7), Basel, pp.

    90-115.

    Mukherji, Joydeep (2005): The Causes of

    Differential Development: Beyond Regime

    Dichotomies, in: Friedman, Edward/ Gilley, Bruce

    (ed.): Asia's Giants: Comparing China and India, NewYork, pp. 55-75.

    Muniappan, Shri G.P. (2002): The NPA Overhang -

    Magnitude, Solutions, Legal Reforms, Paper prepared

    for the CII Banking Summit 2002, Mumbai, pp. 1-11.

    Nanto, Dick K./ Sinha, Radha (2002): China'sBanking Reform, in: Post-Communist Economies, 14

    (4), pp. 469-493.

    Olson, Mancur (1965): The Logic of CollectiveAction - Public Goods and the Theory of Groups,

    Cambridge/Mass.

    Opper, Sonja (2004): The Political Economy of

    Privatization: Empirical Evidence from Transition

    Economies, in: Kyklos, 57 (4), pp. 559-586.

    Otchere, Isaac (2005): Do privatized banks in middle-and low-income countries perform better than rival

    banks? An intra-industry analysis of bank

    privatization, in: Journal of Banking & Finance, 29 (8-

    9), pp. 2067-2093.

    Parker, David/ Kirkpatrick, Colin (2005):

    Privatisation in Developing Countries: A Review ofthe Evidence and the Policy Lessons, in: Journal of

    Development Studies, 41 (4), pp. 513-541.

    Pei, Guifen/ Shirai, Sayuri (2004): The MainProblems of China's Financial Industry and Asset

    Management Companies, in: Working Paper, pp. 1-16.

    Rajan, Raghuram G./ Zingales, Luigi (2003): TheGreat Reversals: The Politics of FinancialDevelopment in the 20th Century, in: Journal of

    Financial Economics, 69 (1), pp. 5-50.

    Reddy, Y.V. (2002a): Monetary and Financial SectorReforms in India: A Practitioner's Perspective, in: RBI

    Bulletin, May, pp. 357-374.

    Reddy, Y.V. (2002b): Public Sector Banks and theGovernance Challenge: Indian Experience, in: RBI

    Bulletin, May, pp. 337-356.

    Reserve Bank of India (2001): Report on Trend andProgress of Banking in India 2000-01.

    Reserve Bank of India (2004): Report on Trend andProgress of Banking in India 2003-04.

  • 8/8/2019 unpan024226

    28/28

    -27-

    Reserve Bank of India (2005a): Database on Indian

    Economy,,

    Accessed: October 2005.

    Reserve Bank of India (2005b): Report on Trend and

    Progress of Banking in India 2004-05.

    Rodrik, Dani (2000): Development Strategies for the21st Century, in: Pleskovic, Boris/ Stern, Nicholas

    (ed.), Paper prepared for the Annual World Bank

    Conference on Development Economics 2000,

    Washington D.C., pp. 85-108.

    Roland, Grard (2002): The Political Economy ofTransition, in: Journal of Economic Perspectives, 16

    (1), pp. 29-50.

    Roubini, Nouriel/ Sala-i-Martin, Xavier (1992):

    Financial repression and economic growth, in: Journalof Development Economics, 39 (1), pp. 5-30.

    Rybczinski, Tad M. (1991): The Sequencing ofReform: Microeconomics of Transition in Eastern

    Europe, in: Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 7 (4),

    pp. 26-34.

    Saez, Lawrence/ Yang, Joy (2001): The Deregulation

    of State-Owned Enterprises in India and China, in:

    Comparative Economic Studies, 43 (3), pp. 69-97.

    Shaw, Edward S. (1973): Financial Deepening in

    Economic Development, New York.

    Sheng, Andrew (1996): Bank RestructuringTechniques, in: Sheng, Andrew (ed.): Bank

    Restructuring: Lesson from the 1980s, Washington

    D.C., pp. 25-48.

    Shirai, Sayuri (2002a): Banking Sector Reforms in

    India and China: Does India's Experience Offer

    Lessons for China's Future Reform Agenda?, in: JBICIDiscussion Paper, No. 2, pp. 1-94.

    Shirai, Sayuri (2002b): Road from State to Market -

    Assessing the Gradual Approach to Banking Sector

    Reforms in India, in: Asian Development Bank

    Institute Research Paper, No. 32, pp. 1-73.

    Singh, Charan (2005): Financial Sector Reforms in

    India, in: Working Paper Stanford University, No.

    241, pp. 1-63.

    The Economist (2004): Non-performing, in: TheEconomist, 370 (8367), pp. 18-19.

    Varma, Jayanth R. (2002): Indian Financial SectorAfter a Decade of Reforms, in: Centre for Civil

    Society Discussion Paper, pp. 1-41.

    Wagener, Hans-Jrgen (1996): Transformation alshistorisches Phnomen, in: Frankfurt Institute of

    Transformation Studies Discussion Paper, No. 7/96,

    pp. 1-19.

    Williamson, John (2004): A Short History of theWashington Consenus, From the Washington

    Consensus towards a new Global Governance,

    Barcelona, pp. 1-14.

    Wolken, Lawrence C. (1990): The Restructuring ofChina's Banking System under the Economic Reforms

    1979-1989, in: Columbia Journal of World Business,

    pp. 53-62.

    Wong, Y.C. Richard/ Wong, M.L. Sonia (2001):Competition in China's Domestic Banking Industry,

    in: Cato Journal, 21 (1), pp. 19-41.

    World Bank (1996): The Chinese Economy: Fighting

    Inflation, Deepening Reform, Washington, D.C.

    World Bank (2001): Finance for Growth - PolicyChoices in a Volatile World, Oxford et al.

    Yang, Ya-Hwei (2004): Development and Problems

    in China's Financial System, in: Working Paper, pp. 1-

    24.