UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ......No. 14-1654 UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE...

42
No. 14-1654 UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE THIRTEENTH CIRCUIT PATRIOT WIRELESS CORP., Plaintiff-Appellee, v. DOMINION TELECOMMUNICATIONS, INC., Defendant-Appellant. Appeal from the United States District Court for the District of Madison BRIEF FOR APPELLEE Team C 123 ABC Street Mason, Madison 98765 (123) 456-7890 Attorney for Plaintiff-Appellee

Transcript of UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ......No. 14-1654 UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE...

Page 1: UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ......No. 14-1654 UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE THIRTEENTH CIRCUIT PATRIOT WIRELESS CORP., Plaintiff-Appellee, v. DOMINION TELECOMMUNICATIONS,

No. 14-1654

UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE THIRTEENTH CIRCUIT

PATRIOT WIRELESS CORP.,

Plaintiff-Appellee,

v.

DOMINION TELECOMMUNICATIONS, INC.,

Defendant-Appellant.

Appeal from the United States District Court for the District of Madison

BRIEF FOR APPELLEE Team C 123 ABC Street Mason, Madison 98765 (123) 456-7890 Attorney for Plaintiff-Appellee

Page 2: UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ......No. 14-1654 UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE THIRTEENTH CIRCUIT PATRIOT WIRELESS CORP., Plaintiff-Appellee, v. DOMINION TELECOMMUNICATIONS,

! i

TABLE OF CONTENTS

TABLE OF AUTHORITIES ...................................................................................................... iv

STATEMENT OF THE ISSUESS PRESENTED FOR REVIEW .......................................... 1

STATEMENT OF FACTS ........................................................................................................... 1

SUMMARY OF THE ARGUMENT .......................................................................................... 4

ARGUMENT ................................................................................................................................. 6

I. MONOPOLISTIC CONDUCT IS PROPERLY ANALYZED UNDER A BURDEN-

SHIFTING FRAMEWORK. ................................................................................................. 6

II. DOMINION’S BUNDLING PRACTICE IS ANTICOMPETITIVE BY BOTH THE

LEPAGE’S AND CASCADE HEALTH STANDARDS. ...................................................... 7

A. The Telecom Market’s Structure Renders Application of a Price-Cost Test Using

AVC Powerless to Prevent Anticompetitive Harms. ..................................................... 8

B. Dominion’s Bundle Caused Anticompetitive Harm Under the LePage’s Test Because

It Excluded an Equally Efficient Competitor or a New Entrant Capable of

Developing into One. ....................................................................................................... 12

1. LePage’s Is the Appropriate Test Here Because Its Direct Assessment of

Anticompetitive Effect Catches Predatory Acts that Cascade Health Cannot. ... 12

2. Dominion’s Bundle Harmed Competition by Excluding an As Efficient Rival or

by Squashing a New Competitor Before It Could Grow into an As Efficient

One. ............................................................................................................................ 13

C. Applying the Cascade Health Price-Cost Test Using an Appropriate Measure of Cost

to the Telecom Market Here Would Result in a Finding of Illegality. ....................... 16

Page 3: UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ......No. 14-1654 UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE THIRTEENTH CIRCUIT PATRIOT WIRELESS CORP., Plaintiff-Appellee, v. DOMINION TELECOMMUNICATIONS,

! ii

1. Due to the Unusually High Ratio of Fixed to Variable Costs in the Telecom

Market, the Proper Measure of Cost Here Is LRIC. ............................................. 16

2. Dominion Harmed Competition by Pricing Cellular Service Below LRIC

Through the Bundle. ................................................................................................. 19

D. Dominion Has No Valid Procompetitive Justification for the Bundle. ...................... 20

III. DOMINION’S REFUSAL TO LEASE NETWORK CAPACITY TO PATRIOT WAS

ANTICOMPETITIVE UNDER SECTION 2 .................................................................... 21

A. Due to the Lack of Regulatory Structure Intended to Introduce Competition into the

Relevant Market, Dominion’s Conduct Is Distinguished from Trinko and Properly

Analyzed As a Refusal to Deal Under the Aspen Exception. ....................................... 21

B. The District Court Correctly Found Dominion’s Refusal to Deal to Be

Anticompetitive Under the Aspen Framework. ............................................................ 23

1. Patriot Has Sufficiently Shown a Theory of Anticompetitive Harm. .................. 23

2. Dominion’s Refusal to Deal Is Anticompetitive Because It Harmed Consumers,

Excluded a Dynamic Competitor, and Indicated a Willingness to Forsake Short-

Term Profit for Long-Term Monopoly. .................................................................. 24

a. Dominion Possesses a Dangerous Probability of Achieving Monopoly Power in

the Relevant Market. ............................................................................................. 24

b. Dominion’s Conduct Was Exclusionary Under Both Interpretations of Aspen. .. 27

i. Dominion’s Conduct Was Exclusionary Under the Supreme Court’s

Reasoning in Aspen Because Dominion Harmed Consumers, Excluded Its

Rival, and Negatively Impacted Its Own Well Being. ..................................... 28

Page 4: UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ......No. 14-1654 UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE THIRTEENTH CIRCUIT PATRIOT WIRELESS CORP., Plaintiff-Appellee, v. DOMINION TELECOMMUNICATIONS,

! iii

ii. Dominion’s Conduct Was Exclusionary Based on the Aspen Factors Found

Important in Trinko. ........................................................................................ 31

c. Dominion Possesses a Specific Intent to Destroy Competition. ........................... 31

3. Dominion’s Proffered Justifications Were Unpersuasive Because Dominion

Could Have Avoided the Cited Problem by Staying on Schedule and Its Reason

for Delay Was Illogical. ............................................................................................ 32

4. On Balance, the Harms Caused by Dominion’s Conduct Outweigh Any

Benefits. ...................................................................................................................... 34

CONCLUSION ........................................................................................................................... 35

CERTIFICATE OF COMPLIANCE ....................................................................................... 35

Page 5: UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ......No. 14-1654 UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE THIRTEENTH CIRCUIT PATRIOT WIRELESS CORP., Plaintiff-Appellee, v. DOMINION TELECOMMUNICATIONS,

! iv

TABLE OF AUTHORITIES

CASES PAGE

3M Co. v. LePage’s Inc., 542 U.S. 53 (2004) ................................................................................. 7

A.A. Poultry Farms, Inc. v. Rose Acre Farms, Inc., 881 F.2d 1396 (7th Cir. 1989) .................... 18

AD/SAT, Div. of Skylight, Inc. v. Associated Press, 181 F.3d 216 (2d Cir. 1999) ........................ 25

Aspen Skiing Co. v. Aspen Highlands Skiing Corp., 472 U.S. 585 (1985) ............................ passim

Broadcom Corp. v. Qualcomm, Inc., 501 F.3d 297 (3d Cir. 2007) .............................................. 22

Brunswick Corp. v. Pueblo Bowl-O-Mat, Inc., 429 U.S. 477 (1977) ........................................... 12

Cal. Dental Ass’n v. F.T.C., 526 U.S. 756 (1999) .......................................................................... 6

Cascade Health Solutions v. PeaceHealth, 515 F.3d 883 (9th Cir. 2007) ............................ passim

Christy Sports, LLC v. Deer Valley Resort Co., 555 F.3d 1188 (10th Cir. 2009) ........................ 32

Covad Commc’ns Co. v. Bell Atl. Corp., 398 F.3d 666 (D.C. Cir. 2005) ..................................... 30

Creative Copier Servs. v. Xerox Corp., 344 F. Supp. 2d 858 (D. Conn. 2004) ............................ 32

Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Servs., Inc., 504 U.S. 451 (1992) ............... 21, 27, 32, 34

Four Corners Nephrology Assocs., P.C., v. Mercy Med. Ctr. of Durango, 582 F.3d 1216 (10th

Cir. 2009) ...................................................................................................................................... 29

Free Freehand Corp. v. Adobe Sys., Inc., 852 F. Supp. 2d 1171 (N.D. Cal. 2012) ......... 14, 15, 25

F.T.C. v. Church & Dwight Co., 665 F.3d 1312 (D.C. Cir. 2011) ................................................. 7

Helicopter Transp. Servs., Inc. v. Erickson Air-Crane Inc., No. CV 06-3077-PA, 2008 WL

151833 (D. Or. Jan. 14, 2008) ...................................................................................................... 27

Image Technical Servs., Inc. v. Eastman Kodak Co., 125 F.3d 1195 (9th Cir. 1997) ............ 24, 25

In re Elevator Antitrust Litig., 502 F.3d 47 (2d Cir. 2007) ........................................................... 31

Kolon Indus., Inc. v. E.I. DuPont de Nemours & Co., 748 F.3d 160 (4th Cir. 2014) ..................... 9

Page 6: UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ......No. 14-1654 UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE THIRTEENTH CIRCUIT PATRIOT WIRELESS CORP., Plaintiff-Appellee, v. DOMINION TELECOMMUNICATIONS,

! v

LePage’s Inc. v. 3M, 324 F.3d 141 (3d Cir. 2003) ................................................................ passim

LiveUniverse, Inc. v. MySpace, Inc., 304 F. App’x. 554 (9th Cir. 2008) ..................................... 31

Lorain Journal Co. v. United States, 342 U.S. 143 (1951) ........................................................... 21

McGahee v. N. Propane Gas Co., 858 F.2d 1487 (11th Cir. 1988) ................................................ 8

MCI Commc’ns Corp. v. Am. Tel. & Tel. Co., 708 F.2d 1081 (7th Cir. 1983) ................. 10, 11, 17

Meijer, Inc. v. Abbott Labs., 544 F. Supp. 2d 995 (N.D. Cal. 2008) .............................. 8, 9, 10, 11

Metronet Servs. Corp. v. Qwest Corp., 383 F.3d 1124 (9th Cir. 2004) ........................................ 22

MiniFrame Ltd. v. Microsoft Corp., 551 F. App’x. 1 (2d Cir. 2013) ........................................... 31

NCAA v. Bd. of Regents, 468 U.S. 85 (1984) .................................................................................. 6

Novell, Inc. v. Microsoft Corp., 731 F.3d 1064 (10th Cir. 2013) ........................................... 22, 31

N.Y. Mercantile Exch., Inc. v. Intercontinental Exch., Inc., 323 F. Supp. 2d 559

(S.D.N.Y. 2004) ............................................................................................................................ 30

Olympia Equip. Leasing Co. v. W. Union Tel. Co., 797 F.2d 370 (7th Cir. 1986) ....................... 27

Polygram Holding, Inc. v. F.T.C., 416 F.3d 29 (D.C. Cir. 2005) ............................................. 6, 32

Rebel Oil Co., Inc. v. Atl. Richfield, Co., 51 F.3d 1421 (9th Cir. 1995) ....................................... 25

S. Pac. Commc’ns Co. v. Am. Tel. & Tel. Co., 740 F.2d 980 (D.C. Cir. 1984) ................ 15, 17, 25

S. Pac. Commc’ns Co. v. Am. Tel. & Tel. Co., 556 F. Supp. 825 (D.D.C. 1982) ......................... 17

Spectrum Sports, Inc. v. McQuillan, 506 U.S. 447 (1993) ..................................................... 24, 31

Spirit Airlines, Inc. v. Nw. Airlines, Inc., 431 F.3d 917 (6th Cir. 2005) ........................... 6, 8, 9, 16

Times-Picayune Publ’g Co. v. United States, 345 U.S. 594 (1953) ............................................. 31

Transamerica Computer Co. v. Int’l Bus. Machs. Corp., 698 F.2d 1377 (9th Cir. 1983) ............ 13

Tucker v. Apple Computer, Inc., 493 F. Supp. 2d 1090 (N.D. Cal. 2006) .............................. 27, 30

United States v. Aluminum Co. of Am., 148 F. 2d 416 (2d Cir. 1945) .......................................... 30

Page 7: UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ......No. 14-1654 UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE THIRTEENTH CIRCUIT PATRIOT WIRELESS CORP., Plaintiff-Appellee, v. DOMINION TELECOMMUNICATIONS,

! vi

United States v. AMR Corp., 335 F.3d 1109 (10th Cir. 2003) ...................................................... 18

United States v. Colgate & Co., 250 U.S. 300 (1919) .................................................................. 21

United States v. E.I. du Pont de Nemours & Co., 351 U.S. 377 (1956) ....................................... 24

United States v. Grinnell Corp., 384 U.S. 563 (1966) .............................................................. 4, 27

United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34 (D.C. Cir. 2001) ........................................... passim

Verizon Commc’ns, Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S. 398 (2004) ...... passim

Virgin Atl. Airways Ltd. v. Brit. Airways PLC, 257 F.3d 256 (2d Cir. 2001) ................................. 6

!

STATUTE

15 U.S.C. § 2 ................................................................................................................................... 4

MISCELLANEOUS

Phillip E. Areeda & Herbert Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law (3d ed. 2008) ....................... 8, 10, 11, 17

Phillip E. Areeda & Donald F. Turner, Predatory Pricing and Related Practices Under Section 2

of the Sherman Act, 88 Harv. L. Rev. 697 (1975) .......................................................................... 9

John B. Kirkwood & Robert H. Lande, The Fundamental Goal of Antitrust: Protecting

Consumers, Not Increasing Efficiency, 84 Notre Dame L. Rev. 191 (2008) ......................... 34, 35

!

Page 8: UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ......No. 14-1654 UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE THIRTEENTH CIRCUIT PATRIOT WIRELESS CORP., Plaintiff-Appellee, v. DOMINION TELECOMMUNICATIONS,

! 1

STATEMENT OF THE ISSUES PRESENTED FOR REVIEW

1. Whether Dominion’s bundled discount in the telecommunications market, which forced an as

efficient rival to operate below costs and stopped a new entrant from increasing its own

efficiency, was anticompetitive.

2. Whether a dominant firm’s unilateral termination of a voluntary and profitable prior course

of dealing, causing the exclusion of a low-cost rival, constitutes attempted monopolization.

STATEMENT OF FACTS

Patriot Wireless Corporation (“Patriot”) is the dynamic, newest entrant to the cellular

service market in the suburban Mason area (“relevant market”), which has two million

subscribing households. R. ¶¶ 2, 4. Within six months of its entry in July 2012, Patriot was able

to vastly exceed growth expectations and attain a 5% share of the relevant market. R. ¶¶ 4-5.

Over half of this market share, i.e. 3%, came from Dominion subscribers. R. ¶ 5. Patriot

performed this feat by providing the same service as its competitors at the market’s lowest price,

i.e. $75 per household per month. R. ¶¶ 3-4. Further, it is a low-cost carrier by design, R. ¶ 4, as

evidenced by its low fixed costs at $2 million per month. R. ¶ 8.

By contrast, Dominion Telecommunications, Inc. (“Dominion”) is the largest competitor

in the relevant market. R. ¶ 3. As of December 2012, Dominion’s market share in the relevant

market was 40% and it has been charging $100 per household per month for cellular service. R. ¶

3. Dominion also has a legal monopoly in the cable service market in the suburban Mason area,

granted by the City of Mason. R. ¶ 2. It charges $100 per household per month for this service.

R. ¶ 2. It is also a major competitor in other large cellular service markets around the country,

but has recently been threatened by the entry of low-cost rivals in these markets. R. ¶ 3.

Page 9: UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ......No. 14-1654 UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE THIRTEENTH CIRCUIT PATRIOT WIRELESS CORP., Plaintiff-Appellee, v. DOMINION TELECOMMUNICATIONS,

! 2

Dominion built the first cellular network in the relevant market in 1993 and has been

amortizing the costs since then. R. ¶¶ 3, 7. Specifically, it is obliged to pay $200 million per year

for the network for each of the next five years. R. ¶ 7. With this existing network, Dominion’s

average variable cost (“AVC”) for providing cellular service is $3 per household per month. R. ¶

7. Its fixed costs are $72.38 million per month. R. ¶ 7. On the other hand, Patriot, being a new

entrant, has yet to construct its own network and must lease network capacity from Dominion at

$5 per household per month in order to operate. R. ¶ 8. The lease was for four years, and

contains a provision stipulating termination on 30 days’ notice. R. ¶ 4.

Since its entry in July 2012, Patriot has been planning to build its own low-cost network.

R. ¶ 4. It estimated the network to cost $220 million over two years, of which $120 million

would come from Patriot and $100 million would be financed by a bank loan. R. ¶ 11. Patriot’s

capital contribution would be drawn from its profits of $5 million per month from existing

operations; the bank loan is contingent upon maintaining this level of profit. R. ¶ 11. This plan

was blocked before construction could even begin, however. R. ¶ 12.

In response to fierce competition from Patriot and its declining market share, Dominion

conducted a market study in October 2012 on market acceptance of a cable-cell service bundle.

R. ¶ 9. The study predicted a 10% growth in the cellular market. R. ¶ 10. Dominion’s internal

projections also found that if its “network had to support 50% or more of the market for a period

of more than six months and the network was not upgraded, there would be a 50% chance” of

service outages. R. ¶ 10 (emphasis added).

Based on these findings, Dominion started offering a $105 per month cable-cell service

bundle to households in the Mason area in December 2012. R. ¶ 9. The bundle gained Dominion

a 5% increase in market share in December 2012, 1% in January 2013, and another 1% in

Page 10: UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ......No. 14-1654 UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE THIRTEENTH CIRCUIT PATRIOT WIRELESS CORP., Plaintiff-Appellee, v. DOMINION TELECOMMUNICATIONS,

! 3

February 2013. R. ¶ 9. After that, however, its growth dropped to zero, with total growth falling

short of the 10% rate Dominion had forecasted. R. ¶ 9. Nevertheless, the bundle severely curbed

Patriot’s growth, as evidenced by its restrained market share throughout this proceeding. R. ¶ 13.

If the bundle had not been enough to completely stunt Patriot’s growth, Dominion’s

refusal to continue leasing network capacity to Patriot was the death knell. R. ¶ 12. On January 2,

2013, Patriot announced the plan to build its own network, stating that until its completion

Patriot would “continue to rely entirely on its lease of Dominion’s facilities.” R. ¶ 11. Only

shortly after this announcement, Dominion gave Patriot notice that it was terminating the lease,

which prompted the banks to withdraw their financing of Patriot’s network. R. ¶ 12. Dominion’s

cited reason for the termination was the findings of its October 2012 internal projections. R. ¶ 12.

What Dominion failed to cite, however, was its own decision to delay upgrading its

network to prevent the predicted glitches. R. ¶¶ 10, 12. In November 2012, based on the study’s

findings, Dominion decided to perform the upgrades necessary to support 50% of the relevant

market. R. ¶ 10. At that time, Dominion already had on hand the $2 million required to complete

the upgrades, which would only take three months. R. ¶ 10. Instead of beginning the upgrades

that it had found necessary to support its predicted market growth, however, Dominion chose to

delay construction until July 2013, citing “greater cash flow” as the reason. R. ¶ 10.

In the end, despite its predictions, Dominion’s network has been functioning normally

since February 2013, when the complaint was filed. R. ¶ 13. At the end of December 2012,

Dominion’s network was supporting 50% of the market, R. ¶ 10, and in February 2013 it was

supporting 52% of the market. R ¶¶ 9-10. Thus, at 2% over the predicted threshold, Dominion’s

network was still able to sustain adequate operation. R. ¶ 13. Since the other two networks in the

market also refused to lease excess capacity to Patriot, R. ¶ 12, Patriot has been able to persevere

Page 11: UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ......No. 14-1654 UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE THIRTEENTH CIRCUIT PATRIOT WIRELESS CORP., Plaintiff-Appellee, v. DOMINION TELECOMMUNICATIONS,

! 4

only because the District Court granted a preliminary injunction requiring Dominion to “continue

providing cellular transmission capacity to [Patriot]” during the proceeding. R. at 1.

In District Court, Patriot and Dominion filed cross-motions for summary judgment. R. at

1. The District Court granted Patriot’s motion for summary judgment, and found that Dominion

had violated Section 2 on both the bundling and refusal to deal claims. R. ¶¶ 18, 20.

SUMMARY OF THE ARGUMENT

Section 2 of the Sherman Act makes illegal any monopoly or attempted monopoly. 15

U.S.C. § 2. To prove a violation of Section 2, the plaintiff must show that the defendant has

market power and that it engaged in exclusionary conduct, “as distinguished from growth or

development as a consequence of a superior product, business acumen, or historic accident.”

Verizon Commc’ns, Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S. 398, 407 (2004)

(quoting United States v. Grinnell Corp., 384 U.S. 563, 570-71 (1966)). Bundling and refusal to

deal are among the exclusionary tactics condemned by Section 2.

Here, Dominion has violated Section 2 by engaging in both acts. First, exploiting its

monopoly in cable service, Dominion offered a cable-cell phone bundle that is predatory by the

appropriate standards. In a high fixed costs - low variable costs market, such as the

telecommunications (“telecom”) market here, the use of AVC in a mechanical application of

Cascade Health cannot accurately reflect long-run anticompetitive harm. Therefore, using either

the LePage’s standard or a different measure of cost is required. Under the LePage’s approach,

which directly measures harm to consumers, Dominion harmed competition by forcing Patriot,

an as efficient competitor, to operate at a loss, or by completely removing Patriot’s ability to

grow from a mere nascent threat to a more efficient rival. Alternatively, using long-run

incremental cost (“LRIC”) as the proper measure of cost to assess exclusionary effect in this

Page 12: UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ......No. 14-1654 UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE THIRTEENTH CIRCUIT PATRIOT WIRELESS CORP., Plaintiff-Appellee, v. DOMINION TELECOMMUNICATIONS,

! 5

market under Cascade Health’s price-cost test, Dominion harmed competition by pricing below

cost. Accordingly, Dominion’s bundle would force a hypothetical competitor with both

Dominion’s costs and market share to operate at a massive yearly loss. Dominion having offered

no valid procompetitive justification for this conduct, its bundle is illegal under Section 2.

Second, Dominion violated Section 2 by attempting to monopolize the relevant market

through refusing to continue dealing with Patriot. Dominion’s ability to actually exclude Patriot

by refusing to lease network capacity, as well as Dominion’s 47% market share in the relevant

market characterized by significant barriers to entry, establishes a dangerous probability of

monopolization. Dominion’s termination of Patriot’s lease is exclusionary under both applicable

standards. Under the Supreme Court’s reasoning in Aspen, Dominion’s conduct was predatory

because it harmed consumers, as well as reflected a willingness to sacrifice short-run profit to

achieve a long-run anticompetitive result. Under the post-Trinko approach, Dominion’s conduct

is similarly exclusionary because it involved the termination of an existing, voluntary, and

profitable course of dealing. Dominion’s proffered justifications are all rebutted. It cited a

concern over possible service outages, but its network has been operating normally even after

exceeding the limits it predicted. Further, Dominion stated that delaying the upgrades was

necessary in order to have a greater cash flow. In reality, however, it has only foregone a source

of significant income that could have funded the majority of the upgrade. Even if Dominion were

to be believed, the benefit that consumers might receive is overwhelmed by the loss of present

and future competition that occurs when Dominion eliminates Patriot. Dominion’s refusal to

deal, therefore, has resulted in a net loss for consumers, and is a violation of Section 2.

Page 13: UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ......No. 14-1654 UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE THIRTEENTH CIRCUIT PATRIOT WIRELESS CORP., Plaintiff-Appellee, v. DOMINION TELECOMMUNICATIONS,

! 6

ARGUMENT

I. MONOPOLISTIC CONDUCT IS PROPERLY ANALYZED UNDER A BURDEN-SHIFTING FRAMEWORK.

Given the myriad of ways in which a single firm’s conduct can violate Section 2, courts

have recently come to rely on a generalized burden-shifting framework to analyze whether a

conduct is anticompetitive. In United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34 (D.C. Cir. 2001)

(per curiam), the Court of Appeals for the District of Columbia Circuit stated concisely this

general framework. First, the plaintiff must assert a theory of anticompetitive harm. Microsoft,

253 F.3d at 58. The defendant’s conduct “must harm the competitive process and thereby harm

consumers.” Id. Next, the plaintiff “must demonstrate that the monopolist’s conduct indeed has

the requisite anticompetitive effect.” Id. at 58-59. Third, if such effect has been established, the

burden shifts to the defendant to provide valid procompetitive justifications for its conduct. Id. at

59. Lastly, if the defendant’s justifications are not rebutted, “then the plaintiff must demonstrate

that the anticompetitive harm of the conduct outweighs the pro-competitive benefits.” Id.

The virtue of this framework is that it eliminates the need for courts to classify a firm’s

conduct under a single label, and allows courts to instead focus on the most important factor:

whether there is anticompetitive harm. See Polygram Holding, Inc. v. F.T.C., 416 F.3d 29, 35

(D.C. Cir. 2005) (citing Cal. Dental Ass’n v. F.T.C., 526 U.S. 756 (1999), and NCAA v. Bd. of

Regents, 468 U.S. 85 (1984) and finding that categories of analysis are less important and that

the true focus of antitrust inquiry is whether a challenged restraint enhances or destroys

competition). This sort of framework has been adopted by courts of appeal to analyze potentially

monopolistic conduct in an array of contexts. See, e.g., Spirit Airlines, Inc. v. Nw. Airlines, Inc.,

431 F.3d 917, 938 (6th Cir. 2005) (discussing monopolistic pricing); Virgin Atl. Airways Ltd. v.

Brit. Airways PLC, 257 F.3d 256, 264 (2d Cir. 2001) (analyzing incentive agreements).

Page 14: UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ......No. 14-1654 UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE THIRTEENTH CIRCUIT PATRIOT WIRELESS CORP., Plaintiff-Appellee, v. DOMINION TELECOMMUNICATIONS,

! 7

Assessment of a monopolist’s bundling arrangement and refusal to deal should be similarly

conducted under this framework.

II. DOMINION’S BUNDLING PRACTICE IS ANTICOMPETITIVE BY BOTH THE LEPAGE’S AND CASCADE HEALTH STANDARDS.

Bundling occurs when a firm “sells a bundle of goods or services for a lower price than

the seller charges for the goods or services purchased individually.” Cascade Health Solutions v.

PeaceHealth, 515 F.3d 883, 894 (9th Cir. 2007); see also LePage’s Inc. v. 3M, 324 F.3d 141,

153 (3d Cir. 2003), cert. denied, 542 U.S. 953 (2004). It is anticompetitive when consumers are

coerced into accepting a bundle due to the seller’s market power in the bundle’s non-competitive

product, while as efficient rivals not producing the desired product are excluded. Cascade

Health, 515 F.3d at 900; LePage’s, 324 F.3d at 155-57 (likening bundling to tying).

The Third Circuit in LePage’s prohibited bundling when it resulted in any

anticompetitive harm. See 324 F.3d at 159-62. The Ninth Circuit in Cascade Health sought to

accomplish the same goal, but did so by using the price-cost test as a proxy. See 151 F.3d at 910.

Resolution of this circuit split is unnecessary to answer the narrow question presented here, i.e.

whether Dominion has harmed competition in this telecom market. See Trinko, 540 U.S. at 411

(“Antitrust analysis must always be attuned to the particular structure and circumstances of the

industry at issue.”); F.T.C. v. Church & Dwight Co., 665 F.3d 1312, 1316-17 (D.C. Cir. 2011)

(refusing to “pass upon the merits of the rule in LePage’s” in deciding on FTC’s subpoena power

in Third Circuit). Under either standard, properly construed and applied to the Mason telecom

market, Dominion’s bundle is exclusionary. Because Patriot can prove that Dominion’s conduct

was exclusionary, and because Dominion fails to provide any valid procompetitive justifications,

this Court should find Dominion’s bundle in violation of Section 2.

Page 15: UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ......No. 14-1654 UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE THIRTEENTH CIRCUIT PATRIOT WIRELESS CORP., Plaintiff-Appellee, v. DOMINION TELECOMMUNICATIONS,

! 8

A. The Telecom Market’s Structure Renders Application of a Price-Cost Test Using AVC Powerless to Prevent Anticompetitive Harms.

Under Cascade Health, bundling is illegal only if, “after allocating the discount given by

the defendant on the entire bundle of products to the competitive product or products, the

defendant sold the competitive product or products below its [AVC] of producing them.” 515

F.3d at 910. Other courts, however, have recognized that in markets where fixed costs are high

and variable costs are negligible, the price can never truly be below AVC. See, e.g., Meijer, Inc.

v. Abbott Labs., 544 F. Supp. 2d 995, 1003-04 (N.D. Cal. 2008) (declining to apply Cascade

Health to pharmaceutical market); Spirit Airlines, 431 F.3d at 953 (holding that predatory pricing

could harm competition by causing rival to exit market with high entry barriers even if predator

priced above AVC). Mechanical application of Cascade Health using AVC would thus always

result in a finding of legality in these markets. Meijer, 544 F. Supp. 2d at 1003-04.

At the same time, however, the predator still injures competition by excluding as efficient

rivals who make fewer products because these rivals cannot offer the same discounted price,

which is above AVC but allows for no recoupment of fixed costs. 3A Phillip E. Areeda &

Herbert Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law ¶ 741e2 at 228 (3d ed. 2008) (“[U]ntil capacity is exhausted,

the incremental cost of serving additional customers is very low. As a result, an average variable

cost test seemed to offer the defendant too much protection.”). If these competitors match the

discount and cover only AVC, their long-run operation in this type of market will be at a loss

even though they still make a “profit” for each individual unit of product sold in the short run.

See McGahee v. N. Propane Gas Co., 858 F.2d 1487, 1495-96 (11th Cir. 1988) (criticizing

marginal cost as “static short-run analysis” and “too permissive of predatory activity”). Thus,

incumbent rivals may exit the market, and new entrants’ growth may be so constrained that they

can never become a threat to the predator. See Microsoft, 253 F.3d at 79-80 (“[I]t would be

Page 16: UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ......No. 14-1654 UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE THIRTEENTH CIRCUIT PATRIOT WIRELESS CORP., Plaintiff-Appellee, v. DOMINION TELECOMMUNICATIONS,

! 9

inimical to the purpose of the Sherman Act to allow monopolists free reign to squash nascent,

albeit unproven, competitors at will . . .”); see also Kolon Indus., Inc. v. E.I. DuPont de Nemours

& Co., 748 F.3d 160, 176 (4th Cir. 2014) (stating that harm by preventing rival’s growth was

“certainly plausible”). As the D.C. Circuit recognized, even if it is not entirely certain that a

“nascent threat” will develop into an as efficient competitor, “the defendant is made to suffer the

uncertain [antitrust] consequences of its own undesirable conduct.” Microsoft, 253 F.3d at 79.

Finally, Cascade Health’s use of AVC as a measure of cost in this type of market

inherently favors the incumbent predator over new entrants. The predator, by entering the market

first, can recoup at least some of its significant fixed costs before any threat of entry arises.

Meijer, 544 F. Supp. 2d at 1004 n.9. The new entrant, however, takes the risk of not being able to

recoup its fixed costs if it enters the market due to the predator’s bundle. Hence, even a potential

competitor with sufficient staying power may be deterred from entry by this comparative

disadvantage. See Phillip E. Areeda & Donald F. Turner, Predatory Pricing and Related

Practices Under Section 2 of the Sherman Act, 88 Harv. L. Rev. 697, 709 (1975) (discussing

exclusionary effect of predatory pricing on as efficient rivals with less staying power). Thus, if

Cascade Health’s application using AVC is widely adopted and predators are permitted to

bundle in this manner in response to every new entry in these high fixed costs - low variable

costs markets, predators can create an additional significant entry barrier with their own

behavior. See Spirit Airlines, 431 F.3d at 936 n.5 (citations omitted) (endorsing description of

“reputation for fierce response to entry” as “the predatory investment in deterrence”).

Meijer offers a clear illustration of the principles just discussed. The relevant market in

that case was the pharmaceutical market for protease inhibitor (“PI”), which is complemented by

another kind of drug called “boosters.” 544 F. Supp. 2d at 997-98. The defendant was dominant

Page 17: UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ......No. 14-1654 UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE THIRTEENTH CIRCUIT PATRIOT WIRELESS CORP., Plaintiff-Appellee, v. DOMINION TELECOMMUNICATIONS,

! 10

in the booster market and also competed in the PI market. Id. It bundled the two products into a

pill, the AVC of which was “negligible—most likely only a few cents per pill.” Id. at 1003. The

Meijer court assumed that AVC for producing the PI, i.e. the competitive product, was $0.05. Id.

Applying the Cascade Health discount attribution test, it found that the PI’s discounted price was

$1.64, which was higher than its AVC. Id. Competitors would have to sell an equally effective PI

for $0.05 or less in order to compete with the bundle. Id. The court further held:

Common sense dictates that no newly developed PI could ever be sold profitably at such a price, because the manufacturer would never be able to recoup its huge research and development costs. If the Cascade rule were applied in this context, it would stifle competition; even a competitor who could produce an equally effective drug for only $0.01 per pill would be excluded from the market.

Id. at 1003-04. Accordingly, the court concluded that applying Cascade Health would inhibit

competition due to “the unique structural characteristics of the pharmaceutical industry, where

fixed costs in the form of investment in research and development dwarf variable costs.” Id. at

1004. The court, therefore, declined to require the plaintiff to allege that the competitive

product’s imputed price was less than its AVC. Id. at 1004-05.

The current case is similar to Meijer in that mechanical application of Cascade Health

would give Dominion carte blanche to cause irreparable harm to competition in the cellular

service market. This market is a telecom market that also has high fixed costs and negligible

variable costs. See MCI Commc’ns Corp. v. Am. Tel. & Tel. Co., 708 F.2d 1081, 1115 (7th Cir.

1983) (rejecting use of short-run marginal cost in telecom market); 3A Areeda & Hovenkamp,

supra, ¶ 741e2 at 232 (using telecom as example for markets unsuitable for AVC). Here,

Dominion’s fixed costs are the network construction costs of $200 million per year plus other

fixed costs of $72.38 million per month. R. ¶ 7. Its total fixed cost is therefore approximately

$1.07 billion per year. Its AVC is $3 per household per month. R. ¶ 7. At 40% market share, R. ¶

Page 18: UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ......No. 14-1654 UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE THIRTEENTH CIRCUIT PATRIOT WIRELESS CORP., Plaintiff-Appellee, v. DOMINION TELECOMMUNICATIONS,

! 11

3, Dominion’s AVC is $28.8 million per year. A comparison between these figures shows that

this market has “unusually high ratios of fixed to variable cost”; thus, AVC is unsuitable for use

as a measure of cost. 3A Areeda & Hovenkamp, supra, ¶ 741e2 at 232. However, under Cascade

Health, Dominion’s bundled price of $5 is still higher than its AVC. R. ¶¶ 7, 18. For this sector,

a court that mechanically applies Cascade Health using AVC would find the bundle legal

regardless of any anticompetitive harm it may perpetrate. Meijer, 544 F. Supp. 2d at 1003-04.

This case is even less suitable than Meijer for mechanical application of Cascade Health

using AVC, in that the fixed costs here are truly sunk costs. In Meijer, the fixed costs were those

of research and development (“R&D”), which the defendant could control to some extent even

after the product has been created. 3A Areeda & Hovenkamp, supra, ¶ 739 at 187 (distinguishing

R&D costs from truly sunk costs of plants and equipment in defining marginal cost). However,

the network here must be built at the start, and these construction costs do not at all depend on

the output thereafter. See id. Hence, while the R&D costs in Meijer could arguably have been

included for the purpose of a Cascade Health marginal cost calculation, here the costs of the

network cannot.

Furthermore, due to its ability to cross-subsidize from its monopolist cable service

operations, R. ¶ 2, Dominion can sustain its bundle at least in the short term. See MCI, 708 F.2d

at 1124-25 (finding cross-subsidization possible if competitive product was priced below LRIC);

see infra Part II.C. By contrast, Patriot, being a new entrant, is precluded from further growth. If

it matches Dominion’s bundled price for cellular service, Patriot only just covers its AVC at $5

per household per month. R. ¶ 8. Dominion has thus forced Patriot to operate at a monthly loss of

$2 million in fixed costs. R. ¶ 8. Without court intervention, therefore, a competitor who lacks

sufficient capital to absorb this loss will eventually be driven from the market.

Page 19: UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ......No. 14-1654 UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE THIRTEENTH CIRCUIT PATRIOT WIRELESS CORP., Plaintiff-Appellee, v. DOMINION TELECOMMUNICATIONS,

! 12

Despite the bundle’s ability to exclude a new entrant, mechanical application of Cascade

Health using AVC to this case would find Dominion’s conduct to be legal because it did not

price cellular service below AVC. Regardless of whether the new entrant is, or is capable of

growing into, an as efficient rival, this categorical finding of legality is “inimical to the purpose

of the Sherman Act.” Microsoft, 253 F.3d at 79.

B. Dominion’s Bundle Caused Anticompetitive Harm Under the LePage’s Test Because It Excluded an Equally Efficient Competitor or a New Entrant Capable of Developing into One.

1. LePage’s Is the Appropriate Test Here Because Its Direct Assessment of

Anticompetitive Effect Catches Predatory Acts that Cascade Health Cannot. The LePage’s court assessed anticompetitive harm by measuring the bundle’s effect on

the plaintiff. 324 F.3d at 159-62. Implicit in the court’s equating harm to the plaintiff with harm

to competition must be a finding that the plaintiff was as efficient as the defendant. This

interpretation of LePage’s is proper because the Third Circuit presumptively followed the

Supreme Court’s mandate that plaintiffs show “antitrust injury.” Brunswick Corp. v. Pueblo

Bowl-O-Mat, Inc., 429 U.S. 477, 488-89 (1977); LePage’s, 324 F.3d at 162 (finding defendant’s

conduct to have “harmed competition itself” because defendant could raise prices after plaintiff

had exited due to high entry barriers). Additionally, LePage’s analysis of anticompetitive harm

resulting from exclusion of a nascent threat capable of developing into an as efficient rival was

supported by ample evidence of the plaintiff’s capacity for growth. 324 F.3d at 159-61 (finding

that plaintiff’s sales had been “skyrocketing” before bundle’s introduction and that defendant

prevented plaintiff from “gaining a foothold in the market”); see also Microsoft, 253 F.3d at 53-

54 (finding plaintiffs’ product capable of developing to compete with defendant’s in the future).

Based on these theories of harm, the Third Circuit’s direct assessment of exclusionary

effect in LePage’s is precisely what the Ninth Circuit purported to do indirectly in Cascade

Page 20: UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ......No. 14-1654 UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE THIRTEENTH CIRCUIT PATRIOT WIRELESS CORP., Plaintiff-Appellee, v. DOMINION TELECOMMUNICATIONS,

! 13

Health. See Cascade Health, 515 F.3d at 909 (“[W]e think it preferable to allow plaintiffs to

challenge bundled discounts if those plaintiffs can prove a defendant’s bundled discounts would

have excluded an equally efficient competitor.”). One method used by the Third Circuit to

measure anticompetitive harm was to calculate how much the plaintiff would have to lower its

own price to match the discount attributed to the competitive product. LePage’s, 324 F.3d at 161.

This calculation is the same discount attribution test adopted by the Ninth Circuit.

However, the Third Circuit went further than merely assessing prices; it also measured

the bundle’s direct effect on the plaintiff, which translated to harm to competition itself. Id. at

159-62; see also Transamerica Computer Co. v. Int’l Bus. Machs. Corp., 698 F.2d 1377, 1388

(9th Cir. 1983) (holding that “cost-price relations should not be the exclusive method of proving

predation” in predatory pricing case). By not relying exclusively on a mechanical test, LePage’s

is capable of catching predatory behavior even when the AVC price-cost test is not an accurate

proxy for effects analysis, such as in this case. See supra Part II.A. Therefore, in such cases, the

LePage’s test rather than mechanical application of Cascade Health is more suitable for

preventing harm to competition.

2. Dominion’s Bundle Harmed Competition by Excluding an As Efficient Rival or by Squashing a New Competitor Before It Could Grow into an As Efficient One.

Patriot is at least as efficient as Dominion in supplying cellular service. Dominion’s fixed

costs are $72.38 million per month. R. ¶ 7. At 40% market share and AVC of $3 per household,

Dominion’s monthly costs of cellular service operations are therefore $74.78 million. By

contrast, Patriot’s fixed costs are $2 million per month. R. ¶ 8. Assuming that Patriot also has

40% market share, at AVC of $5 per household, R. ¶ 8, Patriot’s operation cost would be only $6

million due to the vast disparity between its fixed costs and Dominion’s. Hence, although

Page 21: UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ......No. 14-1654 UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE THIRTEENTH CIRCUIT PATRIOT WIRELESS CORP., Plaintiff-Appellee, v. DOMINION TELECOMMUNICATIONS,

! 14

Dominion’s AVC is lower than Patriot’s in the very short term, a comparison between their

monthly operating costs demonstrates that Patriot is by far the more efficient competitor.

Even if this Court finds that Patriot is not as efficient as Dominion at this moment based

solely on AVC, Patriot’s rapid gain of market share from Dominion is proof that it is entirely

capable of growing into an as efficient rival, had the normal operation of the competitive market

not been disturbed. R. ¶ 5; cf. LePage’s, 324 F.3d at 159-61 (finding plaintiff’s quick growth

supported “nascent threat” theory of harm). The fact that Dominion’s market share has been

threatened by Patriot-like, low-cost rivals in other markets is further proof that Patriot’s business

model could have enabled it to develop into a more efficient competitor than Dominion. R. ¶ 3.

Had Dominion not interfered, Patriot would have earned enough to build its own low-cost

network. R. ¶ 4. By doing this, Patriot could have taken advantage of economies of scale and

reduced its AVC because it would no longer have to lease network capacity. See LePage’s, 324

F.3d at 161 (finding that “large volume customers are essential to achieving economy of scale”).

Moreover, Patriot’s network would have cost $220 million over two years, R. ¶ 11, which is by

far cheaper than Dominion’s network. In fact, because Dominion has been amortizing

construction costs since 1993, its network must cost much more than the $1 billion it has to pay

over the next five years. R. ¶ 7. Therefore, had Dominion not excluded Patriot with its predatory

tactics, see infra Part III.B.2, Patriot would have grown into a better competitor than Dominion.

To compete with the bundle, Patriot must price its cellular service at $5 per household per

month. R. ¶ 18. Hence, Dominion has severely squeezed Patriot’s monthly revenue and caused it

to lose its internal financial capacity and the bank loan necessary to build its own cellular

network. Dominion’s exclusionary tactic succeeded only because Patriot did not enter with the

full range of products that Dominion offers, i.e. both cable and cellular services. See Free

Page 22: UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ......No. 14-1654 UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE THIRTEENTH CIRCUIT PATRIOT WIRELESS CORP., Plaintiff-Appellee, v. DOMINION TELECOMMUNICATIONS,

! 15

Freehand Corp. v. Adobe Sys., Inc., 852 F. Supp. 2d 1171, 1183-84 (N.D. Cal. 2012) (holding

that defendant’s bundling practice constituted significant entry barrier to potential entrants who

lacked full array of products). In fact, no competitor could have offered the full range of products

involved because Dominion holds a legal monopoly, granted by the City of Mason, in the cable

service market. R. ¶ 2. With this legal monopoly, therefore, Dominion has ensured that no rival,

however efficient, could counteract Dominion’s bundle by offering one of its own.

Having forced Patriot to operate at a monthly loss of $2 million, supra Part II.A,

Dominion need only wait for Patriot to exit the market. Even if Patriot is able to absorb the loss

and persevere, Dominion has thoroughly rid itself of the new entrant’s ability to build its own

network and grow into a better competitor than Dominion. See LePage’s, 324 F.3d at 161

(finding that by limiting plaintiff’s market share, defendant reduced its efficiency).

This case is similar to Microsoft, where the D.C. Circuit found Microsoft to have illegally

prevented Netscape and Java from growing into competitors in the applications market at a time

when their middleware products were still only complementary to applications. 253 F.3d at 53-

54, 79, 95. The facts here present a stronger case for anticompetitive harm than in Microsoft

because Patriot is more than a mere “nascent threat”; it has actually taken market share from

Dominion. R. ¶ 5. Accordingly, the harm that Dominion perpetrated is much more certain than

that caused by Microsoft. See 253 F.3d at 79. Patriot’s status as a growing actual competitor is

comparable to that of the LePage’s plaintiff, which produced the private label transparent tape

that competed directly with the defendant’s branded transparent tape. 324 F.3d at 144.

The telecom market’s high entry barriers, such as large sunk costs, also compounded the

bundle’s anticompetitive effects. R. ¶¶ 7-8; S. Pac. Commc’ns Co. v. Am. Tel. & Tel. Co., 740

F.2d 980, 1001-02 (D.C. Cir. 1984) (discussing significant entry barriers in telecom market); see

Page 23: UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ......No. 14-1654 UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE THIRTEENTH CIRCUIT PATRIOT WIRELESS CORP., Plaintiff-Appellee, v. DOMINION TELECOMMUNICATIONS,

! 16

infra Part III.B.2.a. Furthermore, Dominion’s reputation for crushing new entrants may itself

create an entry barrier. Supra Part II.A. This tactic is especially anticompetitive because

Dominion’s predatory reputation would likely spread to all markets in which it participates and

raise their entry barriers as well. Id.; see R. ¶ 3. Hence, in at least the relevant market, Dominion

can recoup its foregone profits after Patriot has been excluded because potential entrants are

unable to enter quickly or are deterred from doing so. See, e.g., Spirit Airlines, 432 F.3d at 950-

51 (discussing effect of high entry barriers on recoupment ability in predatory pricing scheme).

Ultimately, the victims of Dominion’s predatory conduct are the consumers. By curbing

Patriot’s growth, Dominion has eliminated Patriot’s ability to improve its efficiency. R. ¶¶ 11-13.

But for the bundle, consumers would have benefitted from the lower costs of Patriot’s service,

especially in two years’ time. In other words, Dominion has deprived consumers of the

efficiency they would otherwise have received from Patriot’s growth. Moreover, Dominion may

have robbed consumers of a low-cost carrier altogether because Patriot may exit the market,

having been forced to operate at a monthly loss. Even if Patriot does not exit on its own,

Dominion would have directly driven it out by refusing to continue leasing cellular capacity to

Patriot. See infra Part. III.B.2.b.

C. Applying the Cascade Health Price-Cost Test Using an Appropriate Measure of Cost to the Telecom Market Here Would Result in a Finding of Illegality.

1. Due to the Unusually High Ratio of Fixed to Variable Costs in the Telecom

Market, the Proper Measure of Cost Here Is LRIC. If this Court decides to apply Cascade Health to the telecom market here, a measure of

cost different from AVC and short-run marginal cost is necessary. As has been explained, in a

market where fixed costs dwarf variable costs, as is the case here, mechanical application of

Cascade Health using AVC would always lead to a finding of legality because the bundled price

Page 24: UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ......No. 14-1654 UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE THIRTEENTH CIRCUIT PATRIOT WIRELESS CORP., Plaintiff-Appellee, v. DOMINION TELECOMMUNICATIONS,

! 17

of the competitive product will never be below its insignificant AVC. Supra Part II.A.

Meanwhile, the predator is still excluding as efficient competitors or squashing nascent threats,

and use of AVC would have given it carte blanche to do so. Id.

In determining the appropriate measure of cost, cases on predatory pricing are relevant

because the Cascade Health bundling model drew heavily on predatory pricing. 515 F.3d at 895-

903. Especially instructive is the Seventh and D.C. Circuits’ use of LRIC in predatory pricing

cases in the telecom sector. MCI, 708 F.2d at 1115; S. Pac. Commc’ns Co. v. Am. Tel. & Tel.

Co., 556 F. Supp. 825, 922-27 (D.D.C. 1982) (adopting LRIC and commenting that “the

Antitrust Division of the Department of Justice has advocated the use of incremental cost pricing

for the telecommunications industry”), aff’d 740 F.2d 980, 1004-06 (D.C. Cir. 1984) (applying

without adopting LRIC). Professors Areeda and Hovenkamp, from whom the Ninth Circuit

quoted extensively in Cascade Health, have also recognized this measure of cost as appropriate

for high fixed cost - low variable cost markets. 3A Areeda & Hovenkamp, supra, ¶ 741e2 at 230

(describing MCI’s result as “unobjectionable”). In fact, they explicitly used telecom as a model

market for which LRIC is the appropriate measure of costs. Id. ¶ 741e2 at 232.

LRIC measures the incremental cost of adding an entire line of product as opposed to

producing an additional unit of product. MCI, 708 F.2d at 1115. It is properly characterized as

incremental because it reflects “the change in total costs caused by the changes in output over a

longer period of time” for the competitive line of product. S. Pac. Commc’ns., 556 F. Supp. at

922; 3A Areeda & Hovenkamp, supra, ¶ 741e2 at 230 (criticizing the Seventh Circuit’s

characterization of LRIC as measure of average total cost). The costs normally classified as

fixed, such as plant and equipment, become variable because LRIC is calculated over a longer

period of time than short-run marginal cost. See MCI, 708 F.2d at 1115. Therefore, it is a valid

Page 25: UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ......No. 14-1654 UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE THIRTEENTH CIRCUIT PATRIOT WIRELESS CORP., Plaintiff-Appellee, v. DOMINION TELECOMMUNICATIONS,

! 18

measure of incremental cost. See Cascade Health, 515 F.3d at 909-10 (using “incremental cost”

and “marginal cost” interchangeably); compare United States v. AMR Corp., 335 F.3d 1109,

1117-18 (10th Cir. 2003) (holding fully allocated cost test to be invalid as a matter of law

because it measured total costs), with A.A. Poultry Farms, Inc. v. Rose Acre Farms, Inc., 881

F.2d 1396, 1406 (7th Cir. 1989) (using average total cost in predatory pricing case).

Application of LRIC is particularly appropriate to cases like this one because the

bundle’s anticompetitive effects occur only in the long run, when as efficient competitors are

forced to operate at a loss by not covering their huge fixed costs. Supra Part II.A. This strategy is

especially effective against new entrants because the predator has recouped at least some of its

fixed costs before the entry, whereas the entrant cannot afford to cover only AVC unless it has

enough capital to absorb fixed costs for as long as the predator does. Id. This ability to harm

competition in the long run “without sacrificing any short-run profits” is exactly what led the

Ninth Circuit to recognize bundling’s exclusionary effects in the first place. Cascade Health, 515

F.3d at 896-97. Hence, by calculating all the costs of operating the competitive line of product,

LRIC accounts for this long-run effect and properly reflects this type of anticompetitive harm.

Finally, LRIC can show whether a new entrant, if left unimpeded, is capable of growing

into an as efficient competitor, whereas AVC and short-run marginal cost cannot because they

only measure efficiency in the short term. Here, had Dominion not introduced the bundle, Patriot

would have been able to build its low-cost cellular network. Its construction costs would be $220

million over two years. R. ¶ 11. Patriot’s fixed and variable costs are $2 million per month and

$5 per household per month, respectively. R. ¶ 8. Therefore, for the next two years, and at 5%

market share, Patriot’s LRIC would have included fixed costs of $134 million and variable costs

of $6 million per year, totaling $140 million per year. By contrast, Dominion’s fixed costs alone

Page 26: UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ......No. 14-1654 UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE THIRTEENTH CIRCUIT PATRIOT WIRELESS CORP., Plaintiff-Appellee, v. DOMINION TELECOMMUNICATIONS,

! 19

are approximately $1.07 billion each year for the next five years. Supra Part II.A. At $28.8

million per year in variable costs, id., its LRIC is approximately $1.098 billion per year.

Thus, comparison between Patriot’s and Dominion’s LRIC starkly shows that Patriot is

capable of growing into a more efficient competitor than Dominion had it not been pre-empted

by Dominion’s tactics. Moreover, after two years, Patriot’s fixed costs and LRIC would decrease

dramatically because it will have fully paid its network construction costs, while Dominion’s

LRIC would remain unchanged because it would still be amortizing its network. R. ¶ 7. Equally,

if Patriot had finished building its network, it could have reduced its AVC through economies of

scale. See supra Part. II.B.2. Therefore, LRIC is the proper measure of long-term efficiency and

anticompetitive effect in with high fixed cost – low variable cost markets because it demonstrates

the harm in excluding a nascent threat capable of growing into an equally efficient competitor.

2. Dominion Harmed Competition by Pricing Cellular Service Below LRIC Through the Bundle.

Analyzing Dominion’s conduct under the price-cost test using LRIC as the appropriate

measure of costs for this market, this Court should find Dominion’s conduct to be predatory.

After the bundle’s introduction in December 2012, Dominion’s market share increased by 7%, R.

¶ 9, to 47% in February 2013. At 47%, its AVC is $33.84 million per year. With fixed costs at

$1.07 billion per year, its LRIC is approximately $1.1 billion per year. At the bundled price for

cellular service of $5 per household per month, R. ¶ 18, Dominion’s revenue for cellular service

each year is $56.4 million. This revenue covers Dominion’s AVC but is approximately $1.04

billion short of covering its LRIC.

The Ninth Circuit in Cascade Health emphasized the assessment of anticompetitive

effects on a hypothetical as efficient competitor with the discount attribution test. 515 F.3d at

905-07 (rejecting test of exclusionary effect on actual as efficient competitor). A simple

Page 27: UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ......No. 14-1654 UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE THIRTEENTH CIRCUIT PATRIOT WIRELESS CORP., Plaintiff-Appellee, v. DOMINION TELECOMMUNICATIONS,

! 20

calculation has shown that Dominion’s bundle would have forced this hypothetical competitor

with Dominion’s own LRIC and market share to operate at a loss of about $1.04 billion per year.

D. Dominion Has No Valid Procompetitive Justification for the Bundle.

Since Patriot has proven its theory of harm and Dominion’s predatory conduct, the

burden shifts to Dominion to offer a valid justification. Supra Part I. The court need not engage

in any balancing exercise if the predator cannot offer a valid procompetitive justification for its

conduct. See Microsoft, 253 F.3d at 62-64, 71-76. In fact, under Cascade Health, once the

predator has been found to price below a measure of cost, there is hardly any room for

justification at all. See 515 F.3d at 907 (citations omitted) (holding that if the bundled price “is

less than the defendant’s cost, then the package discount is exclusionary”).

This case concisely demonstrates the logic behind Cascade Health’s condemnation of

pricing below cost without the need to assess justifications. Dominion cited the forecasted 10%

growth in the total cellular market as the reason why it introduced the bundle. R. ¶ 9. However,

at $5 per household per month, even if Dominion had captured the entire 10%, R. ¶ 9, its revenue

would only have been $12 million per year. When compared to the $1.04 billion loss per year

that results from the bundle, this increase in revenue appears implausible as the procompetitive

reason for introducing the bundle. Of course, it would become much more plausible if Dominion

can be certain that the new entrant would be eliminated and Dominion can recoup its losses as

well as benefit from an enlarged market share. This would have been the case had the District

Court allowed Dominion to force Patriot out before the end of this proceeding. R. at 1.

Dominion having offered no other, more plausible, justification, this Court need not

weigh the anticompetitive effects of Dominion’s bundle against any procompetitive effect

because there is none here. See Microsoft, 253 F.3d at 62-64, 71-76.

Page 28: UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ......No. 14-1654 UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE THIRTEENTH CIRCUIT PATRIOT WIRELESS CORP., Plaintiff-Appellee, v. DOMINION TELECOMMUNICATIONS,

! 21

III. DOMINION’S REFUSAL TO LEASE NETWORK CAPACITY TO PATRIOT WAS ANTICOMPETITIVE UNDER SECTION 2.

One of the easiest ways for a monopolist to use its power to exclude rivals is by refusing

to do business with them. While generally businesses are free to choose with whom they will

deal, the Supreme Court has long recognized “that does not mean that the right is unqualified.”

Trinko, 540 U.S. at 408 (quoting Aspen Skiing Co. v. Aspen Highlands Skiing Corp., 472 U.S.

585, 601 (1985)); Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Servs., Inc., 504 U.S. 451, 483 (1992)

(“If Kodak adopted its . . . policies as part of a scheme of willful acquisition or maintenance of

monopoly power, it will have violated § 2.”); Lorain Journal Co. v. United States, 342 U.S. 143,

155 (1951) (emphasis added) (quoting United States v. Colgate & Co., 250 U.S. 300, 307

(1919)) (“In the absence of any purpose to create or maintain a monopoly, the [Sherman A]ct

does not restrict the . . . independent discretion as to parties with whom [a firm] will deal.”).

A. Due to the Lack of Regulatory Structure Intended to Introduce Competition into the Relevant Market, Dominion’s Conduct Is Distinguished from Trinko and Properly Analyzed As a Refusal to Deal Under the Aspen Exception. Dominion’s reliance on Trinko—the most current Supreme Court case to find a single

firm’s refusal to deal to not violate Section 2—is misguided because the holding in Trinko was

driven significantly by the presence of an effective regulatory regime designed specifically to

ensure competition in the marketplace; such regulatory system is not present here. In Trinko, the

plaintiff alleged that Verizon, the incumbent local telephone exchange carrier, had refused to

provide competing telephone operators with non-discriminatory access to its network, in

violation of its regulatory obligation under the Telecommunications Act of 1996. 540 U.S. at

404. The Court noted that the Act did not modify the antitrust standard and that any antitrust

analysis should proceed in light of traditional antitrust law, including the refusal to deal analysis.

Id. at 407-08. In this regard, the Supreme Court stated that even considering the “high value”

Page 29: UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ......No. 14-1654 UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE THIRTEENTH CIRCUIT PATRIOT WIRELESS CORP., Plaintiff-Appellee, v. DOMINION TELECOMMUNICATIONS,

! 22

given a company’s right to refuse to deal, this right was not unqualified and in certain cases

could be an illegal use of monopoly power. Id. at 408. However, the Court found that the Act

compelled Verizon to allow access to its network, and held that “the existence of a regulatory

structure designed to deter and remedy anticompetitive harm . . . significantly diminishes the

likelihood of major antitrust harm,” and thus Verizon’s conduct should not be addressed by

Section 2. Id. at 412. In essence, Trinko holds that where a market has an effective regulatory

regime designed to ensure competition through open access, a refusal to deal cannot be found.

This case is distinguished from Trinko, and should be analyzed under traditional

monopoly law. In contrast to the regulatory structure in Trinko, which was designed to

“introduce competition” into the marketplace and served “as an effective steward of the antitrust

function,” 540 U.S. at 402, 413, in this case there is no such regulatory regime. Lacking the

protection of a system designed to regulate competition in the relevant market, if the antitrust

laws are not applied here, there will be no way to ensure that consumers in the Mason area

receive the benefit of a competitive marketplace.

Refusal to deal jurisprudence has long included an exception for conduct that creates an

unlawful monopoly. The leading case for the unlawful monopoly exception is Aspen. This

decision has never been overturned and the exception fortified therein remains widely

recognized, Novell, Inc. v. Microsoft Corp., 731 F.3d 1064, 1074 (10th Cir. 2013); Broadcom

Corp. v. Qualcomm, Inc., 501 F.3d 297, 316, 318 (3d Cir. 2007); Metronet Servs. Corp. v. Qwest

Corp., 383 F.3d 1124, 1134 (9th Cir. 2004), despite subsequent decisions stating that Aspen is

“near the outer boundary of § 2 liability,” Trinko, 540 U.S. at 409.

In Aspen, the defendant owned three of the four downhill skiing mountains in the Aspen

area, and the plaintiff owned the fourth, 472 U.S. at 589-90. Beginning in 1962 and continuing

Page 30: UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ......No. 14-1654 UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE THIRTEENTH CIRCUIT PATRIOT WIRELESS CORP., Plaintiff-Appellee, v. DOMINION TELECOMMUNICATIONS,

! 23

into 1979, the plaintiff and the defendant had collaborated to offer a multi-area pass, allowing

customers visiting the Aspen area for multiple days the flexibility to ski different mountains on

different days with the purchase of a cheaper single ticket. Id. at 587-90, 592-93. In 1979, the

defendant decided to discontinue use of the multi-area pass; it also refused to accept vouchers

issued by the plaintiff to its customers to be used as payment for tickets at the defendant’s

resorts, thwarting the plaintiff’s attempts to re-create the all-area pass. Id. at 592-94. The

Supreme Court found the defendant’s conduct to be exclusionary, and upheld the jury’s verdict

against the defendant. Id. at 611. The Court held that in such cases it is “appropriate to examine

the effect of the challenged pattern of conduct on consumers, on [the monopolist’s] smaller rival,

and on [the monopolist] itself.” Id. at 605. The Court found not only that the defendant’s refusal

“infuriated” customers, id. at 607, but also that the defendant “was not motivated by efficiency

concerns and that it was willing to sacrifice short-run benefits and consumer goodwill in

exchange for a perceived long-run impact on its smaller rival,” id. at 610-11. The District Court

properly distinguished this case from Trinko and analyzed it under Aspen.

B. The District Court Correctly Found Dominion’s Refusal to Deal to Be Anticompetitive Under the Aspen Framework. 1. Patriot Has Sufficiently Shown a Theory of Anticompetitive Harm.

Dominion withdrew access to its network to counter the threat posed by Patriot to

Dominion’s market position in the relevant market. Cf. Microsoft, 253 F.3d at 60 (finding

Microsoft’s conduct “in one market (browsers) served to meet the threat to Microsoft’s

monopoly in another market (operating systems)”). The exclusionary conduct at issue here is

similar to the conduct found to be anticompetitive in Microsoft. The relevant market in Microsoft

was “intel-based PC operating systems.” Id. at 52. The court found that Microsoft had used

exclusionary methods in related markets—such as the Internet browser market—to preserve its

Page 31: UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ......No. 14-1654 UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE THIRTEENTH CIRCUIT PATRIOT WIRELESS CORP., Plaintiff-Appellee, v. DOMINION TELECOMMUNICATIONS,

! 24

monopoly in the operating system market. Id. at 60-61, 64-65. Here, Dominion’s exclusionary

activity in the network market was done to subdue a rival cellular service provider that was

threatening Dominion’s market share in the cellular services market. By terminating the network

lease, Dominion could eliminate the low-cost carrier, a feature desired by consumers (evidenced

by Patriot attaining of a 5% market share within six months of entry, R. ¶ 4), harming both

competition and consumers.

2. Dominion’s Refusal to Deal Is Anticompetitive Because It Harmed Consumers, Excluded a Dynamic Competitor, and Indicated a Willingness to Forsake Short-Term Profit for Long-Term Monopoly.

A claim of attempted monopolization requires the plaintiff to prove (1) “a dangerous

probability of achieving monopoly power” and (2) “that the defendant has engaged in predatory

or anticompetitive conduct” with (3) “a specific intent to monopolize.” Microsoft, 253 F.3d at 80

(quoting Spectrum Sports, Inc. v. McQuillan, 506 U.S. 447, 456 (1993)).

a. Dominion Possesses a Dangerous Probability of Achieving Monopoly Power in the Relevant Market.

The “dangerous probability” element of attempted monopolization is similar to the

market power element of a standard monopoly claim, requiring consideration of the defendant’s

“ability to lessen or destroy competition” in a given market. Spectrum Sports, 506 U.S. at 456;

cf. Image Technical Servs., Inc. v. Eastman Kodak Co., 125 F.3d 1195, 1202 (9th Cir. 1997)

(“The requirements of § 2 monopolization claim are similar [to an attempt claim], differing

primarily in the requisite intent and the necessary level of monopoly power.”). Whether a

defendant has sufficient market power to affect competition can be proven via either direct or

circumstantial evidence. In this case, dangerous probability can be shown both ways.

Monopoly power, defined as “the power to control prices or exclude competition,”

United States v. E.I. du Pont de Nemours & Co., 351 U.S. 377, 391 (1956), can be directly

Page 32: UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ......No. 14-1654 UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE THIRTEENTH CIRCUIT PATRIOT WIRELESS CORP., Plaintiff-Appellee, v. DOMINION TELECOMMUNICATIONS,

! 25

proven by showing that the defendant in fact has the ability to exclude competition, Microsoft,

253 F.3d at 51. Dominion, by terminating the network lease, effectively eliminated Patriot’s

ability to operate in the relevant market. Providing cellular service requires access to a network;

without access, consumers will not use Patriot as their cellular service provider. Dominion

possesses control over network access, and has exploited this control to exclude Patriot.

Dangerous probability can also be proven circumstantially by examining a firm’s market

share and the presence and strength of barriers to entry. Microsoft, 253 F.3d at 51, 82. The first

factor is whether Dominion possesses market power in a properly defined relevant market, the

cellular service market in the Mason area. As of this appeal, Dominion’s market share is 47%. R.

¶¶ 3, 9. This is sufficient for a finding of attempted monopolization. See Image Technical, 125

F.3d at 1207 (stating that “a share near 50%” was sufficient and noting that the court had

previously declined to adopt 50% as a bright line threshold). For instance, the Ninth Circuit has

held that 44% market share is sufficient for finding market power. Rebel Oil Co. v. Atl. Richfield,

Co., 51 F.3d 1421, 1438 (9th Cir. 1995). Further, the Second Circuit has stated that only when

market share is below 40% does it start to become difficult to establish a dangerous probability.

AD/SAT, Div. of Skylight, Inc. v. Associated Press, 181 F.3d 216, 229 (2d Cir. 1999).

A finding of attempted monopolization with a near 50% market share also requires that

the market be characterized by significant barriers to entry. Microsoft, 253 F.3d at 82; Rebel Oil,

51 F.3d at 1438. Such barriers to entry characterize the relevant market. See generally S. Pac.

Commc’ns, 740 F.2d at 1001-02 (discussing significant entry barriers in telecom market); Free

Freehand, 852 F. Supp. 2d at 1183-84 (discussing bundling itself as an entry barrier). The key

barrier here is network capacity. Patriot’s plight indicates that this barrier is not only existent, but

is substantial. Most companies—especially nascent competitors, such as Patriot—do not have

Page 33: UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ......No. 14-1654 UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE THIRTEENTH CIRCUIT PATRIOT WIRELESS CORP., Plaintiff-Appellee, v. DOMINION TELECOMMUNICATIONS,

! 26

access to the necessary resources to construct their own network. Rather, a new company must

attain outside financing. Most lending organizations will only agree to lend such a large sum if

they have some assurance of viability, which in essence requires the company to prove its ability

to succeed in the market. This means that for a company to attain financing to construct an asset

necessary to participate in this market, it must operate successfully in that market and prove that

it can earn a profit sufficient to repay the loan. See R. ¶ 12 (finding that the banks financing

construction of Patriot’s network backed out of the agreement after Dominion’s withdrawal

because Patriot lost its ability to participate in the market during network construction).

The second barrier to entry is proof of reliability. A cellular telephone that does not

receive service in the areas where a consumer needs service is of no use to that consumer. Thus,

consumers will not use a particular cellular service provider unless they are certain that it will

provide the reliability they desire. However, if consumers do not use the provider, it will be

difficult for that company to prove that it has the reliable coverage that consumers demand;

consequently, it will be difficult for the company to earn the income necessary to expand its

network to provide that reliability. See Microsoft, 253 F.3d at 55 (discussing “chicken-and-egg”

situation characteristic of the “applications barrier to entry,” whereby “applications will continue

to be written for the already dominant Windows, which in turn ensures that consumers will

continue to prefer it over other operating systems”). To overcome these barriers, a new cellular

service company must overcome a third barrier—finding an incumbent network that has excess

capacity and is willing to lease that excess to a new competitor.

These significant entry barriers, coupled with Dominion’s 47% market share, as well as

the direct evidence of exclusion, establish a dangerous probability of achieving monopoly power.

Page 34: UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ......No. 14-1654 UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE THIRTEENTH CIRCUIT PATRIOT WIRELESS CORP., Plaintiff-Appellee, v. DOMINION TELECOMMUNICATIONS,

! 27

b. Dominion’s Conduct Was Exclusionary Under Both Interpretations of Aspen.

In considering whether a refusal to deal is exclusionary, courts have analyzed the refusal

in either of two ways. The first follows the Supreme Court’s reasoning in Aspen itself, examining

the conduct’s impact on consumers, rivals, and the predator. The second method uses the facts

found to be most relevant in Aspen—termination of a prior, voluntary, and thus presumably

profitable, course of dealing between the parties—as specific prongs of the analysis.

Following the Court’s reasoning in Aspen is the better approach. First, at no point has the

Supreme Court explicitly overruled Aspen. See Helicopter Transp. Servs., Inc. v. Erickson Air-

Crane Inc., No. CV 06-3077-PA, 2008 WL 151833, at *7 (D. Or. Jan. 14, 2008) (“The Supreme

Court has never held that termination of a preexisting course of dealing is a necessary element of

an antitrust claim.”); Tucker v. Apple Computer, Inc., 493 F. Supp. 2d 1090, 1101 (N.D. Cal.

2006) (“[T]he Court did not confine Aspen to cases in which a prior course of dealing exists.”).

Following the first approach is more true to the actual language of and reasoning behind the

exception to refusal to deal in Aspen.

Second, it is consistent with the Supreme Court’s teaching that courts should conduct a

“factual inquiry into the commercial realities,” as opposed to relying on presumptions based on

formal distinctions, when determining the competitive effect of a firm’s conduct. Eastman

Kodak, 504 U.S. at 466-67, 482 (citing Grinnell Corp., 384 U.S. at 572); see Trinko, 540 U.S. at

411 (“Antitrust analysis must always be attuned to the particular structure and circumstances of

the industry in issue.”); see also supra Part I. In Aspen, for example, the economic reality was

that some cooperation was necessary for effective competition. Olympia Equip. Leasing Co. v.

W. Union Tel. Co., 797 F.2d 370, 379 (7th Cir. 1986) (“If [Aspen] stands for any principle . . . it

is that a monopolist may be guilty of monopolization if it refuses to cooperate with a competitor

Page 35: UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ......No. 14-1654 UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE THIRTEENTH CIRCUIT PATRIOT WIRELESS CORP., Plaintiff-Appellee, v. DOMINION TELECOMMUNICATIONS,

! 28

in circumstances where some cooperation is indispensable to effective competition.”). Finding

liability only after satisfying a checklist of facts, as would be the case if this court follows the

second method of analysis, is analogous to reliance upon formalistic distinctions. This reliance

on a checklist of facts would also undermine the virtue of the framework that has come to

characterize much modern monopoly analysis. Supra Part I.

Under either standard, however, Dominion’s refusal to lease network capacity was

anticompetitive, and therefore the District Court should be affirmed.

i. Dominion’s Conduct Was Exclusionary Under the Supreme Court’s Reasoning in Aspen Because Dominion Harmed Consumers, Excluded Its Rival, and Negatively Impacted Its Own Well Being.

Based on the Supreme Court’s reasoning in Aspen, this court should find Dominion’s

refusal to deal to be exclusionary. In Aspen, the Court found that “[i]f a firm has been attempting

to exclude rivals on some basis other than efficiency, it is fair to characterize its behavior as

predatory,” and that such determination is made by “examin[ing] the effect of the challenged

pattern of conduct on consumers, . . . rivals, and [the monopolist] itself.” 472 U.S. at 605.

First, Dominion’s conduct has a substantial anticompetitive effect on consumers by

eliminating a beneficial and desired product choice. Patriot, as the low-cost choice in the market,

R. ¶ 4, also serves as a restraint on Dominion’s pricing ability. Given the “proof of reliability”

barrier to entry, supra Part III.B.2.a, Patriot’s rapid growth proves that it provides a product

previously lacking and strongly desired by consumers.

Second, Dominion’s conduct had an adverse effect on Patriot’s ability to compete, and on

competition generally. Patriot’s preparations to build its own network, as well as its attempts to

lease capacity from other networks, R. ¶ 11-12, “demonstrates that it tried to protect itself from

Page 36: UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ......No. 14-1654 UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE THIRTEENTH CIRCUIT PATRIOT WIRELESS CORP., Plaintiff-Appellee, v. DOMINION TELECOMMUNICATIONS,

! 29

the loss of its share of the [market],” Aspen, 472 U.S. at 608. Considering the economic realities

of the relevant market, some cooperation is essential to effective and beneficial competition.

Lastly, Dominion’s conduct negatively impacts Dominion itself and shows a “willingness

to sacrifice short-run benefits.” Id. at 610-11. Dominion’s refusal to deal is analogous to the

conduct the Supreme Court found to be anticompetitive in Aspen, where the Court “found

significance in the defendant’s . . . unilateral termination of a voluntary (and thus presumably

profitable) course of dealing.” Trinko, 540 U.S. at 409 (emphasis in original).

Dominion gave Patriot access to its network in accordance with a pre-existing agreement

that was entered into voluntarily by both parties. Contrary to Trinko, where access was

compelled by a regulatory structure, 540 U.S. at 410, in this case there is no regulation to compel

network sharing; the pre-existing course of dealing between Dominion and Patriot was entirely

voluntarily. Voluntariness reveals that the sharing agreement was presumably profitable. When a

large, sophisticated corporate entity, such as Dominion, agrees to cooperate with a new rival, it is

presumably doing so because it believes the arrangement is in the company’s interest, i.e. that it

is profitable for them. Id. at 409; cf. Four Corners Nephrology Assocs., P.C., v. Mercy Med. Ctr.

of Durango, 582 F.3d 1216, 1225 (10th Cir. 2009) (finding that defendant’s refusal to enter into

a professional dealing with the plaintiff was motivated by a desire “to avoid an unprofitable

relationship, and that the hospital pursued the course it did to protect and maximize its chances

of profitability in the short-term”). In denying Patriot continued access to its network, Dominion

was foregoing a substantial benefit of $500,000 per month in “rental income.” R. ¶¶ 1, 4, 8 (two

million households in the market × 5% of the market × $5 per household per month).

Unilateral termination of such a profitable arrangement is anticompetitive. Trinko, 540

U.S. at 409 (“willingness to forsake short-term profits . . . revealed a distinctly anticompetitive

Page 37: UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ......No. 14-1654 UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE THIRTEENTH CIRCUIT PATRIOT WIRELESS CORP., Plaintiff-Appellee, v. DOMINION TELECOMMUNICATIONS,

! 30

bent”); Covad Commc’ns Co. v. Bell Atl. Corp., 398 F.3d 666, 675 (D.C. Cir. 2005); N.Y.

Mercantile Exch., Inc. v. Intercontinental Exch., Inc., 323 F. Supp. 2d 559, 571 (S.D.N.Y. 2004)

(“Because the defendant’s cooperation with the plaintiff would have entailed no cost to the

defendant and indeed would have provided it with immediate benefits, and because consumers

preferred the cooperative arrangement, the only apparent justification for the defendant’s refusal

to deal was anticompetitive malice.”); see also Tucker, 493 F. Supp. 2d at 1101 (finding on

motion to dismiss that “Apple deliberately foregoes iPod sales to prospective customers . . . facts

that, if proven, could establish that Apple was acting with ‘anticompetitive malice’ rather than

‘competitive zeal’”). Dominion’s termination of the lease was highly irrational. Its only

reasonable motivation is a desire to exclude Patriot from the market. Such evidence of intent

sheds light on the anticompetitive effect of Dominion’s conduct. Microsoft, 253 F.3d at 59.

Analyzing the structure of the relevant market supports this finding of anticompetitive

effect. As an incumbent cellular service provider, Dominion cannot plausibly argue that it did not

recognize the essential importance of network access. Dominion observed Patriot’s commercial

success and viability, and recognized that continuing to lease network capacity to Patriot would

ultimately fortify a robust competitor. By refusing to lease network capacity to Patriot, Dominion

was fully aware that it was cutting off Patriot’s lifeline, for “no monopolist monopolizes

unconscious of what he is doing.” Aspen, 472 U.S. at 602 (quoting United States v. Aluminum

Co. of Am., 148 F.2d 416, 432 (2d Cir. 1945)). The decision to terminate the lease “was

apparently motivated entirely by a decision to avoid providing any benefit to [Patriot] even

though . . . [it] would have entailed no cost” to Dominion. Aspen, 472 U.S. at 610. In sum, under

the Supreme Court’s approach in Aspen, Dominion’s refusal to deal was exclusionary.

Page 38: UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ......No. 14-1654 UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE THIRTEENTH CIRCUIT PATRIOT WIRELESS CORP., Plaintiff-Appellee, v. DOMINION TELECOMMUNICATIONS,

! 31

ii. Dominion’s Conduct Was Exclusionary Based on the Aspen Factors Found Important in Trinko.

If this Court decides to follow the post-Trinko approach, it should still find Dominion’s

termination of Patriot’s lease to be exclusionary. Post-Trinko, some courts have held that “[t]o

invoke Aspen’s limited exception . . . at least two features in Aspen must be present in the case at

hand”—(1) “a preexisting voluntary and presumably profitable course of dealing between the

monopolist and the rival” and (2) “discontinuation of the preexisting course of dealing must

suggest a willingness to forsake short-term profits to achieve an anti-competitive end.” Novell,

731 F.3d at 1074-75; e.g., LiveUniverse, Inc. v. MySpace, Inc., 304 F. App’x. 554, 556 (9th Cir.

2008); MiniFrame Ltd. v. Microsoft Corp., 551 F. App’x. 1, 2 (2d Cir. 2013) (citing In re

Elevator Antitrust Litig., 502 F.3d 47, 53 (2d Cir. 2007) (per curiam)).

Dominion’s conduct satisfies both prongs. Dominion’s refusal to deal is highly similar to

the facts of Aspen, as discussed in depth in the preceding subsection. First, Dominion’s refusal to

deal was made in the context of a voluntary pre-existing agreement between the parties. This

voluntariness indicates that the sharing agreement was profitable. Second, termination of this

prior and profitable relationship was for the purpose of and resulted in anticompetitive effect:

harm to consumers, the exclusion of a robust competitor, and harm to the competitive process.

c. Dominion Possesses a Specific Intent to Destroy Competition.

A claim of attempted monopolization requires a showing that the defendant had a specific

intent to monopolize the market. This intent is “a specific intent to destroy competition or build

monopoly.” Times-Picayune Publ’g Co. v. United States, 345 U.S. 594, 626 (1953). Specific

intent can be inferred from a monopolist’s unfair or predatory conduct. Spectrum Sports, 506

U.S. at 459. The exclusionary conduct established in the prior subsection is thus sufficient to

establish Dominion’s specific intent to exclude Patriot. However, specific intent can also be

Page 39: UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ......No. 14-1654 UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE THIRTEENTH CIRCUIT PATRIOT WIRELESS CORP., Plaintiff-Appellee, v. DOMINION TELECOMMUNICATIONS,

! 32

established more directly here. Dominion’s irrational and unilateral termination of Patriot’s

lease, coupled with the structural conditions of the industry, demonstrates that Dominion was

cognizant of what would result from its conduct—the exclusion of a robust rival, Patriot.

3. Dominion’s Proffered Justifications Were Unpersuasive Because Dominion Could Have Avoided the Cited Problem by Staying on Schedule and Its Reason for Delay Was Illogical.

If a plaintiff proves that a monopolist’s conduct has an anticompetitive effect, a defendant

is given the chance to provide justifications for its conduct. Eastman Kodak, 504 U.S. at 483;

Microsoft, 253 F.3d at 59. For instance, in holding the defendant’s conduct to be anticompetitive

in Aspen, the Court found “perhaps most significant” that the defendant was unable to proffer

any legitimate business justification for its conduct. 472 U.S. at 608; Christy Sports, LLC v. Deer

Valley Resort Co., 555 F.3d 1188, 1197 (10th Cir. 2009). The defendant bears the burden of

proving the legitimacy of its justification. Eastman Kodak, 504 U.S. at 483-84. In this case, the

District Court correctly found all proffered justifications to be pretextual and unpersuasive.

A business cannot operate in any way it pleases “if the sole reason for and effect of so

doing is to stifle or unnecessarily impair competition.” Creative Copier Servs. v. Xerox Corp.,

344 F. Supp. 2d 858, 867 (D. Conn. 2004). In particular, “a defendant’s assertion that it acted in

furtherance of its economic interests does not constitute the type of business justification that is

an acceptable defense to § 2 monopolization.” LePage’s, 324 F.3d at 163; see also Polygram,

416 F.3d at 38; Microsoft, 253 F.3d at 71 (finding that Microsoft “wants to preserve its power in

the operating system market” but holding that not to be a legitimate justification).

The crux of Dominion’s justification is its October 2012 internal projection, which stated

“that if Dominion’s network had to support 50% or more of the market for a period of more than

six months and the network was not upgraded, there would be a 50% chance that Dominion’s

Page 40: UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ......No. 14-1654 UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE THIRTEENTH CIRCUIT PATRIOT WIRELESS CORP., Plaintiff-Appellee, v. DOMINION TELECOMMUNICATIONS,

! 33

cell network” would face reliability problems. R. ¶ 10 (emphasis added). In light of this report

and its expected growth, Dominion decided in November that it would undertake the upgrades

necessary to enable it to support more than 50% of the market, i.e. the ability to support both

Patriot’s and its own customers. R. ¶ 10. “Dominion had sufficient resources on hand to

upgrade” its network immediately, but decided to delay upgrades until July 2013. R. ¶ 10.

The anomalous timing of Dominion’s decisions to upgrade its network, to delay the

upgrade, and to terminate Patriot’s lease further indicates that Dominion’s conduct was

anticompetitive. Such evidence of intent “helps us understand the likely effect of the

monopolist’s conduct.” Microsoft, 253 F.3d at 59. Had Dominion proceeded with the upgrades

as planned, the upgrades would have been completed at approximately the same time that Patriot

was removed from the network in February 2013. R. ¶ 12. This is well before the end of the six

month period stated in the study; this would also be the case if Dominion had only delayed for

three months. R ¶¶ 10, 12. After six months, the chance of service outages would still only be

50%. R. ¶ 10. In essence, as the District Court found, “[t]he Defendant would have avoided the

danger just by staying on its planned course.” R. ¶ 20. Between December 2012, when

Dominion’s network began supporting 50% of the relevant market, and the District Court’s

Order, Dominion has not cited any network failures. R. ¶ 13. Nor does Dominion provide

evidence that it experienced service outages when Dominion had previously served 50% of the

market, prior to Patriot’s entry. R. ¶ 3.

Dominion’s argument that it needed to delay in order to have a greater cash flow during

the upgrades is similarly unpersuasive. At the time of its decision to delay, Dominion had

“sufficient resources on hand” to perform the upgrades. R. ¶ 10. Additionally, by commencing

the upgrades as scheduled, Dominion would have been able to fund 75% of the cost of the

Page 41: UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ......No. 14-1654 UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE THIRTEENTH CIRCUIT PATRIOT WIRELESS CORP., Plaintiff-Appellee, v. DOMINION TELECOMMUNICATIONS,

! 34

upgrades with the $500,000 per month leasing income that it would have earned during the three-

month upgrade period. See supra Part III.B.2.b.i. Dominion’s argument that it desired a “greater

cash flow” before upgrading while simultaneously removing this income is illogical. The

Supreme Court has found such logical inconsistency sufficient to rebut a justification. Eastman

Kodak, 504 U.S. at 484 (internal citations omitted) (finding that “Kodak simultaneously claims

that its customers are sophisticated enough to make complex and subtle lifecycle-pricing

decisions, and yet too obtuse to distinguish which breakdowns are due to bad equipment and

which are due to bad service” established “that Kodak’s first reason is pretextual.”). Thus, the

District Court was correct in finding Dominion’s justifications pretextual.

4. On Balance, the Harms Caused by Dominion’s Conduct Outweigh Any Benefits.

“[I]f the monopolist’s procompetitive justification stands unrebutted, then the plaintiff

must demonstrate that the anticompetitive harm of the conduct outweighs the procompetitive

benefit.” Microsoft, 253 F.3d at 59. Here, since Dominion’s justifications have all been rebutted,

there is no need for this Court to undertake such balancing. However, if this Court does decide

that Dominion’s justifications are unrebutted, it should subsequently find the anticompetitive

effect of Dominion’s conduct to outweigh any benefits.

The outcome of this balancing is resolved by considering the impact of Dominion’s

conduct on consumers. Dominion’s termination of the lease would have forced Patriot’s

expulsion from the market, had it not been for the District Court’s injunction. “Squashing” a new

rival before it has the opportunity to develop into a better competitor harms not only the rival,

but also competition generally. Id. at 79. Harm to competition is harm to consumers, id. at 58,

who benefit from lower costs and increased product choice, see John B. Kirkwood & Robert H.

Lande, The Fundamental Goal of Antitrust: Protecting Consumers, Not Increasing Efficiency, 84

Page 42: UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ......No. 14-1654 UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE THIRTEENTH CIRCUIT PATRIOT WIRELESS CORP., Plaintiff-Appellee, v. DOMINION TELECOMMUNICATIONS,

! 35

Notre Dame L. Rev. 191, 217-22 (2008) (discussing an array of Supreme Court and Courts of

Appeals cases which identify one of the key goals of antitrust law as creating consumer benefit).

In contrast, Dominion’s justifications do not generate any consumer benefit. The implied

benefit of its conduct is a decreased likelihood of service outages. R. ¶ 12. However, Dominion

found it necessary to perform the upgrades, notwithstanding Patriot’s presence, based on its own

anticipated growth. R. ¶ 12. Thus, the appropriate question is whether delaying the upgrades had

any benefit to consumers. Contrary to Dominion’s position, consumers would benefit from an

earlier upgrade. Independent of Patriot’s elimination from the market, any delay of the

installation increases the cited risk of service outages. For instance, had Dominion reached its

expected market growth quicker than anticipated, or even surpassed its anticipated growth, the

threat of service outage would have been the same; only be installing the upgrades at an earlier

time could outages be avoided in such circumstances. Thus, delaying the upgrades may actually

harm consumers. Upon balancing the anticompetitive harm to consumers and the (lack of any)

benefits, this Court should find Dominion’s conduct to be anticompetitive.

CONCLUSION

For the reasons stated above, this Court should affirm the District Court’s finding that

Dominion’s bundling practice and refusal to deal were anticompetitive.

Respectfully submitted,

Dated: January 20, 2015 /s/ Team C Team C

CERTIFICATE OF COMPLIANCE

I certify that (1) this document has been prepared using Microsoft Word, Times New Roman, 12-

point; and (2) this document contains 11,622 words.