Topic 8: Optimal Investment - School of Economics and ...yluo/teaching/econ6012/2013topic8.pdf ·...

22
Topic 8: Optimal Investment Yulei Luo SEF of HKU November 22, 2013 Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) Macro Theory November 22, 2013 1 / 22

Transcript of Topic 8: Optimal Investment - School of Economics and ...yluo/teaching/econ6012/2013topic8.pdf ·...

Topic 8: Optimal Investment

Yulei Luo

SEF of HKU

November 22, 2013

Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) Macro Theory November 22, 2013 1 / 22

Demand for Investment

The importance of investment. First, the combination of firms’investment demand and households’saving supply jointly determineshow much of an economy’s output is invested, which matters forlong-run growth.

Second, investment is highly volatile. That is, investment isimportant for understanding short-run aggregate fluctuations.

A static investment model: Consider a firm that can rent capital at aprice rK . The firm’s profits are given by

π (K ;X1, · · ·,X1)− rKK , (1)

where K is the desired capital stock and the X ′s are exogenousvariables. (e.g., X ′s include the output price and the costs of otherinputs.) Assume that the revenue function π (·) satisfies: πK > 0and πKK < 0.

Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) Macro Theory November 22, 2013 2 / 22

Optimal (Desired) Capital Stock

The FOC for the profit-maximizing choice of K :

πK (K ;X1, · · ·,X1) = rK , (2)

which means that the firm rents capital up to the point where itsmarginal revenue equals its rental price.

(2) implicitly defines the firm’s desired capital stock as a function ofrK and the X ′s:

K ∗ = f (rK ;X1, · · ·,X1) . (3)

The main problems of this investment problem:1 Adjustments of capital stock are costless. (In reality, capital stockadjusts gradually with respect to changes in the X ′s.)

2 Expectations do not affect the demand for investment. (In realty,expectations about demand and costs are central to investmentdecisions.)

Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) Macro Theory November 22, 2013 3 / 22

Introducing Adjustment Costs

To overcome the first problem, we assume that firms face costs ofadjusting their capital stocks. Examples include the costs of installingthe new capital and training workers to operate new machines.

Specifically, assume that the adjustment costs, C (i), where i is therate of change of the firm’s capital stock (i.e., investment), satisfy

C (0) = 0,C ′ (0) = 0,C ′′ (·) > 0, (4)

which means that it is costly for a firm to change its capital stock,and that the marginal adjustment cost is increasing in the size of theadjustment.

Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) Macro Theory November 22, 2013 4 / 22

An Investment Model with Adjustment Costs

The firm’s objective function is to maximize the expected discountedpresent value of profits:

vt = max

[∞

∑s=t

(1

1+ r

)s−t (AsF (Ks , , Ls )−

χ

2I 2sKs− wsLs − Is

)],

(5)subject to

Ks+1 = (1− δ)Ks + Is , s ≥ t (6)

given Kt−1. For simplicity, we may assume that δ = 0.

In this model, χ2I 2sKsis the cost of installation and is paid by the firm

above the actual cost Is of purchasing the new capital goods.

Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) Macro Theory November 22, 2013 5 / 22

Optimal Conditions

The Lagrangian is

Lt =∞

∑s=t

(1R

)s−t [ (AsF (Ks , Ls )− χ2I 2sKs− wsLs − Is

)+qs (Ks + Is −Ks+1)

], (7)

where qs is the Lagrange multiplier. For simplicity, here we assumethat ws and Ls are given and F (Ks , , Ls ) is linearly homogenous.The FOC for Is gives

−χIsKs− 1+ qs = 0. (8)

This condition can be rewritten as

Is =qs − 1

χKs , (9)

which means that investment is positive only if the shadow price qs ofexisting installed capital exceed 1, the price of new, uninstalledcapital. (Tobin’s q theory.)

Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) Macro Theory November 22, 2013 6 / 22

The FOC for Ks+1 gives

qs =1R

[As+1FK (Ks+1) +

χ

2

(Is+1Ks+1

)2+ qs+1

], (10)

which can be regarded as the investment Euler equation.

Implications: At an optimum for the firm, the time s shadow price qsof an extra unit of capital is the discounted sum of:

1 the capital’s marginal product next period;2 the capital’s marginal contribution to lower installation costs next

period(

χ2

(IsKs

)2);

3 the shadow price of capital on the next period, s + 1.

Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) Macro Theory November 22, 2013 7 / 22

Intuitively, (10) means that at an optimum, the firm cannot increaseprofits by raising its installed capital at marginal cost:

qs = 1+χIsKs, (11)

benefiting a higher marginal product and lower investment cost:

As+1F (Ks+1) +χ

2

(Is+1Ks+1

)2, (12)

and then disinvesting the unit of capital at the end of s + 1 to reap amarginal revenue of

qs+1 = 1+χIs+1Ks+1

. (13)

Using the usual iterative substitution on (10), we have

qt =∞

∑s=t+1

(1R

)s−t [AsFK (Ks ) +

χ

2

(IsKs

)2]+ limT→∞

(1R

)Tqt+T .

(14)

Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) Macro Theory November 22, 2013 8 / 22

If limT→∞( 1R

)Tqt+T > 0,

qt >∞

∑s=t+1

(1R

)s−t [AsFK (Ks ) +

χ

2

(IsKs

)2], (15)

where the RHS is the stream of earnings that a marginal unit ofcapital permanently in place will generate for the firm, and the LHS isthe value to the firm of dismantling the marginal unit of capital andselling it on the market. That is, “>”says that the firm cannot beoptimizing: its capital stock is too high since discounted profits canbe raised by a permanent reduction in capital.A symmetric argument rules out the possibility thatlimT→∞

( 1R

)Tqt+T < 0. Therefore, limT→∞

( 1R

)Tqt+T = 0 and

qt =∞

∑s=t+1

(1R

)s−t [AsFK (Ks ) +

χ

2

(IsKs

)2], (16)

which means that the shadow price of installed capital equals itsdiscounted stream of future marginal products plus the discountedstream of its marginal contributions to the reduction in future capitalinstallation costs.Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) Macro Theory November 22, 2013 9 / 22

Investment Dynamics

(9) can be rewritten in terms of capital:

Kt+1 −Kt =qt − 1

χKt , (17)

and (10) can be rewritten as

qt+1 − qt = rqt − AFK (Kt+1)−χ

2

(It+1Kt+1

)2,=⇒

qt+1 − qt = rqt − AFK((

1+qt − 1

χ

)Kt

)− 12χ(qt+1 − 1)2(18)

where we use the facts that

Kt+1 =(1+

qt − 1χ

)Kt and

(It+1Kt+1

)2=

(qt+1 − 1

χ

)2.

In the steady state, both Kt and qt remain constant over time. (17)and (18) clearly shows that q = 1 and K satisfies

r = AFK(K). (19)

Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) Macro Theory November 22, 2013 10 / 22

The linearized two-equation system is

Kt+1 −Kt =Kχ(qt − 1) , (20)

qt+1 − qt =

(r −

AKFKK(K)

χ

)(qt − 1)− AFKK

(K) (Kt −K

).(21)

We can use the phase diagram to analyze the model’s dynamics. Theschedule, ∆Kt+1 = 0, means that it is horizontal at qt = q = 1. Theschedule, ∆qt+1 = 0 can be written as(

r −AKFKK

(K)

χ

)(qt − 1)− AFKK

(K) (Kt −K

)= 0,

which means that

dqdK|∆qt+1 =

AFKK(K)

r − AKFKK(K)

/χ< 0 (22)

because FKK(K)< 0. Therefore, the system is saddle-point-stable,

i.e., for any starting capital stock Kt , there is one and only one valueof qt that places the firm on the stable adjustment path.Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) Macro Theory November 22, 2013 11 / 22

Another Way to Check

More compactly,

[Kt+1qt+1

]=

1 Kχ

−AFKK(K)R − AKFKK (K )

χ

︸ ︷︷ ︸

K

[Ktqt

], (23)

where Kt = Kt −K and qt = qt − 1. The characteristic roots b forthe system satisfy

trace = b1 + b2 = 1+ R −AKFKK

(K)

χ> 2, (24)

det = b1b2 = R > 1. (25)

Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) Macro Theory November 22, 2013 12 / 22

(conti.) Hence, the discriminant should be positive because

∆ = trace (K )2 − 4 det (K ) =(1+ R −

AKFKK(K)

χ

)2− 4R

> (R − 1)2 > 0

which means that both roots are real. Also, because det > 1 andtrace > 2, the two roots must individually be positive. We can alsojudge the magnitudes of the two roots as follows:

p (b) = (b− b1) (b− b2) = 0 =⇒

p (1) = (1− b1) (1− b2) = 1− trace+ det =AKFKK

(K)

χ< 0

This can only be true if one root (say b1) is less than 1 and the otherroot is greater than 1. We can then conclude (and confirm thepredictions of the PD) that the equilibrium is saddle-point.

Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) Macro Theory November 22, 2013 13 / 22

Marginal and Average q

What is the relationship between q and the stock-market value of aunit of the firm’s capital: v/K .In the deterministic model,

1+ r =dt+1 + vt+1

vt, (26)

where vt+1 is the stock market value of the firm and dt+1 is thefirm’s dividend.(26) implies that at t,

vt =dt+11+ r

+vt+11+ r

. (27)

Continuing in this way, we have

vt =∞

∑s=t+1

(1R

)s−tds , (28)

provided a condition ruling out asset price bubbles:limT→∞

( 1R

)Tvt+T = 0.

Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) Macro Theory November 22, 2013 14 / 22

Multiplying Kt+1 the investment Euler equation gives

qtKt+1

=1R

[At+1FK (Kt+1, Lt+1)Kt+1 +

χ

2I 2t+1Kt+1

+ qt+1Kt+1

]=

1R

[At+1FK (Kt+1, Lt+1)Kt+1 +

χ

2I 2t+1Kt+1

+ qt+1 (Kt+2 − It+1)]

=1R

[At+1FK (Kt+1, Lt+1)Kt+1 −

χ

2I 2t+1Kt+1

− It+1 + qt+1Kt+2]

where we use that fact that qt+1 = 1+χIt+1Kt+1

. Since the productionfunction is linear homogenous, the forward iteration on qtKt+1 andusing the Euler equation give

qtKt+1 =∞

∑s=t+1

(1R

)s−t [AsF (Ks , Ls )−

χ

2I 2sKs− wsLs − Is

], vt .

(29)

Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) Macro Theory November 22, 2013 15 / 22

It means thatqt =

vtKt+1

, (30)

i.e., the shadow price of capital, q, equals the stock-market value of aunit of the firm’s capital: v/K (the marginal q equals the average q.)

The asset-market equilibrium:

R =

[At+1FK (Kt+1, Lt+1)− χ (It+1/Kt+1)

2 /2−It+1/Kt+1 + qt+1 (Kt+2/Kt+1)

]qt

, (31)

equating the gross rate of return on a unit of the firm capital to R.The numerator on the RHS equals dividends paid out per unit oft + 1 capital plus capital gain.

Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) Macro Theory November 22, 2013 16 / 22

A Linear-Quadratic Version of Lucas and Prescott (1971)

Consider an industry in which n identical competitive firms use asingle input, capital, to produce a single output. The industrydemand curve for output at t is

pt = A0 − A1Yt + ut , (32)

where A0,A1 > 0, pt is the price of output, Yt is industry output, andut is a demand shock.

The output of each firm is f0kt where kt is the firm’s capital stockand f0 > 1. Yt = nf0kt . The firms are competitive in the output andfactor markets and thus are price takers with respect to the sequencesof output prices {pt+j}∞

j=0 and capital prices {qt+j}∞j=0.

Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) Macro Theory November 22, 2013 17 / 22

Optimizing Problem

Suppose that the typical firm chooses a sequence of capital stocks,{kt+j}∞

j=0, to maximize the following expected discounted presentvalue:

vt = Et

{∞

∑j=0bj[pt+j (f0kt+j )− qt+j (kt+j − kt−1+j )

− 12d (kt+j − kt−1+j )2

]}, (33)

given that kt−1 given and d > 0 determines the cost of adjustment.

The Euler equation for this problem is

Et [d (kt − kt−1)− bd (kt+1 − kt )] = Et [pt f0 − qt + bqt+1] ,

Et

[kt+1 −

(1+

1b

)kt +

1bkt−1

]= − 1

bdEt [pt f0 − qt + bqt+1](34)

for any t.

Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) Macro Theory November 22, 2013 18 / 22

(conti.)[1−

(1+

1b

)L+

1bL2]Et [kt+1] = −

1bdEt [pt f0 − qt + bqt+1] ,[(

1− 1bL)(1− L)

]Et [kt+1] = −

1bdEt [pt f0 − qt + bqt+1] ,

(1− L)Et [kt+1] =d−1L−1

1− bL−1Et [pt f0 − qt + bqt+1] ,

(1− L)Et [kt+1] =d−1

1− bL−1Et [pt+1f0 − qt+1 + bqt+2] .(35)

Substituting (35) into (34), we can solve for kt :

kt = kt−1 +d−1

1− bL−1Et [pt f0 − qt + bqt+1] , (36)

which gives the firm’s rate of investment as a function of expectedfuture values of the prices of output and capital. Expectation hereplays a role in determining investment.

Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) Macro Theory November 22, 2013 19 / 22

Market Equilibrium

While individual firms take the price of output as given when makingdecisions, the price is affected by the actions of all firms together since

pt = A0 − A1 (nf0kt ) + ut . (37)

We now seek an equilibrium pair of sequences {p∗t }∞t=0 and {k∗t }

∞t=0

that satisfy the following two equilibrium conditions:1 Given the typical firm’s equilibrium capital sequence {k∗t }∞

t=0, pricesclear the market:

p∗t = A0 − A1 (nf0k∗t ) + ut . (38)

2 When the firm faces the sequence {p∗t }∞t=0 as given, the sequence

{k∗t }∞t=0 maximizes (33).

That is, in the equilibrium the firm is on its demand curve for capital(36) and the market clears so that (38) is satisfied.

Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) Macro Theory November 22, 2013 20 / 22

Procedure to Determine the Equilibrium

Substituting pt = A0 − A1 (nf0kt ) + ut into the Euler equation,

Et

[kt+1 −

(1+

1b

)kt +

1bkt−1

]= − 1

bdEt [pt f0 − qt + bqt+1] ,

(39)gives

Et

[kt+1 −

(1+

1b+A1nf 20d

)kt +

1bkt−1

]= − 1

bdEt [(A0 + ut ) f0 − qt + bqt+1] ,

Et [(1− λ1L) (1− λ2L) kt+1]

= − 1bdEt [(A0 + ut ) f0 − qt + bqt+1] ,

where λ1 < 1 < 1b < λ2.

Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) Macro Theory November 22, 2013 21 / 22

The solution is

Et [k∗t+1] = λ1k∗t +λ1d−1

1− λ−12 L−1Et [(A0 + ut+1) f0 − qt+1 + bqt+2] ,

(40)for any t, which gives the equilibrium sequence of kt . Substituting(40) into (39), we can solve for the equilibrium k:

k∗t = λ1k∗t−1 +λ1d−1

1− λ−12 L−1Et [(A0 + ut ) f0 − qt + bqt+1]

= λ1k∗t−1 +λ1d

∑i=0

(1

λ2

)iEt [(A0 + ut+i ) f0 − qt+i + bqt+1+i ] .

Substituting the equilibrium k sequence into the market demandschedule gives

p∗t = A0 − A1 (nf0k∗t ) + ut . (41)

That is, by construction, we have generated sequences, {p∗t }∞t=0 and

{k∗t }∞t=0 that satisfy the two equilibrium conditions.

Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) Macro Theory November 22, 2013 22 / 22