Unclassified ECO/WKP(2016)70 - OECD€¦ · ECO/WKP(2016)70 2 OECD Working Papers should not be...

36
Unclassified ECO/WKP(2016)70 Organisation de Coopération et de Développement Économiques Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development 22-Nov-2016 ___________________________________________________________________________________________ _____________ English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT PUBLIC FINANCE, ECONOMIC GROWTH AND INEQUALITY: A SURVEY OF THE EVIDENCE ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT WORKING PAPER No. 1346 By Åsa Johansson OECD Working Papers should not be reported as representing the official views of the OECD or of its member countries. The opinions expressed and arguments employed are those of the author(s). Authorised for publication by Jean-Luc Schneider, Deputy Director, Policy Studies Branch, Economics Department. All Economics Department Working Papers are available at www.oecd.org/eco/workingpapers JT03405922 Complete document available on OLIS in its original format This document and any map included herein are without prejudice to the status of or sovereignty over any territory, to the delimitation of international frontiers and boundaries and to the name of any territory, city or area. ECO/WKP(2016)70 Unclassified English - Or. English

Transcript of Unclassified ECO/WKP(2016)70 - OECD€¦ · ECO/WKP(2016)70 2 OECD Working Papers should not be...

Page 1: Unclassified ECO/WKP(2016)70 - OECD€¦ · ECO/WKP(2016)70 2 OECD Working Papers should not be reported as representing the official views of the OECD or of its member countries.

Unclassified ECO/WKP(2016)70 Organisation de Coopération et de Développement Économiques Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development 22-Nov-2016

___________________________________________________________________________________________

_____________ English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT

PUBLIC FINANCE, ECONOMIC GROWTH AND INEQUALITY:

A SURVEY OF THE EVIDENCE

ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT WORKING PAPER No. 1346

By Åsa Johansson

OECD Working Papers should not be reported as representing the official views of the OECD or of its member

countries. The opinions expressed and arguments employed are those of the author(s).

Authorised for publication by Jean-Luc Schneider, Deputy Director, Policy Studies Branch, Economics

Department.

All Economics Department Working Papers are available at www.oecd.org/eco/workingpapers

JT03405922

Complete document available on OLIS in its original format

This document and any map included herein are without prejudice to the status of or sovereignty over any territory, to the delimitation of

international frontiers and boundaries and to the name of any territory, city or area.

EC

O/W

KP

(20

16)7

0

Un

classified

En

glish

- Or. E

ng

lish

Page 2: Unclassified ECO/WKP(2016)70 - OECD€¦ · ECO/WKP(2016)70 2 OECD Working Papers should not be reported as representing the official views of the OECD or of its member countries.

ECO/WKP(2016)70

2

OECD Working Papers should not be reported as representing the official views of the OECD or of its member countries. The opinions expressed and arguments employed are those of the author(s).

Working Papers describe preliminary results or research in progress by the author(s) and are published to stimulate discussion on a broad range of issues on which the OECD works.

Comments on Working Papers are welcomed, and may be sent to OECD Economics Department, 2 rue André Pascal, 75775 Paris Cedex 16, France, or by e-mail to [email protected].

All Economics Department Working Papers are available at www.oecd.org/eco/workingpapers. This paper is part of an OECD project on the quality of public finance. Other outputs from this project include:

Fournier, J.M. and Å. Johansson (2016), “The Effect of the Size and the Mix of Public Spending on Growth and Inequality”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 1344, OECD Publishing.

Fournier, J.M. (2016), “The Positive Effect of Public Investment on Potential Growth”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 1347, OECD Publishing.

Bloch, D., J.M. Fournier, D. Gonzales and A. Pina (2016), “Trends in Public Finances: Insights from a New Detailed Dataset”, OECD Economic Department Working Papers, No. 1345, OECD Publishing.

This document and any map included herein are without prejudice to the status of or sovereignty over any territory, to the delimitation of international frontiers and boundaries and to the name of any territory, city or area. The statistical data for Israel are supplied by and under the responsibility of the relevant Israeli authorities. The use of such data by the OECD is without prejudice to the status of the Golan Heights, East Jerusalem and Israeli settlements in the West Bank under the terms of international law. Latvia was not an OECD Member at the time of preparation of this publication. Accordingly, Latvia does not appear in the list of OECD Members and is not included in the zone aggregates. © OECD (2016)

You can copy, download or print OECD content for your own use, and you can include excerpts from OECD publications, databases and multimedia products in your own documents, presentations, blogs, websites and teaching materials, provided that suitable acknowledgment of OECD as source and copyright owner is given. All requests for commercial use and translation rights should be submitted to [email protected]

Page 3: Unclassified ECO/WKP(2016)70 - OECD€¦ · ECO/WKP(2016)70 2 OECD Working Papers should not be reported as representing the official views of the OECD or of its member countries.

ECO/WKP(2016)70

3

ABSTRACT/RÉSUMÉ

Public finance, economic growth and inequality: A survey of the evidence

This paper reviews the key issues concerning the impact of public spending and taxation on long-run

growth and inequality and takes stock of existing theoretical and empirical studies. Overall, the evidence

highlights that the size of the government matters for long-term growth as a too large government may

undermine growth through the cost of financing public spending. A reallocation of public spending

towards infrastructure and education would raise income in the long run, whereas increasing social welfare

spending can reduce inequality as such spending increases redistribution and risk sharing. Similarly, the

available evidence also supports the hypothesis that some taxes are more distortionary than others, with

income taxes found to be more harmful for growth than consumption and property taxes. However, a tax

shift from income towards consumption taxes has equity implications, since income taxes are generally

more progressive than other taxes. The effect of a reallocation of spending and taxes on growth and

inequality likely varies across countries depending on country characteristics.

JEL classification: D31; H11; H20; H21; H30; H50; O40; O43

Keywords: Public spending, taxation, fiscal policy, economic growth, income inequality

*****

Finances publiques, croissance économique et inégalités: Une revue de littérature

Ce rapport examine les principales questions liées à l’impact des dépenses publiques et de la fiscalité sur la

croissance à long terme et les inégalités, et fait le point sur les études théoriques et empiriques déjà

publiées. Il ressort de ces publications que la taille du secteur public exerce une influence sur la croissance

à long terme, dans la mesure où un secteur public trop important peut freiner la croissance en raison de la

charge financière qu’il représente. La réaffectation des dépenses publiques au financement des

infrastructures et de l’éducation peut avoir un effet bénéfique sur le revenu à long terme, tandis que

l’augmentation des dépenses allouées à la protection sociale peut contribuer à résorber les inégalités en

favorisant la redistribution et la mutualisation des risques. Ces études corroborent en outre l’hypothèse

selon laquelle certains impôts génèrent davantage de distorsions que d’autres : il est ainsi attesté que les

impôts sur le revenu pèsent davantage sur la croissance que les impôts sur la consommation ou la

propriété. Néanmoins, un transfert de la charge fiscale du revenu vers la consommation a des implications

en termes d’équité, étant donné que les impôts sur le revenu sont généralement plus progressifs que les

autres. Les conséquences qu’aurait, sur la croissance et les inégalités, une réaffectation des dépenses et des

impôts varient selon les pays, en fonction des caractéristiques de chacun.

Classification JEL : D31 ; H11 ; H20 ; H21 ; H30 ; H50 ; O40 ; O43

Mots clés : dépenses publiques, fiscalité, politique budgétaire, politique fiscale, inégalités de revenu

Page 4: Unclassified ECO/WKP(2016)70 - OECD€¦ · ECO/WKP(2016)70 2 OECD Working Papers should not be reported as representing the official views of the OECD or of its member countries.

ECO/WKP(2016)70

4

TABLE OF CONTENTS

1. Introduction .............................................................................................................................................. 5 2. The size of the government ...................................................................................................................... 6

2.1. Evidence on the link between the size of the government and growth ............................................. 7 2.2. Optimal size of the government ........................................................................................................ 8

3. Composition of spending ......................................................................................................................... 8 3.1. Evidence on the role of the composition of spending for growth and inequality .............................. 8 3.2. Spending instruments, drivers of growth and inequality ................................................................. 11

4. Composition of taxes ............................................................................................................................. 16 4.1. Evidence on the role of the tax structure for growth and inequality ............................................... 18 4.2. Tax instruments, drivers of growth and inequality .......................................................................... 19

5. Fiscal policy environment ...................................................................................................................... 23 5.1. Regulatory and judiciary environment ............................................................................................ 23 5.2. Budget practices .............................................................................................................................. 23 5.3. Fiscal councils ................................................................................................................................. 24 5.4. Fiscal decentralisation ..................................................................................................................... 25

REFERENCES .............................................................................................................................................. 26

Figures

1. Public finance and growth ....................................................................................................................... 6 2. Potential output efficiency gains in OECD countries ............................................................................ 10 3. Redistribution in the tax and transfer system ......................................................................................... 15 4. Flatness of the tax system ...................................................................................................................... 16 5. Top personal income tax rate ................................................................................................................. 17 6. Income tax progressivity ........................................................................................................................ 17 7. VAT revenue ratio ................................................................................................................................. 18 8. Statutory corporate tax rate .................................................................................................................... 18

Boxes

Box 1. Estimates of public spending efficiency ........................................................................................... 9 Box 2. Redistribution due to fiscal instruments ......................................................................................... 15 Box 3. Tax policy design: Insights from tax theory ................................................................................... 16

Page 5: Unclassified ECO/WKP(2016)70 - OECD€¦ · ECO/WKP(2016)70 2 OECD Working Papers should not be reported as representing the official views of the OECD or of its member countries.

ECO/WKP(2016)70

5

PUBLIC FINANCE, ECONOMIC GROWTH AND INEQUALITY:

A SURVEY OF THE EVIDENCE

Åsa Johansson1

1. Introduction

1. In most countries a key policy concern is to sustain long-term economic growth, while at the

same time addressing redistributive concerns and ensuring that the debt path is sustainable. To achieve

these outcomes, public resources should be spent in an efficient and equitable way and tax revenues should

be collected in a way that minimises the cost of distortions to the functioning of labour, product and

financial markets. The effect of public spending on long-run growth and inequality likely differs with the

type and the effectiveness of spending. Likewise, all taxes are not equivalent in terms of their effects upon

growth and some combination of taxes may be more redistributive than others. This underlines the

importance of understanding how public spending and tax systems could best be designed to promote

economic growth and well-being. Indeed, improving the quality of the public finances is a key policy issue

for many governments. This paper provides an overview of the current knowledge of the key links between

public finance, long-run growth and inequality. It also reviews the existing empirical evidence on these

links.

2. Public finance influences growth and inequality through several channels (Figure 1):

The size of the government sector can influence long-run growth as a too large government

may undermine growth through the cost of financing public spending. Moreover, if public

investment and production are less productive than that of the business sector, large governments

may undermine growth. However, also a too small government can be detrimental for growth due

to a failure of providing basic functions necessary for economic development. Taxes influence

households and firms’ incentives to undertake various economic activities such as investment in

human and physical capital, savings and labour supply. Taxes are crucial for raising revenues to

finance public expenditure on transfers, health and education, which can favour low-income

households.

The composition and efficiency of government spending can support long-run growth when

spending is oriented towards increasing investment in physical and human capital, R&D or

infrastructure, particularly where market failures lead to under-investment by the private sector.

Social spending mainly has a redistributive and risk sharing purpose and can reduce inequality.

When markets fail to provide adequate insurance for individuals, it can also be efficiency

enhancing. For example, spending on active labour market policies and childcare can boost

employment of certain groups.

1. Åsa Johansson works at the OECD Economics Department. The author would like to thank Economics

Department colleagues Debbie Bloch, Jean-Marc Fournier, Peter Hoeller, Christian Kastrop and Jean-Luc

Schneider for their valuable comments and suggestions and Celia Rutkoski for excellent editorial support.

She also thanks Bert Brys from the Centre for Tax Policy and Administration for his comments and

suggestions. The paper has also benefitted from comments by members of Working Party No. 1 of the

OECD Economic Policy Committee.

Page 6: Unclassified ECO/WKP(2016)70 - OECD€¦ · ECO/WKP(2016)70 2 OECD Working Papers should not be reported as representing the official views of the OECD or of its member countries.

ECO/WKP(2016)70

6

The composition and design of the tax system can support growth as some tax mixes and tax

designs are more conducive to growth than others. Though most taxes have disincentive effects,

taxes that reduce incentives to invest in human and physical capital appear particularly damaging

as they can undermine long-run productivity growth. More progressive tax systems make the

post-tax income distribution more equal. However, it is the tax and transfer system in

combination that is an important determinant of the distribution of disposable income.

The fiscal framework can support growth to the extent that it can help achieve sound and

sustainable public finances and play a role in macroeconomic stabilisation. Well-designed fiscal

frameworks are typically associated with better budgetary outcomes in terms of deficit and debt

developments, allowing for fiscal stimulus in downturns. Transparency and accountability in the

budget process can also build citizens’ trust in the government and increase the efficiency and

effectiveness of government policies (OECD, 2015f).

Figure 1. Public finance and growth

2. The size of the government

3. Economic theory stresses the role of government spending and taxation as a driver of growth (see

e.g. Barro and Sala-i-Martin, 1992; Tanzi and Schuknecht, 1997 and Myles 2009a for overviews). In

neoclassical growth models, government spending and taxation affect the level of output through the

saving rate, without affecting the economy’s long-run growth rate (Solow, 1956 and Swan, 1956).

Nonetheless, the temporary growth effects of government policy changes may last for several years as the

economy adjusts to its new steady state. By contrast, in endogenous growth models, without diminishing

returns to capital, government activity has permanent growth effects via its effect on technology

(e.g. Romer, 1986; Lucas, 1988). This implies that the distortionary growth effects of taxes are eventually

greater in endogenous than in neoclassical growth models. On the other hand, the potential growth gains

Composition of taxes

Section 4

Long-run growth and inequality

Composition of spending Section 3

Fiscal en

viron

me

nt –> Sectio

n 5- Labour utilisation - Productivity

- Investment in education - Private investment- Savings

Size of government Section 2

Channels through which spending and taxes affect growth

Fiscal instruments

- Public investment - Health- Education- Social protection

- Corporate taxes- Personal taxes- Consumption taxes- Property taxes

Page 7: Unclassified ECO/WKP(2016)70 - OECD€¦ · ECO/WKP(2016)70 2 OECD Working Papers should not be reported as representing the official views of the OECD or of its member countries.

ECO/WKP(2016)70

7

from productive government spending are also larger in endogenous growth models (Barro, 1990). Thus,

the negative growth effects of higher distortive taxes may be off-set by government spending on education,

R&D and health care, which can lead to higher long-term growth by affecting technical progress.

4. In standard Keynesian models, a short-term fiscal stimulus, either via a tax cut or increased

government spending, increases total demand and output via multiplier effects. For instance, additional

government spending on investment generates an increase in the demand for firms’ products and, as a

result, increases firms’ production and employment. In turn, higher employment increases households’

income and consumption.

2.1. Evidence on the link between the size of the government and growth

5. There is a vast empirical literature investigating the relationship between the size of the

government and economic growth (see Slemrod, 1995; Myles, 2009b; Bergh and Henrekson, 2011 for

overviews). Generally, the empirical studies in this area suffer from methodological problems, mainly due

to endogeneity and reverse causality, making it difficult to draw clear conclusions.2 Another limitation is

that in practice it is difficult to distinguish the effect of public policies on the level of GDP from that on

growth rates. This is because policies that raise the long-run level of output will raise the growth rate since

effects on GDP levels take time to materialise.

6. Most of the early cross-country studies found a negative link between government size (measured

as the ratio of public expenditure or tax revenues to GDP) and economic growth (see e.g. Landau, 1983;

Barro, 1990 and Slemrod, 1995 for an overview). However, most of these studies did not control, or only

included a few controls, for other factors affecting growth besides the size of the government. Indeed, the

inclusion of additional control variables in the empirical specification has been shown to wipe out this bi-

variate link (e.g. Levine and Renelt, 1992; Easterly and Rebelo, 1993; Agell et al., 2007). Recent studies,

exploiting cross-country panel data and including a wider range of control variables, provide better insights

on the link between the size of the government and growth. A review by Bergh and Henrekson (2011),

based on papers published in peer reviewed journals after 2000, suggested a negative relationship in OECD

countries. Likewise, a recent OECD study also found a negative relationship between the size of

government and GDP growth in a sample of OECD countries (Fall and Fournier, 2015).

7. Yet, it is important to keep in mind that a negative correlation does not imply causality. In the

short-run, reflecting automatic stabilisers, a negative correlation between government spending and growth

is expected. For instance, in upturns government spending on unemployment benefits will be lower, while

the opposite is the case in downturns.3 Besides, complementarities may exist between the size of

government and other policies and institutions, affecting this relationship. For instance, Freeman (1995)

showed that in Sweden the mix of growth-friendly structural policies with a high level of trust in public

institutions may have off-set the adverse growth effect of a large government sector.

2. The lack of good instruments for government size implies that it is difficult to settle the issue of causality.

3. The reverse causality bias works in the opposite direction for taxes, with higher growth leading to higher

tax revenues leading to a positive correlation.

Page 8: Unclassified ECO/WKP(2016)70 - OECD€¦ · ECO/WKP(2016)70 2 OECD Working Papers should not be reported as representing the official views of the OECD or of its member countries.

ECO/WKP(2016)70

8

2.2. Optimal size of the government

8. The direction of the link between the size of the government and growth may vary with the

income level and could be hump-shaped (Armey, 1995). At low levels of income, there is a positive

association between government size and growth, if the government is successful in collecting taxes and

providing the basic functions necessary for economic growth such as protecting property rights and

enforcing the rule of law (Slemrod, 1995; Bergh and Henrekson, 2011). Moreover, when such a minimal

government expands its activities to provide infrastructure, health care and education, the effect on growth

is likely positive. If government spending is characterised by diminishing returns, at some level of

spending the negative effect of taxes will dominate the positive effect of increased productive spending. In

addition, the distortive effects of taxation may increase with the level of taxation. In fact, increasing tax

rates beyond a certain point can even become counter-productive for raising tax revenue further (i.e. so-

called Laffer curve).

9. A number of studies have focused on the non-linear relation between the size of the government

and growth. The results are mixed. Some studies support the hypothesis of an inverted U-shaped relation in

selected countries (e.g. Vedder and Gallaway (1998) for the United States, Canada, Denmark, Italy,

Sweden and the United Kingdom; Pevcin (2004) for eight European countries). The existence of a non-

linear relationship allows calculating the optimal size of government. A number of studies have done so,

with varying estimates depending on the estimation approach, time period and country coverage. For

instance, Vedder and Gallaway (1998) estimated that the optimal size of federal government spending in

the United States over 1947-1997 was about 17% of GDP. Pevcin (2004) found that the level of

government spending was on average 19% above the optimal level of spending in eight European countries

(i.e. Italy, France, Finland, Sweden, Germany, Ireland, Netherlands and Belgium). Chobanova and

Mladenova (2009) estimated that the growth maximising size of government spending as share of GDP

was 25% in a sample of 29 OECD countries over 1970-2007.

3. Composition of spending

10. Public finance theory provides no clear guidance on the optimal allocation of spending across

various expenditure items. In public finance theory, public expenditure and the production of public goods

are often justified on the basis of the existence of market failures, inefficiencies and redistributive

concerns. Public expenditure that addresses market failures and externalities can be growth enhancing. In

theory, for instance, investment in public infrastructure and provision of funding for liquidity-constrained

households to invest in human capital can raise labour and capital productivity. Public expenditure aimed

at creating social safety nets, particularly where the market fails to provide for them or when the

government is more efficient in providing them, and redistributive expenditure can be equity enhancing. In

practice, the effect on growth and inequality depends on the effectiveness of government interventions in

addressing market failures and achieving the desired outcomes.

3.1. Evidence on the role of the composition of spending for growth and inequality

11. The empirical literature has identified a role for the composition and the efficiency of

government spending for long-run growth (e.g. Kneller et al., 1999; Gemmel et al., 2011; Cournède et al.,

2013). In this strand of research, government spending is classified into productive and non-productive,

depending on whether they are included in the production function or not (see Barro, 1990). In practice,

existing empirical studies generally focused on the impact of main expenditure items such as public

investment, categories of public consumption and social welfare or redistributive spending on growth.

12. In the earlier empirical literature, there was a widespread non-robust impact of various spending

items on growth (Kneller et al., 1999; Levine and Renelt, 1992). This non-robustness may in part reflect

Page 9: Unclassified ECO/WKP(2016)70 - OECD€¦ · ECO/WKP(2016)70 2 OECD Working Papers should not be reported as representing the official views of the OECD or of its member countries.

ECO/WKP(2016)70

9

that most studies focused on a certain spending item while leaving others aside, without considering the

linear restriction implied by the government’s budget constraint (Kneller et al., 1999).4 In more recent

empirical studies, which explicitly consider the government's budget constraint, the findings tend to be

more robust. For instance, Teles and Mussolini (2014) found in a sample of developing and developed

countries, that productive spending affects economic growth positively, though this impact declines as

public debt increases. Gemmell et al. (2014) focused on the long-run GDP impact of changes in total

government spending and in the shares of different spending categories in OECD countries. Their results

implied that reallocating total spending towards infrastructure and education would raise income in the

long run. Increasing the share of social welfare spending was associated with modestly lower long-run

GDP levels. The effect of a reallocation of spending on growth and inequality likely varies across countries

depending on their initial level and mix of spending.

13. Thus, a reallocation of public expenditure towards certain spending items is one strategy to

improve the quality of public finance. However, a reallocation towards infrastructure away from social

protection spending may have adverse redistributive consequences as cash transfers reduce income

dispersion more than taxes in most OECD countries (Joumard et al., 2012). The magnitude of this trade-off

is not clear. As mentioned, Gemmell et al. (2014) found that such a reallocation of spending may not

induce sizeable growth effects. However, more research is needed to better understand the effect of a

change in the detailed composition of social expenditure on growth and inequality. In any case, efficiency

gains are likely to be large from a more efficient use of public resources, including improving the quality

of spending, and money saved could be used for cutting distortive taxes or raising growth-enhancing and

redistributive spending (Box 1).

Box 1. Estimates of public spending efficiency

Data Envelopment Analysis (DEA) is one method for evaluating the efficiency of public expenditure. The idea is to evaluate the relative efficiency with which inputs are turned into an output or outcome by comparing a country’s outcome in an area of public policy with that of the best performing countries. A country’s relative distance to the DEA-estimated frontier is interpreted as a measure of achievable efficiency gains. Results from DEA analysis should be interpreted with caution as the estimates are sensitive to the composition and size of the sample, the choice of input and output variables as well as to the statistical package used. In particular, the DEA-estimated frontier is only driven by the observations that are close to the frontier, and hence by a small part of the sample. In addition, cost efficiency analysis should be interpreted with care when there are sizeable relative price differences that contribute to the apparent efficiency. Even so, DEA estimates can give an indication of a country’s performance relative to other countries.

A recent OECD study updated previous OECD efficiency estimates for health care, secondary education and general administration (Dutu and Sicari, 2016). The results show significant potential efficiency gains in a number of countries (Figure 2). In some cases the potential gains appear very large and they should be interpreted with caution.

4. Not controlling for the government’s budget constraint will yield biased estimates due to misspecification

of the model.

Page 10: Unclassified ECO/WKP(2016)70 - OECD€¦ · ECO/WKP(2016)70 2 OECD Working Papers should not be reported as representing the official views of the OECD or of its member countries.

ECO/WKP(2016)70

10

Box 1. Estimates of public spending efficiency (cont.)

Figure 2. Potential output efficiency gains in OECD countries

A: Health care, %

B: Secondary education, %

C: General public administration, %

Note: Panel A shows that in Hungary life expectancy could be increased by about 7% if Hungary were to match the best performing countries with similar levels of spending. Panel B shows that in Slovakia on average PISA scores could be raised by 12% if Slovakia were to match the best performing countries with similar levels of spending. Panel C shows that in Slovakia public administration performance (measured by a composite indicator) could be increased by about 45% if Slovakia were to match the best performing countries with similar levels of spending. Life expectancy is life expectancy at birth. Secondary education is the mean PISA score of reading literacy, mathematics and science. General public administration is a composite index aggregating (with equal weights) indicators on the quality of justice, the pervasiveness of corruption, government inefficiency and bureaucracy and product market regulation.

Source: Dutu R. and P. Sicari (2016), “Public Spending Efficiency in the OECD: Benchmarking Health Care, Education and General Administration”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 1278, OECD Publishing, Paris.

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

JPN

ISL

CH

E

KOR

ISR

ITA

FRA

AUS

NZL

SWE

TUR

ESP

MEX CH

L

NO

R

LUX

CAN

GR

C

NLD

OEC

D

PRT

AUT

DEU IR

L

SVN

GBR FI

N

BEL

POL

CZE

DN

K

EST

USA SV

K

HU

N

2012 2007

Potential gains in life expectancy

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

KOR

JPN

EST

FIN

PRT

CAN

POL

NLD

CHE

IRL

DEU

MEX NZ

L

AUS

BEL

OEC

D

CZE

GBR

DNK

ESP

NOR

SVN

FRA

CHL

USA

ISL

LUX

ITA

ISR

SWE

SVK

2012 2009

Potential gains in synthetic PISA scores

0

10

20

30

40

50

0

10

20

30

40

50

CH

E

NLD

GB

R

JPN

DE

U

NO

R

FIN

ES

T

SW

E

LUX

ISR

ISL

TUR

IRL

FRA

DN

K

OE

CD

PR

T

PO

L

AU

T

BE

L

HU

N

US

A

SV

N

CZE

KO

R

ES

P

GR

C

ITA

SV

K

2012 2007

Potential gains in efficiency scores of the performance indicator

Page 11: Unclassified ECO/WKP(2016)70 - OECD€¦ · ECO/WKP(2016)70 2 OECD Working Papers should not be reported as representing the official views of the OECD or of its member countries.

ECO/WKP(2016)70

11

3.2. Spending instruments, drivers of growth and inequality

14. Public spending influences growth and the distribution of income via a number of channels

including the accumulation of physical and human capital, innovation and health. A large number of

empirical studies have focused on the impact of specific spending items on various drivers of long-term

growth and inequality. This section summarises the key findings of this literature.

Public investment

15. Public investment is an important driver of economic growth (IMF, 2015). Investment in

infrastructure, education and innovative activities adds to a country’s capital stock, which enhances the

economy’s long-run productivity growth (Romp and de Haan, 2007). There is a large literature estimating

the effects of public investment on long-term growth (e.g. Straub, 2011; Romp and de Haan, 2007 for

overviews). A recent meta-analysis by Bom and Ligthart (2014) found that the impact of public investment

on economic activity is positive. Some studies showed that public investment may have non-linear effects

with stronger growth effects at lower levels of provision (e.g. Sutherland et al., 2009). Moreover, the effect

of public investment may vary with the type of investment, with some (e.g. R&D) being more likely to

promote economic activity than others (BIS, 2015; Guellec and van Pottelsberghe, 2003).

16. Interactions between public investment and fiscal institutions may exist, affecting the return on

public investment and, in turn, its impact on economic activity. Institutions that are transparent, stable,

enforce property rights and establish trust in governments may affect the effectiveness of investment. For

instance, Agenor (2010) showed that in countries with weak public investment management processes,

public investment is unlikely to fully translate into growth effects. A recent IMF study also found that

better public investment management practices enhance public infrastructure quality and economic growth,

particularly in emerging and lower-income economies (IMF, 2015). Bergh et al. (2015) highlighted that

countries with weak institutions also often have a low capital stock. This implies that the returns to

additional capital can be high in these countries even though they have weak institutions.

17. Public investment can also affect growth by influencing business investment. In this context,

growth theory suggests that more public investment could either increase or decrease private investment

(Aschauer, 1989; BIS, 2015). Public spending, such as on infrastructure and research could generate

positive spillovers and complementarities that induce the private sector to invest more. Conversely, public

investment could simply be a substitute for private investment. It could also lower the rate of return on

private investment, and thereby reduce business investment. The large empirical literature on the effect of

public investment on private fixed investment is mixed (e.g. Sen and Kaya, 2013; Erden and Holcombe,

2005).

Fiscal incentives and productivity

18. The findings in the empirical literature suggest that fiscal incentives to R&D boost private R&D

expenditure. Ultimately, it is important that they raise productivity growth (Andrews and Criscuolo, 2013).

Fiscal R&D incentives could be expected a priori to have positive effects on productivity growth, since

they induce additional business R&D and such investment has important effects on productivity growth

(Westmore, 2013). However, empirical evidence on the impact of fiscal R&D incentives on productivity

growth is not clear-cut (Brouwer et al., 2005; Lokshin and Mohnen, 2007; Westmore, 2013). The failure to

find an effect on productivity growth could reflect several factors. For instance, projects financed by fiscal

incentives could have a lower return than other projects, they could lead to duplication or re-labelling of

existing non-R&D activities and measurement and identification issues exist (Andrews and Criscuolo,

2013).

Page 12: Unclassified ECO/WKP(2016)70 - OECD€¦ · ECO/WKP(2016)70 2 OECD Working Papers should not be reported as representing the official views of the OECD or of its member countries.

ECO/WKP(2016)70

12

19. Part of the observed rise in wage inequality in past decades reflects an increasing dispersion in

average wages paid across firms (Song et al., 2015; Card et al., 2013). One possible explanation for this

phenomenon is growing productivity differentials across firms. Research also shows that one source of the

productivity slowdown over the past decades is the slowing of the pace at which innovations spread

throughout the economy (OECD, 2015a; Comin and Mestieri, 2013). Taken together this suggests that

improving productivity performance of less-productive firms could reduce wage inequality. Stronger

competition can enable the diffusion of existing technologies to laggards, raising their productivity. A

fiscal environment that does not maintain inefficient business structures such as poorly managed family

businesses via inheritance tax exemptions may also improve productivity (OECD, 2015a).

Education spending and student performance

20. Public spending represents on average more than 80% of total spending on education in OECD

countries (OECD, 2012). Private spending is more prevalent at the pre-primary and the tertiary education

level. The justification of government funding of education is based on the presence of market failures in

the provision of education. Specifically, if the public benefits of education are greater than the private

benefits, markets alone may fail to provide an adequate amount of education. The case for public funding

is less strong for tertiary education where individual relative to societal returns tend to be the highest.

21. Economic theory has put forward several channels through which education may affect economic

growth. First, education increases the human capital of the labour force, which increases labour

productivity and growth (Mankiw et al., 1992). Second, education may increase the innovative capacity of

the economy (e.g. Lucas 1988; Romer 1990; Aghion and Howitt, 1992). Third, education may facilitate the

diffusion of knowledge and the adoption of new technologies, which promotes economic growth

(Benhabib and Spiegel, 2005).

22. In the empirical literature, a controversy has emerged whether it is the level of education (often

proxied by years of schooling) or the change in education that drives growth. Earlier studies found a

positive effect of schooling levels, but not of changes. Later studies suggest that both the level and change

in the years of schooling are positively associated with growth (e.g. de la Fuente and Doménech, 2006;

Cohen and Soto, 2007; Hanushek and Woessmann, 2012 for an overview). More recently, Hanushek and

Woessmann (2012) showed that students’ cognitive skills (measured by test scores) are positively

associated with growth. Even though theory and evidence support a link between education and growth,

the evidence of the role of schooling inputs such as resources, class size and teacher pay for student

achievement is less clear (e.g. Hanushek, 1986; Card and Krueger, 1992). Indeed, research tends to show a

weak relationship between the amount of educational spending and student performance (e.g. PISA scores)

(Hanushek and Woessmann, 2011). Instead, research points to the importance of the quality of resources

and how these resources are used (OECD, 2013a).

23. Education is a key transmission mechanism in generating intergenerational social mobility,

promoting the matching of skills with needs and changing patterns of inequality (OECD, 2015b; Causa and

Johansson, 2009). Equity in education is crucial in order to ensure that all students reach a basic level of

skills regardless of their family background or socio-economic circumstances. Recent research has found

that investing in early childhood education yields high returns as it makes it easier to acquire skills and

knowledge later on, particularly for children from disadvantaged backgrounds (OECD, 2014; Heckman,

2011; Cuhna et al., 2010; Woessman, 2008). Financial constraints that hamper access to higher education

are likely to be more important for children from low-income backgrounds. There is suggestive evidence

that universal government-supported loan systems can reduce liquidity constraints, thereby enhancing the

equality of access, while maintaining incentives for swift and successful study completion (Oliveira

Martins et al., 2007).

Page 13: Unclassified ECO/WKP(2016)70 - OECD€¦ · ECO/WKP(2016)70 2 OECD Working Papers should not be reported as representing the official views of the OECD or of its member countries.

ECO/WKP(2016)70

13

24. From an equity perspective, greater cost-recovery of public spending should be sought at higher

levels of education as the private returns are high. However, this may come at the expense of equitable

access for post-secondary and tertiary education among poorer households (OECD, 2002). Thus, the

allocation of limited educational resources at different levels of education entails a non-trivial trade-off

between efficiency and equity (OECD, 2008).

Health spending and health outcomes

25. Health can affect economic growth in a similar way as education by affecting the quality of

labour. Healthier workers are more productive and are less likely to be absent due to illness. Improvements

in health status also increase the incentive to acquire education since these investments can be amortised

over a longer working life. Physical capital per worker may also rise because the increase in labour input

from healthier workers will increase capital’s marginal product (Bloom et al., 2004; Weil, 2007). The

empirical literature, estimating the contribution of health to economic growth, usually relies on health

outcomes (e.g. life expectancy, mortality etc.) rather than health inputs. The consensus stemming from this

research is that the population’s health status is significantly associated with economic growth, although

causality is unclear (Swift, 2011; Acemoglu and Johnson 2007; Bloom et al., 2004 for a survey). Turning

to the link between spending and health outcomes (e.g. life expectancy, mortality), the empirical evidence

is so far inconclusive about the strength of the link between health care spending and health outcomes

(Martin et al., 2008; Joumard et al., 2010). This is partly because other factors such as life-style, diet and

environment are perceived as key factors determining health outcomes.

26. All OECD countries use a mix of private and public financing of health care. On average across

the OECD almost three-quarters of total spending comes from public sources (OECD, 2015e). Even in

countries where the public sector plays a key role in financing, the provision of healthcare varies in terms

of the mix of public and private providers. Health care systems also vary in the extent that they steer the

demand and the supply via market mechanisms (e.g. fee-for services, private insurances etc.) or via public

command and control (OECD, 2010). On balance, research has shown that no health care system performs

systematically better in delivering cost-effective health care. Rather it is how the system is managed that

matters for effective outcomes (Joumard et al., 2010).

27. Equity in health care can promote income growth and a more equal income distribution. Low-

income households tend to consume less health and preventive care and their life expectancy and perceived

health status is lower than that of high-income households. Differences in health status reflect many

factors, including living and working conditions as well as life style factors. Low-income households may

also have more limited access to certain health services or use these services less for financial reasons,

notably certain preventive services (OECD, 2013c). Equity in health care access can contribute to

improvements in health status and life expectancy for low-income households. In turn, this can raise these

households’ productivity and employment opportunities and thereby underpin inclusive growth.

Social protection and labour utilisation

28. Social protection expenditure affects growth in various ways. Social protection spending can

raise growth. This can be the case when it provides liquidity-constrained households with funding to invest

in education or when it creates a social safety net where the market fails to provide efficiently for it

(Hubbard and Judd, 1987; Imrohoroglu et al., 1995). However, social protection may affect growth

adversely. It can discourage individuals from working (e.g. OECD, 2011d) and can reduce household

saving which may reduce the amount of capital available for investment.

29. There is a vast empirical literature investigating the effect of various social spending items on the

drivers of growth (Morgan and Mourougane, 2003 for an overview). A particular focus has been on

Page 14: Unclassified ECO/WKP(2016)70 - OECD€¦ · ECO/WKP(2016)70 2 OECD Working Papers should not be reported as representing the official views of the OECD or of its member countries.

ECO/WKP(2016)70

14

exploring the effect of unemployment benefits and spending on active labour market policies on labour

utilisation. A consistent finding in this literature is that too generous unemployment benefits increase

aggregate unemployment and reduce employment prospects (OECD, 2006; Flaig and Rothman, 2011;

Murtin and de Serres, 2014). By contrast, spending on certain active labour market programmes (ALMPs),

such as well-designed labour market training and private sector incentive programmes, can improve re-

employment chances and is associated with lower unemployment (Kluve, 2010). Interactions between

policies may exist. Bassanini and Duval (2006) found that the adverse impact of unemployment benefits on

unemployment was mitigated by high public spending on ALMPs, possibly because high spending on

ALMPs is accompanied with an emphasis on activation. Research on the effects of early retirement

incentives embedded in pensions systems and other social transfer programmes suggests that a high

implicit tax on continued work deters older workers from continuing to work beyond certain ages

(Bassanini and Duval, 2006; Duval et al., 2011).

30. Social spending mainly has redistributive and risk sharing purposes. Apart from affecting

households’ income directly, labour market institutions (e.g. unemployment benefits and active labour

market policies) can affect the distribution of income via their impact on employment. There is a growing

empirical literature investigating the effects of various social spending items on measures of inequality

(i.e. labour earnings or disposable income inequality). The findings of this literature are mixed. For

instance, some empirical studies have found support for the inequality reducing effect of unemployment

benefits (Koeniger et al., 2007; Causa et al., 2015 for unemployment benefits to the long-term

unemployed), while others have not. There is also some evidence that when active labour market

programmes increase jobseekers’ employment chances and wages once in employment, they reduce

income inequality (Salverda and Checchi, 2014; Causa et al., 2015). Some research also suggests that

public employment can have an inequality-reducing effect (Alesina et al., 2000; Fournier and Koske,

2012). However, other research has found that direct job creation measures typically provide few long-run

benefits for the claimants and society (Martin, 2000). In any case, the overall redistributive effect of the

public finances depends on the combined effect of transfers, taxes and in-kind benefits (Box 2).

Page 15: Unclassified ECO/WKP(2016)70 - OECD€¦ · ECO/WKP(2016)70 2 OECD Working Papers should not be reported as representing the official views of the OECD or of its member countries.

ECO/WKP(2016)70

15

Box 2. Redistribution due to fiscal instruments

Redistribution due to taxes and transfers varies across countries (Figure 3). In some countries disposable income inequality (measured by the Gini coefficient) is nearly halved as compared to market income inequality (e.g. Ireland, Slovenia, Belgium and Finland). In other countries, redistribution via taxes and transfers is limited (e.g. Mexico, Korea and Turkey). In most countries the bulk of redistribution occurs via transfers. On average in the OECD, about three-quarters of the reduction in inequality between market and disposable income are due to transfers. These estimates of redistribution do not factor in in-kind benefits via publicly provided services (e.g. education, health etc.), which are often sizeable. Past work showed that publicly provided services reduced income inequality in the late 2000s by between one-fifth and two-thirds depending on how inequality is measured, but country rankings in terms of inequality change little (OECD, 2011a).

Figure 3. Redistribution due to the tax and transfer system

2012

A: Gini coefficient

B: Reduction in the Gini coefficient due to taxes and transfers, %

Note: Panel A shows the Gini coefficient on market income which measures the extent to which the distribution of income among individuals within a country deviates from a perfectly equal distribution. A coefficient of 0 represents perfect equality, while a coefficient of 1 implies perfect inequality. Panel B shows the per cent reduction between the market income and disposable income Gini coefficient as well as the contributions of transfers and taxes to this reduction. Detailed data on the share of redistribution via taxes and transfers is not available for Hungary, Mexico, Turkey, Korea and the United Kingdom.

Source: OECD (2016), "Income distribution", OECD Social and Welfare Statistics (database). DOI: http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/data-00654-en

0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

Gini (market income, before taxes and transfers) Gini (disposable income, post taxes and transfers)

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

Share of redistribution due to transfers Share of redistribution due to taxes%

Page 16: Unclassified ECO/WKP(2016)70 - OECD€¦ · ECO/WKP(2016)70 2 OECD Working Papers should not be reported as representing the official views of the OECD or of its member countries.

ECO/WKP(2016)70

16

4. Composition of taxes

31. Tax systems are primarily aimed at financing public spending. They are also used to promote

equity and to address social and environmental concerns (see Brys et al. 2016 for an overview). In many

countries a favourable tax treatment exists to promote investment in certain assets such as housing and

R&D. Taxes influence households’ decision to save, supply labour and invest in education and housing,

the decisions of firms to produce, create jobs, invest and innovate, as well as the choice of savings channels

and assets by investors. Not only the level of taxes matters for these decisions, but also the design and mix

of different tax instruments. Economic theory suggests that differences in the tax structure may play a role

in explaining differences in economic performance since some tax instruments are more distortionary than

others (Box 3). Likewise, some tax structures and designs are more progressive and redistributive than

others (Joumard et al., 2012).

Box 3. Tax policy design: Insights from tax theory

Tax theory provides a number of insights for tax policy design based on stylised models that focus on the behavioural response of households and firms to taxes (Mankiw et al., 2009 for an overview). In practice, the design of tax systems should also reflect a range of other considerations such as efficiency, equity, tax avoidance and effectiveness of the tax administration. These considerations vary across countries, implying that there is no one-size-fits-all optimal tax system. Generally, a low tax rate with a broad tax base is desirable.

Early studies suggested that a flat income tax where the same marginal tax rate applies at every income level is close to optimal (e.g. Mirrless, 1971; Mankiw et al., 2009). Taking into account broader aspects of tax systems (e.g. complexity, avoidance etc.), other studies have shown that higher rates at low and high incomes may be warranted (Mankiw et al., 2009; Saez, 2001). To gauge the flatness of the

tax system the marginal tax rate at 167% of average earnings is compared to the rate at 67% (Figure 4). According to this measure, the flatness of the tax system has remained broadly unchanged since 2000 in most countries.

Figure 4. Flatness of the tax system

Ratio of the marginal tax rate at 167% to 67% of average earnings

Source: OECD (2015), "Personal Income Tax: Marginal rates and social security contributions (Edition 2015)", OECD Tax Statistics (database). DOI: http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/179a0c55-en

Tax theory is unclear on the optimal top income tax rate. Early studies showed that the income tax rate

could decline at high incomes (Mirrlees, 1971), while the more recent literature found the opposite (Piketty et al., 2014; Saez, 2001). Despite this ambiguity, in several OECD countries the top personal income tax rate declined during the past 15 years, although in a few countries they slightly increased or remained unchanged (Figure 5).

0

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5

2014 2000

Page 17: Unclassified ECO/WKP(2016)70 - OECD€¦ · ECO/WKP(2016)70 2 OECD Working Papers should not be reported as representing the official views of the OECD or of its member countries.

ECO/WKP(2016)70

17

Box 3. Tax policy design: Insights from tax theory (cont.)

Figure 5. Top personal income tax rate

Per cent

Source: OECD (2015), "Personal Income Tax: Marginal rates and social security contributions (Edition 2015)", OECD Tax Statistics (database). DOI: http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/179a0c55-en

The optimal degree of redistribution should increase with wage inequality. On average, the

progressivity of the personal income tax (measured as the income tax rate at 167% of average earnings relative to the one at 67%) has not changed drastically (OECD, 2015d). There is no clear sign that tax systems have become more progressive in countries that experienced a greater increase in wage inequality (measured as the ratio of the wage at the 90

th to the 10

th percentile) than elsewhere (Figure 6).

Figure 6. Income tax progressivity

Note: The change in wage inequality is measured as the difference in the ratio of the wage at the 90

th to the 10

th percentile

between the early 2000s and 2012 (or latest year available). An increase refers to a change in this ratio of greater than 5%; unchanged to a change less than 5% and greater than -5%; and a decrease to a change below -5%.

Source: OECD (2015), "Personal Income Tax: Marginal rates and social security contributions (Edition 2015)", OECD Tax Statistics (database). DOI: http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/179a0c55-en

There are strong arguments for a uniform broad-based tax rate on consumption goods (Diamond and

Mirrless, 1971). A non-uniform rate can be justified for certain price inelastic goods (Ramsey, 1927). Another exception is the case of goods that generate negative externalities. One option of a consumption tax is VAT, which exempts intermediate business inputs through a credit system. Many countries have differentiated consumption taxes due to exemptions and zero ratings on certain goods and services (e.g. groceries, books, tourism etc.) to address inequality. Indeed, the VAT revenue ratio (which captures the effect of exemptions, reduced rates and non-compliance on VAT revenues) is well-below unity in most countries (Figure 7). However, targeted transfers to low-income households are better than VAT exemptions for equity and efficiency (OECD, 2009).

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

2014 2000

Page 18: Unclassified ECO/WKP(2016)70 - OECD€¦ · ECO/WKP(2016)70 2 OECD Working Papers should not be reported as representing the official views of the OECD or of its member countries.

ECO/WKP(2016)70

18

Box 3. Tax policy design: Insights from tax theory (cont.)

Figure 7. VAT revenue ratio

Note: The VAT revenue ratio measures the difference between the VAT revenue actually collected and what would theoretically be raised if VAT applied at the standard rate to the entire potential tax base and all revenue was collected.

Source: OECD (2015), "Revenue Statistics: Comparative tables (Edition 2015)", OECD Tax Statistics (database). DOI: http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/6e3323fd-en

Traditional theory suggested that capital income should not be taxed in the long run (Atkinson and Stiglitz, 1976; Judd, 1985; Chamely, 1986). In recent models, with wage uncertainty and inheritance, a positive capital tax is part of the overall tax mix (Piketty and Saez, 2013; Golosov et al., 2006). One marked trend over the past

decades is a reduction in statutory corporate tax rates (Figure 8). Even though, corporate tax revenue has remained fairly stable as a share of GDP, suggesting that in many countries a broadening of the base has accompanied the cuts in the rate (OECD, 2015c).

Figure 8. Statutory corporate tax rate

Per cent

Source: OECD (2015), "Personal Income Tax: Marginal rates and social security contributions (Edition 2015)", OECD Tax Statistics (database). DOI: http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/179a0c55-en

4.1. Evidence on the role of the tax structure for growth and inequality

32. The empirical literature on the effect of the tax structure on growth is fairly limited in comparison

with the vast number of studies assessing the impact of the size and structure of government spending.

Nonetheless, the findings of the existing empirical studies tend to support the hypothesis that some taxes

0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

1

2011 2003

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

2014 2000

Page 19: Unclassified ECO/WKP(2016)70 - OECD€¦ · ECO/WKP(2016)70 2 OECD Working Papers should not be reported as representing the official views of the OECD or of its member countries.

ECO/WKP(2016)70

19

are more harmful for growth than others. In this research, taxes are classified in broad categories

depending on their a priori theoretical distortionary effect on growth. Corporate and personal income taxes

are considered relatively more distortionary than consumption taxes. An early study by Kneller et al.

(1999) concluded that distortionary taxes reduce growth while non-distortionary taxes do not. One of the

key insights of this study is the importance of controlling for the government’s budget constraint as failing

to do so would yield biased estimates. More recent studies, Gemell et al. (2011) and Gemell et al. (2014)

rely on longer time series data for OECD countries and confirm the earlier findings of Kneller et al. (1999).

33. In line with this research, a past OECD study, based on a standard empirical growth model and

controlling for the government’s budget constraint, found a “tax and growth ranking” of taxes with respect

to their negative effect on GDP per capita in a panel of OECD countries (Arnold et al., 2011). Specifically,

the study suggested the following order from the most to the least harmful tax for growth: 1) corporate

income taxes; 2) personal income taxes; 3) consumption taxes; and 4) recurrent taxes on immovable

property. This ranking implies that replacing part of the revenues from income taxes with revenues from

taxes that have smaller distortionary effects, for a given overall level of the tax burden, could bring

economic gains. Studies focusing on both OECD and non-OECD countries established broadly similar

results. Acosta-Ormaechea and Yoo (2012) confirmed that property and consumption taxes are less

detrimental to growth than income taxes (particularly personal income taxes). Likewise, McNabb and

LeMay-Boucher (2014) found that a tax shift away from income taxes to trade or consumption taxes would

boost GDP growth.

34. However, a tax shift towards consumption or recurrent taxes on immovable property would

reduce the overall progressivity of the tax system as these taxes are less progressive than income taxes. For

example, micro-simulations of a tax shift from the personal income to the value added tax (VAT) confirm

the regressive impact of this shift (e.g. Pestel and Sommer, 2013; Decoster et al., 2011). Some studies have

found that after accounting for labour-supply adjustments, the adverse distributional impact is smaller due

to increased work incentives. Thus, this type of tax shift entails a trade-off between equity and growth,

with the magnitude of this trade-off depending on the level of inequality, behavioural responses and

preferences for redistribution.

4.2. Tax instruments, drivers of growth and inequality

35. The tax structure matters for growth because of the way different taxes affect economic decisions

of individuals and firms. In general, income taxes have larger effects on these decisions than other taxes,

and therefore they create larger welfare losses. A number of empirical studies have investigated the impact

of individual tax instruments on various drivers of growth. The main insights from this research are

summarised in the following section. When possible, this section also highlights the redistributive

implications of different taxes and tax designs.

Corporate income tax: investment and productivity

36. The corporate income tax influences investment and productivity. First, corporate income taxes

discourage firms’ investment by reducing its after-tax return. In a similar way, domestic corporate and

cross-border taxation affect the after-tax return on foreign direct investment (FDI). Existing evidence,

including OECD work, confirms that higher effective corporate tax rates reduce firms’ investment

(e.g. OECD, 2009; Djankov et al., 2010). However, in an increasingly global economy, the sensitivity of

investment to corporate taxes may depend on the possibility to exploit international tax planning. Indeed, a

recent OECD study found that tax planning reduces the effect of corporate taxation on investment of tax-

planning MNEs (OECD, 2015c). There is also a vast literature, including past OECD work, suggesting an

adverse effect of the host country corporate tax rate on foreign investment (Hajkova et al., 2006; Feld and

Heckemeyer, 2011). But corporate taxes are only one among many factors (e.g. labour and product market

Page 20: Unclassified ECO/WKP(2016)70 - OECD€¦ · ECO/WKP(2016)70 2 OECD Working Papers should not be reported as representing the official views of the OECD or of its member countries.

ECO/WKP(2016)70

20

regulation, size of the market, labour taxes, governance and infrastructure etc.) affecting firms’ location

choice. For instance, their influence appears relatively small in comparison with labour taxes (Hajkova

et al., 2006).

37. Second, corporate taxes affect productivity in several ways. High corporate taxes may reduce

incentives to invest in innovative activities, with adverse implications for productivity (OECD, 2009).

Given that corporate taxes reduce FDI and the presence of foreign multinational enterprises they can hinder

technology transfers and knowledge spill-overs to domestic firms. Also, corporate taxes distort corporate

financing decisions, favouring debt over equity since interest payments on debt are generally deductible

from taxable profits, while dividend payments are not (de Mooij, 2011; 2012). This can affect productivity

if it distorts the allocation of investment towards firms that can raise debt easily over those that have to rely

on equity finance, such as knowledge-based innovative firms investing in intangible assets (OECD, 2009).

The empirical literature on the impact of corporate taxes on productivity is fairly limited. Nonetheless, the

few existing studies suggest that corporate taxes adversely affect productivity. Past OECD work found that

lowering statutory corporate tax rates can lead to particularly large productivity gains in firms that are

dynamic and profitable, i.e. those that can make the largest contribution to GDP growth (Arnold et al.,

2011). Similarly, Gemmel et al. (2012) found that corporate taxation reduces productivity growth of small

firms that are furthest from the technological frontier.5

Distributional aspects

38. Many OECD countries have moved away from taxing all types of income at progressive tax rates

(i.e. comprehensive tax systems) to taxing capital income at a proportional and often at a lower rate than

labour income (e.g. dual or semi-dual income tax systems). This change in the taxation of capital income

was in most cases not accompanied by a broadening of the capital income base (Brys et al., 2016). At the

same time, corporate income tax rates have declined and special tax incentives exist in many countries

(e.g. R&D tax credits, exemptions for small firms etc.). In combination, this has decreased the tax burden

on capital and the progressivity of the tax system, particularly since wealthier households own and earn

more income from capital than lower-income households.

39. In any case, the distributional effect of corporate taxes depends on who bears the burden of the

tax. In theory, the impact of corporate taxes on wages and capital income over the long run depends on the

relative mobility and substitutability of capital and labour (Auerbach, 2006). In a globalised economy, the

incidence of corporate taxes will tend to fall on wages, if labour is relatively immobile, with the effect

being reduced when the country is large enough to influence the international rate of return on capital

(Kotlikoff and Summers, 1987). Indeed, recent empirical evidence on the long-run incidence of corporate

taxation suggests that a significant share of the tax burden falls on wages (IMF, 2014).

Personal income taxes: labour utilisation and productivity

40. Taxes on labour income can have adverse effects on labour utilisation by affecting both labour

supply and demand. Labour taxes affect labour supply through both the decision to work and average hours

worked (Hausman, 1985; Meghir and Phillips, 2010; Koskela, 2002). In theory, a decrease in labour taxes

can have both a substitution and an income effect on participation and hours worked, with the net effect on

labour supply being an empirical matter. Labour taxes also influence firms’ labour cost especially when the

tax burden cannot be shifted on to lower net wages. In this case, lower taxes reduce labour costs and firms

5. Recent research highlights that preferential tax treatment of intellectual property can attract research

activities with potential positive implications for productivity. But, it can also induce artificial relocation of

the ownership of intangible assets without attracting any real R&D activities (Griffith et al., 2014; OECD,

2015c).

Page 21: Unclassified ECO/WKP(2016)70 - OECD€¦ · ECO/WKP(2016)70 2 OECD Working Papers should not be reported as representing the official views of the OECD or of its member countries.

ECO/WKP(2016)70

21

respond by increasing labour demand (Nickell, 2004; Pissarides, 1998; Layard et al., 1991). Social security

contributions (SSC) can have a smaller impact on labour supply than other taxes, if the benefits that

workers receive are related to the amount of contributions that they have paid (e.g. Disney, 2004).

41. The empirical literature on the impact of labour taxes on labour utilisation is vast. Generally,

empirical studies have found hours worked to be only modestly responsive to labour taxes while

participation is much more responsive to them (Heckman, 1993; Blundell et al., 1999). Most empirical

studies also find that the estimated elasticity of hours worked with respect to the after-tax wage is very

small for men while for women/second-earners it is larger (Saez et al., 2012; Meghir and Phillips, 2010;

Causa, 2008). Empirical studies, including past OECD work, investigating the effect of labour taxes on

employment have found that high tax wedges reduce employment by increasing labour cost (e.g. Bassanini

and Duval, 2006). The degree of progressivity of labour taxes may also affect individuals’ decisions to

supply labour and invest in education as it affects their after-tax return. There is some empirical evidence

that progressivity reduces GDP per capita (Arnold et al., 2011).

Distributional aspects

42. Low-income and second-earner workers tend to be more responsive to work incentives than other

income groups. Interactions between tax and benefit systems can create high average and marginal

effective tax rates for certain groups, affecting labour force participation, hours worked and employment

(OECD, 2011b). One way of raising work incentives of low-income earners is by providing “in-work

benefits”, which aim at increasing the financial reward from moving from inactivity to work. Most of the

empirical evaluations of the labour supply effect of such schemes have focused on the United Kingdom

and the United States (Immervoll and Pearson, 2009 for an overview). These benefits or tax credits, which

top up the earnings of low-income earners, have had some success in reducing “inactivity traps” of some

groups of workers (Brewer, 2006; Blundell et al., 2009; Aaberge and Flood, 2013). There is some evidence

that lack of information and administrative complexity can hinder take-up of benefits among disadvantaged

households (Currie, 2006). This suggests that the design of transfer programmes should be simple as this

could lower administrative costs and increase take-up.

43. From an equity perspective, financing spending and redistribution by levying higher taxes or

phasing out tax expenditures at higher incomes can be justified. There is evidence that the labour supply

response of high-income earners is low, especially when the tax base is broad and tax avoidance

opportunities are limited (Piketty et al., 2014; Saez et al., 2012). However, high top marginal income taxes

may discourage risk-taking and entrepreneurship with potential adverse effects for growth, indicating a

trade-off between equity and efficiency.

Consumption taxes: labour utilisation

44. Consumption taxes can affect labour supply by reducing the after-tax real wage in a similar way

as a proportional income tax. Otherwise, consumption taxes are perceived as neutral as they do not

discourage savings and investment. The empirical evidence on the impact of consumption taxes on labour

supply and employment is limited as most studies exclude consumption taxes from the relevant labour tax

wedge (OECD, 2011b). Some studies that include the consumption tax in the overall labour tax wedge

found that an increase in the overall tax wedge reduces employment (e.g. Nickell, 2004; Bassanini and

Duval, 2006). However, these studies did not estimate a separate effect of consumption taxes on

employment.

45. Consumption taxes and VAT are typically perceived as regressive. The reason is that low-income

households spend a larger share of their income on consumption as compared to high-income households.

Recent micro simulations have shown that the regressive nature of consumption taxes depends on whether

Page 22: Unclassified ECO/WKP(2016)70 - OECD€¦ · ECO/WKP(2016)70 2 OECD Working Papers should not be reported as representing the official views of the OECD or of its member countries.

ECO/WKP(2016)70

22

the tax burden is measured as a per cent of current income or expenditure, with current expenditure

possibly better reflecting lifetime income. Consumption taxes are less regressive when measured as a

percentage of household income, while they are proportional or slightly progressive when measured as a

percentage of household expenditure (OECD/KIPF, 2014). In line with this, in France the regressivity of

the VAT is reduced when the distributional effects consider the entire life-cycle (Georges-Kot, 2015).

Property taxes

46. Property taxation consists of recurrent taxes on land and buildings, taxes on financial and capital

transactions, taxes on net wealth and taxes on gifts and inheritances. These taxes vary in their distortionary

effects. However, not much empirical work exists on the impact of the various property taxes on the

drivers of growth. Nonetheless, theory suggests that recurrent taxes on land and buildings are more

efficient than other types of taxes. This is because these taxes do not affect the decisions of economic

agents to the same extent as some other taxes. By contrast, taxes on financial and capital transactions are

highly distortionary as they discourage both the ownership and the transfer of ownership of the asset

(Diamond and Mirrlees, 1971). Net wealth taxes and inheritance taxes are potentially less distortionary

than most other taxes, unless they induce wealthy households to move assets to lower-tax countries.

Wealth taxes may discourage savings, while inheritance taxes have the advantage of avoiding taxation of

most life-cycle savings.6

47. The distributional impact of recurrent taxes on immovable property is difficult to gauge due to

capitalisation of taxes into house values. Progressive recurrent taxes on residential property can increase

the progressivity of the tax system. This is the case if tax reliefs are introduced to reduce liquidity

constraints for low-income households with illiquid assets (e.g. generous basic allowance). On

distributional grounds, there is a strong case for inheritance taxes and net wealth taxes, especially if

exemptions are made for low-income asset-rich households.

Environmental taxes

48. Taxes that penalise the production and consumption of “bads” such as taxes on pollution can

improve environmental outcomes by placing a direct cost on environmental damage. Compared with

regulations such as emission limits, environmental taxes have the advantage that they encourage incentives

for abatement for each pollution unit. The design of environmentally related taxes plays an important role.

In general, taxies levied closer to the actual source of pollution (e.g. taxes on CO2 emissions rather than on

motor vehicles) likely provides a stronger environmental impact (OECD, 2011c).

49. Environmental taxes are traditionally seen as a cost or burden to economic activity, at least in the

short to medium term. Compliance with environmental taxes directly raises firms’ cost due to pollution

abatement and indirectly via increases in input prices in industries affected by the tax. However, the effects

of environmental taxes on productivity are complex and a priori uncertain (Koźluk and Zipperer, 2013 for

an overview). Indirect effects of taxes may actually increase productivity in some sectors. For instance,

workers may become more productive if the adverse effects of air pollution on their health are reduced

(Graff Zivin and Neidel, 2012). In addition to encouraging the adoption of known pollution abatement

measures, environmentally related taxes can provide significant incentives for innovation as firms and

consumers seek new, cleaner solutions in response to the price put on pollution (Ambec et al., 2013).

6. Not all bequests are accidental or unplanned and in these cases inheritance taxes will affect savings

decisions.

Page 23: Unclassified ECO/WKP(2016)70 - OECD€¦ · ECO/WKP(2016)70 2 OECD Working Papers should not be reported as representing the official views of the OECD or of its member countries.

ECO/WKP(2016)70

23

5. Fiscal policy environment

50. The institutional environment within which fiscal policy operates can influence the quality of

public finance, growth and well-being in several ways. The fiscal environment is shaped by formal

institutions such as rules, regulations and legal systems and cultural traits (or “informal” institutions)

including values, beliefs and trust. Institutions and cultural traits interact and therefore it is difficult to

disentangle the two (e.g. Alesina and Giuliano, 2015). The focus in this paper will be on the following

features: (i) rules and regulations that facilitate contract enforcement, secure property rights and ensure an

impartial judiciary; (ii) budget practices such as budget and expenditure rules and budget procedures that

determine how public budgets are prepared, executed and monitored; (iii) fiscal councils that monitor fiscal

policy; and (iv) the degree of fiscal decentralisation. Together these factors create the environment in

which fiscal policy operates and as such they affect fiscal policy outcomes.

5.1. Regulatory and judiciary environment

51. Economic theory highlights that well-designed regulatory and judiciary rules facilitate long-term

growth. In this strand of literature, a key factor driving growth is the setting of rules and their

conduciveness for trust in the government. In particular, regulations and rules shape incentives of key

economic actors and, in turn, influence investment in physical and human capital and technology

(e.g. Robinson et al., 2005). There is a consensus in the empirical literature of the importance of the rule of

law and enforcement of property rights for growth (Asoni, 2008 provides a review).7 Indeed, cross-country

differences in the regulatory framework are found to play a key role in explaining differences in long-term

growth in developed and emerging economies (Acemogolu and Robinson, 2010; Rodrik et al., 2004;

Acemoglu et. al., 2001).

52. Inclusive regulatory and judiciary rules and institutions, which level the playing field and provide

all citizens with opportunities to participate in and shape public policy, may increase redistribution and

reduce inequality (Acemoglu et al., 2015 for an overview). For instance, research has shown that

democracy has an “equalising” effect by extending the political power to the poorer segments of society,

which increases the demand for redistributive policies (Melzer and Richard, 1981). However, in practice

democracy may be constrained or captured (Acemoglu and Robinson, 2006). For example, lobbying may

allow those with greater organisational and financial resources better access to decision-making processes

as compared to others (OECD, 2013d).8

5.2. Budget practices

53. Budget practices, notably the rules that determine the preparation and execution of the budget

play an important role for the quality of public finances. Government spending is often targeted to certain

groups, while it is financed by all tax payers. This implies that governments may engage in excessive

spending, since the voters they represent do not bear the full cost of spending programmes.9 In turn, this

can create inefficient and overly large public sectors, potentially undermining growth and the sustainability

of the public finances. Hence, public budgeting may suffer from co-ordination failure, if governments

7. For instance, a seminal paper by Acemoglu et al. (2001), which addresses the potential endogeneity

problem of institutions with respect to growth, established a robust positive effect of better institutions on

growth.

8. Becker (1985) found that the adverse effect of lobbying is higher when there is highly unequal access to

political influence.

9. In a dynamic context, time inconsistency can lead to excessive deficits as governments do not fully

internalise the cost that future governments will bear in servicing public debt (e.g. Krogstrup and Wyplosz,

2010).

Page 24: Unclassified ECO/WKP(2016)70 - OECD€¦ · ECO/WKP(2016)70 2 OECD Working Papers should not be reported as representing the official views of the OECD or of its member countries.

ECO/WKP(2016)70

24

cannot overcome the pressure of interest groups. To address this co-ordination failure it is crucial to create

incentives that induce governments to recognise the true marginal costs and benefits of spending

programmes (e.g. Hallerberg and von Hagen, 1999). One way to do this is to set medium-term targets for

the budget. An alternative is to delegate the budget responsibility to a part within the government that is

less prone to respond to special interests and instead takes a comprehensive view of the allocation of

spending across areas.

54. There is evidence that well-established and enforceable fiscal rules mitigate expenditure and

deficit biases. For instance, Hallerberg et al. (2007) found that fiscal contracts that require and enforce

multi-year budget targets increase fiscal discipline, particularly in countries with ideologically dispersed

coalitions. Centralisation of the budget was found to restrain public debt in countries with one-party

government or coalition governments with similar ideologies. Recent OECD research found that fiscal

rules affect fiscal performance. For instance, a budget balance rule was found to have a positive and

significant effect on the primary balance and a negative and significant effect on spending (Fall et al.,

2015). Still, a significant association between stricter fiscal rules and fiscal performance may not

necessarily imply causality. It may reflect the fact that governments that are more concerned with long-

term sustainability are also likely to implement stricter rules (Bergman et al., 2013).

55. Transparency and accountability in the budget process via, for instance, budget practices such as

open and participatory budgeting, can affect the quality of public finance by enhancing fiscal discipline

(Debrun and Kumar, 2007). Likewise, prioritisation in the allocation of expenditure and performance-

based budgeting may improve the quality of public finances by raising cost-effectiveness of public

spending across policy areas (Kastrop et al., 2016). Inclusive political and budget processes can also create

more responsive and equitable polices and public services that are better suited for diverse needs (OECD,

2014). In addition, access to public sector information and transparency can enable citizens to exert more

effective control over public servants, which can improve outcomes (Gellner, 1994). It can also build

citizens’ trust in government (OECD, 2015f). In turn, a high level of trust can reduce transaction costs in

economic and political relationships and may help increase the efficiency and effectiveness of government

operations (OECD, 2013d).

5.3. Fiscal councils

56. Independent fiscal institutions (IFIs) are independent bodies set up by governments or

parliaments to improve oversight of fiscal policy. IFIs have existed for a long time in some countries (e.g.

Netherlands, Denmark, Germany and the United States). Recently the establishment of IFIs has multiplied.

The remit of these institutions varies across countries and often it includes assessments of fiscal plans,

long-term sustainability, and the evaluation or provision of macroeconomic and budgetary forecasts (IMF,

2013; Fall et al., 2015; OECD, 2016). To the extent that IFIs promote stronger fiscal discipline, long-term

sustainability, transparency and credibility they may improve the quality of public finance. The empirical

evidence on the effect of fiscal councils on fiscal performance is fairly limited and is mostly based on the

earlier established IFIs. An IMF study found that fiscal councils can promote fiscal discipline as long as

they are well-designed (IMF, 2013). The OECD Principles for Independent Fiscal Institutions (2014) aim

to assist countries to design an effective enabling environment while codifying lessons learned and good

practices that are firmly grounded in the experience of practitioners to date. Fall et al. (2015) showed that

fiscal councils can underpin transparency, fiscal discipline and the credibility of fiscal rules particularly in

the case of complex rules.

Page 25: Unclassified ECO/WKP(2016)70 - OECD€¦ · ECO/WKP(2016)70 2 OECD Working Papers should not be reported as representing the official views of the OECD or of its member countries.

ECO/WKP(2016)70

25

5.4. Fiscal decentralisation

57. The theoretical literature on the economics of fiscal federalism has identified several potential

channels through which fiscal decentralisation influences economic growth. The traditional literature

focuses on the efficiency aspects of decentralisation (Tiebout, 1956). Decentralisation increases economic

efficiency as local governments can be better than national governments in providing services to citizens

due to closeness and informational advantages. Furthermore, the possibility of experimentation and

competition between local governments in the delivery of public services, coupled with mobility of

households and firms, promotes a more efficient provision of services. By contrast, the more recent

literature argues that decentralisation can increase corruption and government inefficiency, if local

governments shield businesses operating in their jurisdiction from laws applying at the central level, thus

effectively eroding the rule of law. Moreover, local governments may be more easily captured by special

interest groups (Martinez-Vazquez and McNab, 2003 for an overview).

58. The empirical evidence on the impact of decentralisation on growth is ambiguous. A recent meta-

analysis, based on 31 empirical studies, found that the evidence on the effect of decentralisation on growth

is inconclusive (Baskaran et al., 2014). The failure to find clear-cut results partly reflects problems of

measuring the autonomy of sub-federal jurisdictions accurately.10

Nonetheless, an OECD study found that

decentralisation (measured by revenue or spending shares) was positively associated with GDP per capita

(Bloechinger et al., 2013). Furthermore, the impact of decentralisation was found to be stronger for

revenue than for spending decentralisation. The research also found that investment in physical and human

capital was significantly higher in more decentralised economies.

59. Similar to the literature on growth, the theoretical and empirical literature provides no clear-cut

answer on the link between fiscal decentralisation and inequality (Tselios, 2012). Fiscal decentralisation

can reduce inequality. Decentralisation brings governments closer to their citizens, making local officials

better informed about local needs than central governments. By contrast, fiscal decentralisation may lower

the likelihood of attracting skilled officials as the supply of skills may be limited at the local level and, in

turn, reducing the efficiency in delivering redistributive polices (Prud’homme, 1995). A recent OECD

study provides ambiguous results on the association between fiscal decentralisation and inequality, with

the results depending on the particular inequality and decentralisation measure considered in the analysis

(Blöchliger, Bartolini and Stossberg, 2016).

10. The majority of studies measure decentralisation by the share of sub-federal spending (or revenue) in total

government spending (or revenue). Theoretical models assume autonomy of sub-federal decision-making

over the provision and financing of public goods. However, spending decentralisation may simply indicate

the extent of administrative federalism within states, rather than actual autonomy (e.g. Stegarescu, 2005).

Page 26: Unclassified ECO/WKP(2016)70 - OECD€¦ · ECO/WKP(2016)70 2 OECD Working Papers should not be reported as representing the official views of the OECD or of its member countries.

ECO/WKP(2016)70

26

REFERENCES

Aaberge R. and L. Flood (2013), “U.S. versus Sweden: The Effect of Alternative In-Work Tax Credit

Policies on Labour Supply of Single Mothers”, IZA DP, No. 7706.

Acemoglu, D. and J. Robinson (2010), “The Role of Institutions in Growth and Development”, Review of

Economics and Institutions, Vol. 1, No. 2.

Acemoglu, D. and J. Robinson (2006), Economic Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy, Cambridge

University Press, New York, NY.

Acemoglu, D. and S. Johnson (2007), “Disease and Development: The Effect of Life Expectancy on

Economic Growth”, Journal of Political Economy, 2007, Vol. 115.

Acemoglu, D., S. Naidu, P. Restrepo and J. Robinson (2015), “Democracy, Redistribution, and

Inequality”, in: Handbook of Income Distribution.

Acemoglu, D., S. Johnson and J. Robinson (2001), “The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development:

An Empirical Investigation”, The American Economic Review, 91(5), pp 1369-1401.

Acosta-Ormaechea, S. and J. Yoo (2012), “Tax Composition and Growth: A Broad Cross-Country

Perspective”, IMF Working Paper, WP/12/257.

Agell, J., T. Lindh and H. Ohlsson (1997), “Growth and the Public Sector: A Critical Review Essay”,

European Journal of Political Economy, 13, pp 33-52.

Agénor, P.-R. (2010), “A Theory of Infrastructure-led Development”, Journal of Economic Dynamics and

Control, Elsevier, Vol. 34(5).

Aghion, P. and P. Howitt (1992), "A Model of Growth through Creative Destruction", Econometrica,

Econometric Society, Vol. 60(2), pp. 323-51.

Alesina, A., R. Baqir and W. Easterly (2000), “Redistributive Public Employment”, Journal of Urban

Economics, Vol. 48, pp 219-241.

Alesina, A. and P. Giuliano (2015), "Culture and Institutions", Journal of Economic Literature, 53(4).

Ambec, S., M. A. Cohen, S. Elgie and P. Lanoie (2013), “The Porter Hypothesis at 20: Can Environmental

Regulation Enhance Innovation and Competitiveness?”, Review of Environmental Economics and

Policy, Vol. 7(1).

Andrews, D. and C. Criscuolo (2013), "Knowledge-Based Capital, Innovation and Resource Allocation",

OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 1046, OECD Publishing, Paris.

Page 27: Unclassified ECO/WKP(2016)70 - OECD€¦ · ECO/WKP(2016)70 2 OECD Working Papers should not be reported as representing the official views of the OECD or of its member countries.

ECO/WKP(2016)70

27

Arnold, J., B. Brys, C. Heady, A. Johansson, C. Schwellnus and L. Vartia (2011), “Tax Policy for

Economic Recovery and Growth”, Economic Journal, Vol. 121.

Armey, D. (1995), The Freedom Revolution, Washington: Regnery Publishing.

Asoni, A. (2008), “Protection of Property Rights and Growth as Political Equilibria”, Journal of Economic

Surveys, 22 (5): 953–987.

Aschauer, D. (1989), “Does Public Capital Crowd out Private Capital?”, Journal of Monetary Economics,

24.

Atkinson, A. and J. Stiglitz, (1976), "The Design of Tax Structure: Direct Versus Indirect Taxation",

Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 6.

Auerbach, A. (2006), “Who Bears the Corporate Tax? A Review of What We Know”, in: J. Poterba (ed.)

Tax Policy and the Economy, Vol. 20, Cambridge: MIT Press.

Barro, R. (1990), “Government Spending in a Simple Model of Endogenous Growth”, Journal of Political

Economy, 98 (5).

Barro, R. and X. Sala-i-Martin (1992), “Public Finance in Models of Economic Growth”, Review of

Economic Studies, 59(4): 645-61.

Baskaran, T., L. Feld and J. Schnellenbach (2014), “Fiscal Federalism, Decentralization and Economic

Growth: Survey and Meta-Analysis”, CESIFO Working Paper, No. 4985.

Bassanini, A. and R. Duval (2006), "Employment Patterns in OECD Countries: Reassessing the Role of

Policies and Institutions", OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 486, OECD

Publishing, Paris.

Becker, G. (1985), “Public Policies, Pressure Groups, and Dead Weight Costs”, Journal of Public

Economics, Vol. 28.

Benhabib, J. and M. Spiegel (2005), "Human Capital and Technology Diffusion", in: Philippe, A. and S.

Durlauf (eds.), Handbook of Economic Growth, Edition 1, Volume 1, Chapter 13, Elsevier.

Bergh, A. and M. Henrekson (2011), “Government Size and Growth: A Survey and Interpretation of the

Evidence", IFN Working Paper, No. 858.

Berg, A., E. Buffie, C. Pattillo, R., Portillo, A. Presbitero and L. Zanna (2015), “Some Misconceptions

about Public Investment and Growth”, IMF Working Paper, No. 15/272.

Bergman, M., M. Hutchison and S. Hougaard Jensen (2013), “Do Sound Public Finances Require Fiscal

Rules or Is Market Pressure Enough?”, Economic Papers, No. 489, European Economy.

Bloch, D., J.M. Fournier, D. Gonzales and A. Pina (2016), “Trends in Public Finances: Insights from a

New Detailed Dataset”, OECD Economic Department Working Paper, No. 1345, OECD Publishing,

Paris.

Blöchliger, H., B. Égert and K. Bonesmo Fredriksen (2013), "Fiscal Federalism and its Impact on

Economic Activity, Public Investment and the Performance of Educational Systems", OECD

Economics Department Working Papers, No. 1051, OECD Publishing, Paris.

Page 28: Unclassified ECO/WKP(2016)70 - OECD€¦ · ECO/WKP(2016)70 2 OECD Working Papers should not be reported as representing the official views of the OECD or of its member countries.

ECO/WKP(2016)70

28

Blöchliger, H., D. Bartolini and S. Stossberg (2016), "Does Fiscal Decentralisation Foster Regional

Convergence?", OECD Economic Policy Papers, No. 17, OECD Publishing, Paris.

DOI: http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/5jlr3c1vcqmr-en

Bloom, D. E., D. Canning, and J. Sevilla (2004), “The Effect of Health on Economic Growth: A

Production Function Approach”, World Development, 32: 1–13.

Blundell, R. and T. MaCurdy (1999), “Labor Supply: A Review of Alternative Approaches”, in: O.

Ashenfelter and R. Layard (eds.), Handbook of Labor Economics, Vol. 3A, Amsterdam, North

Holland.

Blundell, R., M. Brewer, P. Haan and A. Shephard (2009), "Optimal Income Taxation of Lone Mothers:

An Empirical Comparison of the UK and Germany", Economic Journal, 119, F101-F121.

Brewer, M., A. Duncan, A. Shepard and M-J. Suárez (2006), “Did Working Families Tax Credit Work?

The Impact of In-work Support on Parent's Labour Supply and Take-up Behavior in Great Britain”,

Labour Economics, 13, 699 – 720.

Brouwer, E., T. Grosfeld, P. den Hertog and T. Poot (2005), "Evaluation of a Major Dutch Tax Credit

Scheme (WBSO) Aimed at Promoting R&D", mimeo.

Brys, B., et al. (2016), "Tax Design for Inclusive Economic Growth", OECD Taxation Working Papers,

No. 26, OECD Publishing, Paris.

DOI: http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/5jlv74ggk0g7-en

BIS (2015), “What is the Relationship between Public and Private Investment in R&D?”, Economic

Insight.

Card, D., J. Heining and P. Kline (2013), “Workplace Heterogeneity and the Rise of West German Wage

Inequality,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics.

Card, D. and A. Krueger (1992), "Does School Quality Matter? Returns to Education and the

Characteristics of Public Schools in the United States", Journal of Political Economy, 100(1).

Causa, O., A. de Serres and N. Ruiz (2015), "Can Pro-growth Policies Lift all Boats? An Analysis Based

on Household Disposable Income", OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 1180,

OECD Publishing, Paris.

Causa, O. and Å. Johansson (2009), "Intergenerational Social Mobility", OECD Economics Department

Working Papers, No. 707, OECD Publishing, Paris.

Causa, O. (2008), "Explaining Differences in Hours Worked among OECD Countries: An Empirical

Analysis", OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 596, OECD Publishing, Paris.

Chamley, C. (1986), “Optimal Taxation of Capital Income in General Equilibrium with Infinite Lives”,

Econometrica, 54(3).

Chobanov, D. and A. Mladenova (2009), “What Is the Optimum Size of Government”, Institute for Market

Economics, August.

Cohen, D. and M. Soto (2007), “Growth and Human Capital: Good Data, Good Results", Journal of

Economic Growth.

Page 29: Unclassified ECO/WKP(2016)70 - OECD€¦ · ECO/WKP(2016)70 2 OECD Working Papers should not be reported as representing the official views of the OECD or of its member countries.

ECO/WKP(2016)70

29

Comin, D. and M. Mestieri (2013), “If Technology Has Arrived Everywhere, Why Has Income

Diverged?”, NBER Working Paper Series, No. 19010.

Cournède, B., A. Goujard and Á. Pina (2013), “Reconciling Fiscal Consolidation with Growth and

Equity”, OECD Journal: Economic Studies, OECD Publishing, Paris.

Cunha, F., J. Heckman and S. Schennach (2010), “Estimating the Technology of Cognitive and Non-

cognitive Skill Formation”, Econometrica, Vol. 78.

Currie, J. (2006), “The Take-up of Social Benefits”, in: A. J. Auerbach, D. Card and J. M. Quigley (eds.),

Public Policy and the Income Distribution, , Russell Sage Foundation, New York.

De la Fuente, A. and R. Domenech (2006), “Human Capital in Growth Regressions: How much Difference

does Quality Data Make?”, Journal of the European Economic Association, 4(1).

De Mooij, R. (2011), “The Tax Elasticity of Corporate Debt: A Synthesis of Size and Variations”, IMF

Working Paper, WP/11/95, International Monetary Fund.

De Mooij, R. (2012), “Tax Biases to Debt Finance: Assessing the Problem, Finding Solutions”, Fiscal

Studies, Institute for Fiscal Studies, Vol. 33(4).

Decoster A. J., C. Loughrey, O’Donoghue and D. Verwerft (2011), “Microsimulation of Indirect Taxes”,

International Journal of Microsimulation, 4(2), pp 41-56.

Diamond, P. A. and J. A. Mirrlees (1971). “Optimal Taxation and Public Production I: Production

Efficiency”, American Economic Review, 61(1).

Disney, R. (2004), “Are Contributions to Public Pension Programmes a Tax on Employment?”, Economic

Policy.

Djankov, S., T. Ganser, C. McLiesh, R. Ramalho and A. Shleifer (2010), “The Effect of Corporate Taxes

on Investment and Entrepreneurship”, American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, Vol. 2, No. 3.

Dutu, R. and P. Sicari (2016), “Public Spending Efficiency in the OECD: Benchmarking Health Care,

Education and General Administration”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 1278,

OECD Publishing, Paris.

Duval, R., M. Eris and D. Furceri (2011), “The Effects of Downturns on Labour Force Participation:

Evidence and Causes”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 875, OECD Publishing,

Paris.

Debrun, X. and Kumar, M.S. (2007), "Fiscal Rules, Fiscal Councils and all that: Commitment Devices,

Signalling Tools or Smokescreens?" in: Central Bank of Italy, Fiscal Policy: Current Issues and

Challenges, Conference Proceedings, Rome, Central Bank of Italy.

Easterly, W. and S. Rebelo (1993), “Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth: An Empirical Investigation”,

Journal of Monetary Economics, 32 (3), 417-458.

Erden, L. and R. Holcombe (2005), “The Effects of Public Investment on Private Investment in

Developing Economies”, Public Finance Review, Vol. 33.

Page 30: Unclassified ECO/WKP(2016)70 - OECD€¦ · ECO/WKP(2016)70 2 OECD Working Papers should not be reported as representing the official views of the OECD or of its member countries.

ECO/WKP(2016)70

30

Fall, F. and J.M. Fournier (2015), "Macroeconomic Uncertainties, Prudent Debt Targets and Fiscal Rules",

OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 1230, OECD Publishing, Paris.

Feld, L. and J. Heckemeyer (2011), “FDI and Taxation: A Meta-Study”, Journal of Economic Surveys,

Vol. 25, No. 2.

Flaig, G. and H. Rottmann (2011), "Labour Market Institutions and Unemployment. An International

Comparison", CESifo Working Paper, No. 3558.

Fournier, J.M. (2016), “The Positive Effect of Public Investment on Potential Growth”, OECD Economics

Department Working Papers, No. 1347, OECD Publishing, Paris.

Fournier, J.M. and Å. Johansson (2016), “The Effect of the Size and the Mix of Public Spending on

Growth and Inequality”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 1344, OECD

Publishing, Paris.

Fournier, J.M. and I. Koske (2012), "Less Income Inequality and More Growth – Are they Compatible?

Part 7. The Drivers of Labour Earnings Inequality – An Analysis Based on Conditional and

Unconditional Quantile Regressions", OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 930.

Freeman, R. (1995), “The Large Welfare State as a System”, American Economic Review, 85 (2), 16–21.

Gemmell, N., R. Kneller and I. Sanz (2011), “The Timing and Persistence of Fiscal Policy Impacts on

Growth: Evidence from OECD Countries”, The Economic Journal, 121.

Gemmell, N., R. Kneller and I. Sanz (2014), “ Does the Composition of Government Expenditure Matter

for Long-run GDP Levels?”, Victoria University Working Paper, No. 10/2014.

Gemmell, N., R. Kneller, D. McGowan and I. Sanz (2012), “Corporate Taxation and Productivity Catch-

Up: Evidence from 11 European Countries”, Discussion Papers in Economics, No. 12/06, University

of Nottingham.

Georges-Kot, S. (2015), “Annual and Lifetime Incidence of the Value-added Tax in France”, Document de

travail de l’INSEE, G2015/12.

Golosov, M., A. Tsyvinski and I. Werning (2006), “New Dynamic Public Finance: A User's Guide”, NBER

Macroeconomics Annual.

Graff Zivin, J. and M. Neidel (2012), “The Impact of Pollution on Worker Productivity”, American

Economic Review, Vol. 102(7).

Griffith, R., H. Miller and M. O’Connell (2014), “Ownership of Intellectual Property and Corporate

Taxation”, Journal of Public Economics, 112.

Guellec, D. and B. Van Pottelsberghe De La Potterie (2003),” The Impact of Public R&D Expenditure on

Business R&D”, Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 12:3.

Hallerberg, M. and J. von Hagen (1999), "Electoral Institutions, Cabinet Negotiations, and Budget Deficits

within the European Union", in: Poterba, J. and J. von Hagen (Eds.), Fiscal Institutions and Fiscal

Performance, University of Chicago Press.

Page 31: Unclassified ECO/WKP(2016)70 - OECD€¦ · ECO/WKP(2016)70 2 OECD Working Papers should not be reported as representing the official views of the OECD or of its member countries.

ECO/WKP(2016)70

31

Hallerberg, M., R. Strauch and J. von Hagen (2007), “The Design of Fiscal Rules and Forms of

Governance in European Union Countries”, European Journal of Political Economy, 23.

Hajkova, D., G. Nicoletti, L. Vartia and K. Yoo (2006), “Taxation and Business Environment as Drivers of

Foreign Direct Investment in OECD Countries”, OECD Economic Studies, No. 43/2, OECD

Publishing, Paris.

Hanushek, E. (1986), "The Economics of Schooling: Production and Efficiency in Public Schools",

Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 24.

Hanushek, E. and L. Woessmann (2012), “Do Better Schools Lead to More Growth? Cognitive Skills,

Economic Outcomes, and Causation”, Journal of Economic Growth, Vol. 17.

Hanushek, E. and L. Woessmann (2011), “The economics of international differences in educational

achievement” in E. Hanushek, S. Machin, and L. Woessmann (Eds.), Handbook of the Economics of

Education, Vol. 3. Amsterdam: North Holland.

Haskel J., A. Hughes and E. Bascavusoglu-Moreau (2014), “The Economic Significance of the UK

Science Base”, UK-IRC.

Hausman, J. (1985), “Taxes and Labor Supply”, in: Auerbach, A. and M. Feldstein (eds.), Handbook of

Public Economics, Vol. 1.

Heckman, J. (2011), “The Economics of Inequality: The Value of Early Childhood Education”, American

Educator, Spring.

Heckman, J. (1993), “What Has Been Learned about Labor Supply in the Past Twenty Years?”, American

Economic Association Papers and Proceedings, (May 1993), 83(2), 116-121.

Hubbard, R.G. and K.L. Judd (1987), “Social Security and Individual Welfare”, American Economic

Review, No. 77, Vol. 4.

IMF (2013), “The Functions and Roles of Fiscal Councils”, IMF.

IMF (2014), “Fiscal Policy and Income Inequality”, IMF.

IMF (2015), “Making Public Investment more Efficient”, IMF.

Immervoll, H. and M. Pearson (2009), “A Good Time for Making Work Pay? Taking Stock of In-Work

Benefits and Related Measures across the OECD”, Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA) Policy

Paper, No. 3.

Imrohoroglu, A., S. Imrohoroglu and D.H. Jones (1995), “A Life Cycle Analysis of Social Security”,

Economic Theory, No. 6, Vol. 1, pp 83-114.

Joumard, I., C. André and C. Nicq (2010), “Health Care Systems: Efficiency and Institutions”, OECD

Economics Department Working Papers, No. 769, OECD Publishing, Paris.

Joumard, I., M. Pisu and D. Bloch (2012), “Less Income Inequality and More Growth – Are They

Compatible? Part 3. Income Redistribution via Taxes and Transfers across OECD Countries”,

OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 926, OECD Publishing, Paris.

Page 32: Unclassified ECO/WKP(2016)70 - OECD€¦ · ECO/WKP(2016)70 2 OECD Working Papers should not be reported as representing the official views of the OECD or of its member countries.

ECO/WKP(2016)70

32

Judd, K. (1985), “Redistributive Taxation in a Simple Perfect Foresight Model”, Journal of Public

Economics, 28(1).

Kastrop, C., B. Cournède, F. Fall and A. Mourougane (2016), “Fiscal Consolidation Strategies”, Paper

prepared for the conference “Rethinking Fiscal Policy after the Crisis”, forthcoming.

Kluve, J. (2010), “The Effectiveness of European Active Labor Market Programs”, Labour Economics,

17:6.

Kneller, R., M. Bleaney and N. Gemmell (1999), “Fiscal Policy and Growth: Evidence from OECD

Countries”, Journal of Public Economics, Elsevier, Vol. 74(2).

Koeniger, W., M. Leonardi and L. Nunziata (2007), “Labor Market Institutions and Wage Inequality”,

Industrial and Labor Relations Review, Vol. 60. No. 3, pp 340-356.

Koskela, E. (2002), “Labour Taxation and Employment in Trade Union Models: A Partial Survey”, in:

S. Ilmakunnas and E. Koskela (eds), Towards Higher Employment: The Role of Labour Market

Institutions, Helsinki.

Kotlikoff, L. and L., Summers (1987), "Tax Incidence", in: A. J. Auerbach and M. Feldstein (eds.),

Handbook of Public Economics, Edition 1, Volume 2, Chapter 16, Elsevier.

Koźluk, T. and V. Zipperer (2013), “Environmental Policies and Productivity Growth: A Critical Review

of Empirical Findings”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 1096, OECD

Publishing, Paris.

Krogstrup S. and C. Wyplosz (2010), “A Common Pool Theory of Supranational Deficit Ceilings”,

European Economic Review, Vol. 54

Landau, D. (1983), “Government Expenditure and Economic Growth: A Cross-Country Study”, Southern

Economic Journal, 49 (3): 783–792.

Layard, R., S. Nickell and R. Jackman (1991), Unemployment: Macroeconomic Performance and the

Labour Market, Oxford University Press.

Levine, R. and D. Renelt (1992), “A Sensitivity Analysis of Cross-Country Growth Regressions”,

American Economic Review, 82(4): 942-63.

Lokshin, B. and P. Mohnen (2007), “Measuring the Effectiveness of R&D Tax Credits in the Netherlands”,

CIRANO Working Papers.

Lucas, R. (1988), “On the Mechanics of Economic Development”, Journal of Monetary Economics,

Vol. 22.

McNabb, K. and P. LeMay-Boucher (2014), “Tax Structures, Economic Growth and Development”, ICTD

Working Paper, No. 22.

Mankiw, N. G., D. Romer and D. N. Weil. (1992), “A Contribution to the Empirics of Economic Growth”,

Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 107(May).

Mankiw, G. M., Weinzierl and D. Yagan (2009), “Optimal Taxation in Theory and Practice”, NBER

Working Paper, No. 15071.

Page 33: Unclassified ECO/WKP(2016)70 - OECD€¦ · ECO/WKP(2016)70 2 OECD Working Papers should not be reported as representing the official views of the OECD or of its member countries.

ECO/WKP(2016)70

33

Martin, S., N. Rice and P. Smith (2008), “Does Health Care Spending Improve Health Outcomes?

Evidence from English Programme Budgeting Data”, Health Economics, Vol. 27(4).

Martin, J. P. (2000), “What Works among Active Labour Market Policies: Evidence from OECD

Countries’ Experiences”, OECD Economic Studies, No. 30, OECD Publishing, Paris.

Martinez-Vazquez, J. and R.M. McNab (2003), "Fiscal Decentralization and Economic Growth", World

Development, 31, 1597 – 1616.

Meghir, C. and D. Phillip (2010), “Labour Supply and Taxes”, in: The Mirrlees Review: Reforming the Tax

System for the 21st Century, Oxford University Press.

Meltzer, A.M. and S.F. Richard (1981), “A Rational Theory of the Size of Government”, Journal of

Political Economy, Vol. 89.

Mirrlees, J. (1971) “An Exploration in the Theory of Optimal Income Taxation”, Review of Economic

Studies, Vol. 38, 175-208.

Morgan J. and A. Mourougane (2003), “Active Labour Market Policies in Europe”, in: Edward Elgar (ed.),

Institutions and Wage Formation in the New Europe.

Murtin, F. and A. de Serres (2014), “How Do Policies Affect the Exit Rate out of Unemployment?

Disentangling Job Creation from Labour Market Frictions”, Labour, Vol. 28(2).

Myles, G. (2009a-c), “Economic Growth and the Role of Taxation”, OECD Economics Department

Working Papers, No. 713-715, OECD Publishing, Paris.

Nickell, S. (2004), “Employment and Taxes”, CEP Discussion Paper, No. 634.

OECD (2002), Financing Education - Investments and Returns, OECD Publishing, Paris.

OECD (2006), Boosting Jobs and Incomes: The OECD Jobs Strategy, OECD Publishing, Paris.

OECD (2008), "Ten Steps to Equity in Education", OECD Policy Briefs, OECD Publishing, Paris.

OECD (2009), “Taxation and Economic Growth”, Economic Policy Reforms, Going for Growth,

Chapter 5, OECD Publishing, Paris.

OECD (2010), “Health Care Systems: Getting more Value for Money”, OECD Economics Department

Policy Notes, No. 2, OECD Publishing, Paris.

OECD (2011a), Divided We Stand: Why Inequality Keeps Rising, OECD Publishing, Paris.

OECD (2011b), Taxation and Employment, OECD Publishing, Paris.

OECD (2011c), "Taxation, Innovation and the Environment: A Policy Brief", OECD Publishing, Paris.

OECD (2011d), Employment Outlook, OECD Publishing, Paris

OECD (2012), Government at a Glance, OECD Publishing, Paris.

Page 34: Unclassified ECO/WKP(2016)70 - OECD€¦ · ECO/WKP(2016)70 2 OECD Working Papers should not be reported as representing the official views of the OECD or of its member countries.

ECO/WKP(2016)70

34

OECD (2013), PISA 2012 Results: What Makes Schools Successful (Volume IV): Resources, Policies and

Practices, OECD Publishing, Paris. DOI: http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264201156-en

OECD (2013b), Government at a Glance, OECD Publishing, Paris.

OECD (2013c), Health at a Glance 2013: OECD Indicators, OECD Publishing, Paris.

OECD (2013d), Trust in Government: Assessing the Evidence, Understanding the Policies, OECD

Publishing, Paris.

OECD (2014), All on Board: Making Inclusive Growth Happen, OECD Publishing, Paris.

OECD/KIPF (2014), "The Distributional Effects of Consumption Taxes in OECD Countries", OECD Tax

Policy Studies, OECD Publishing, Paris.

OECD (2015a), The Future of Productivity, OECD Publishing, Paris.

OECD (2015b), Education at a Glance, OECD Publishing, Paris.

OECD (2015c), Measuring and Monitoring BEPS, Action 11 - 2015 Final Report, OECD Publishing,

Paris. DOI: http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264241343-en

OECD (2015d), OECD Revenue Statistics, OECD Publishing, Paris.

OECD (2015e), Focus on Health Spending, OECD Health Statistics, OECD Publishing, Paris.

OECD (2015f), "Recommendation of the Council on Principles for Independent Fiscal Institutions", OECD

Publishing, Paris.

OECD (2016), "Principles for Independent Fiscal Institutions and Country Notes", forthcoming, OECD

Publishing, Paris.

Oliveira Martins J., R. Boarini, H. Strauss, C. de la Maisonneuve and C. Saadi (2007), “The Policy

Determinants of Investment in Tertiary Education”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers,

No. 576, OECD Publishing, Paris.

Pevcin, P. (2004), “Does an Optimal Spending Size of Government Exist?”, Paper presented at the

European Group of Public Administration Conference, 1-4 September 2004, Ljubljana, Slovenia.

Pestel, N. and E. Sommer (2013), “Shifting Taxes from Labor to Consumption: Efficient, but

Regressive?”, IZA Discussion Paper, No. 7804

Piketty T. and E. Saez (2013), “A Theory of Optimal Inheritance Taxation”, Econometrica, Vol. 81.

Piketty T., E. Saez and S. Stantcheva (2014), “Optimal Taxation of Top Labour Incomes: A Tale of Three

Elasticities”, American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 6(1).

Pissarides, C. (1998), “The Impact of Employment Tax Cuts on Unemployment and Wages: the Role of

Unemployment Benefits and Tax Structure”, European Economic Review, Vol. 42.

Prud’homme, R. (1995), “The Dangers of Decentralization”, World Bank Research Observer, 10.

Page 35: Unclassified ECO/WKP(2016)70 - OECD€¦ · ECO/WKP(2016)70 2 OECD Working Papers should not be reported as representing the official views of the OECD or of its member countries.

ECO/WKP(2016)70

35

Ramsey, F. (1927), “A Contribution to the Theory of Taxation”, Economic Journal, 37.

Robinson, J., A. D. Acemoglu and S. Johnson, (2005), “Institutions as a Fundamental Cause of Long-Run

Growth”, Handbook of Economic Growth, 1A.

Rodrik, D., A. Subramanian, and F. Trebbi (2004), “Institutions Rule: The Primacy of Institutions over

Geography and Integration in Economic Development”, Journal of Economic Growth, 9(2),

pp 131-65.

Romer, P. (1986), "Increasing Returns and Long-run Growth", Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 94(5).

Romer, P. (1990), "Human Capital and Growth: Theory and Evidence," Carnegie Rochester Conference

Series on Public Policy, Vol. 32.

Romp, W. and J. de Haan (2007), “Public Capital and Economic Growth: A Critical Survey”, Perspektiven

der Wirtschaftspolitik, Vol. 8.

Salverda W. and D. Checchi (2014), "Labour-Market Institutions and the Dispersion of Wage Earnings",

IZA Discussion Paper, No. 8220.

Saez, E., J. Slemrod and S. Giertz (2012), “The Elasticity of Taxable Income with Respect to Marginal Tax

Rates: A Critical Review”, Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 50 (1), pp 3–50.

Saez, E. (2001), “Using Elasticities to Derive Optimal Income Tax Rates”, Review of Economic Studies,

No. 68.

Sen, H. and A. Kaya (2014), “Crowding-Out or Crowding-In? Analyzing the Effects of Government

Spending on Private Investment in Turkey”, Panoeconomicus, Vol. 6, Issue 6.

Slemrod, J. (1995), “What Do Cross-Country Studies Teach about Government Involvement, Prosperity

and Economic Growth?”, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, pp.373-431.

Solow, R. (1956), “A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth”, The Quarterly Journal of

Economics, Vol. 70, No. 1.

Song, J., D. Price, F. Guvenen, N. Bloom and T. von Wachter (2015), “Firming up Inequality”, NBER

Working Paper, No. 21199.

Stegarescu, D. (2005), “Public Sector Decentralization. Measurement Concepts and Recent International

Trends”, Fiscal Studies, 26, 301 – 333.

Sutherland, D., S. Araujo, B. Égert and T. Koźluk (2009), "Infrastructure Investment: Links to Growth and

the Role of Public Policies", OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 686, OECD

Publishing, Paris.

Swan, T. (1956), “Economic Growth and Capital Accumulation”, Economic Record, 32.

Swift, R. (2011), “The Relationship between Health and GDP in OECD Countries in the very Long Run”,

Health Economics, 20.

Tanzi, V. and L. Schuknecht (1997), “Reconsidering the Fiscal Role of Government: The International

Perspective”, American Economic Review, No. 87.

Page 36: Unclassified ECO/WKP(2016)70 - OECD€¦ · ECO/WKP(2016)70 2 OECD Working Papers should not be reported as representing the official views of the OECD or of its member countries.

ECO/WKP(2016)70

36

Teles, V.K. and C.C. Mussolini (2014), “Public Debt and the Limits of Fiscal Policy to Increase Economic

Growth”, European Economic Review, Vol. 66.

Tselios, V. et al. (2012), “Income Inequality, Decentralisation, and Regional Development in Western

Europe”, Environment and Planning A, Vol. 44, pp 1278-1301.

Tiebout, C.M. (1956), "A Pure Theory of Local Expenditures", Journal of Political Economy, 64, 416-424.

Vedder, R. and L. Gallaway (1998), “Government Size and Economic Growth”, Paper prepared for the

Joint Economic Committee, Washington, D.C.

Weil, D. (2007), "Accounting for the Effect of Health on Economic Growth", The Quarterly Journal of

Economics, Vol. 122(3), pp. 1265-1306.

Westmore, B. (2013), "R&D, Patenting and Growth: The Role of Public Policy", OECD Economics

Department Working Papers, No. 1047, OECD Publishing, Paris.

Woessmann, L. (2008), “Efficiency and Equity of European Education and Training Policies”,

International Tax and Public Finance, Vol. 15, No. 1, pp. 199-230.