UNIT II:Firms & Markets

48
UNIT II: Firms & Markets Theory of the Firm Profit Maximization Perfect Competition • Review 7/14 MIDTERM 7/7

description

UNIT II:Firms & Markets. Theory of the Firm Profit Maximization Perfect Competition Review 7/14 MIDTERM. 7/7. Perfect Competition. Is it true that the rational pursuit of private interests produces coherence rather than chaos, and if so, how is it done? -- Frank Hahn - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Transcript of UNIT II:Firms & Markets

Page 1: UNIT II:Firms & Markets

UNIT II: Firms & Markets

• Theory of the Firm• Profit Maximization• Perfect Competition• Review• 7/14 MIDTERM

7/7

Page 2: UNIT II:Firms & Markets

Perfect Competition

Is it true that the rational pursuit of private interests produces coherence rather than chaos, and if so, how is it done?

-- Frank Hahn

Adam Smith described a world in which market competition weed-outs inefficient behavior, so that the ‘pursuit of private interests’ is led, as if by an invisible hand, to promote the general welfare of society.

Today, we will solve for a competitive equilibrium and consider its welfare implications. We will also construct a general equilibrium model of Smith’s vision.

Page 3: UNIT II:Firms & Markets

Perfect Competition

• Assumptions and Implications (from last time)• Solving for the Competitive Equilibrium• Equilibrium and Efficiency• General Equilibrium• Welfare Analysis

Page 4: UNIT II:Firms & Markets

Perfect Competition

Assumptions

• Firms are price-takers: can sell all the output they want at P*; can sell nothing at any price > P*.

• Homogenous product: e.g., wheat, t-shirts, long-distance phone minutes.

• Perfect factor mobility: in the long run, factors can move costlessly to where they are most productive (highest w, r).

• Perfect information: firms know everything about costs, consumer demand, other profitable opportunities, etc.

Page 5: UNIT II:Firms & Markets

Perfect Competition

Implications

1) Firms produce at minimum average cost, i.e., “efficient scale.” (AC = ACmin)

2) Price is equal to marginal cost. (P = MC)

3) Firms earn zero (economic) profits. ( = 0)

4) Market equilibrium is Pareto-efficient.

Page 6: UNIT II:Firms & Markets

Perfect Competition

In the Long-run…

1) Firms produce at minimum average cost, i.e., “efficient scale.” (AC = ACmin)

2) Price is equal to marginal cost. (P = MC)

3) Firms earn zero (economic) profits. ( = 0)

4) Market equilibrium is Pareto-efficient.

Page 7: UNIT II:Firms & Markets

Perfect Competition

The Short-run & the Long-run

In the short-run, firms adjust to price signals by varying their utilization of labor (variable factors).

In the long-run, firms adjust to profit signals by – varying plant size (fixed factors); and – entering or exiting the market.

We can use this account to understand (and solve for) the long-run competitive equilibrium.

Page 8: UNIT II:Firms & Markets

Short-run equilibrium with three firms. Firm A is making positive profits, Firm B is making zero profits, and Firm C is making negative profits (losses).

Firm A Firm B Firm C q q q

$

P

MC MC MCAC

ACAC

q: firm

Q: market

Perfect Competition

Page 9: UNIT II:Firms & Markets

Short-run equilibrium with three firms. Firm A is making positive profits, Firm B is making zero profits, and Firm C is making negative profits (losses).

Firm A Firm B Firm C q q q

$

P

In the long run,Firm C will exit the market.

MC

AC

MC

AC

Perfect Competition

Page 10: UNIT II:Firms & Markets

In the long-run, inefficient firms will exit, and new firms will enter, as long as some firms are making positive economic profits.

Firm A Firm B Firm D q q q

$

P

MC MC

AC

MC

ACAC

Perfect Competition

Page 11: UNIT II:Firms & Markets

In the long-run, if there are no barriers to entry, then new firms have access to the most efficient production technology. We call this the efficient scale.

Firm A Firm D Firm E q* q q* q q* q

$

P*

MC MC

AC

MC

ACAC

Perfect Competition

Page 12: UNIT II:Firms & Markets

Long-run equilibrium. Firms are producing at the efficient scale. P* = ACmin; = 0.

$

P*

q* q Q* Q

$

LRS

MC

AC

D

Perfect Competition

Page 13: UNIT II:Firms & Markets

Perfect Competition

Consider a perfectly competitive industry characterized by the following total cost and demand functions: 

TC = 100 + q2 QD = 1000 – 20P

Find the market equilibrium in the long-run. How many firms are in the market?

 

Page 14: UNIT II:Firms & Markets

Perfect Competition

TC = 100 + q2 QD = 1000 – 20P

q* = 10 q 600 Q

$

LRS

MC = 2q

AVC = q

AC = 100/q + q

Firms produce at ACmin

i) AC = MC 100/q + q = 2q 100 + q2 = 2q2

q2 = 100; q* = 10

ii) AC’ = 0 -100/q2 + 1 = 0 q2 = 100; q* = 10

$

P* = 20

q* is the efficient scale

Page 15: UNIT II:Firms & Markets

Perfect Competition

TC = 100 + q2 QD’ = 1500 – 20P

q.n = (MC/2)n = (P/2)n => QS = 30P SRS$

P* = 20

q’ = 15 q Q’ = 900 Q

$

LRS

MC = 2q

AVC = q

AC = 100/q + q

n = 60

SRS

D

D’

P’ = 30

Page 16: UNIT II:Firms & Markets

Perfect Competition

TC = 100 + q2 QD’ = 1500 – 20P

$

P* = 20

q* = 10 q Q** = 1100 Q

$

LRS

MC = 2q

AVC = q

AC = 100/q + q

n = 110

D

D’

Page 17: UNIT II:Firms & Markets

Perfect Competition

In the Long-run …

1) Firms produce at minimum average cost, i.e., “efficient scale.”

2) Price is equal to marginal cost.

3) Firms earn zero (economic) profits.

4) Market equilibrium is Pareto-efficient.

Page 18: UNIT II:Firms & Markets

Equilibrium & Efficiency

Is it true that the rational pursuit of private interests produces coherence rather than chaos, and if so, how is it done?

-- Frank Hahn

Equilibrium: most generally, an equilibrium is a state of the market in which decision plans are mutually consistent and therefore can be implemented.

In the market, coordination takes place via prices: at a given price, all the output firms want to produce can be sold and all the goods consumers want to purchase can be bought.

Page 19: UNIT II:Firms & Markets

Equilibrium & Efficiency

Pareto Efficiency: an economic situation is Pareto efficient if no one can be made any better off without making someone else worse off.

Pareto efficiency is a “good” thing, but it says nothing about equity; income distribution; economic justice.

Competitive markets produce Pareto efficient equilibria (Q*), because at Q* the price someone is willing to pay for an additional unit of the good is equal to the price that someone must be paid to sell that unit.

Page 20: UNIT II:Firms & Markets

Equilibrium & Efficiency

The market equilibrium is Pareto efficient because at Q* the price someone is willing to pay for an additional unit of the good is equal to the price that someone must be paid to sell that unit.

D

Q Q* Q

P At Q < Q*, a buyer and seller can exchange and

both be better off Willing to pay Pb

Pb = Ps

Willing to sell for Ps

S

Page 21: UNIT II:Firms & Markets

Equilibrium & Efficiency

We know that in a market equilibrium, both consumers and firms are optimizing, and we used these conditions to derive Demand and Supply curves.

D: MRS = Px/Py

S: MR = MC

Q* Q

P

Po

P*

Consumer Surplus

The total difference between what

consumers are willing to pay and

the market price

CS = ½(Po- P*)Q*

CS

Page 22: UNIT II:Firms & Markets

Equilibrium & Efficiency

We know that in a market equilibrium, both consumers and firms are optimizing, and we used these conditions to derive Demand and Supply curves.

D: MRS = Px/Py

S: MR = MC

Q* Q

P

Po

P*

Producer Surplus

The total difference between the firms’

marginal cost of production and the

market price

PS = (- FC)

CS

PS

Page 23: UNIT II:Firms & Markets

Equilibrium & Efficiency

We know that in a market equilibrium, both consumers and firms are optimizing, and we used these conditions to derive Demand and Supply curves.

D: MRS = Px/Py

S: MR = MC

Q* Q

P

Po

P*CS

PS

Social Surplus

The sum of consumer and

producer surplus

SS = CS + PS

Greatest at Q*

Page 24: UNIT II:Firms & Markets

Pure Exchange

An Edgeworth Box

Indifference curves for Person 1.

X

Y

1

Page 25: UNIT II:Firms & Markets

Pure Exchange

An Edgeworth Box

Indifference curves for Person 1 and Person 2. The dimensions of the box represent the total amounts of X and Y in the economy.

1

2Y

X

Page 26: UNIT II:Firms & Markets

Pure Exchange

An Edgeworth Box

Contract Curve: the set of Pareto efficient allocations, where each person is at the highest possible indifference curve, given the indifference curve of the other person.

1

2Y

X

Page 27: UNIT II:Firms & Markets

Pure Exchange

An Edgeworth Box

The initial endowment is shown in the graph, above. Both are better off at a point in the shaded area.

1

2Y

X

Endowment

Page 28: UNIT II:Firms & Markets

Pure Exchange

An Edgeworth Box

Exchange (trade) should occur until they reach a point on the contract curve.

1

2Y

X

Endowment

Page 29: UNIT II:Firms & Markets

Pure Exchange

An Edgeworth Box

1

2Y

X

Endowment

Exchange (trade) should occur s.t., MRS1= MRS2 = Px/Py.

Page 30: UNIT II:Firms & Markets

Pure Exchange

An Edgeworth Box

1

2Y

X

Endowment

Efficient Allocation

Exchange leads to a Pareto Efficient Allocation.

Page 31: UNIT II:Firms & Markets

General Equilibrium

Consider an economy with 2 consumers and 1 producer. Despite their small numbers, all behave as price-takers. Consumers consume leisure (X) and widgets (W), and widgets require only labor (L) to produce, according to the following production function:

W = LConsumers’ preferences are described by:

U1 = X11/3W1

2/3; and U2 = X22/3W2

1/3

Also, L + X = 24 (hrs/day) and the wage (w) is $1/hr.

Find: X1,2, W1,2, P

Page 32: UNIT II:Firms & Markets

General Equilibrium

Start by constructing the market demand curve

W = W1 + W2 => W = 24/Pw

U1 = X11/3W1

2/3 U2 = X22/3W2

1/3

MUx = 1/3X-2/3W2/3 MUx = 2/3X-1/3W1/3

MUw = 2/3X1/3W-1/3 MUw = 1/3X2/3W-2/3

MRS1 = W/(2X) = Px/Pw MRS2 = 2W/X = Px/Pw

Px=1 => X = 1/2PwW => X = 2PwW

BC: I = PxX + PwW BC: I = PxX + PwW

24 = 3/2 PwW 24 = 3PwW

=> W1 = 16/Pw => W2 = 8/Pw

Page 33: UNIT II:Firms & Markets

General Equilibrium

Now consider the firm’s problem:

Profit ( = Total Revenue(TR) – Total Cost(TC)

TR(Q) = PQ TC(Q) = rK + wL

P Price L LaborQ Quantity K Capital

w Wage Rater Rate on Capital

Page 34: UNIT II:Firms & Markets

General Equilibrium

Now consider the firm’s problem:

Profit ( = Total Revenue(TR) – Total Cost(TC)

TR = PW TC(Q) = rK + wL

P Price L LaborW Widgets K Capital

w Wage Rater Rate on Capital

Page 35: UNIT II:Firms & Markets

General Equilibrium

Now consider the firm’s problem:

Profit ( = Total Revenue(TR) – Total Cost(TC)

TR = PW TC(Q) = rK + wLMR = P MC = w

since w =1, we know: P = 1; W = 24 W1 = 16; W2 = 8 X1 = 8; X2 = 16

also L + X = 24, so: L1 = 16; L2 = 8; L = 24 rRate on Capital

From the Demand curve: W = 24/Pw

Page 36: UNIT II:Firms & Markets

General Equilibrium

Now consider the firm’s problem:

Profit ( = Total Revenue(TR) – Total Cost(TC)

TR = PW TC(Q) = rK + wLMR = P MC = w

since w =1, we know: P = 1; W = 24 W1 = 16; W2 = 8 X1 = 8; X2 = 16

also L + X = 24, so: L1 = 16; L2 = 8; L = 24 rRate on Capital

Page 37: UNIT II:Firms & Markets

General Equilibrium

The Market for Widgets r Rate on

Capital

W* = 24 W

P

P*= 1

Demand: W = 24/Pw

Supply: P = 1

Page 38: UNIT II:Firms & Markets

Welfare

First Theorem of Welfare Economics: All competitive equilibria are Pareto-efficient.

Second Theorem of Welfare Economics: Any allocation (of wealth or goods) can be

sustained in a competitive equilibrium.

Page 39: UNIT II:Firms & Markets

Welfare

D = d

Q

P Demand

Represents the horizontal sum of

individual consumers’

demand curves

d = consumer

D = Market Demand

We know that in a market equilibrium, both consumers and firms are optimizing, and we used these conditions to derive Demand and Supply curves.

Page 40: UNIT II:Firms & Markets

Welfare

We know that in a market equilibrium, both consumers and firms are optimizing, and we used these conditions to derive Demand and Supply curves.

D: MRS = Px/Py

Q

P Demand

Since all consumers are optimizing at

the same output prices

(Px/Py)

MRS1 = MRS2

Consumption Efficiency

d = consumer

D = Market Demand

Page 41: UNIT II:Firms & Markets

Welfare

We know that in a market equilibrium, both consumers and firms are optimizing, and we used these conditions to derive Demand and Supply curves.

D: MRS = Px/Py

P = mc: MRTS = w/r

Q* Q

P

Po

P*

Supply

Represents individual firm’s

optimal factor proportion, given

factor prices

(w/r)

mc = individual firm’s marginal cost

Page 42: UNIT II:Firms & Markets

Welfare

We know that in a market equilibrium, both consumers and firms are optimizing, and we used these conditions to derive Demand and Supply curves.

D: MRS = Px/Py

P = mc: MRTS = w/r

Q* Q

P

Po

P*

Supply

Since all firms are optimizing

(minimizing cost) at the same factor

prices (w/r)

MRTSx = MRTSy

mc = individual firm’s marginal cost

Production Efficiency

Page 43: UNIT II:Firms & Markets

Welfare

We know that in a market equilibrium, both consumers and firms are optimizing, and we used these conditions to derive Demand and Supply curves.

D: MRS = Px/Py

Q* Q

P

Po

P*

Supply

Represents total marginal cost

of production

mc = firm’s

S = Market SupplyS = mc

Page 44: UNIT II:Firms & Markets

Welfare

We know that in a market equilibrium, both consumers and firms are optimizing, and we used these conditions to derive Demand and Supply curves.

D: MRS = Px/Py

Q* Q

P

Po

P*

Supply

Represents marginal social cost

of production

mc = firm’s

S = Market SupplyS = MC

Page 45: UNIT II:Firms & Markets

Welfare

We know that in a market equilibrium, both consumers and firms are optimizing, and we used these conditions to derive Demand and Supply curves.

D: MRS = Px/Py

S: MR = MC

Q* Q

P

Po

P*

Supply

Since relative prices fully reflect

relative costs

MRSyx = MRTyx (MRTyx = MCx/MCy)

Product mix is optimal

Marginal Rate of Transformation

MRTyx = MCx/MCy

Allocative Efficiency

Page 46: UNIT II:Firms & Markets

Welfare

Consumption Efficiency: All consumers are optimizing at given output prices (Px/Py)

MRS1 = MRS2

Production Efficiency: All firms are optimizing (minimizing cost) at given factor prices (w/r) MRTSx = MRTSy

Allocation Efficiency: Product mix will be optimal; relative prices fully reflect relative costs

MRSyx = MRTyx (where MRTyx = MCx/MCy)

Page 47: UNIT II:Firms & Markets

Welfare

The raison d'être of Welfare Economics is simple. How desirable it would be if we were able to pronounce as a matter of scientific demonstration that such and such a policy was good or bad(Robbins 1984, p. xx).

Page 48: UNIT II:Firms & Markets

Next Time

7/12

UNIT III: