The State and the Capitalist Crisis

download The State and the Capitalist Crisis

of 19

Transcript of The State and the Capitalist Crisis

  • 8/8/2019 The State and the Capitalist Crisis

    1/19

    First published in February 1976. 2nd Edition, September 1978

    The State and the Capitalist Crisis

    David Yaffe, 1976-1998

    Foreword to the www edition

    This speech/article should be seen as a commentary on the ideological debate

    following the end of the post-war boom. It was a defence of the Marxist standpoint on

    the theory of crisis and a Marxist analysis of role of the state intervention in the

    capitalist economies after the Second World War. Much of the material, therefore,

    should prove valuable to the new generation of comrades returning to Marxism.

    It had, however, a number of weaknesses which have been corrected since that period.

    It did not integrate the theory of crisis and imperialism. Therefore, inevitably, it

    underestimated capital's ability to divide the working class. One of the mostsignificant features of 'neo-liberalism' has been the rapid increase of economic and

    political divisions among the working class in imperialist countries such as Britain,

    with skilled workers and the middle classes supporting the election of Tory

    governments on four occasions, as poverty increased for larger and larger sections of

    the working class. It has been the failure of neo-liberal policies over the last few years

    which, in turn, has driven the more privileged layers of the working class and middle

    classes back to Blair's Labour Party. For a discussion of the latter see David Yaffe's

    article The Politics and Economics of Globalisation from FRFI 137 and Robert

    Clough's Labour: a party fit for imperialism and much other material contained in the

    Marxism, Larkin Publications and Fight Racism! Fight Imperialism! sections of the

    RCG/FRFI web site.

    November 1998

    Foreword to the Second Edition

    The article The State and the Capitalist Crisis was based on a speech given to the

    VESVU Conference, Amsterdam in October 1975. Nearly three years have passed

    since that conference and it is clear that the arguments put forward in the article have

    been confirmed by events. While the average rate of inflation has temporarily fallen

    in the OECD area from a peak of 12.5% in 1975 to about 7% now, unemployment atthe beginning of 1978 in the OECD area was over 16 million, some half a million

    higher than at the trough of the 1975 recession. Recent trends indicate that matters

    will get worse with both inflation and unemployment rising together again.

    In Britain unemployment is over 1.6 million in spite of artificial state-run schemes to

    keep it down. Although the rate of inflation has fallen it should be remembered that

    1977 saw the greatest fall in living standards in any single year in Britain since

    statistics were kept. The rate of inflation will soon be rising again, even as

    unemployment increases. True to form the Labour government has used incomes

    policies and a compliant TUC General Council to hold living standards down. At

    present the Labour government wants to impose a 5% increase of wages in a periodwhen inflation is nearly 8% and starting to rise.

  • 8/8/2019 The State and the Capitalist Crisis

    2/19

    The last three years has seen an unprecedented attack on state sector workers in order

    to cut back state expenditure. In the Civil Service alone 12,000 jobs have been lost

    since April 1976. All the ideological stops were pulled out by the ruling class to

    divide state sector workers from workers in the private sector all the better to continue

    the attack on all workers. The government-allocated funds going into Education andHealth Service sectors are now simply inadequate to maintain the already poor

    standard of service that was normal during the post-war boom. A serious deterioration

    in these sectors is rapidly taking place.

    Most of the ideological positions countered in the article have been used by the press

    and the Labour and Trade Union leadership to hold back any serious opposition to

    these attacks on the working class. Even those opposing the Labour government

    policies have been unable to mount a serious counter attack. They rely on precisely

    those ideological positions underconsumptionist, regeneration of industry which

    undermine any united class response.*

    There is one point in the article which needs developing. The article includes a

    critique of those sections of the working class movement who remain tied within the

    framework of debate set by the bourgeoisie. What should be pointed out is that this is

    not simply a question of their holding 'incorrect ideas', but rather an expression of

    their own material interests, their own real ties to the continued existence of British

    imperialism. Opportunist currents necessarily develop in the working class movement

    and become a major barrier to building a revolutionary movement in the working

    class. Whether they consist of the Labour and Trade Union leaders who argue for

    wage restraint and responsible trade unionists or academics and other pseudo lefts

    who see wage increases as a significant factor causing inflation, such opportunist

    currents have an interest in the maintenance of the capitalist system.** Their major

    role will be to contain the movement which will necessarily develop as the working

    class is forced by the ever-deepening crisis to defend its living standards.

    David Yaffe

    2nd September 1978

    * This is developed in my article 'Trade Unions and the State: The Struggle against

    the Social Contract' in Revolutionary Communist 7 pp22-29.

    ** See 'Which Way Forward for Communists? Critique of the British Road to

    Socialism' in Revolutionary Communist 7 especially p18ff and also the 'Editorial' in

    the same issue for a discussion of these points.

  • 8/8/2019 The State and the Capitalist Crisis

    3/19

    The State and the Capitalist Crisis

    Introduction

    It is very interesting to compare the discussion about what was taken for Marxianeconomics over the last twenty years with the period we are moving into today. I

    think it can be said that in the period of the post-war boom the bourgeoisie was

    confident enough to start talking about and discussing Marx. The whole discussion

    about Marxian economics reflected this confidence. It became fashionable to show

    how Keynes had Marx as precursor or how near to Marx Keynes was or how near to

    Keynes Marx was and so on. A book Marx and Modern Economics [1] [2] Once

    again we have the ideas of Adam Smith and Ricardo as central components of the

    discussion about the nature of the present crisis. Published in 1968 contained the main

    contributions over the period on this issue. Its title sums up the whole approach. The

    bourgeoisie was confident, it was living through the post-war boom. It was witnessing

    the greatest expansion of capitalist production in its history, and so it could be 'liberal'with Marx. Today we see something quite different. The trend has changed as that

    confidence has been undermined. A major discussion is taking place between

    economists, which brings back to life the central theories raised by classical political

    economy in the period before Marx.

    The bourgeoisie, soon after Marx had written his devastating critique of political

    economy, completely dropped the categories used and turned to a standpoint which

    was to become the foundation of neoclassical economics. The very categories which

    Ricardo had developed, in particular his labour theory of value, had become too

    dangerous. The very understanding of capitalism as a class society had to be brushed

    aside. For the bourgeoisie after Marx the question was not whether there was a

    division of interest between the working class and the capitalist class. It was not only

    how much the working class but the capitalist class, the landlord, the technician and

    every other freebooting hireling of bourgeois society contributed to the product. The

    division was not between the workers and capitalists but an harmonious division

    between all sections of society. The basic categories that classical political economy

    had developed and that Marx had exposed to a revolutionary critique, were, in

    cowardly fashion, laid to rest. Yet today those categories of classical political

    economy have been revived. A ruling class in decay has to turn to those warriors of

    yesterday to find its weapons as the class struggle, class divisions become threatening

    again. They are able to return to classical political economy in spite of Marx'srevolutionary critique precisely because the Marxist movement is so weak today. It,

    therefore, becomes necessary to show not only how vital the categories developed by

    Marx are for an understanding of the present crisis but also how those categories are

    political categories and not economic in the narrow sense of the term. I will show how

    we can understand the present crisis from the standpoint of the categories developed

    by Marx and in so doing lay the basis for a political defence of the working class.

    The first point I want to make is that Marx was not an economist. Marx was not a

    writer of a book on economics. He wrote a critique of political economy. That is, a

    critique of the ideas with which the bourgeoisie attempted to understand its own

    society. In that sense any critique of those ideas today in relation to the crisis is acritique of political economy. But it is more than that, because underlying the

  • 8/8/2019 The State and the Capitalist Crisis

    4/19

    solutions that the bourgeoisie puts forward to solve its crisis are those ideas. A

    critique of those ideas is, therefore, the basis of a critique of the very solutions which

    the bourgeoisie wishes to use to solve the present crisis at the expense of the working

    class. So immediately we are involved with a political question, we are involved in a

    discussion of the various solutions the different classes in society wish to utilize to

    overcome the present crisis. That is my starting point. I am not talking abouteconomics, in the narrow sense of the term, but about a critique of political economy,

    a critique of the ideas with which the bourgeoisie attempts to understand its own

    society. And this includes a critique of those sections of the working class movement

    who remain tied within the framework of debate set by the bourgeoisie.

    The way capitalism presents itself

    Why do we need a theory of crisis? Is such a theory really necessary in dealing with

    the present problems of world capitalism? I want to explain why a theory of crisis is

    an essential political weapon. The major problems faced in understanding capitalismarise because of the way capitalist relations of production appear to the working class,

    the capitalists and to those studying it. Things appear in inverted form. Everything

    appears to be the opposite of what it actually is. Let us consider an example of this

    that Marx discussed in Capital. The wage-labour relation seems to be an equal

    relation. The worker sells his labour power to the capitalist and the capitalist buys that

    labour power and there seems to be a fair exchange. In the working class movement

    in Britain there has grown the slogan 'A fair day's pay for a fair day's work'. This

    results from the idea that there can be some kind of real equality in the exchange of

    labour power, in the worker selling his capacity to work for a period of time, and what

    the capitalist pays for that sale. Yet we know that this exchange is an unequal

    exchange, because underlying it is the fact that the worker works a longer time than

    the time necessary to produce the consumption goods required to reproduce the

    worker's capacity to work. And in that time differential, part of the working day is

    taken gratis by the capitalist. It is in the time that is the difference between the time

    the worker works and the time necessary to produce the goods that the worker

    requires that we have the source of profit. And yet in the exchange of a worker's

    labour power for money, in the process of being paid wages for a job of work done,

    this unequal 'exchange' has completely disappeared. It seems as though an equal

    relationship has taken place. The source of capitalist profit, the fact that the worker is

    exploited, is completely hidden from view.

    Now when we come to discuss inflation this kind of problem manifests itself again. If

    you immediately accept that an equal relationship (exchange) has taken place, then

    the notion that if wages rise a price rise must follow seems to conform with common

    sense. You have a theory, which is the general theory that the bourgeoisie uses, that

    final prices are made up of different types of costs. You have the costs of buying

    machinery, the costs of buying raw materials, the costs of wages and the cost that is

    often sneaked in as being a cost like all other costs, that of profits. This latter cost is

    something to be paid to the capitalist for risking or lending his capital, or for

    supervising production and so on. Various apologetic theories have been put forward

    to justify profits. Once all these costs are added up together then the final price is

    computed. This is the standpoint of the individual capitalist. It is how the individualcapitalist experiences the problem.

  • 8/8/2019 The State and the Capitalist Crisis

    5/19

    On this commonsensical view if wages rise, so must the final price. It only needs a

    little imagination to then argue that wage increases are a primary cause of inflation.

    On the other hand according to a popular left-wing view it is the price rises of

    monopolies, the activities of multinational corporations in securing high profits that is

    the primary cause of inflation. In a similar way the national chauvinists from theimperialist countries have seen in the increasing raw material and oil prices, resulting

    from the 'selfish' activities of among others the oil states, a primary cause of inflation.

    In all these cases, different rising costs, which themselves need to be explained, are

    part of the explanation of rising prices. A rise of wages causes inflation, a rise in

    profits causes inflation and so on. In other words, inflation, which is the rise of prices

    is explained in this remarkable conception of the bourgeois economists, by rising

    prices. And that sums up the brilliant achievement of many bourgeois academics in

    attempting to explain inflation.

    If we are to explain inflation we have to explain why those prices rose, we have to

    explain why money wages increase, why raw material prices have increased andfinally why, in spite of the increase of the mass of profits the rate of profit has fallen.

    This is what a theory of the present crisis has to attempt to do. It cannot be done by

    explaining rises in prices by rises of other prices. But the problem is that 'common

    sense' views tied to the appearance of capitalist production have a lot of appeal. In

    Britain when the Heath Conservative government was in power they put forward the

    view that wage costs, wage increases were the fundamental cause of inflation. They

    argued that a wage freeze was necessary to stop inflation. Unfortunately for the

    government when they introduced a wage freeze prices continued to rise. How were

    they to explain this? Well the government did not say that the problem was the

    contradictions of the capitalist system and not wage increases. No they had to

    temporarily shift the blame elsewhere. It was the foreigners, it was those other

    countries, who were putting their prices up, so that import prices of goods brought

    into Britain were very much higher. Inflation increased because of high import prices,

    nothing whatsoever to do with the British, or the capitalist system but the foreigners

    who were putting their prices up. And so at each and every stage those trying to

    explain inflation and deal with its political consequences always have to avoid the real

    issues facing them. Otherwise they would be forced to question the very system of

    production they support. It is the workers, it is the large firms, or the importers, the

    blame has to shift elsewhere.

    We now turn to another argument related to the way capitalism appears. In theadvanced capitalist countries over the last ten to fifteen years or so, we have seen an

    enormous growth of state expenditure. The state in many countries today utilizes

    more than 50% of the gross national product. Thus has arisen the commonsensical

    view that as inflation has increased with the growth of state expenditure, then the

    cause of inflation is the growth of state expenditure. What could be more obvious?

    You can draw various graphs and produce volumes of statistics and it will appear that

    as state expenditure rises the rate of inflation increases as well. And so the cause of

    inflation is said to be the growth of state expenditure. This view has been put forward

    by a section of the academic profession who, I suppose, we could call monetarists (it

    is not the best description of them). What they see as the cause of inflation is the

    continually growing money supply and the failure of governments to control thisgrowth. They argue that the money supply is continuously rising ('out of control') so

  • 8/8/2019 The State and the Capitalist Crisis

    6/19

    that the government can finance its own rapidly rising expenditure. Therefore they

    say, if you stop the rise of the money supply, if you slow it down and cut back state

    expenditure, then inflation will slow down as a result.

    We will find that the growth of state expenditure cannot explain inflation. On the

    contrary, the rise of inflation and the rise of state expenditure follow from thecontradictions of the capitalist system itself. They are particular expressions of these

    contradictions at a certain stage of the historical development of capitalist production.

    It is because of the way things appear, because state expenditure has grown and prices

    have risen at the same time, that the crude view that the growth of state expenditure is

    the cause of inflation has come to the fore.

    There is a further feature to this problem which has surfaced as a major political

    discussion in Britain. It is in Britain, a weak link in the capitalist chain, where we

    already see the central arguments which the bourgeoisie intends to use to begin its

    attack on the working class. The working class has been divided into two types. There

    are those who are productive workers, and are good for capitalism as they produceprofitable (marketable) goods, and those who are unproductive workers, who are bad

    as they consume too large a share of the profits produced. It turns out that the major

    part of unproductive workers are employed in the state sector. As the state sector has

    been growing and is seen as a primary cause of inflation, the very simple proposition

    has been put forward that too much investment is going into sectors of the economy

    employing unproductive workers. This fact underlies the present crisis of capitalism.

    And so the call and cry has gone out to massively reduce the numbers of unproductive

    worker. A larger part of society's investment must go into the profitable sector and

    relatively more productive workers must be employed.

    This view is shared by both the right and the left in Britain today. This is a very

    important trend and a very dangerous one. The ruling class needs to split the working

    class into productive and unproductive workers as a prelude to attacking all workers.

    It has no obvious allies to aid it in the form, for example, of a conservative peasantry

    which would support the ruling class in its attack on the working class. So it must

    split the working class. And it has developed the ideological basis for doing this from

    the division between productive and unproductive workers.

    The most extreme right-wing view of this kind has been put forward by a monetarist

    who is now the leading adviser to the conservative opposition in Britain, Sir Keith

    Joseph. It is worth quoting from him to show how this issue has become a very realquestion in the minds of these who will attempt to solve the crisis at the expense of

    the working class. He says:

    "Yet is there any substitute for the entrepreneur, from the one-man businessman to the

    tycoon? Someone has to create the wealth. State enterprise has yet to do so. Until now

    it has lived off the surplus created by the private sector. But as the state sector grows

    and a new subsidised private sector with it, designed to perpetuate occupational

    population patterns inherited from the industrial revolution the private sector is in

    danger of collapsing under the burden." [3]

    Here we see the perversity of it all. We see a return to the standpoint of Adam Smith.Sir Keith Joseph is calling for a new bourgeois revolution in the period of the decay

  • 8/8/2019 The State and the Capitalist Crisis

    7/19

    of the capitalist mode of production. He calls for a new bourgeois revolution to solve

    the present crisis of capitalism.

    The real problem is the enormously growing state sector. What we have to do is

    return industry to private capital, and not only to private capital but to that special

    individual the entrepreneur. The situation has got so bad for the bourgeoisie that theydare say that someone has to create the wealth and suggest that this is the

    entrepreneur. So you see the stand and the lengths that the bourgeoisie has to go to try

    and justify its present positions.

    I want to leave the discussion of these central problems connected with the

    appearances of capitalist production and how they give tremendous strength to the

    views of the bourgeoisie about the nature of the present crisis. I shall now discuss

    briefly what a theory of crisis should actually attempt to do, what it should show and

    so on.

    The components of a theory of crisis

    There are three aspects to the theory of crisis. The first, from a Marxist standpoint, is

    to show that socialism is possible, that it is not some utopian viewpoint, but is

    scientifically grounded in the development of capitalism itself. So the idea of social

    planning, the idea of running an economy on the lines of a socialised economy, not on

    the lines of private enterprise, the idea of planning for people's needs rather than to

    produce for profit, has to be something that is possible. The theory of crisis has to

    show how all tendencies in capitalism itself indicate that socialism actually is a

    possibility, that it is not a utopian dream.

    The second aspect is to show that socialism is a necessity. That is that the problems

    facing the working class, and in that sense the mass of the population, are not

    resolvable within capitalism. Capitalism cannot solve the basic problems facing

    humanity. So the second aspect of the theory of crisis is that socialism must be

    necessary if the basic problems facing the working class are to be resolved.

    The third question that must be answered is why, in a period of capitalist decay which

    has lasted since the beginning of the twentieth century, is it that we still have

    capitalism? Why is it that the dominant views in the working class movement are

    those of the reformists, who hold the position that capitalism, with better or more

    radical government, can resolve the problems facing the working class? Why is it thatthese views generally have been accepted in the working class movement and why

    has revolutionary Marxism so far been rejected? The first part of my talk was to give

    part of an answer to this question, to actually show that it is the way that capitalism

    appears to those who are involved in production, distribution and so on, which gives

    tremendous strength to bourgeois ideas about the nature of the capitalist system. If we

    look at our own time, the period of the post-war boom, we can see that ideas, to the

    effect that the state can act in a neutral way in the interests of all sections of the

    population and not just the ruling class, have been given tremendous strength by the

    enormous growth of production over the last twenty or thirty years, and the increasing

    role the state has played in the capitalist economy. It seems to be the case that the

    state can play a leading role, can attempt to redistribute income in the interests of theworking class. Scientific Marxism is required to combat such views. To show this I

  • 8/8/2019 The State and the Capitalist Crisis

    8/19

    shall first of all examine incorrect theories of crisis, and then briefly discuss the

    Marxian theory of crisis before going on to the question of the capitalist state.

    Incorrect views of the capitalist crisis

    The first incorrect view of the crisis I want to deal with has generally been called anunderconsumptionist view of crisis. This theory argues that an increase in

    consumption if, for example, the state increases its expenditure can rescue the

    crisis. This is because the crisis is primarily due to the lack of consuming power in

    society. In classical times Malthus argued a view that was similar to this, except that

    he wanted the unproductive consumption of landlords and the aristocracy to increase.

    Today we have the state that can play a central role for this argument. If the state can

    increase its expenditure, if it can be a stimulus to production, then the crisis can be

    overcome.

    An underconsumptionist view of the crisis, the theory of the permanent arms

    economy, has been put forward by Michael Kidron and Tony Cliff to explain the post-war boom. [4] It explains the generation of the post-war boom as being due to the

    growth of arms expenditure. The reformist implications of this standpoint have never

    been grasped by the writers. Nevertheless others have taken a similar view with

    regard to all state expenditure rather than a particular component of it. They see a

    solution to the present crisis with the state increasing its interventionist role in the

    capitalist economy, rather than decreasing it. This is the dominant view in the British

    labour movement. The state has to increase its involvement in manufacturing industry

    or extend Public Works if the crisis is to be solved and unemployment reduced. The

    argument is often put in the following way by, for example, the Communist Party of

    Great Britain and many other groups on the radical left: if you reduce the wages of the

    working class or the expenditure of the state then it will make matters worse. By

    reducing overall consuming power, less will be spent on the commodities produced

    and as a result the capitalists will not be able to sell their commodities. They will

    cease to invest and unemployment will increase. This is a viewpoint that has been put

    forward very strongly in the recent period. It is in fact nonsense because what the

    capitalists are concerned about is selling their commodities at a profit not just selling

    their commodities. The condition for investment to increase is precisely an increase of

    unemployment and a reduction of wages below the value of labour power. These are

    the conditions necessary for the capitalists to restore the rate of profit.

    Another incorrect view of the capitalist crisis has been put forward by among othersGlyn and Sutcliffe. They explain the crisis as being due to two factors. One is

    increasing international competition making it more and more difficult for cost

    increases to be passed on in the final prices of the product to be sold. The other is the

    main increase of costs, the growing wages of the working class, resulting from the

    increased combativity of the working class movement leading to both direct increases

    and indirect increases through changes of the 'social wage'. [5] So you have a squeeze

    on profits, a squeeze which is due to competition preventing prices going up on the

    one hand, and wages eating into profits on the other. This view is a view which is

    almost identical to the arguments put forward by Adam Smith. The difference is that

    in those far off days the problem was not the inability to pass on rising costs by

    increasing prices, that is of competition preventing prices being raised, but ofcompetition driving prices down. The fall in profits then was said to be due to

  • 8/8/2019 The State and the Capitalist Crisis

    9/19

    competition driving prices down while wages more or less remained the same or

    increased as accumulation accelerated. The bourgeoisie saw the real problem as too

    much competition and too high wages. Today we have the same basic argument.

    Profits are falling because international competition is preventing prices going up

    sufficiently and wages are too high. Marx once said that history repeats itself, 'the first

    time as tragedy, the second as farce'. Today we see the farce of the crude repetition ofviews long since criticised and rejected. We need to examine Marx's theory of crisis

    to lay the foundation of a critique of the above views.

    The Marxian theory of crisis

    I now briefly want to examine the Marxian theory of crisis, The point about capitalist

    production is that it is production for profit. A commodity is not merely a use-value

    but also a value, an exchange-value. Commodities are not produced unless they make

    a profit for the capitalist class. Labour is employed by capital to increase the profits of

    the capitalist class or to lead to the realisation of these profits. The commodity is

    therefore a use-value and an exchange-value. Now if you increase the productivity oflabour, which means that you produce more commodities in the same time, the value

    of the individual commodity falls. This is a critical point. By increasing the

    productivity of labour it means that the same commodities contain less value than

    before. So you have to produce more commodities to have more value than before.

    This expresses itself by the fact that to produce the same values as before, capital

    investment has to be continually increased. This is because increases in the

    productivity of labour mean that less labour is employed by a given amount of capital.

    If capital investment did not increase then the values produced would not increase,

    accumulation would not take place and unemployment would grow. So that

    increasing the productivity of labour is a contradictory process for capital. Many more

    use-values are produced, but each use-value contains less value. An increase in the

    productivity of labour is expressed, under capitalist conditions of production, as a rise

    in the organic composition of capital. That is, more capital is invested as constant

    capital, on machinery and raw materials than as variable capital, that is paid out as

    wages for productive workers. So that an increase in the productivity of labour

    involves an increase in the organic composition of capital, this value relation between

    fixed capital and raw materials, and labour employed. Profits arise out of the

    exploitation of workers alone. However the rate of profit is measured over the total

    capital invested not just that invested in labour power. So that as productivity

    increases, there are relatively fewer workers exploited by a given amount of capital

    and a larger cost of machinery etc over which to measure the rate of profit. Thismeans that there is a tendency of the rate of profit to fall. This is (the basis of) Marx's

    theory of the tendency of the rate of profit to fall. [6] It is a form of the theory which

    classical political economy could not discover, and it is a theory that is just as much

    rejected today because of its revolutionary implications as it was after Marx's time.

    The tendency of the rate of profit to fall is an expression of the central contradiction

    of capitalist production. The more capital is invested, the more the tendency of the

    rate of profit to fall asserts itself. The important point is this, that an increase in the

    productivity of labour means in Marx's analysis an increase in the rate of exploitation

    of the working class. This is because less time is needed to reproduce what the

    workers require, more time of the working day is available for profits. But the sameprocess which increases the rate of exploitation of the working class expresses itself

  • 8/8/2019 The State and the Capitalist Crisis

    10/19

    as a fall in the rate of profit. So the rate of profit falls not because workers are less

    exploited and wages rise but because they are more exploited and the value of labour

    power falls. And that expresses in heightened form the contradiction of the capitalist

    system of production. This is really Marx's revolutionary contribution. Because of this

    at a certain stage in the accumulation process when capital has invested too much in

    relation to the rate of exploitation, profits are continually rising but not sufficiently forthe amount of total capital invested, at a certain stage in this process the capitalist

    crisis occurs, and the crisis is an indication that capital has been overaccumulated.

    Too much is invested given the mass of profits produced. Too much is invested given

    the rate of exploitation of labour.

    The capitalist crisis

    The capitalist crisis is both the expression of the contradictions of capitalism, an

    expression of the disease of a system, and of the way capitalism attempts to cure itself

    internally. It is both the disease and at the same time the way to a cure. Too much

    capital has been invested, and in the crisis capital is destroyed as capital, machineryand buildings are not used and capital is written off. Firms are forced out of business

    and become bankrupt. A large amount of capital in the crisis no longer functions as

    capital and can lay claim to the mass of profits produced. The amount of capital

    laying a claim to the mass of profits is reduced. In the crisis the process of

    concentration and centralisation of capital takes place. In general it is only the more

    productive capitals that survive, the least efficient go to the wall first, become

    bankrupt first. Large firms buy up small firms in this process where only the most

    efficient survive. In the crisis unemployment begins to increase, and capitalists are in

    a stronger position to force the working class to accept a reduction of wages below the

    normal value of labour power, below the normal levels that have been achieved in

    previous periods. In that sense the rate of profit can be increased because of the

    reduction of wages below the value of labour power.

    The capitalist crisis begins to create the conditions for a new period of capital

    accumulation. It reduces wages below the value of labour power, it destroys less

    efficient capitals, and in this way attempts to restore the rate of profit for capital.

    Whether it can do this or not, whether capital can reduce wages below the value of

    labour power, and is able to discipline the working class to work at a higher level of

    intensity and so on, is a political question. Every crisis poses before the capitalist

    system the question as to whether it can survive, whether it can go on to a new round

    of capital accumulation.

    We are now able to understand the significance of the two world wars within this

    context of the capitalist crisis. During the whole inter-war period, it became clear that

    the first World War alone and the great depression were not able to resolve the crisis

    of capitalism, to usher in a new period of capital accumulation. In spite of the massive

    destruction of capital, and very high levels of unemployment during the inter-war

    years the working class was still too strong. The Russian revolution had had a major

    effect on working class resistance to the capitalists in the whole of Europe up to the

    early 1930s. So the actual effects of the First World War and the period after the war

    were insufficient to restore profitability. It took a Second World War and the defeats

    of the working class expressed by the victory of fascism to recreate these conditions.

  • 8/8/2019 The State and the Capitalist Crisis

    11/19

    I wish to go over the factors, briefly, which were important at the end of the Second

    World War. First of all we have the massive destruction of capital in the war itself.

    Secondly we had, in the period before the war and leading up to the war, the greatest

    defeats of the working class in its history. Fascism and war itself were expressions of

    those defeats. Perhaps the conditions were laid for those defeats when the main

    leaders of the working class movement in Europe decided to support their owncapitalist class and participated in the war between the major capitalist states. The

    major exceptions to this were the Bolsheviks in Russia. However fascism and war

    resulted from the crushing blows struck against the Italian, Spanish, German,

    Japanese and French working class. After the war in Japan and Germany, the working

    class having been defeated could be controlled and easily 'persuaded' into acceptance

    of a new period of capital accumulation. The rate of profit, for example, in Germany,

    once reconstruction began after the war, was the highest that is has ever been in its

    history. The governments carrying through this process, and this was true for Japan,

    could be right-wing conservative ones.

    In those countries where the working class had not been defeated by fascism or wherethe bourgeoisie had been thoroughly compromised through its relationship with the

    fascists it was the actual ability to integrate the leadership of the working class that

    was central in the reconstruction period. This occurred through the social democratic

    party in Britain, the Labour Party, and in France and Italy, by bringing the Communist

    Party into government. This process was necessary if capital was to be able to achieve

    the conditions, including a low level of wages, that were necessary for the restoration

    of capital accumulation.

    The third and equally important factor was that the inter-imperialist rivalries which

    expressed themselves in battles between the major advanced capitalist powers during

    the Second World War were temporarily overcome by the end of the Second World

    War. One country dominated and dictated to the world economy, the United States of

    America. In other words the conflict between capitalist nations had provisionally been

    resolved by one country dominating the capitalist world. This process has a vivid

    statistical expression. Just before the Second World War, the US share of world

    industrial output in 1937 was 41%. By 1953 it had increased to 52%. Today, it is

    below the 1937 figure at approximately 40%. In other words the conditions before the

    Second World War are actually the conditions in terms of world industrial power

    which are beginning to be established again today. For example, the EEC's share of

    world industrial output in 1937 was 22%, it fell to 16% in 1953 after the war and by

    1970 it was back to the pre-war level of 22%. It is possible to confirm this picture bylooking at statistics for the export of goods and the export of capital as well as other

    factors. The conditions of world power over the post-war boom have led to a situation

    that is very similar to that before the Second World War. Only the situation of Japan

    and Britain Japan has seen a considerable growth and Britain a continual decline. [7]

    have changed.

    After the Second World War the dominance of the US was a major factor in the

    recovery of the capitalist system. The US could give credits to Germany and Japan

    once that it had decided to rebuild these nations' economies again in view of the threat

    that the extension of nationalised property relations into Eastern Europe posed for the

    capitalist system. The conditions for profitable capital accumulation existed, what waslacking was the funds and the US could provide them. So that the destruction of the

  • 8/8/2019 The State and the Capitalist Crisis

    12/19

    war, the existence of a working class which had been defeated or could be 'persuaded'

    into acceptance of a new period of capital accumulation, and the dominance by one

    country of the world economy laid the basis for the post-war boom.

    State expenditure and the post-war boom

    One dominant feature of the post-war boom, in particular during the last 10 to 15

    years, has been the growth of the state's role in the capitalist economy. The rest of my

    discussion will be concerned with the contradictions of state expenditure. I shall

    examine just what those contradictions are and see why the growth of state

    expenditure is not responsible for inflation. I shall show why the present crisis is a

    severe crisis for capitalism and how it can reach classical proportions in the not too

    distant future.

    For a whole period of time capital has attempted to overcome the fall of the rate of

    profit by pushing up prices to levels which, in monetary terms, maintain the rate of

    profit. To do this it was necessary to have a continual process of credit expansionwhich the inter-involvement of capitalist firms with the banks and the state made

    possible. The necessary conditions for the capitalists to sell their commodities at

    prices higher than those really merited by the conditions of production is that credit

    has to be extended in one form or another to allow these higher prices to be realised,

    that is to allow commodities to be sold at the higher prices. If credit is not extended,

    the commodities would not be sold and the real conditions of production would

    express themselves by a severe fall in the rate of profit.

    What the capitalists are attempting to do when they increase their prices is to

    overcome this fall in the rate of profit. They do not increase prices to make super-

    profits as the monopoly profit theories of inflation would have it, but to try and

    maintain conditions of profitability in a situation where the rate of profit is falling. In

    the period between the two world wars, in fact from around 1895 onwards, we have a

    continuous increase of prices, outside the years of the great depression, in spite of the

    large increases in the productivity of labour taking place. The reason for this was that

    production was allowed to expand by the extensive use of credit, so that capitalists

    could attempt to maintain their rate of profit by increasing prices. But the growth of

    credit does not cause the increase of prices, rather the growth of credit is necessary if

    these prices are to be realised, that is if the commodities are to be sold at these prices.

    If credit was not extended the individual capitalist would be immediately faced with a

    severe fall of the rate of profit and would cease to invest so precipitating a severecrisis. The expansion of credit postpones the crisis. Production is allowed to expand

    through the expansion of credit.

    After the Second World War, however, this process alone was insufficient to keep

    capital accumulating at an adequate rate. The state itself, more and more, had to play

    a significant role in stimulating production, in particular through deficit financing and

    in guaranteeing the conditions [for] capital accumulation itself. [8] And it is to this

    process I now wish to turn.

    State expenditure by allowing the crisis to be postponed, exacerbates the very

    conditions that made state expenditure necessary, that is the tendency of the rate ofprofit to fall. This is really what is central to my position on state expenditure. State

  • 8/8/2019 The State and the Capitalist Crisis

    13/19

    expenditure, by postponing the immediate consequences of the fall in the rate of

    profit, by allowing capital accumulation to expand, necessitates an increase of credit

    and therefore the money supply to finance its own expenditure. In such a way the

    state maintains the general conditions of capital accumulation, and supports the

    attempts of capital to stave off the fall in the rate of profit. However it is just this

    process which is a contradictory one.

    In spite of the intervention of the state the rate of return on capital (this gives some

    empirical indication as to what is happening to the overall rate of profit of capital) has

    been continually falling over the main part of the post-war period, in particular since

    about 1958-60 onwards. The capitalist does not experience the rate of profit falling

    directly, rather it is experienced as a continual rise in costs. The next part examines

    the role of the state in this process.

    The first point about state expenditure is that it is usually associated with a so-called

    full employment policy. That is, the capitalist state did not allow unemployment to

    increase to the levels that existed in the inter-war years. This is a part of the cost paidfor integrating the working class in the process of restoration of capitalist production

    after the war and of keeping the institutions etc of the class tied to the machinery of

    the state. The point about a 'full' employment policy is that it means that once the

    process of capital accumulation is underway, the capitalist is not able to reduce wages

    below the value of labour power as a means of restoring the rate of profit. Because

    most workers are employed the capitalists do not have the strength to force wages

    down. However, real wages after tax in most advanced capitalist countries have risen

    at a rate below that of productivity growth although the standard of living of workers,

    in the sense of use-values consumed has increased. This means that the value of

    labour power has continually fallen in spite of increases in the standard of living.

    Values and use-values are not the same thing. The more you increase the productivity

    of labour the more use-values you produce in the same time so that each commodity

    contains less value than before. So according to this argument what has happened is

    that the value of labour power has fallen and there has been an increase in the rate of

    exploitation in spite of the improvement in living standards. So to return to the central

    argument, one method has not been available to the capitalist class to restore the rate

    of profit and that is to reduce the standard of living of the working class by reducing

    wages below the value of labour power. This means that the only way open to the

    individual capitalist to increase profits is to increase the productivity of labour, to

    continually create conditions which allow the reproduction requirements of the

    working class, the consumption goods etc, to be produced in less time than before, i.e.by increasing the rate of exploitation. And this very method of increasing the

    productivity of labour leads for capital as a whole to a fall in the rate of profit. So the

    fact that the state has a 'full' employment policy means that the tendencies in capitalist

    society to increase the productivity of labour are strengthened and this accentuates the

    tendency of the rate of profit to fall.

    The second point in relation to state expenditure involves the effect of the increase of

    social services and welfare expenditure are on the rate of profit of individual capital.

    We must make a distinction here between the general rate of profit and the rate of

    profit of the individual capitalist. The general rate of profit is calculated from the total

    profits (surplus-value) produced over the total capital invested, but the individualcapitalist has to pay part of his profit to the banks as interest for money borrowed, and

  • 8/8/2019 The State and the Capitalist Crisis

    14/19

    a contribution to taxation to finance the expenditure of the capitalist state itself. So the

    general rate of profit falls, but the individual rate of profit falls further because of

    increased deductions for interest as borrowing increases and as the state's expenditure

    grows. The next section will examine the growth of the state sector.

    We must examine first what social services are, what it is to give higher pensions andunemployment benefit, what it is to increase health and education expenditure and so

    on. Is it an increase in the wages of the working class? Does it contribute to capital

    accumulation and make profits for the capitalist class? My general answer to these

    questions is that far from increasing the profits of the capitalist class, these

    expenditures are a deduction from these profits. I want to concentrate on health and

    education expenditure because the role of unemployment benefits and pensions are

    reasonably clear. People who get pensions do not produce surplus-value for the

    capitalist. Neither do the unemployed make any contribution to profit making. So we

    can regard these expenditures as a cost to capital, as a deduction from surplus value.

    We reject the concept of a 'social wage' to cover this expenditure. These expenditures

    do not form part of the variable capital (capital invested in labour power for thepurpose of increasing profits) and in general are so low in relation to the average

    working wage that they do not, in any sense, merit the designation wage, let alone

    'social'. However, health and education are more complex. I shall examine them in

    some detail.

    To begin with education. What does education do? What has its expansion achieved?

    Well, my argument is that a very small amount of education is useful for capitalist

    production in the sense of increasing value and surplus value. Education of course

    plays an ideological role. But most of it is useless as far as production is concerned.

    This is why there has been a move in most capitalist countries to cut down

    expenditure on the university sector and expand on the more 'technical' sectors. It

    becomes clear, for example, that universities cannot produce a very useful product for

    capitalist industry when the rate of profit is falling and the crisis is deepening. During

    the period of the post-war boom, with the enormous increase of the mass of profits,

    the situation seems to be a reasonable one, and the bourgeoisie could be 'liberal' about

    education and was prepared to extend the university and other sectors of education.

    But once the crisis begins to assert itself, the call is raised to cut down the length of

    courses in those countries such as Germany, where courses extended over many

    years, to the three years which is normal in Britain. The 'advantages' of three-year

    courses are suddenly being recognised in a number of countries in Europe at the

    present time. The reason for this is that the extra years are not only useless as far asprofitable production is concerned but very costly as well. Most education

    expenditure does not help once capitalism begins to move into a crisis situation and

    so, with or without the best of liberal intentions, it will be cut back.

    A small part of education expenditure increases the value of labour power without

    directly increasing the surplus value produced. Those who are engaged with training

    productive workers are involved with changing the special commodity labour power

    itself. The production of this special commodity labour power differs from the

    production of other commodities. What is involved is the training of a worker who is

    then going to sell his labour power to the capitalist to be exploited in the process of

    production. Now if this labour power contains an element of surplus value, an elementof profit, then the capitalist who buys that labour power will be paying more than is

  • 8/8/2019 The State and the Capitalist Crisis

    15/19

    necessary. He will be paying for labour power which contains an extra element of

    profit. And this the capitalist class is not prepared to do. They can also avoid doing

    this. If labour power with a particular skill becomes too expensive, you can do away

    with using that skill, you can introduce another method of production which does not

    need that skill. You'll find, for example in industries like computers and other

    industries associated with the so-called technological revolution that at one stage youhad people working there and carrying out basic processes who were university

    trained. Today the time has come where they can do away with most of these skills

    altogether and workers who have had an ordinary education (secondary school) can

    usually work in these industries. That is an indication of how capital determines

    whether it is going to pay surplus value as part of labour power or not. In general it

    won't do it, and in general this is the reason that the state has taken over education.

    Because the state is an employer that does not have to make a profit. The capitalist

    has to, the state does not have to, and in this sense the state will take over education.

    In the case of education or training which increases the value of labour power and the

    productivity of labour the costs of education may be partially offset by the increase in

    productivity,

    But I would argue that most education is not of this kind, most education is of the

    kind which is not contributing anyway to increasing the value of labour power or its

    value creating capacity. Further, most workers in capitalist society today are

    unproductive workers. They are a majority now, and this means that most education is

    going on unproductive workers anyway.

    So for all these reasons I would argue that education expenditure as a whole does not

    contribute to the increase of profits. Therefore the growth of the education sector is a

    deduction from the mass of profits, which means that the rate of profit of the

    individual capitalists falls further than it would otherwise do if this was not the case.

    The same is true of health, except that there are no ways in which health can offset the

    costs involved. Health is merely a cost to capital. Where it is involved with productive

    workers all it does is increase the value of labour power, without increasing the mass

    of profits. And in this sense health will reduce the rate of profit. In the case of

    unproductive workers it reduces the mass of profits without increasing the value of

    labour power. As far as the police, the growing administration in the state sector, the

    obvious unproductive workers are concerned this is merely a reduction of the mass of

    profits of individual capital.

    So the financing of the state sector which is necessary to pay for this growth is a

    deduction from the growing mass of profits. A deduction from an already insufficient

    mass of profits, in relation to the total amount of capitol which has been invested. The

    individual capitalist finds himself with a smaller rate of profit than the already falling

    general rate of profit.

    This is the situation with the social services and in fact most of the state sector. An

    exception to this is the nationalised industries these industries which the state takes

    over, and by taking them over guarantees the basic inputs, steel, electricity, postage,

    gas and so on, to the capitalist class at a cheaper rate. In most advanced capitalist

    countries, the capitalists would not be able to produce these basic inputs at a profit.The state takes them over or subsidises them as the state is able to produce at a lower

  • 8/8/2019 The State and the Capitalist Crisis

    16/19

    than average rate of profit, or making no profits at all. It is very hard to decide which

    is the case because the pricing policies of these industries are such that they are a

    subsidy to the capitalist class, to the large corporations which use them.

    How is the state sector financed, is the final question in dealing with the

    contradictions of state expenditure. It is financed either out of taxation, or throughdeficit financing, that is future taxation, because if you borrow money it has to be paid

    back, and the main revenue of the state comes through taxation. In fact, the deficit is,

    in most capitalist countries, continually increasing. Taxation obviously falls on the

    working class as well. That is, the working class pays taxes. But it is more correct to

    see taxation as a deduction from the profits of the capitalist class. If the working class

    maintains its real standard of living, that is, through the class struggle itself the

    working class can maintain its real wages after tax, or if the real wages after tax grow

    slightly with productivity increases, then taxation is a deduction from the capitalists'

    profits.

    So in spite of the fact that in most advanced capitalist countries, as the rate of profithas been falling, taxes on corporations have been reduced enormously, to the extent

    that the leading journal of the bourgeoisie (in Britain), The Economist, actually

    admitted that there is no point in reducing corporation tax (tax on profits of industry)

    any more, because they were paying so little anyway, they still have to pay gross

    wages to the working class and it is that part of taxation which is quite vital. This is

    where the class struggle becomes important. Because if you are introducing incomes

    policies, wage freezes, social contracts (the latter is what we have in Britain at the

    present time) what you are attempting to do is to make sure that, as inflation

    increases, more and more of the

    growth of taxation falls on the working class and is actually a deduction from working

    class wages. This occurs when taxation allowances do not increase as fast as inflation.

    And if this is the case, then inflation becomes a tax on the working class. You will

    find that in most capitalist countries the share of taxes falling on the working class has

    increased enormously. This has meant that more and more workers, who have never

    paid tax before are actually paying it now. The class struggle determines the outcome

    of this process.

    What I have attempted to show is how the growth of the state is a necessary condition

    for allowing capital accumulation to proceed. But its cozy existence accentuates the

    tendency of the rate of profit to fall. The full-employment policies, the fact that alarge share of the growing

    surplus value has to go to the state, means that the rate of profit falls faster than would

    otherwise be the case for the individual capitalist. But the rate of profit does not fall

    because of the growth of state expenditure. The rate of profit falls because of the

    contradictions within capital accumulation itself. The actual attempt to overcome

    those contradictions, to maintain accumulation in conditions where it is not viable

    given the real conditions of production, the attempt to do this actually makes the

    problem worse. It accelerates the tendency of the rate of profit to fall.

    I have argued that as productivity increases, less and less workers are employed by agiven amount of capital. Without the intervention of the state sector unemployment

  • 8/8/2019 The State and the Capitalist Crisis

    17/19

    would therefore increase with the growth of the productivity of labour. Private capital

    would not increase investment sufficiently to maintain full employment given the

    falling rates of profit. The growth of state expenditure and the maintenance of 'full'

    employment exacerbates this process, as I have just shown. It makes increases in the

    productivity of labour all the more essential if the individual capitalist is to increase

    profits. So that at every stage the capitalist state has to increase its expenditure if fullemployment is to be maintained. Again we see that the process is a self defeating one.

    At a certain stage the growth of state expenditure is insufficient to offset the relative

    stagnation of accumulation in the private sector. In spite of the fact that the state

    sector is growing faster than the overall growth of production, it is insufficient to

    compensate for the fall in employment in the private sector. Inflation and

    unemployment increase together. The extension of credit and the extension of state

    expenditure merely lead to an increase of inflation. They do nothing else.

    What it means is that we have reached a stage where even the growth of credit and of

    state expenditure will no longer allow profits to be increased significantly enough forthe capitalist to continue to invest. The whole post-war period has avoided a crisis

    precisely because it has allowed accumulation to go on, capitalists to expand in

    conditions where, in fact, the real conditions of profitability did not merit this. But it

    expressed itself not as an immediate fall in production and increase of unemployment,

    but as rising costs or rising inflation. Each stage of attempting to avoid the crisis

    meant that more and more credit was thrown into the economy, the state sector was

    made to increase more and more, and the capitalists had to push up their prices more

    and more to maintain their profits.

    And slowly but surely the rate of inflation gathered momentum, and we are in a

    situation where in the recent period the rate of inflation has doubled every two years.

    That is what has occurred. What it means is that no growth of state expenditure now,

    no expansion of credit will bring about an increase of profitable production. And so

    there is only one answer to resolve this crisis and that is to re-establish the conditions

    for a higher rate of profit. And those are two-fold:

    One is massive unemployment, to force down wages below the value of labour power.

    That is to go against those very conditions that the capitalist state has engendered as

    part of the 'full' employment policy, to increase unemployment massively, to reduce

    wages massively below the value of labour power. So that what is facing the working

    class is a large reduction in the standard of living.

    And the second is that capital has to be completely and utterly restructured. That is,

    the less efficient capitals have to be literally destroyed, have to go out of the market,

    there has to be a major now round of concentration and centralisation of capital.

    This problem is not a national problem, it is a world problem. The problem we are

    seeing is reflected in the growth of inter-imperialist rivalries again on a world scale.

    The concentration now has reached a stage where we are not talking about small firms

    merging in individual capitalist countries, but of massive concentrations of capital

    that actually have a worldwide domain. The situation we have reached is one where

    we can say that the conditions internationally that existed before the first world warhave much more in common with today's conditions than the period since the war.

  • 8/8/2019 The State and the Capitalist Crisis

    18/19

    In fact, we are entering a situation in which nations have to try and get their working

    class to accept the kind of struggles that have been taking place in the past and the

    question of war between nation states is posed all over again. Because the only way

    the capitalist class can begin to obtain the profits required to restore its rate of profit is

    in terms of a worldwide change in the balance of power for capitals. This means, asfar as I am concerned, a tendency towards protectionism, import controls, and if the

    situation develops further, a tendency for these antagonisms to be expressed once

    more in the form of war. This is not exaggerating. We should remember the words of

    Mr Kissinger on the question of the Middle East, where they were actually talking in

    terms of sending in the imperialist armies, in particular the US army, to try and deal

    with this problem of rising oil prices in the way they know best. More and more the

    question of protectionism and import controls has become a major issue in the daily

    newspapers, and indeed in the working class movement itself.

    And so with the profits falling to the degree they are, with the fact that the state in its

    traditional role can no longer increase profitable accumulation, the fact that creditpolicies will no longer work in the degree that they did in the past the conditions for

    this do not exist we are now seeing a return of classical crisis conditions. So that

    now we have an attack on the growth of state expenditure, the very growth which

    helped maintain capital accumulation over the post-war period. There is an attack on

    state expenditure, it has to be cut down, says the capitalist class, and in particular an

    attack on the workers who work in that sector.

    On the other hand, there is also an attack on the workers who work in all sectors in the

    sense that wages, say the capitalist class, are much too high. What we see is an

    attempt to restructure capital to a greater profitability. And it must take the expression

    of a growing and growing crisis. Because any increase in state expenditure, any

    reflation of the world economy will accelerate the rate of inflation. That has reached

    proportions now where it itself is threatening social stability, so the whole reason for

    the growth of state expenditure is now at an end. The very way of actually ensuring

    social stability has now led, in a contradictory manner, to results which threaten social

    stability. So that is the impasse capital finds itself in. Either you reduce inflation and

    cut state expenditure, which means massive unemployment again together with cuts

    in social services and all the hardships this implies. Or you maintain employment and

    adequate state expenditure levels and accept a massive increase in inflation, which

    leads to all the problems of financing capitalist industry and state expenditure which

    have existed over the last few years. Capital has reached an impasse.

    David Yaffe

    20.2.76

  • 8/8/2019 The State and the Capitalist Crisis

    19/19

    NOTES

    1. Marx and Modern Economics ed. David Horowitz, MacGibbon and Kee 1968.

    2. For a discussion of this and what follows see Peter Howell 'Once again on

    Productive and Unproductive Labour' in Revolutionary Communist 3/4, Nov. 1975

    pp46 ff.3. New Statesman April 1975 p502

    4. See Michael Kidron, Western Capitalism Since the War, Penguin 1970, and T.

    Cliff, 'Perspectives of the Permanent War Economy', Socialist Review 1957. For a

    critique of the underconsumptionist position see D. Yaffe 'The Marxian theory of

    crisis, capital and the state' in Economy and Society Vol.2 No.2 May l973, also P.

    Howell op cit for a refutation of Kidron's standpoint.

    5. See Glyn and Sutcliffe, British Capitalism, Workers and the Profits Squeeze,

    Penguin 1972 and Glyn 'Notes on the Profits Squeeze' in the Bulletin of the

    Conference of Socialist Economists Feb 1975 Vol.IV No.1. For a critique see Paul

    Bullock and David Yaffe, 'Inflation, the Crisis and the Post-War Boom' in

    Revolutionary Communist 3/4, Nov. 1975 pp5-46.6. For a full discussion of this see ibid pp13-22 and David Yaffe 'The Marxian

    theory...' op cit pp193-207.

    7. See Bullock and Yaffe op cit pp37-40 for the relevant statistics and discussion.

    8. See ibid for a full discussion of the role of the state, pp31-35.

    < Prev Next >