the role of governance on growth in least developed - World Bank

92
T.C. MARMARA ÜNİVERSİTESİ SOSYAL BİLİMLER ENSTİTÜSÜ İKTİSAT (İNG) ANABİLİM DALI İKTİSAT (İNG) BİLİM DALI THE ROLE OF GOVERNANCE ON GROWTH IN LEAST DEVELOPED COUNTRIES Yüksek Lisans Tezi ADEM GÖK İSTANBUL, 2012

Transcript of the role of governance on growth in least developed - World Bank

T.C.

MARMARA ÜNİVERSİTESİ

SOSYAL BİLİMLER ENSTİTÜSÜ

İKTİSAT (İNG) ANABİLİM DALI

İKTİSAT (İNG) BİLİM DALI

THE ROLE OF GOVERNANCE ON GROWTH IN

LEAST DEVELOPED COUNTRIES

Yüksek Lisans Tezi

ADEM GÖK

İSTANBUL, 2012

T.C.

MARMARA ÜNİVERSİTESİ

SOSYAL BİLİMLER ENSTİTÜSÜ

İKTİSAT (İNG) ANABİLİM DALI

İKTİSAT (İNG) BİLİM DALI

THE ROLE OF GOVERNANCE ON GROWTH IN

LEAST DEVELOPED COUNTRIES

Yüksek Lisans Tezi

ADEM GÖK

Danışman: PROF. DR. ALİ SUUT DOĞRUEL

İstanbul, 2012

i

Name Surname : Adem Gök

Field : Economics

Program : Economics (English Medium)

Supervisor : Prof. Dr. Ali Suut Doğruel

Degree Awarded and Date : MA – June 2012

Keywords : Governance, Institutions, LDCs, Growth, Difference GMM

ABSTRACT

This dissertation addresses the issue of the low level of GDP per capita growth in Least

Developed Countries (LDCs), with special emphasis on the role of governance as a main

determinant of growth. Based on the existing literature; especially Aysan, Nabli and Varoudakis

(2006), the study categorizes what types of governance institutions promote growth.

When the aggregate governance indicators of LDCs are compared with High Income

OECD countries, LDCs have performed worse. The positive correlations between aggregate

governance indicators and GDP per capita suggest that better governance leads to higher

income per capita, thus growth. The separate block dispersion of corresponding LDCs and High

Income OECD countries also illustrates the hypothesis that rich countries can afford better

institutions. The evolution of governance quality in LDCs is evaluated to identify whether there is

a convergence or divergence in these countries and also to specify which countries that are

deteriorated or improved with respect to aggregate governance indicators.

In order to determine the role of aggregate governance indicators together with the role

of control variables; “lag of GDP per capita”, “human capital”,” import penetration”,” trade

openness” and “net official development assistance and official aid received”, two alternative

difference GMM techniques are applied in panel regressions. According to estimation results, it

was found that governance quality as an overall aggregate index has positive significant effect on

GDP per capita growth. This result is particularly true in the case of “administrative quality”

and “political stability”. Evidence in favor of “democratic accountability public voice” seems

less robust. Estimation results also stress that lag of income per capita and human capital have

positive significant effect on growth. The results for other control variables are less robust.

ii

İsim ve Soyadı : Adem Gök

Ana Bilim Dalı : İngilizce İktisat

Programı : İngilizce İktisat

Tez Danışmanı : Prof. Dr. A. Suut Doğruel

Tez Türü ve Tarihi : Yüksek Lisans – Haziran 2012

Anahtar Kelimeler : Yönetişim, Kurumlar, EAGÜ, Büyüme, Fark GMM

ÖZET

Bu tez, En Az Gelişmiş Ülkeler’ de (EAGÜ) büyümenin ana belirleyicisi olan yönetişimin

kişi başına düşen düşük seviyeli milli gelirdeki büyüme üzerine etkisini incelemektedir. Bu

çalışma, literatürdeki kaynaklara; özellikle Aysan, Nabli ve Varoudakis (2006) makalesine

dayanarak, ekonomik büyümeyi arttıran yönetişim kurumlarını kategorize etmektedir.

EAGÜ ile Yüksek Gelirli OECD ülkelerinin toplu yönetişim göstergeleri

karşılaştırıldığında, EAGÜ’ in daha düşük performans gösterdiği görülmektedir. Kişi başına

düşen Gayri Safi Yurtiçi Hasıla (GSYİH) ile toplu yönetişim göstergeleri arasındaki pozitif

korelasyonlar, daha kaliteli yönetişimin daha yüksek kişi başına düşen milli gelire, dolayısıyla

ekonomik büyümeye yol açtığını göstermektedir. EAGÜ ve Yüksek Gelirli OECD ülkelere karşılık

gelen iki ayrı blok halinde yayılmış kişi başına düşen milli gelir ve yönetişim performansları

zengin ülkelerin daha iyi yönetişim kurumlarına sahip oldukları hipotezini desteklemektedir.

EAGÜ’ deki yönetişim kalitesinin değişimi, bu ülkelerin yönetişim kalitelerinde zaman içersinde

birbirlerine yakınsama mı yoksa ıraksama mı olduğunu, ayrıca ıraksayan yönetişim göstergeleri

için bu ülkelerden hangilerinin daha iyi yada daha kötü yönetişime sahip olduğunu

göstermektedir.

Panel regresyonlarda iki alternatif “Fark GMM” tekniği kullanılarak, toplu yönetişim

göstergelerinin diğer kontrol değişkenleri; “önceki dönem kişi başına düşen GSYİH”, “beşeri

sermaye”, “ithalat nüfuz endeksi”, “ticari açıklık” ve “net resmi kalkınma desteği ve gelen resmi

yardımlar” ile birlikte ekonomik büyüme üzerine olan etkisi incelenemiştir. Regresyon

sonuçlarına göre, toplu yönetişim kalitesini gösteren birleştirilmiş yönetişim göstergesinin

“kişibaşına düşen GSYİH” üzerine önemli pozitif etkisi olduğu bulunmuştur. Bu sonuç, “idari

yönetim kalitesi” ve “politik istikrar” için de aynı çıkmıştır. Bir diğer birleştirilmiş yönetişim

göstergesi olan “demokratik hesap verilebilirlik söz hakkı” nın ekonomik büyüme üzerine etkisi

ise belirsiz çıkmıştır. “Önceki dönem kişi başına düşen milli gelir” ve “beşeri sermaye” nin

ekonomik büyüme üzerine önemli pozitif etkisi olduğu, diğer kontrol değişkenlerinin ise ekonomik

büyüme üzerine olan etkilerinin belirsiz olduğu bulunmuştur.

iii

TABLE OF CONTENTS

ABSTRACT………………………………………………………………………………………. i

ÖZET………………………………………………………………………………………...…... ii

TABLE OF CONTENTS………………………………………………………………………. iii

TABLE LIST……………………………………………………………………………….…… vi

FIGURE LIST………………………………………………………………………………….. vii

ABBREVIATIONS……………………………………………………………………………. viii

CHAPTER 1: INTRODUCTION………………………………………………………………. 1

CHAPTER 2: CATEGORIZATION OF LDCS………………………………………………. 4

2.1. Criteria and Procedure for Inclusion……………………………………………...……… 4

2.1.1. Initial Criteria for Inclusion…………………………..…………………………… 5

2.1.2. Latest Criteria for Inclusion…………………….…………………………..…….. 5

2.1.2.1. GNI per Capita…………………………………………………………… 5

2.1.2.2. Human Assets Index (HAI) ……………………………………...……… 7

2.1.2.3. Economic Vulnerability Index (EVI)……………….…....…………...… 9

2.1.3. Procedure for Inclusion…………………………………………………………... 12

2.2. Rules and Procedure for Graduation……………………………………………………. 12

2.2.1. Rules for Graduation…………………………………………………………...… 12

2.2.2. Procedure for Graduation and Smooth Transition……………………………….. 13

CHAPTER 3: SPECIAL SUPPORT MEASURES FOR THE LDCS…………………...…. 15

3.1. International Trade…………………………………………………………………….... 16

3.1.1. Preferential Market Access………………………………………………………. 18

3.1.2. Other Trade-Related Measures…………………………………………...……… 19

3.2. International Aid………………………………………………………...…….…...…… 20

3.2.1. Bilateral Assistance………………………………………….…………………... 20

3.2.2. Multilateral Assistance………………………………………………….……..… 23

3.2.2.1. Global Environment Facility (GEF).……………………………………. 23

3.2.2.2. The United Nations Capital Development Fund (UNCDF)….…………. 23

3.2.2.3. World Food Programme (WFP)…..…………………………………….. 23

3.2.2.4. World Meteorological Organization (WMO)………….………………... 24

3.3. Other Forms of Support Measures………………………………………………….…... 24

iv

CHAPTER 4: CLASSIFICATION OF GOVERNANCE INSTITUTIONS………….….… 26

4.1. Literature on Classification of Governance Institutions………………………………... 27

4.1.1. Kaufmann, Kraay and Mastruzzi (2003).………………………………………... 27

4.1.2. World Bank (2003)……………………………….……………………………… 28

4.1.3. Aysan, Nabli and Varoudakis (2006)…………….………….…………………... 28

4.1.4. Economic Commission for Africa (ECA) project……………………………...... 28

4.1.5. Asian Development Bank/Viet Nam………………………………...…………... 29

4.1.6. African Peer Review Mechanism (APRM) ……………………………………... 29

4.2. Classification of Governance Institutions in the Study…………………………….…... 30

4.2.1. Administrative Quality Index (AQI) …………………………………..………... 30

4.2.1.1. Corruption……………………………………………………...…….….. 31

4.2.1.2. Bureaucracy Quality………………………………...…………………... 31

4.2.1.3. Investment Profile………………………………………………...….….. 31

4.2.1.4. Law and Order…………………………………………………………... 31

4.2.2. Political Stability Index (PSI) …………………………………………….….….. 32

4.2.2.1. Government Stability…………………………………………………..... 32

4.2.2.2. Internal Conflict……………………………………………………...….. 32

4.2.2.3. External Conflict………………………………………………….….….. 32

4.2.2.4. Ethnic Tensions……………………………………………………....….. 32

4.2.2.5. Religious Tensions……………………………………………….…..….. 32

4.2.3. Democratic Accountability Public Voice Index (DAPVI) …………………..….. 33

4.2.3.1. Democratic Accountability…………………………………….…….….. 33

4.2.3.2. Military in Politics……………………………………………….…….... 33

4.2.3.3. Political Rights………………………………………...………….….….. 33

4.2.3.4. Civil Liberties……………………………………………….…….…….. 33

4.2.4. Governance Quality Index (GOVI) ……………………………………….…….. 34

CHAPTER 5: GOVERNANCE IN LDCS…………………………………………………… 35

5.1. Comparison of Governance and Growth in LDCs and High Income OECD

Countries……………………………………………………………………………….. 38

5.2. The Evolution of Governance in LDCs………………………………….…………….. 40

5.2.1. Administrative Quality Index (AQI) ……………………………..……………... 40

5.2.2. Political Stability Index (PSI) …………………………………………………... 41

5.2.3. Democratic Accountability Political Voice Index (DAPVI) …………………… 42

5.2.4. Aggregate Governance Index (GOVI)…………………………………………... 43

CHAPTER 6: EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS……………………………………………………. 45

6.1. Methodology: Arellano-Bond (1991) Difference GMM ………………………..…….. 45

6.2. Data…………………………………………………………………………………….. 47

6.3. Empirical Models………………………………………………………..……………... 52

6.4. Estimation Results……………………………………………….……………………... 54

CHAPTER 7: CONCLUSION……………………………………………………………….. 60

REFERENCES……………………………………………………………………………...… 63

v

APPENDIX 1…………………………………………………………………………………. 66

APPENDIX 2…………………………………………………………………………………. 67

APPENDIX 3…………………………………………………………………………………. 68

vi

TABLE LIST

Page No.

Table 1: Colonial Origins and Last Disturbances on Governance in LDCs………….…… 70

Table 2: Income per capita and Governance Comparison of LDCs and High

Income OECD Countries……………………………………………….………. 76

Table 3: Variables and Sources…………………………………………………………… 78

Table 4: First Generation Panel Unit Root Tests……………………………………..…… 49

Table 5: Second Generation Panel Unit Root Tests…………………………………….… 51

Table 6: Summary Statistics of All Variables In Panel Regressions (1991-2010) ……….. 80

Table 7: Estimation Results of Model 1………………………………………………...… 57

Table 8: Estimation Results of Model 2………………………………………………...… 58

vii

FIGURE LIST

Page No.

Figure 1: GNI per capita ($) of LDCs (Atlas Method)……………………………...…… 6

Figure 2: Human Assets Index (HAI) of LDCs…………………………………..……… 8

Figure 3: Economic Vulnerability Index (EVI) of LDCs……………………………..… 11

Figure 4: Merchandise Exports by LDCs as a Percentage of World Exports,

1948–2008……………………………………………………………………. 17

Figure 5: Official Development Assistance (ODA) to LDCs, Value and Percentage

of GNI of DAC Member Countries, 1990- 2006………………………...…… 21

Figure 6: Averages of Income per Capita and Governance of LDCs and

High Income OECD Countries………………………………………………... 39

Figure 7: Evolution of AQI in LDCs……………………………………………………. 41

Figure 8: Evolution of PSI in LDCs…………………………………………………….. 42

Figure 9: Evolution of DAPVI in LDCs………………………………………………… 43

Figure 10: Evolution of GOVI in LDCs………………………………………………..… 44

Figure 11: Foreign Trade in LDCs (1985-2010) ………………………………………… 59

viii

ABBREVIATIONS

APRM : African Peer Review Mechanism

AQI : Administrative Quality Index

AU : African Union

CDP : Committee for Development Planning

D1 : First Difference

DAPVI : Democratic Accountability Political Voice Index

DESA : United Nations Department of Economic and Social Affairs

DFQF : Duty-Free and Quota-Free

ECA : Economic Commission for Africa

EVI : Economic Vulnerability Index

GATT : General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade

GCF : Gross Capital Formation

GDP : Gross Domestic Product

GEF : Global Environment Facility

GMM : Generalized Method of Moments

GNI : Gross National Income

GOVI : Aggregate Governance Index

GPC : Gross Domestic Product per Capita

GSP : Generalized System of Preferences

GSTP : Global System of Trade Preferences

GSYİH : Gayri Safi Yurtiçi Hasıla

HAI : Human Assets Index

HUMC : Human Capital Index

I.I.D. : Independent and Identically Distributed

IF : The Integrated Framework

IPS : Im, Peseran and Shin Panel Unit Root Test

EAGÜ : En Az Gelişmiş Ülkeler

EIF : Enhanced Integrated Framework

FDI : Foreign Direct Investment

ix

L1 : First Lag

LDCF : Least Developed Countries Fund

LDCs : Least Developed Countries

LIFDCs : Low-Income Food-Deficit Countries

LLC : Levin, Lin and Chu Panel Unit Root Test

LN : Natural Logarithm of Aggregate Governance Index

IMPEN : Import Penetration Index

MDGs : Millennium Development Goals

MFN : Most Favored Nation

NAPAs : National Adaptation Programmes of Action

NMHSs : National Meteorological and Hydrological Services

OECD : Organization of Economic Development

p. : Page

PSI : Political Stability Index

SDT : Special and differential treatment

TROP : Trade Openness Index

UN : United Nation

UNCDF : United Nations Capital Development Fund

UNFCCC : United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change

UNCTAD : United Nations Conference on Trade and Development

WFP : World Food Programme

WMO : World Meteorological Organization

WTO : World Trade Organization

1

CHAPTER 1: INTRODUCTION

The most fundamental question concentrated on the field of growth and development is

“What are the reasons behind the large differences in the welfare of states?” which is being

motted as “Why are some countries much poorer than others?” (Acemoglu, Johnson and

Robinson, 2005, p.338) or more specifically “What are the fundamental causes of the large

differences in income per capita across countries?” (Acemoglu, Johnson and Robinson, 2001,

p.1369)

The dissertation looks for the answer to this historical question by concentrating on the most

vulnerable poor countries which are classified as “Least Developed Countries” (LDCs) by the

United Nations (UN) classification. The main issue of this study is the low level of growth in the

LDCs, with special emphasis on the role of governance institutions as a main determinant of

growth.

A broad consensus among growth economists, development experts and aid donors views

‘good governance’ as a pre-requisite for sustained increase in living standards of the society.

Although this literature has made important advances in uncovering the political, institutional and

social determinants of development, the new political economy of growth is not without

problems. Econometric works show that institutions are the key determinant of economic

performance. However, the new political economy of growth still lacks a proper grasp of the

channels through which institutions affect growth and the political sources of good institutions.

(Avellaneda, 2009) The study is attempted to fill this gap in the literature by concentrating on the

growth incapability of LDCs especially resulting from bad governance as a main structural

impediment to growth.

Although the traditional neoclassical growth models consider the economic environment in

which institutions are embedded as in the form of well-defined property rights which encourage

the “animal spirit” of “homo economicus” and the market mechanism which is the fundamental

institutions of overall pure capitalist system, the differences in the welfare of the states proxied

by differences in income per capita between states and also the economic growth leading to

overall development of the state has not been explained by the variation in institutions even in the

2

simple form of pure capitalist economy. Instead, the differences in income per capita are

explained in terms of different paths of factor accumulation by Solow, Cass and Koopmans (eg.,

Solow, 1956, Cass, 1965 and Koopmans, 1965, cited in Acemoglu et al., 2005, p.338) or in

terms of externalities from physical and human capital accumulation by Romer and Lucas (eg.,

Romer, 1986 and Lucas, 1988, cited in Acemoglu et al., 2005, p.338). Even though Romer,

Grossman and Helpman, Aghion and Howitt endogenized steady-state growth and technical

progress, they could not go beyond the previous explanations of income per capita differences

between countries (eg., Romer, 1990, Grossman and Helpman, 1991 and Aghion and Howitt,

1992, cited in Acemoglu et al., 2005, p.338).

The real contribution to the literature is ”the factors we have listed (innovation, economies of

scale, education, capital accumulation, etc.) are not the causes of growth; they are growth”

(North and Thomas,1973, p.2). According to Acemoglu et al. (2005), factor accumulation and

innovation or the technical progress can only be proximate causes of growth. Hence the

fundamental reason and the explanation of the difference between the welfare of states; thus the

touchstone of the differing paths of economic growth leading to more or less developed status of

states, is the quality of institutions. Countries that have well-established governance institutions

will invest more in both physical and human capital by using these factors more efficiently in

order to achieve greater level of income per capita (eg., North and Thomas, 1973, Jones, 1981,

North, 1981, cited in Acemoglu et al., 2001).

As North and Thomas (1973) argued, the fundamental explanation of comparative growth is

the differences in institutions and their governance which alters our perceptions about the quality

of those institutions.

For the LDCs, the main differences in institutions and thus governance are not mainly based

on the colonial origin of these countries but on the last disturbances in these countries emanating

from invasions, wars, civil wars, coupes, regime changes, etc., after they won their indepence

from colonial regimes as in Table 1. (Only two of the LDCs; Ethiopia and Nepal are not ex-

colonies.) That is why the study has concentrated on relatively short-run period rather than very-

long period starting from colonial origin suggested by Acemoglu et al. (2001). But the reason for

concentrating on this relatively short-run period is not because of the difficulty of overcoming the

econometric problems such as reverse causality and multicollinearity resulting in endogeneity

3

problem as in Dollar and Kraay (2002), but because these countries are no more colonies; but

independent states.

The study is organized as follows. The second chapter explains the categorization of LDCs

based on the criteria, rules and procedures for inclusion in and graduation from LDC category. It

gives a visual representation of LDCs with respect to three main criteria determining their

inclusion or graduation. The third chapter introduces the special support measures for LDCs

regarding the international trade, development assistance and aid from donor countries and

international communities. The fourth chapter examines the previous classification of governance

institutions in the literature and introduces the classification of aggregate governance clusters

developed by the author mainly based on the categorization of Aysan, Nabli and Varoudakis

(2006). The fifth chapter compares governance and growth in LDCs and High Income OECD

countries and the evolution of governance institutions in LDCs according to the aggregate

governance clusters developed in the previous chapter. The sixth chapter introduces the

characteristics of data, panel unit root tests for the variables in first differences, the methodology

of difference GMM and finally it represents the estimation results according to two empirical

models based on two alternative estimation techniques of difference GMM. The last chapter

presents the conclusion.

4

CHAPTER 2: CATEGORIZATION OF LDCs

In order to alleviate the problems of underdevelopment of the poorest countries, the category

of LDCs was first advocated in the 1960s to attract special support measures for the most

disadvantaged economies in the world. The responsible body of the UN; the Committee for

Development Planning (CDP) took the responsibility to carry out a comprehensive examination

of the special problems facing the LDCs and to recommend special measures for dealing with

those problems. CDP proposed an initial list of 25 LDCs based on a simple set of criteria at its

seventh session in 1971. CDP has been responsible for undertaking a review of the list in every

three years, regarding countries which should be included in or graduated from the list. Even

though the indicators composing the criteria are evolved over time as a “measurement of long-

term structural weaknesses”, the underlying principle of identifying LDCs has essentially

remained as “low-income countries that face structural handicaps to growth”. (CDP, 2008, p.V)

According to criteria that evolved over time, the initial list of LDCs covering 25 countries is

expanded into 48 countries which are scattered around three continents as of today. (For the

current list of LDCs, see Appendix 1)

2.1. Criteria and Procedure for Inclusion

Indicators reflecting the structural handicaps of low-income countries for growth are the high

vulnerability of the countries’ economies and their low level of human capital. (CDP, 2008, p.1)

CDP selected indicators that are proved to be sufficiently stable over time to minimize the

likelihood of easy reversibility of status from LDC to non-LDC and vice versa owing to dramatic

fluctuations in any single criterion. (CDP, 2008, p.5)

“In its choice of statistical indicators, the Committee attempts to identify those that most

closely reflect or capture the features that are of relevance for the classification of an

LDC.”(CDP, 2008, p.4)

5

2.1.1. Initial Criteria for Inclusion

The initial criteria for inclusion in the LDCs list was accepted by the Committee’s seventh

session in 1971 as:

• per capita GDP which indicates the level of income in a given country

• share of manufacturing in GDP which indicates the degree of industrialization since high

degree of industrialization was seen to be the structural characteristic of developed

countries (CDP, 2008, p.3)

• adult literacy rate which indicates a country’s level of human capital development (CDP,

2008, p.3)

Even though the underlying principle of identifying LDCs as “low-income countries that face

structural handicaps to growth” has essentially remained, a number of improvements have been

introduced into the criteria to identify least developed countries as data availability on

development indicators for developing countries continued to improve. (CDP, 2008, p.5)

2.1.2. Latest Criteria for Inclusion

CDP defines the category of the LDCs as comprising those low-income countries suffering

from structural handicaps to economic development. The eligibility criteria for LDCs have

evolved into the three types as “Gross National Income (GNI) Per Capita”, “Human Assets

Index” (HAI) and “Economic Vulnerability Index” (EVI).

The Committee determined in 1991 that countries with a population exceeding 75 million

should not be considered for inclusion in the list of LDCs.

2.1.2.1. GNI Per Capita

GNI per capita can provide an indication of the income position of a country vis-à-vis other

developing countries and it also gives a rough idea of the productive capacity of an economy and

its ability to provide requisite services. (CDP, 2008, p.39)

The threshold for graduation is set at a higher level as $900 which is about 20 per cent above

the $745 threshold for inclusion. (CDP, 2008, p.39)

6

0

200

400

600

800

1000

1200

1400

1600

1800

2000

2200

2400

2600

2800

3000

Afg

han

ista

n

Angola

Ban

gla

des

h

Ben

in

Bhu

tan

Bu

rkin

a F

aso

Bu

rundi

Cam

bodia

Cen

tral

Afr

ican

Rep

ubli

c

Chad

Com

oro

s

Dem

ocr

atic

Rep

ubli

c of

the

Congo

Dji

bou

ti

Equ

atori

al G

uin

ea

Eri

trea

Eth

iopia

Gam

bia

Gu

inea

Gu

inea

-Bis

sau

Hai

ti

Kir

ibat

i

Lao

Peo

ple

's D

emocr

atic

Rep

ubli

c

Les

oth

o

Lib

eria

Mad

agas

car

Mal

awi

Mal

div

es

Mal

i

Mau

rita

nia

Moza

mbiq

ue

Myan

mar

Nep

al

Nig

er

Rw

anda

Sam

oa

Sao

Tom

e an

d P

rinci

pe

Sen

egal

Sie

rra

Leo

ne

Solo

mon I

slan

ds

Som

alia

Su

dan

Tim

or-

Les

te

Togo

Tu

val

u

Ugan

da

Unit

ed R

epu

bli

c of

Tan

zania

Van

uat

u

Yem

en

Zam

bia

Figure 1: GNI per capita ($) of LDCs (Atlas Method)

Source: Author’s Own Calculation based on DESA Development Policy and Analysis Division, Data Retrieval, 2009 Review.

Note: Dark blue charts indicate the LDCs that are included in the econometric analysis.

$ 8936

Graduation Threshold:$1086

Inclusion Threshold:$905

7

2.1.2.2. Human Assets Index (HAI)

The HAI provides information on the level of development of human capital by focusing on

achievements in health and education as an indication of the capacity countries have to take

advantage of opportunities for development. It has two indicators for health and nutrition; “the

percentage of population that is undernourished” and “the rate of mortality for children aged five

years and under” and two indicators for education; “the gross secondary school enrolment ratio”

and “the adult literacy rate”. (CDP, 2008, p.45)

Undernourishment and mortality rate have an important negative impact on productivity.

They reflect the social, economic and environmental conditions in a society. For low-income

countries, differences in life expectancy of population tend to be strongly influenced by

differences in the levels of child mortality rates. A low level of education is a major obstacle to

development as it implies an overall shortage of skills for the organization and functioning of the

economy and reflects a low capacity to absorb technological advances. The adult literacy rate

indicates the size of the base available for enlarging the trained and skilled human resources

needed for development and the gross secondary enrolment ratio complements that information

by providing an indication of the share of population with a certain level of skills. (CDP, 2008,

p.46)

8

Figure 2: Human Assets Index (HAI) of LDCs

Source: Author’s Own Calculation based on DESA Development Policy and Analysis Division, Data Retrieval, 2009 Review.

Note: Dark blue charts indicate the LDCs that are included in the econometric analysis.

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

40

45

50

55

60

65

70

75

80

85

90

95

100

Afg

han

ista

n

Angola

Ban

gla

des

h

Ben

in

Bhu

tan

Bu

rkin

a F

aso

Bu

rundi

Cam

bodia

Cen

tral

Afr

ican

Rep

ubli

c

Chad

Com

oro

s

Dem

ocr

atic

Rep

ubli

c of

the

Congo

Dji

bou

ti

Equ

atori

al G

uin

ea

Eri

trea

Eth

iopia

Gam

bia

Gu

inea

Gu

inea

-Bis

sau

Hai

ti

Kir

ibat

i

Lao

Peo

ple

's D

emocr

atic

Rep

ubli

c

Les

oth

o

Lib

eria

Mad

agas

car

Mal

awi

Mal

div

es

Mal

i

Mau

rita

nia

Moza

mbiq

ue

Myan

mar

Nep

al

Nig

er

Rw

anda

Sam

oa

Sao

Tom

e an

d P

rinci

pe

Sen

egal

Sie

rra

Leo

ne

Solo

mon I

slan

ds

Som

alia

Su

dan

Tim

or-

Les

te

Togo

Tu

val

u

Ugan

da

Unit

ed R

epu

bli

c of

Tan

zania

Van

uat

u

Yem

en

Zam

bia

Inclusion Threshold:58

Graduation Threshold:64

9

2.1.2.3. Economic Vulnerability Index (EVI)

EVI reflects the possible negative and long-lasting effects of the shocks that have on growth

and development in order to express information on the magnitude of countries’ economic

vulnerability. It takes the structural characteristics of the country into consideration which

concerns the degree to which it is exposed to such shocks and the country’s capacity to react to

shocks. The criterion in designating countries as LDCs, there is a need to focus on those sources

of vulnerability that “accentuate or perpetuate underdevelopment”, “are not the result of

misguided policies but instead are such that they limit policymakers’ capacity to respond to

shocks” and “are beyond a country’s control”. (CDP, 2008, p.48)

Seven indicators are grouped into simple, unweighted averages of two components as

“exposure index” and “shock index”.

Exposure index is composed of “smallness”, “location index” and “structural index”.

Smallness is proxied by the logarithm of the size of its population in which smaller size is often

associated with a persistent lack of structural diversification and dependence on external markets

and small economies experience higher exposure to natural shocks. The main argument behind

the location index (remoteness) is that the countries isolated from main markets have difficulty in

diversifying their economies and remoteness is a structural obstacle to trade and growth and a

possible source of vulnerability when shocks occur. (CDP, 2008, p.50) The structural index is

composed of “merchandise export concentration” considering the fact that export concentration

increases a country’s exposure to trade shocks and “share of agriculture, forestry and fisheries in

gross domestic product” in which a larger share implies higher exposure to shocks both in

relation to terms of trade and to natural disasters. (CDP, 2008, p.52)

Shock index is composed of “natural shock index” and “trade shock index”. Natural shock

index is defined as the simple average of two components as “homelessness due to natural

disasters” and “the instability of agricultural production”. (CDP, 2008, p.52) Natural disasters

have a negative impact on economic development and are an important source of vulnerability

for low-income countries. The homelessness index conveys information on the average share of

the population that is displaced by natural disasters over a period of time. (CDP, 2008, p.53)

10

Trade shock index is measured by “instability of exports of goods and services” which is

based on the idea that low-income countries, particularly heavily dependent on agricultural

exports or the provision of tourism services, instability of export resourcing mainly from climatic

events or changes in policies of major importing markets proceeds is a source of vulnerability.

(CDP, 2008, p.54)

11

Figure 3: Economic Vulnerability Index (EVI) of LDCs

Source: Author’s Own Calculation based on DESA Development Policy and Analysis Division, Data Retrieval, 2009 Review.

Note: Dark blue charts indicate the LDCs that are included in the econometric analysis.

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

40

45

50

55

60

65

70

75

80

Afg

han

ista

n

Angola

Ban

gla

des

h

Ben

in

Bhu

tan

Bu

rkin

a F

aso

Bu

rundi

Cam

bodia

Cen

tral

Afr

ican

Rep

ubli

c

Chad

Com

oro

s

Dem

ocr

atic

Rep

ubli

c of

the

Congo

Dji

bou

ti

Equ

atori

al G

uin

ea

Eri

trea

Eth

iopia

Gam

bia

Gu

inea

Gu

inea

-Bis

sau

Hai

ti

Kir

ibat

i

Lao

Peo

ple

's D

emocr

atic

Rep

ubli

c

Les

oth

o

Lib

eria

Mad

agas

car

Mal

awi

Mal

div

es

Mal

i

Mau

rita

nia

Moza

mbiq

ue

Myan

mar

Nep

al

Nig

er

Rw

anda

Sam

oa

Sao

Tom

e an

d P

rinci

pe

Sen

egal

Sie

rra

Leo

ne

Solo

mon I

slan

ds

Som

alia

Su

dan

Tim

or-

Les

te

Togo

Tu

val

u

Ugan

da

Unit

ed R

epu

bli

c of

Tan

zania

Van

uat

u

Yem

en

Zam

bia

Graduation Threshold:38

Inclusion Threshold:42

12

2.1.3. Procedure for Inclusion

The expert group, consisting of CDP members in the triennial reviews of the list of the LDCs,

analysis the economic and social conditions in all low-income countries according to the most

recent available data and the preliminary results of the application of the criteria. It prepares a

preliminary list of countries identified for inclusion satisfying the inclusion threshold levels with

respect to all three criteria. The United Nations Department of Economic and Social Affairs

(DESA) will prepare a country assessment note on the basis of the group’s finding of eligibility

by means of statistical evidence and it will incorporate other relevant information for presentation

to the CDP. Particular consideration will be given to the reasons for the recent deterioration of

economic and social conditions in the country in order to determine whether that deterioration is

due to structural or transitory factors. Then, DESA notifies the government of that country of this

conclusion and the findings considered by the CDP at its forthcoming triennial review. On receipt

of the assessment note, the country may submit a written statement to the CDP, expressing its

views on its possible inclusion in the list, including any objections to such inclusion. (CDP, 2008,

p.9)

If the country does not express a formal objection to inclusion in the list of LDCs, the CDP

will make an appropriate recommendation in its report to the Council. If the country has

expressed a formal objection, the finding of eligibility as well as the country’s objection will be

recorded in the report and no recommendation for inclusion will be made. (CDP, 2008, p.9)

Once the Council endorses the recommendation for inclusion after the acceptance of country,

the country will be formally added to the list of LDCs. (CDP, 2008, p.9)

2.2. Rules and Procedure for Graduation

2.2.1. Rules for Graduation

A country must cease to meet two out of the three inclusion criteria.

• A country is eligible for the graduation, if its GNI increases to at least twice the

graduation threshold level, even if that country has not met both HAI and EVI criteria.

Since higher levels of GNI per capita are often required to improve a country’s human

13

assets and to confront existing economic vulnerabilities, and it indicates greater

availability of resources for the implementation of those policies.

• Eligibility for graduation has to be observed over 2 consecutive triennial reviews.

• Graduation takes place only after 3 years, in order to give the country time to prepare

itself for a smooth transition from the list

Graduation does not require approval from the country concerned.

The graduation rules are established in 1991 with additional principles to ensure that

graduation takes place only after a country’s development prospects have significantly improved

and the graduated country can sustain its development path. (CDP, 2008, p.5)

2.2.2. Procedure for Graduation and Smooth Transition

By analyzing the most recent available data on the economic and social conditions in all low-

income countries and the preliminary results of the application of the criteria, the expert group

prepares a preliminary list of countries identified for graduation in the triennial reviews of the list

of LDCs. In its report, the CDP will notify the Council of all LDCs that meet the graduation

criteria, and those countries that are confirmed eligible for the second consecutive time are

recommended for graduation.

As in the inclusion process, DESA will inform the country concerned of the findings of

eligibility for graduation after the first review. Then, UNCTAD will prepare a vulnerability

profile giving an overall background of the economic and development situation of that country

and it will compare the values of the indicators used in the CDP criteria with relevant national

statistics. UNCTAD will further assess other vulnerabilities that the country is facing which are

not covered by the EVI, as well as other structural features of the country that are of relevance for

the graduation decision (CDP, 2008, p.11)

In cooperation with UNCTAD, DESA will prepare an ex ante impact assessment of the likely

consequences of graduation for the country’s economic growth and development by identifying

potential risk factors, or gains, that the country may face after graduation. With the cooperation

of the country concerned as well as its development partners, DESA will focus on the expected

14

implications of a loss of LDC status, in particular with regard to development financing,

international trade and technical assistance. (CDP, 2008, p.13)

When a country meets the graduation criteria for the second consecutive time, the CDP may

recommend the country for graduation in its report to the Council after considering all relevant

quantitative and qualitative information at its disposal. If the Council endorses the

recommendation, graduation will take effect three years after the General Assembly takes note of

the recommendation. During the three-year period before graduation takes effect, the country

concerned may prepare a transition strategy in cooperation with its development partners. (CDP,

2008, p.13)

After the country has officially graduated, the strategy aims at ensuring that the phasing out

of support measures resulting from its change of status will not disrupt the country’s continued

development efforts. The CDP will monitor the development progress of those countries whose

graduation has not become effective and include its findings in its annual report to the Council in

order to identify any signs of reversal in the development progress of the country concerned

during the post-graduation period and bring them to the attention of the Council as early as

possible. The CDP will report to the Council on the findings of the monitoring exercise as a

complement to the triennial review of the list of LDCs. (CDP, 2008, p.14)

(See Appendix 1 for the countries that are graduated and rejected to be enlisted as LDC)

15

CHAPTER 3: SPECIAL SUPPORT MEASURES FOR THE LDCS

The structural impediments to growth in LDCs are so pervasive that they prompt the

international community consisting of the bilateral donors and multilateral organizations to

extend special support measures in the form of financial, institutional and technical support and

also a higher degree of preferential trade-related treatment. (CDP, 2010, p.1)

Each of the ten year UN Programmes of Action (PoAs) cover the framework for international

cooperation by outlining the development strategies, the priority areas for policy intervention and

the special support measures envisaged for LDCs. (CDP, 2010, p.1)

The first PoA launched in 1981 had two defining features. The first was an emphasis on

poverty alleviation through food self-sufficiency and the second was a reliance on development

planning in order to mobilize and utilize resources effectively. It was planned to increase the

share of manufacturing in gross domestic product (GDP), particularly through the development

of agro-processing industries. Expansion of the manufacturing capacity was needed not only to

meet domestic demand but also to increase exports since the low export revenue was seen as a

major constraint to the capacity of these countries to import. (CDP, 2010, p.3) But as seen from

the Figure 11, the exports of LDCs did not increase while the imports were throughout the 1980s,

leading to huge trade deficits for most of the LDCs.

The second PoA in 1990 relied on unleashing free markets for the efficient reallocation of

resources and on promoting the role of the private sector in economic growth by handling adverse

effects of import controls, tariffs, direct price controls and other regulations imposed by the State

to enhance market access and to gain export diversification. LDCs were advised to downsize

State interventions, deregulate markets, restore and maintain macroeconomic stability and

liberalize their economies, so that markets could send the right price signals for private initiatives

to pursue profit-making activities. The creation of a domestic policy environment conducive to

growth was designed to minimize the structural constraints facing LDCs and to help them embark

upon a path of sustained and sustainable growth. (CDP, 2010, p.4)

The third PoA was adopted in 2001 stating its key objectives to carry out the Millennium

Development Goals (MDGs) and to increase the share of LDCs in global trade, finance and

16

investment. It was the first time the Committee drives a great deal of attention to good

governance, especially the effective rule of law and participation in political and economic

activities by civil society, institutional reform and the provision of social services. 30 specific

objectives are identified to be achieved by means of fostering pro-poor growth, building

institutional and human capabilities, reducing inequality and promoting greater popular

participation, especially of women, and ensuring the rule of law, property rights and respect for

internationally recognized human rights. Access to developed-country markets for LDC exports

were received greater attention than previous PoAs and provisions were included to ensure that

the pace of integration of the LDCs into the multilateral trading system would be commensurate

with their structural weaknesses. (CDP, 2010, p.5)

The objectives contained in these three PoAs have not been fully met because of the

following reasons: the goals set by the PoAs were too ambitious in relation to the measures

introduced to achieve them; even where reasonable goals were set, inadequate external support,

misguided domestic policies and unforeseen shocks such as natural disasters and conflicts made

it difficult to implement the strategies and projects according to the original plans; the PoAs

overemphasized international measures whose impact on development in general and on poverty

reduction in particular has not been compellingly demonstrated and the international support

measures, while necessary, may not be sufficient to address the structural impediments facing the

LDCs. (CDP, 2010, p.V)

These special support measures offered to LDCs in order to overcome their structural

weaknesses to grow fall into three main areas as “international trade”, “official development

assistance (ODA), including development financing and technical cooperation” and “other forms

of assistance”. (CDP, 2008, p.15)

3.1. International Trade

The share of LDCs in world exports of goods decreased from 3 per cent in 1950 to 1.5

percent in 1971. Since the establishment of the category in 1971, the share of LDCs in world

trade has steadily decreased even to the designated PoAs which gives special support measures to

LDCs in order to increase their trade performance. It had declined to 0.75 percent in 1980, and to

0.56 percent in 1990 and it hit its lowest level of 0.47 percent in 1995. After 1995, it was

17

progressively rebounded, reaching 1.1 per cent in 2008. But it would be misleading to conclude

that the trade performance of LDCs had been increased or the second and third PoA had been

fulfilling their promises. Since this recent increase in the world market share was essentially the

result of oil-export growth in five LDCs of Angola, Equatorial Guinea, Myanmar, the Sudan and

Yemen. In fact, the combined share of these five LDCs in world oil production rose from 0.14

per cent in 1995 to 0.54 percent in 2008. Excluding the oil exporters, the LDC share in world

trade has stagnated at about 0.33 per cent since 1995. This downward shift in trade in goods was

not compensated for by a rise in the share of world exports of services. Despite an increase in the

number of LDCs, the share of LDCs in world exports of goods and services declined from 0.85

percent in 1980 to 0.5 percent in 1990 and has remained at about that level ever since, standing at

0.49 percent in 2007. (CDP, 2010, p.7)

Figure 4: Merchandise exports by LDCs as a percentage of world exports, 1948–2008

Source: UNCTAD Handbook of Statistics. (CDP,2010,p.7,Figure 1)

18

3.1.1. Preferential Market Access

It allows exporters from developing countries to pay lower tariffs or to have duty- and quota-

free access to third-country markets in order to facilitate export growth under two general

preferential schemes as non-reciprocal “Generalized System of Preferences“(GSP) and reciprocal

“Global System of Trade Preferences” (GSTP). (CDP, 2008, p.15)

Special trade preferences to developing countries through a temporary waiver to the General

Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) rules began in 1971. (CDP, 2010, p.8)

The GSP is signed in 1968 at the second session of the UNCTAD to increase the export

earnings of developing countries, promote industrialization and accelerate their rate of growth.

By the “Enabling Clause” in 1979, selected products exported from developing countries would

be granted zero or reduced tariff rates instead of the Most-Favored-Nation (MFN) rates of duty

allowing wider product coverage and deeper tariff cuts for LDCs. But only a small number of

developing countries have introduced duty-free and quota-free (DFQF) access to exports from

LDCs during the 2000s. Also preferences are eroded when further trade liberalization occurs in

the importing market. For countries or regions that extend different preferential treatment to other

trading partners, the actual magnitude of preferential access offered to LDCs needs to be

measured in relation to the effective tariff paid by all other exporters to that market, rather than in

relation to the MFN tariff. When preferential access is measured in this way, the preference

margins enjoyed by the LDCs are found to be very small and the level of preference extended

therefore seems to be quite small on average. (CDP, 2008, p.16 and CDP, 2010, p.8)

The GSTP entered into force in 1989 as an agreement among 43 participants on cooperation

on tariffs, para-tariffs, non-tariff measures, direct trade measures and sectoral agreements to

extend concrete preferential treatment measures and concessions especially for current seven

members of LDCs. (CDP, 2008, p.16)

There are other regional or bilateral trade agreements and/or non-reciprocal market access

schemes offering market access concessions to LDCs as “South Asian Free Trade Agreement“

(SAFTA), “Everything But Arms” (EBA) initiative that is initiated by the European Union (EU).

(CDP, 2008, p.17)

19

Despite these preferential market accesses offered, LDCs continue to experience important

obstacles to the full utilization of trade preferences including supply-side constraints, rules of

origin restrictions, non-tariff barriers complying with product standards, sanitary measures and

eco-labeling and subsidies in developed countries. (CDP, 2008, p.17) Especially, supply

constraints constitute a major obstacle affecting the exporting capacity of most LDCs not only in

terms of the lack of adequate trade infrastructure but also in terms of their own narrow production

base. Supply capacity is often negatively affected by weak or inadequate institutional and

governance structures which verify that the governance is the most important structural

impediments to growth in LDCs as mentioned before. (CDP, 2010, p.11)

3.1.2. Other Trade-Related Measures

In addition to preferential market access, LDCs benefit from other “special and differential

treatment” (SDT) related to the disciplines of WTO agreements and have access to the

“Integrated Framework” (IF) and “Enhanced Integrated Framework” (EIF) for trade-related

technical assistance to LDCs. (CDP, 2010, p.11)

SDTs for LDCs are expected to facilitate the integration of LDCs into the multilateral trade

regime by exempting them from having to comply with certain disciplines or by giving them

extended periods or technical assistance, or both, to implement the measures. (CDP, 2010, p.11)

The impact of SDTs on the growth of LDCs is debatable since exemptions to WTO

obligations may not benefit LDCs in the long run if STDs lead them to postpone the reforms

necessary for creating more open economies. Most LDCs have small economies and cannot

develop without being open to outside markets, and high protectionist barriers would hinder

productivity growth and the strengthening of their competitiveness. It is also not clear whether

WTO disciplines are compatible with the current stage of development in LDCs. These countries

are structurally vulnerable to external shocks and need a careful examination of flexible outward-

oriented measures and supports are required. Since SDTs alone cannot accelerate development in

LDCs, measures are needed to increase the resilience of the LDCs to external shocks, which

include insurance mechanisms, shock-smoothing facilities and capacity-building, together with

the other specific measures discussed in the previous section. (CDP, 2010, p.13)

20

Some of these provisions have already expired or are no longer applicable such as; the longer

period extended to LDCs for implementing certain WTO agreements has expired; special

provisions for LDCs for the “Agreement on Textiles and Clothing” (ATC), are no longer

applicable.

The IF was created in 1997 aiming to deliver technical assistance to improve the capacity of

LDCs to formulate, negotiate and implement trade policies so as to facilitate and derive greater

benefits from their integration into the multilateral trading system. Since only modest results

were accomplished during the early years, it was strengthened in 2007 as the enhanced Integrated

Framework. The EIF aims to achieve qualitative goals such as mainstreaming trade into

development policies and improving policy-making processes. (CDP, 2010, p.13)

3.2. International Aid

3.2.1. Bilateral Assistance

The United Nations PoAs for LDCs grants provisions for giving priority to LDCs in the

allocation of official development assistance (ODA). It started with the first United Nations

Conference on the LDCs in 1981 stating that the members of the Development Assistance

Committee of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD/DAC)

committed themselves to allocating 0.15 per cent of their total gross national income (GNI) to

LDCs, including funds that are channeled through international organizations, while there are no

targets for individual LDCs. The ratio has fluctuated between 0.08 and 0.1 per cent since the first

LDC Conference and stood at 0.09 per cent in 2008. In turn, aid to LDCs as a share of total aid

fluctuated around the 30 percent despite an increase in the number of LDCs since 1971. (CDP,

2010, p.14)

The introduction of the LDC category in 1971 drew the attention of donors to the these

countries in a way that the average growth rate of ODA to LDCs nearly trebled to 23.7 per cent

per year during the 1970s, from an average annual rate of growth of 8.4 per cent of ODA to the

same countries in the 1960s. In contrast, ODA to other developing countries grew on average by

10 per cent per year in the 1970s from 3.4 per cent in the 1960s. (CDP, 2010, p.14)

21

This favorable allocation of aid to LDCs was reversed during the 1980s and 1990s. The

average annual rate of growth of ODA flows to LDCs slowed down to about 6.9 per cent in the

1980s and even contracted by an annual rate of 3.7 percent in the 1990s. In contrast, aid to other

developing countries grew by 7.9 percent during the 1980s, 1 percentage point higher than aid to

LDCs, and declined only marginally, about 0.5 percent per year during the 1990s. ODA flows to

LDCs recovered in the 2000s as it can be seen in Figure 6, but were comparable to the recovery

observed in flows directed to other developing countries. It suggests that belonging to the

category of LDC does not necessarily imply that an LDC will receive a relatively greater amount

of bilateral aid than other developing countries even to the United Nations conferences and

international communities that promised to favor LDCs to overcome their structural weaknesses

to grow. (CDP, 2010, p.14)

Figure 5: Official development assistance (ODA) to LDCs, value and percentage of GNI of

DAC member countries, 1990- 2006

Source: OECD Development Database on Aid from DAC Members. (CDP, 2008, p.27, Figure

II.1)

22

The contribution of ODA to the growth of LDC economies is generally difficult to assess

since the literature has not yet reached a consensus on what makes aid more effective, although it

tends to confirm that aid itself is generally an important tool for enhancing the development

prospects of poor nations in specific contexts. It is argued that aid flows have a significant impact

on the growth of countries that are structurally more vulnerable, particularly countries that

experience high instability in their export earnings. This implies that, in countries where GNI per

capita and the human assets index (HAI) are similar, aid is more effective in the country with

higher economic vulnerability especially resulting from the negative effects of shocks. (CDP,

2010, p.15)

The results of an econometric analysis by Guillaumont and Chauvet (2001) who consider the

three criteria used to classify countries as LDCs, indicate that there is a statistically significant,

negative relationship between per capita ODA and per capita income of the recipient LDC.

Hence, it can be concluded that aid allocation seems to favor those LDCs that are further away

from the graduation threshold in terms of per capita GNI. In other words, poorer countries get

more aid. Also a similar relationship is observed between ODA per capita and the HAI, implying

that LDCs with fewer human assets tend to get more ODA. There is a statistically insignificant,

positive correlation between the economic vulnerability index (EVI) and ODA per capita. So,

there does not seem to be a systematic effort by donors to use aid to mitigate economic

vulnerability once GNI per capita and HAI have been taken into account.. (CDP, 2010, p.16)

Development assistance for the LDCs needs to be increased in quantity and made more

effective through improved coordination among donors with the development strategies of

recipient LDCs. The potential for increasing aid effectiveness should be unleashed through

untying of aid, aligning of support with country priorities, giving more aid as budget support on

long-term commitments, and harmonizing donor policies and practices in all forms of aid

delivery, reducing the uncertainty and unpredictability of aid flows through long-term

commitments. (CDP, 2004, p.8)

Donors should also increase the share of ODA in the form of grants, particularly to countries

with high economic vulnerability to ensure that the debt of LDCs is sustainable in the long term.

(CDP, 2004, p.7)

23

3.2.2. Multilateral Assistance

Several multilateral organizations carry out programmes specially designed for providing

assistance to the LDCs. (CDP, 2008, p.30)

3.2.2.1. Global Environment Facility (GEF)

The GEF with the assistance of its implementing agencies, UNDP, UNEP and the World

Bank manages the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC) for

LDCs to support projects addressing the urgent and immediate adaptation needs of the LDCs as

identified by their national adaptation programmes of action (NAPAs). The Least Developed

Countries Fund (LDCF) responds to the unique circumstances of the LDCs, which are the low

capacity and highly vulnerable to the adverse impacts of climate change. These LDCs are in need

of immediate and urgent support in starting to adapt to current and projected adverse effects of

climate change. LDCF provide support for the preparation and implementation of NAPAs that

propose activities whose further delay could increase vulnerability or lead to increased costs at a

later stage. To date, 15 donor countries are contributing to the LDCF on a voluntary basis have

pledged to the LDCF: Canada, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Ireland, Italy, the

Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland and the United

Kingdom and Northern Ireland. The total amount pledged is $120 million. (CDP, 2008, p.31)

3.2.2.2. The United Nations Capital Development Fund (UNCDF)

The United Nations General Assembly adopted a resolution requesting the UNCDF to

concentrate its investments, first and foremost, in the LDCs in 1973. UNCDF is now active on

the ground in 37 of the 48 LDCs by focusing in support to decentralized public investments and

support to private investments through micro-financing. The approach of UNCDF is to support

the LDCs in piloting small-scale investments that can be replicated on a larger scale with the

assistance of other development partners who can bring additional financial support. (CDP, 2008,

p.31)

3.2.2.3. World Food Programme (WFP)

The WFP allocates at least 50 percent of its development resources to LDCs and at least 90

percent to low-income food-deficit countries (LIFDCs) including LDCs. Up to 10 per cent of

24

resources will remain available to meet either the additional needs of these countries or the

special needs of non-LIFDCs. The WFP will increase the level of development activities in LDCs

by investing in their capacity to implement food aid programmes including training or support for

non-food inputs and essential services, providing up to 20 per cent of resources for food fund

facilities and experimental projects, and supporting the maintenance of infrastructure and basic

public services on a trial basis, as long as phase-out plans are specified and results closely

monitored. (CDP, 2008, p.31)

3.2.2.4. World Meteorological Organization (WMO)

The WMO established a programme for LDCs in 2003 by a trust fund to receive voluntary

cash contributions from members, bilateral and multilateral funding agencies and other

cooperating partners. The WMO programme aims to enhance and strengthen the capacities of the

National Meteorological and Hydrological Services (NMHSs) of LDCs so that they can meet the

national, regional and global needs in relation to weather, climate and water. (CDP, 2008, p.31)

3.3. Other Forms of Support Measures

The United Nations provides financial support for the participation of representatives of

LDCs in annual sessions of the General Assembly by paying the travel, but not subsistence

expenses as follows; up to five representatives per LDC attending a regular session of the General

Assembly, one representative per LDC attending a special or emergency session of the General

Assembly, and one member of a permanent mission in New York designated as a representative

or alternate to a session of the General Assembly. (CDP, 2008, p.32)

A number of United Nations organizations and conventions have also established financial

mechanisms to fund the participation of LDCs in their processes as follows; the specific trust

fund for the travel and daily subsistence allowance of two representatives from each LDC to

attend the annual review of the third PoA, the voluntary trust fund to assist developing countries,

in particular LDCs, small island developing States and landlocked developing States, to attend

meetings of the United Nations Consultative Process on Oceans and the Law of the Sea by

covering the costs of travel and daily subsistence allowance and the United Nations Framework

Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC) special Trust Fund for Facilitating the Participation

of Parties in the UNFCCC Process provides funding to LDCs. (CDP, 2008, p.32)

25

Overall, existing international support measures for LDCs have generated rather limited

results because of the following reasons: the goals set by the strategies may have been

excessively ambitious suggesting a lack of coherence between the objectives and the policy

measures instituted to achieve them; even where goals were reasonable, there were difficulties in

implementing the strategy owing to inadequate external support, misguided domestic policies,

poor governance or random shocks; the measures turned out to be inadequate because the LDC

strategy had overemphasized those international measures whose impact on growth, poverty

alleviation; and eventually graduation had not been convincingly demonstrated and the strategies

include measures which may be “necessary” but not “sufficient” to address the structural

handicaps affecting the LDCs as many important domestic and international obstacles to

development were neglected. (CDP, 2010, p.19)

26

CHAPTER 4: CLASSIFICATION OF GOVERNANCE

INSTITUTIONS

According to North (1991), institutions are the humanly devised constraints that structure

political, economic and social interaction in order to create order and reduce uncertainty in

exchange. They define the choice set and therefore determine transaction and production costs

and hence the profitability and feasibility of engaging in economic activity. They provide the

incentive structure of an economy; as that structure evolves, it shapes the direction of economic

change towards growth, stagnation, or decline.

Governance is defined as the management of society by the traditions and institutions that

determine how authority is exercised in a particular country. (Kaufmann, Kraay and Lobatón,

2000 and CDP, 2004, p.9)

Currently, there are two distinct streams of discourse on good governance as one is rooted in

academic research and the other is donor-driven. Academic discourse has dealt mainly with the

way in which power and authority relations are structured in different contexts as in the aggregate

governance clusters in the study, whereas the donor-driven discourse has focused more on state

structures designed to ensure accountability, due processes of law, and related safeguards.

Academic discourse is directed mainly towards better understanding of institutional linkages

among the State, civil society and the private sector. Donor-driven discourse is oriented towards

enhancing policy effectiveness as in the PoAs and CDP reports. (CDP, 2004, p.9)

There exist two propositions for the effect of governance on growth; theoretical proposition

and normative proposition namely. Theoretical proposition argues that institutions and economic

policies of a country are decisive for its economic performance and normative proposition argues

that any poor countries that adopt relatively good economic policies and institutions enjoy rapid

catch-up growth. (Avellaneda, 2009)

The concept of good governance is first considered in donor discourse in 1990, when the

World Bank adopted it as a condition for lending to developing countries. In the beginning, the

notion was rather apolitical and focused primarily on improving the quality of public sector

management in recipient countries. By the mid-1990s, concept of good governance had expanded

27

to include the notions of transparency, accountability and participation and the aspect of

predictability was added to the mix in the wake of the financial crises of the late 1990s, along

with calls for improvements in corporate governance and international financial market stability.

Currently, the concept of good governance is being explored at three separate, interacting levels

as: the national level which covers all of the standard elements of a political, economic and

administrative nature; the global level which encompasses all of those elements introduced by the

process of globalization, including the regulation of global public goods and stability in capital

flows and the corporate level. (CDP, 2004, p.10) The study is concentrated on the national level.

The Committee focused its attention on governance at the national level and the concept of

good governance is currently predicated upon mutually supportive and cooperative relationships

among government, civil society and the private sector assume critical importance. (CDP, 2004,

p.10) Successful implementation of the objectives, policies, commitments and measures at the

national level among other things should be supported by good governance through transparent,

accountable, and efficient institutions and practices within the Government, the private sector and

civil society. (UN Conference, 2001)

4.1. Literature on Classification of Governance Institutions

Various authors have aggregated certain indices to better capture the common features of the

governance institutions under main clusters that are reflecting different aspects of governance

institutions.

How to measure good governance, as well as which indicators to select, is based on analytical

frameworks that are normative in character since the same indicator may elicit different

interpretations depending on which value judgments are utilized and different sets of indicators

may be used to measure governance, depending on the nature of the ends in question. (CDP,

2004, p.10)

4.1.1. Kaufmann, Kraay and Mastruzzi (2003)

In order to measure different aspects of governance, they categorized governance institutions

in 6 broad groups based on 194 variables drawn from 17 different sources. They defined

governance as the traditions and institutions by which authority in a country is exercised. The

28

ability of the government to formulate and implement sound policies is summarized in

“Government Effectiveness” and “Regulatory Quality” indices . The respect of citizens and the

state for the institutions which govern their interactions is categorized as “Rule of Law” and

“Control of Corruption”. "Political Stability and Absence of Violence" measure perceptions of

likelihood that the government in power will not be destabilized and indicate the continuity of

policies. “Voice and Accountability” captures the process by which citizens of a country are able

to participate in the selection of their government.

4.1.2. World Bank (2003)

For the MENA region, the World Bank (2003) used principal component analysis (PCA)

which is performed on 22 indicators of governance to derive three broad indexes as “Index of

Public Accountability (IPA), which aggregates 12 indicators”, “Index of Quality of

Administration (IQA), which aggregates 10 indicators” and “Index of Governance Quality (IGQ),

which aggregates all 22 indicators.

4.1.3. Aysan, Nabli and Varoudakis (2006)

For the MENA region, they categorized the governance variables which are likely to affect

individual investors’ decision into 3 broad clusters: “Quality of Administration” (QA) which

aggregates 4 indicators, “Public Accountability” which aggregates 2 indicators (PA), and

“Political Stability” (PS) which aggregates 4 indicators.

The Committee also reviewed several approaches to the measurement of good governance at

the national level where the goals of social equality and poverty reduction had been explicitly

included in the construction of questionnaires and self-assessment methodologies. Three projects

for the measurement of good governance models for LDCs are offered: (CDP, 2004, p.11)

4.1.4. Economic Commission for Africa (ECA) Project

In order to monitor the progress towards good governance in a sample of 28 countries in the 5

sub-regions of Africa, 6 components of good governance that yield data on 83 indicators have

been identified as: political system that encourages input from all groups of civil society;

impartial and credible electoral administration, and an informed and active citizenry;

strengthened public sector legislative and administrative institutions; transparency, predictability,

29

and accountability in decisions by government and public bodies; effective public sector

management with stable macroeconomic conditions, effective resource mobilization, and

efficient use of public resources; and adherence to the rule of law in a manner that protects

personal and civil liberties and gender equity, and ensures public safety and security with equal

access to justice for all. (CDP, 2004, p.11)

4.1.5. Asian Development Bank/Viet Nam

The Poverty Task Force of the Asian Development Bank has produced a proposal for the

implementation of the Comprehensive Poverty Reduction and Growth Strategy of the

Government of Viet Nam. Five areas of governance have been identified for improvement as:

more efficient public service; more transparent public financial management; wider access to

justice and ensuring its universal application; more participative and responsive government; and

a government that fights corruption at all levels. Eight outcome and process indicators have been

developed to assess progress in the five areas, namely: level of information publicly available

regarding services, policies and planning arrangements at all levels; extent of access of the poor

to such basic government services as health, education, infrastructure, water and power at the

local level; level of budget transparency regarding provincial and local taxation, budgeting and

spending patterns in each sector; extent to which, at the national level, the level of expenditure

that is targeted to pro-poor purposes is predictable from year to year; extent to which the

decisions and verdicts of courts and tribunals are publicly available; extent to which local

government is responsive and follows up on service delivery problems that are brought to its

attention by the poor; extent to which the Grass-roots Democracy Decree has been implemented

in each commune so as to improve opportunities for public participation; and extent to which

laws combating corruption are effective. (CDP, 2004, p.12)

4.1.6. African Peer Review Mechanism (APRM)

It is a self monitoring mechanism, intended to foster the adoption of policies, standards and

practices that will lead to political stability, sustainable development and regional and continental

integration through sharing of experiences and of successful best practices, including identifying

deficiencies and assessing the need for capacity building, voluntarily acceded to by the member

States of the African Union (AU). The APRM focuses on four main areas with specific

30

objectives, standards and codes, criteria and indicators in terms of which the programmes and

policies of the participating countries will be assessed as: political governance; economic

governance; corporate governance; and socio-economic development. They use different

indicators to reflect different dimensions of governance with a great deal of variation in the

specification of measures for cross-national comparisons and rankings and also for tracking the

development record of a country over time. (CDP, 2004, p.13)

4.2. Classification of Governance Institutions in the Study

The main categorization of governance clusters developed by Aysan, Nabli and Varoudakis

(2006) are used in the study by adding two more governance indicators to “Political Stability”

and changing the name of “Public Accountability” as “Democratic Accountability Public Voice

Index” by adding one more governance indicators to this cluster.

Three aggregate governance clusters are composed as Aysan et al. (2006)’s governance

categorizations considering;

Although these indices are subjective and outcome-based rather than representing the quality

of actual institutions, deficiencies in these governance perceptions depending on experts’ views

and surveys do not constitute a severe problem in analyzing the effects of governance on growth

since especially the private investors and donor countries or WTO takes these kinds of

governance data into consideration for investment or aid decisions for these countries at the time

of investment or aid. Thus like a self-fulfilling prophecy, the true governance perceptions is

realized according to these possibly subjective deficient governance perceptions.

4.2.1. Administrative Quality Index (AQI)

AQI assesses the capability of the public administration to formulate and implement sound

policies and the respect for the institutions governing interactions between citizens and

government. (World Bank, 2003, p. xix)

“The process by which governments are selected, monitored and replaced”, “the

capacity of the government to effectively formulate and implement sound policies”,

and the respect of citizens and the state for the institutions that govern economic and

social interactions among them”. (Kaufman and Kraay, 2002, p.5)

31

AQI consists of four indicators from ICRG Database (2010) named as “Corruption”,

“Bureaucracy Quality”, “Investment Profile” and “Law and Order”.

4.2.1.1. Corruption

Corruption has negative effects on economic growth by rising risks in business environment,

leading popular discontent, leading to unrealistic and inefficient controls on the economy and

encouraging the development of black market. (World Bank, 2003, p.183) This index is in the

form of “control over corruption” meaning that high scores corresponding less corruption

perceptions. Thus it is expected that good performance in control over corruption leads to growth

by tackling problems above.

4.2.1.2. Bureaucracy Quality

It assesses the degree of strength and expertise the bureaucrats have and the ability of them to

manage public services. Good performance on this index suggests that autonomous bureaucracies

established which are free from political pressures and an established mechanism for recruitment

and training. (World Bank, 2003, p.184)

4.2.1.3. Investment Profile

It assesses the attitude of the government to inward investment by considering contract

viability, taxation, labor costs, profit repatriation and risk to operations including start-up and

operating costs. (Aysan, 2006) Good performance in this index as tackling the problems of

overregulation and over-taxation which deter investments enhances growth. (World Bank, 2003,

p.184)

4.2.1.4. Law and Order

It assesses both the strength and impartiality of the legal system and popular observance of

the law. (Aysan, 2006) Good performance for this index suggests that the institutions ensure

equitable and consistent rule of law protecting private property.

32

4.2.2. Political Stability Index (PSI)

PSI consists of five indicators from ICRG Database (2010) as “Government Stability”,

“Internal Conflict”, “External Conflict”, “Ethnic Tensions” and “Religious Tensions”.

4.2.2.1. Government Stability

It assesses the ability of government to carry out its declared program(s) and to stay in office

by considering the type of governance, the unity of the government, approach of an election, and

command of the legislature and popular approval of government policies. (Aysan, 2006 and

ICRG Variables, 2012)

4.2.2.2. Internal Conflict

It assesses the political violence in the country and its actual or potential impact on

governance by considering civil war, civil disorder and terrorism within borders. Highest

performance suggests that both of no armed opposition to government and no arbitrary violence

to the citizens by the government. (Aysan, 2006 and ICRG Variables, 2012)

4.2.2.3. External Conflict

It assesses both the risk to the incumbent government and to inward investment, ranging from

trade restrictions and embargoes through geopolitical disputes, armed threats and warfare, cross-

border conflicts and foreign-supported insurgency. (ICRG Variables, 2012)

4.2.2.4. Ethnic Tensions

It assesses the degree of tension attributable to racial, national, or language divisions. Lower

performance scores are given to countries where tensions are high because of intolerant and

uncompromising opposing groups. (ICRG Variables, 2012)

4.2.2.5. Religious Tensions

It assesses the degree of religious tensions arising from the domination or a desire of

domination of society by a single religious group to replace civil law by religious law and to

exclude other religions from the political or social processes by suppressing religious freedom or

expressions of religious identity. (ICRG Variables, 2012)

33

4.2.3. Democratic Accountability Public Voice Index (DAPVI)

DAPVI consists of two indicators from the International Country Risk Guide (ICRG, 2010) as

“Democratic Accountability” and “Military in Politics” and two indicators from Freedom House

(FRH) as “Political Rights” and “Civil Liberties”.

4.2.3.1. Democratic Accountability

It assesses the degree of free and fair elections and the responsiveness of government to

citizens.

4.2.3.2. Military in Politics

It assesses the degree of the military's involvement in politics stemming from an external or

internal threat, or be a full-scale military takeover. (ICRG Variables, 2012)

4.2.3.3. Political Rights

It assesses the degree of not only the free and fair elections of head of the state, government

and legislative representatives but also the fair electoral laws. It also questions whether the people

have the ability to organize in different political parties or groups of their choice that increse their

support or gain power through elections. (World Bank 2003, p.180)

4.2.3.4. Civil Liberties

It assesses the degree of freedom of press, assembly, demonstration, equality of citizens under

the law, nondiscriminatory judiciary, protection from unjustified imprisonment, exile or torture,

free businesses or cooperatives, personal social freedom including gender equality, property

rights, freedom of movement and the equality of opportunity for the citizens.

Contrary to the ratings of ICRG (2010), the ratings of Freedom House for “Political Rights”

and Civil Liberties” are originally decreases as performance of the corresponding country

increases. Thus, these ratings of FRH were revised in a way that higher ratings correspond to

higher performances.

34

4.2.4. Governance Quality Index (GOVI)

This overall governance index summarizes all three aspects of governance. Instead PCA, the

averages of three aggregate governance indices of AQI, PSI and DAPVI are taken since all the

possible correlations among single governance indices are consumed by creating these three

aggregate governance clusters.

35

CHAPTER 5: GOVERNANCE IN LDCs

CDP (2008) states that the underlying principle of identifying LDCs as “low-income

countries that face structural handicaps to growth” has essentially remained, although the

indicators composing the criteria are evolved over time as a “measurement of long-term structural

weaknesses”.

Governance is one of the ignored structural handicaps that the study attempts to contribute to.

Even though governance has never been considered as an indicator for the identifying criteria of

LDCs, the importance of good governance institutions have always been considered especially

for poverty reduction. The CDP considers in 2003 triennial review that good governance could be

instrumental for achieving the goals of poverty reduction only if the process of measurement and

assessment is not biased in favor of external criteria relevant to the donors, investors and

international monitoring bodies, as opposed to the internal perspective of the country. In

designing institutions and mechanisms for good governance in LDCs, an interactive process

between donors and recipient countries is essential. Although recipient countries need assistance

from donors to bring their institutions and social, political and economic processes closer to those

required by good governance, measures imposed by donors consider the cultural and historical

characteristics of recipient countries to be succeed. LCDs should be invited to participate in the

deliberations of institutions where global norms and standards for aspects of good governance are

established. (CDP, 2004, p.iii)

For LDCs, good governance is a necessary condition for expanding their ability to generate

income and reduce poverty in the future. Good governance enhances economic efficiency and

reduces transaction costs through the effective application of the rule of law, transparency in

government and corporate management, and accountability for every institution and individual in

society. To the extent that good governance catalyses civil society to increase the rate of physical

and human capital accumulation, it can also help to reduce dependency and vulnerability of

LDCs, and even ameliorate the impact of economic vulnerability they face. LDCs should

continue to participate in the discourse on good governance and should develop expertise and

capacity in this area. Improving governance should be part of their national policy agenda and

should be implemented in ways that are relevant to their particular conditions. International

36

institutions that establish global norms and standards for aspects of good governance should

involve LDCs in their deliberations. Moreover, such bodies should themselves be subject to good

governance principles. (CDP, 2004, p.13)

Weaknesses in governance, such as lack of transparency and accountability in the public

sector and occurrences of corruption, reduce the ability of LDCs to participate in the global

marketplace through trade, attract foreign direct investment (FDI) and obtain external assistance

as well. LDCs should strive for governance systems that are characterized by participation in and

transparency of decision-making processes and that embody pro-poor policies, social safety nets,

policies for the sustainable use of resources and effective monitoring. (CDP, 2004, p.6)

Despite efforts by LDCs, their governance goals have not yet been achieved. These efforts

need to be pursued, with the support of the international community as an essential factor. In

LDCs, many institutions and processes are inadequately developed, reflecting low overall levels

of socio-economic development. It should be recognized that promoting good governance in

these countries needs to be approached with a long-term view. (UN Conference, 2001)

Governance issues at the international level and international economic decision making

processes that affect the development of LDCs, including issues of their effective participation,

should be addressed. Multilateral policy and regulatory issues that affect the development efforts

of LDCs should also be addressed. The circumstances and interests of LDCs should be taken

fully into account in multilateral institutions and processes. Adequate attention must be paid to

checking unfair business practices and corruption by multinational companies, domestic firms

and any other business entities. (UN Conference, 2001)

Committee advised that an interactive process between donors and recipient countries is

essential while designing institutions and mechanisms for good governance in developing

countries. “The importance of the assistance that are needed by recipient countries from donors to

bring their institutions and social, political and economic processes closer to those required by

good governance”, “weaknesses in governance, such as lack of transparency and accountability

in the public sector and occurrences of corruption, reduce the ability of LDCs to participate in the

global marketplace through trade, attract FDI and, increasingly, obtain external assistance as

well” and “bad policies and bad governance in recipient countries were considered largely

37

responsible for the aid being ineffective in achieving its objectives” were emphasized in 2004

triennial review. The Committee proposed that LDCs be invited to participate in the deliberations

of institutions where global norms and standards for aspects of good governance are established.

CDP (2004) states that good governance has become a condition for development assistance from

donor agencies in the third PoA for the LDCs (2001-2010)

But the main significance of governance institutions in LDCs, or the role of deficient

governance institutions causing to less developed status of LDCs by other words, has never been

emphasized neither by the CDP nor the involving parties at the triennial reviews that are

organized by CDP in every three years since 1971. This point; “the role of governance

institutions on growth in LDCs” measured by the author’s own governance indicators will be

another contribution of this thesis to the literature. By classifying aggregate governance indices

each reflecting distinct sphere of governance, we are able to discuss what types of governance

institutions bear the utmost importance for growth in LDCs.

Since the early 1990s, the notion of good governance, as being necessary for sustainable

development and poverty reduction has gained widespread currency, especially among

international organizations. Market-based structural adjustment policies had failed to rekindle

economic growth in many countries, and concern that aid was often ineffective in achieving its

objectives. Bad policies and bad governance in recipient countries were considered largely

responsible for these failures. Hence, good governance has become a condition for development

assistance from donor agencies.

Throughout this chapter, all the aggregate governance indices are calculated by Principal

Component Analysis (PCA) instead of natural logarithm of simple averages in order to depict the

huge difference in governance performance between LDCs and High Income OECD Countries.

38

5.1. Comparison of Governance and Growth in LDCs and High Income

OECD Countries

As it can be seen from the Table 2 for individual countries or Figure 1 for country groupings,

the LDCs can be characterized by a clear deficit in “good” governance institutions. (See Chapter

3 for the categorization of governance clusters and their sub indices) “Economies that are

different for a variety of differences will differ both in their institutions and in their per capita

income” (Acemoglu et al., 2001, p.1369) as in the case of High Income OECD countries and

LDCs in Figure 1.

We can analyze Figure 1 as relationships between governance quality and per capita incomes

or governance quality and growth in the very long run, “since initial per capita incomes in the

distant path were not very different across countries, the current dispersion in per capita incomes

on the vertical axis reflects differences across countries in growth in the very long run”.

(Kaufman and Kraay, 2002, p.1) The positive correlations between our aggregate governance

indicators and GDP per capita suggest that better governance leads to higher income per capita

thus growth. The separate block dispersion of corresponding High Income OECD and LDC

scores in Figure 1 also illustrates the hypothesis that “Rich countries can afford better

institutions” (Acemoglu et al., 2001, p.1369) with exception of Israel, which has a low score of

political stability index because of external conflict, ethnic and religious tensions. Since Israel

established its state after WWII, it does not have long-lived or established institutions as other

developed countries. Thus it has inadequate governance quality and can be considered as an

outlier in the group of high income OECD countries. Figure 1 also shows that the relationship

between natural logarithm of GDP per capita and aggregate governance indicator is more

divergent in LDCs.

39

y = 0.6858x - 5.8867 R² = 0.8577

-3

-2.5

-2

-1.5

-1

-0.5

0

0.5

1

1.5

2

0 5 10 15 AQ

I

ln (GDP per capita, PPP, 2005 $)

Averages of Administrative Quality

Index and GDP per capita (1985-2010)

HIGH

INCOME OECD

LDC

SUD

HAI CON

ANG

GAM

LIB

y = 0.3644x - 3.1276 R² = 0.5498

-3

-2.5

-2

-1.5

-1

-0.5

0

0.5

1

1.5

0 3 6 9 12 PSI

ln (GDP per capita, PPP, 2005 $)

Averages of Political Stability Index and

GDP per capita (1985-2010)

ISR

SUD

TAN CON

LIB

MOZ GAM

ANG LDC

HIGH

INCOME OECD

y = 0.8864x - 7.6087 R² = 0.8204

-4

-3

-2

-1

0

1

2

3

0 3 6 9 12

DA

PV

I

ln (GDP per capita, PPP, 2005 $)

Averages of Democratic Accountability

Political Voice Index and GDP per capita

(1985-2010)

HIGH

INCOME OECD

ANG

MYA

SUD TAN CON

ZAM ISR

LDC

Figure 6: Averages of Income and Governance of LDCs and High Income OECD Countries

Source: Author’s Own Calculations based on World Bank, World Development Indicators

(2012) and ICRG Data (2010).

Even though LDCs are no longer colonized countries, they still have both lower per capita

income and inadequate GDP per capita growth rates compared with the developed countries, as it

can be seen in last two columns of Table 2. Even the corresponding growth rates between 1991

and 2009 seem to be high for some of the LDCs, their GDP per capita are very low. So it will be

y = 0.6455x - 5.541 R² = 0.831

-3

-2.5

-2

-1.5

-1

-0.5

0

0.5

1

1.5

2

0 5 10 15 GO

VI

ln (GDP per capita, PPP, 2005 $)

Averages of Aggregate Governance

Index and GDP per capita (1985-2010)

ISR

SUD

HIGH

INCOME OECD

LDC

TAN CON

ANG

40

misleading to conclude that some of the LDCs have high growth rates. Altough Angola which

has a current GDP per capita of 5390 (current USD), it is approximately thirty two percent of that

of Poland, which has the lowest GDP per capita among high income OECD countries (as of

2009). The situation is more severe for other LDCs which has GDP per capita between 298 and

2267 (current USD).

Since the PoA for the LDCs (2001-2010) by the UN stated that recipient LDCs need

assistance from donors to bring their institutions and social, political and economic processes

closer to those required by good governance and also the donor countries and the other countries

that extend financial aid to LDCs are mostly OECD countries, the quality of governance

institutions of LDCs were compared with the quality of governance institutions of High Income

OECD countries according to the aggregate governance indices which are calculated by PCA as

mentioned above.

5.2. The Evolution of Governance in LDCs

The following four descriptive statistics are evaluated for twenty four LDCs and for twenty

seven High Income OECD countries:

• The evolution of the standard deviation of each aggregate governance indicator,

• The average index values of each aggregate governance indicator of LDCs compared with

High Income OECD countries,

• For the diverging aggregate governance indicators, the evolution of LDCs which are

above or below one standard deviation of the average governance indicators.

5.2.1. Administrative Quality Index (AQI)

The decreasing trend in the standard deviation of AQI indicates the convergence of LDCs

with respect to this indicator. The increasing trend in the average value together with the

convergence shows that LDCs have generally improved with respect to this indicator. (See Figure

7)

Compared with the High Income OECD countries, LDCs have poor performance in

administrative quality index because of inadequate control over corruption leading to unrealistic

and inefficient controls on the economy and encouraging the development of black market, low

41

0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

19

91

19

92

19

93

19

94

19

95

19

96

19

97

19

98

19

99

20

00

20

01

20

02

20

03

20

04

20

05

20

06

20

07

20

08

20

09

20

10

Standart Deviation of AQI

AQI

-2

-1.5

-1

-0.5

0

0.5

1

1.5

2

19

91

19

92

19

93

19

94

19

95

19

96

19

97

19

98

19

99

20

00

20

01

20

02

20

03

20

04

20

05

20

06

20

07

20

08

20

09

20

10

Averages of AQI

HIGH INCOME OECD LDC

bureaucracy quality indicating deficient public services, high political pressures on bureaucrats

and inefficient mechanism for recruitment and training (World Bank, 2003, p.184), low

investment profile indicating to high risks for business environment in the form of lack of

contract viability, overregulation and over-taxation and poor performance on law and order

indicates the weak, partial, unequal, inconsistent legal system and also the common disobedience

to the law which protecting private property. (Aysan et al., 2006)

Figure 7: Evolution of AQI in LDCs

Source: Author’s Own Calculations based on ICRG Data (2010).

5.2.2. Political Stability Index (PSI)

The decreasing trend in the standard deviation of PSI indicates the convergence of LDCs with

respect to this indicator. The increasing trend in the average value together with the convergence

shows that LDCs were generally improved with respect to this indicator. (See Figure 8)

Compared with the High Income OECD countries, although the performance of LDCs seem

to have improved, they are still behind the High Income OECD countries in political stability

index because of the inability of governments in LDCs to carry out their declared program(s),

popular disapproval of government policies, trade restrictions and embargoes, political violence

arising from civil war, civil disorder, terrorism, warfare, ethnic and religious tensions. (Aysan et

al., 2006 and ICRG Variables, 2012)

42

-2.5

-2

-1.5

-1

-0.5

0

0.5

1

1.5

19

91

19

92

19

93

19

94

19

95

19

96

19

97

19

98

19

99

20

00

20

01

20

02

20

03

20

04

20

05

20

06

20

07

20

08

20

09

20

10

Averages of PSI

HIGH INCOME OECD LDC

0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

1.2

19

91

19

92

19

93

19

94

19

95

19

96

19

97

19

98

19

99

20

00

20

01

20

02

20

03

20

04

20

05

20

06

20

07

20

08

20

09

20

10

Standart Deviation of PSI

PSI

Figure 8: Evolution of PSI in LDCs

Source: Author’s Own Calculations based on ICRG Data (2010).

5.2.3. Democratic Accountability Political Voice Index (DAPVI)

The non-decreasing trend in the standard deviation of DAPVI indicates the divergence of

LDCs with respect to this indicator. The increasing trend in the average value together with the

divergence shows that while some LDCs have improved, some of the others have worsened with

respect to this indicator. The main problem is to identify the countries that improved or

worsened. (See Figure 9)

While the performance of Mali and Zambia improved one standard deviation of the mean,

Congo Democratic Republic, Myanmar, Sudan and Tanzania are deteriorated one standard

deviation of the mean with respect to this index, especially after 1992.

Compared with the High Income OECD countries, LDCs, especially those four LDCs

mentioned above, have poor performance in this index because of unfair elections and electoral

laws, irresponsiveness of governments to their citizens, coups and dicta regimes, inability of

people to organize in different political parties or groups, partial press, inequality of citizens

under the law, unjustified imprisonments, gender inequality, less freedom of movement and

inequality of opportunity for the citizens. (ICRG Variables, 2012)

43

-2.5

-2

-1.5

-1

-0.5

0

0.5

1

1.5

2

19

91

19

92

19

93

19

94

19

95

19

96

19

97

19

98

19

99

20

00

20

01

20

02

20

03

20

04

20

05

20

06

20

07

20

08

20

09

20

10

Averages of DAPVI

HIGH INCOME OECD LDC

0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

1.2

1.4

19

91

19

92

19

93

19

94

19

95

19

96

19

97

19

98

19

99

20

00

20

01

20

02

20

03

20

04

20

05

20

06

20

07

20

08

20

09

20

10

Standart Deviation of DAPVI

DAPVI

-4

-3.5

-3

-2.5

-2

-1.5

-1

-0.5

0

0.5

1

19

91

19

92

19

93

19

94

19

95

19

96

19

97

19

98

19

99

20

00

20

01

20

02

20

03

20

04

20

05

20

06

20

07

20

08

20

09

20

10

LDCs Improved or Worsened w.r.t. DAPVI

Zambia

Mali

Congo,DR

Tanzania

Sudan

Myanmar

Figure 9: Evolution of DAPVI in LDCs

Source: Author’s Own Calculations based on ICRG Data (2010) and FRH Database (2012).

5.2.4. Aggregate Governance Index (GOVI)

The decreasing trend in the standard deviation of GOVI indicates the convergence of LDCs

with respect to this indicator. The increasing trend in the average value together with the

convergence shows that the governance quality in LDCs generally improved. (See Figure 10)

44

-2

-1.5

-1

-0.5

0

0.5

1

1.5

19

91

19

92

19

93

19

94

19

95

19

96

19

97

19

98

19

99

20

00

20

01

20

02

20

03

20

04

20

05

20

06

20

07

20

08

20

09

20

10

Averages of GOVI

HIGH INCOME OECD LDC

0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

1.2

1.4

19

91

19

92

19

93

19

94

19

95

19

96

19

97

19

98

19

99

20

00

20

01

20

02

20

03

20

04

20

05

20

06

20

07

20

08

20

09

20

10

Standart Deviation of GOVI

GOVI

Because of the argued deficiencies in previous governance clusters in which this aggregate

governance index is the simple average of, the governance quality in LDCs are far below the

High Income OECD countries.

Figure 10: Evolution of GOVI in LDCs

Source: Authur’s Own Calculations based on ICRG Data (2010).

45

CHAPTER 6: EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS

6.1. Methodology: Arellano-Bond (1991) Difference GMM

According to Roodman (2006), the difference GMM estimators are designed for panel

analysis that embodies the following assumptions about the data-generating process as:

The process may be dynamic, with current realizations of the dependent variable are

influenced by the past ones.

There may be arbitrarily distributed fixed individual effects in the dynamic model, so that the

dependent variable consistently changes faster for some observational units than others. This

argues against cross-section regressions, which must essentially assume fixed effects away, and

in favor of a panel set-up, where variation over time can be used to identify parameters.

• The idiosyncratic disturbances, those apart from the fixed effects, may have individual-

specific patterns of heteroscedasticity and serial correlation.

• The idiosyncratic disturbances are uncorrelated across individuals.

• Some regressors may be predetermined but not strictly exogenous; even if independent of

current disturbances, are still influenced by past ones. The lagged dependent variable is an

example.

• Some regressors may be endogenous.

• Finally, since the estimators are designed for general use, they do not assume that good

instruments are available outside the immediate data set. In effect, it is assumed that the

only available instruments are “internal”—based on lags of the instrumented variables.

The general model studied is as followed in the matrix form ;

yit = αyi,t-1 + x’it β + εit

εit = µi + νit

E [µi] = E [νit] = E [µiνit] = 0

i indicates the country and t represents the time of the variable.

i = 1,2,.....,24 (Number of LDCs)

46

t = 1,2,.....,20 (Years from 1991 to 2010)

The disturbance term (εit) has two orthogonal components as the fixed effects (µi) and the

idiosyncratic shocks (νit).

The application of OLS to this empirical model gives rise to “dynamic panel bias” since yi,t-1

is endogenous to the fixed effects (µi) in the error term (εit). The positive correlation between a

regressor and the error violates a necessary assumption for the consistency of OLS. In order to

work around this endogeneity, difference GMM transforms the data to remove the fixed effects.

(Roodman, 2006)

Applying the “first difference transformation” thus “difference GMM”;

∆yit = α∆yi,t-1 + ∆x’it β + ∆νit

Though the fixed effects are gone, the lagged dependent variable is still endogenous, since the

yi,t-1 term in ∆yit = yi,t-1 - yi,t-2 correlates with the νit-1 in ∆νit = νit - νit-1. Likewise, any

predetermined variables in x that are not strictly exogenous become potentially endogenous

because they too may be related to νit-1. But deeper lags of the regressors remain orthogonal to the

error, and available to be used as instruments. (Roodman, 2006)

Since the balanced panel is used in the study, the first-difference transformation does not have

a weakness arising from the missing values of ∆yit and ∆yit-1 in the case of missing values of yit.

The deeper lags of the lagged dependent variable become uncorrelated with the transformed

error term and remain as instruments for the transformed lagged dependent variable. First and

deeper than first lags of endogenous variables were used as instruments in the level equations.

The first differences of exogenous variables were used as instrumental variables in the first-

difference equations.

47

6.2. Data

The study uses yearly data for the natural logarithm of the variables of income per capita

(lngpc), lag of income per capita (lngpcL1), aggregate governance indices (lngovi, lnaqi, lnpsi

and lndapvi), human capital index (lnhumc), import penetration index (lnimpen), trade openness

index (lntrop) and net official development assistance and official aid received (lnaa). Twenty-

four of LDCs are included in the analysis because of data limitations. (See Appendix 4 for the list

of the LDCs included in the analysis). The data is a balanced panel and it covers the 1991-2010

period. In order to construct a balanced panel, linear interpolation and extrapolation techniques

are applied for unavailable 1466 data points which make less than % 13 of all 11976 data points.

The dependent variable is the natural logarithm of GDP per capita (lngpc) which is used as a

proxy for both the income performance of the LDCs in the corresponding year and also the

economic growth in the very long-run since in the distant past, there is no significant difference

in the income level of countries as explained in the Introduction section.

The lag of the dependent variable (lngpcL1) is also used as an independent variable to decide

whether there is convergence or divergence in the income level of LDCs in the short-run or in the

growth in the very long-run.

Administrative Quality Index (lnaqi) is the natural logarithm of the simple average of four

indicators from ICRG Database (2010) named as “Corruption”, “Bureaucracy Quality”,

“Investment Profile” and “Law and Order”.

Political Stability Index (lnpsi) is the natural logarithm of the simple average of five

indicators from ICRG Database (2010) named as “Government Stability”, “Internal Conflict”,

“External Conflict”, “Ethnic Tensions” and “Religious Tensions”.

Democratic Accountability Political Voice Index (lndapvi) is the natural logarithm of the

simple average of four indicators; two from the International Country Risk Guide (ICRG, 2010)

as “Democratic Accountability” and “Military in Politics” and two from Freedom House (FRH)

as “Political Rights” and “Civil Liberties”.

The scores of each index both from ICRG and FRH is converted to 0-100 scale before taking

natural logarithm in which higher values reflects better governance quality.

48

Governance Quality Index (lngovi) summarizes all three aspects of governance. It is the

natural logarithm of simple average of three aggregate governance indices.

Human Capital Index (lnhumc) is the natural logarithm of the average of two sub-indices.

Education sub-index is the simple average of “adult literacy rate”, ”gross primary enrollment

rate”, ”gross secondary enrollment rate” and ”gross tertiary enrollment rate”. Health sub-index is

the simple average of “life-expectancy at birth”, 100-(“mortality rate under 5 years old”/10) and

100-“prevalence of undernourishment”. Mortality rate and prevalence of undernourishment are

revised in the previous formula representing that a higher percentage reflects better performance.

Import penetration Index (lnimpen) is the natural logarithm of the ratio of imports to total

demand (GDP – Exports + Imports).

Trade Openness Index (lntrop) is natural logarithm of the share of total exports and imports

of good and services in GDP.

lnaa is the natural logarithm of the “net official development assistance and official aid

received”.

For the sources of the variables, see Table 3 and for the statistical properties of the variables,

see Table 6.

Table 4 reports the results of LLC and IPS first generation panel unit root tests for the first

differences of all variables since difference GMM uses first-difference transformation. According

to the LLC test, none of the variables have unit root. Thus according to LLC test, it can be

concluded that all of the variables are stationary. According to IPS test, all variables except

lnhumcD1 are stationary. But lnhumcD1 is stationary at % 10 significance level for the case of

constant. Thus, all the variables could be considered as stationary according to IPS test.

49

Table 4: First Generation Panel Unit Root Tests

Variable Case Individual Unit Root Common Unit Root

IPS LLC

lngpcD1

Constant -12.23* -10.87*

(0.00) (0.00)

Constant

and Trend

-10.56* -11.67*

(0.00) (0.00)

lngpcL1D1

Constant -11.56* -10.76*

(0.00) (0.00)

Constant and Trend

-9.52* -12.13*

(0.00) (0.00)

lngoviD1

Constant -13.66* -13.95*

(0.00) (0.00)

Constant and Trend

-13.88* -14.01*

(0.00) (0.00)

lnaqiD1

Constant -16.43* -16.43*

(0.00) (0.00)

Constant

and Trend

-12.69* -10.34*

(0.00) (0.00)

lnpsiD1

Constant -14.75* -17.71*

(0.00) (0.00)

Constant and Trend

-14.04* -16.68*

(0.00) (0.00)

lndapviD1

Constant -13.10* -13.46*

(0.00) (0.00)

Constant and Trend

-10.44* -11.15*

(0.00) (0.00)

lnhumcD1

Constant -1.56 -3.53*

(0.06) (0.00)

Constant

and Trend

-1.08 -2.14*

(0.14) (0.02)

lnimpenD1

Constant -18.11* -16.93*

(0.00) (0.00)

Constant and Trend

-14.62* -12.38*

(0.00) (0.00)

lntropD1

Constant -18.40* -16.84*

(0.00) (0.00)

Constant and Trend

-15.73* -13.19*

(0.00) (0.00)

lnaaD1

Constant -16.84* -17.96*

(0.00) (0.00)

Constant

and Trend

-15.08* -15.81*

(0.00) (0.00)

Note: The null hypothesis for LLC and IPS are unit root. The numbers in brackets are the p-

values for all tests. (*) denotes significance at 5 % level, meaning the rejection of the null of unit

root.

50

Table 5 reports the results of the second generation panel unit root tests. According to the

Moon and Perron test, none of the variables have unit root, hence all are stationary. According to

the Pesaran test, all the variables except lnhumcD1 are stationary. lnhumcD1 is stationary at % 10

significance level for the case of constant when p takes the value of one. So it would not be a

mistake to consider all of the variables stationary.

51

Table 5: Second Generation Panel Unit Root Tests

Variable Case Moon and Perron Test Statistics Pesaran CIPS Test Statistics

k=1 k=4 k=6 p=1 p=2

lngpcD1

Constant ta* -25.98* -28.37* -26.56*

-2.90* -2.71* tb* -7.29* -13.10* -11.84*

Constant and Trend

ta* -15.61* -14.29* -11.84* -3.62* -3.38*

tb* -17.27* -13.66* -10.19*

lngpcL1D1

Constant ta* -47.70* -54.30* -49.72*

-3.16* -3.10* tb* -14.99* -16.14* -14.76*

Constant and Trend

ta* -19.61* -24.05* -20.81* -3.24* -3.26*

tb* -17.88* -23.23* -18.78*

lngoviD1

Constant ta* -37.99* -47.55* -43.22*

-3.48* -3.28* tb* -16.15* -19.20* -16.08*

Constant

and Trend

ta* -20.76* -22.93* -26.05* -3.49* -3.87*

tb* -18.48* -21.41* -25.21*

lnaqiD1

Constant ta* -35.65* -52.83* -53.77*

-3.91* -3.35* tb* -14.66* -23.94* -25.11*

Constant

and Trend

ta* -22.51* -25.48* -25.85* -3.74* -3.29*

tb* -23.84* -24.70* -26.95*

lnpsiD1

Constant ta* -52.11* -52.59* -63.62*

-3.85* -3.60* tb* -24.25* -22.91* -25.26*

Constant and Trend

ta* -32.60* -35.82* -31.86* -3.98* -3.77*

tb* -31.17* -39.12* -32.80*

lndapviD1

Constant ta* -37.26* -47.11* -49.90*

-3.01* -2.74* tb* -13.31* -18.20* -15.71*

Constant and Trend

ta* -16.32* -24.01* -22.85* -3.14* -2.92*

tb* -14.32* -25.38* -20.51*

lnhumcD1

Constant ta* -1.26 -1.37 -1.85*

-2.12 -2.04 tb* -1.56 -3.08* -3.04*

Constant and Trend

ta* -1.95* -4.98* -4.42* -1.91 -1.84

tb* -1.92* -5.50* -4.77*

lnimpenD1

Constant ta* -42.83* -54.08* -58.61*

-3.29* -3.22* tb* -12.42* -17.65* -19.69*

Constant and Trend

ta* -24.94* -35.76* -36.72* -3.45* -3.41*

tb* -19.82* -39.20* -38.94*

lntropD1

Constant ta* -42.60* -61.17* -57.55*

-3.23* -3.21* tb* -11.50* -18.41* -20.51*

Constant and Trend

ta* -25.15* -32.82* -33.93* -3.37* -3.40*

tb* -20.12* -31.33* -36.03*

lnaaD1

Constant ta* -50.98* -57.27* -50.69*

-3.33* -3.28* tb* -16.02* -17.47* -16.10*

Constant

and Trend

ta* -21.84* -25.56* -23.13* -3.42* -3.45*

tb* -19.84* -24.75* -22.17*

Note: The null hypothesis for Pesaran is unit root. (*) denotes significance at 5 % level,

meaning the rejection of the null of unit root. For CIPS test, the critical value in the case of a

constant is -2.15 and in the case of a constant and trend is -2.67 at 5% significance level.

52

6.3. Empirical Models

Since the positive correlations between our aggregate governance indicators and GDP per

capita suggest that better governance leads to higher income per capita thus growth and the

separate block dispersion of corresponding scores of high income OECD countries and LDCs in

Figure 6 also illustrates the hypothesis that “Rich countries can afford better institutions”

(Acemoglu et al., 2001, p 1369) indicating the reverse causality problem, the aggregate

governance indicators are endogenous in the growth equation. Chong and Calderon (2000),

Acemoglu (2001), Przeworski (2004) and Dollar and Kraay (2002) found strong evidence of

causation running in both directions, from institutions to growth, and from growth to institutional

quality. (eg., Chong and Calderon, 2000, Acemoglu, 2001 and Przeworski, 2004 cited in

Avellaneda, 2009) By contrast, Kaufmann and Kraay (2002) found no evidence of a positive

effect of incomes on the quality of institutions, calling into question the often-heard argument

that only wealthy countries can afford good governance. Glaeser, Porta, Silanes and Shleifer

(2004) question the validity of these instruments and show that ‘the evidence that institutions

cause economic growth, as opposed to growth improving institutions, is non-existent. (eg.,

Kaufmann and Kraay, 2002 and Glaeser et al., 2004 cited in Avellaneda, 2009)

Two models are estimated in the study for four regressions of the aggregate governance

indicators. First model includes import penetration index and second model includes trade

openness index. Each of the four regressions, one aggregate governance index is used for the

panel regressions.

Model 1;

lngpcit = αlngpcit-1 + β1lngovit + β2lnhumcit + β3lnimpenit + β4lnaait + εit

lngov corresponds to lngovi, lnaqi, lnpsi, lndapvi in each of the four regressions.

Model 2;

lngpcit = αlngpcit-1 + β1lngovit + β2lnhumcit + β3lntropit + β4lnaait + εit

lngov corresponds to lngovi, lnaqi, lnpsi, lndapvi in each of the four regressions.

The lag of the dependent variable, lngpcL1, is included in the empirical models in order to

capture the convergence effect of the Solow growth model. Countries with lower GDP per capita

53

are presumed to gradually catch up with the more developed counterparts. Hence, a negative sign

on the coefficient of lag of GDP per capita is expected.

The relationship between the aggregate governance indices and growth is expected to be

positive since the main argument in the study is that the lack of quality in governance institutions

is the main structural impediment to growth in LDCs.

Human capital index is also endogenous since higher quality of human capital leads to higher

growth while higher per capita income indicates greater available resources that can be employed

to enhance the human capital. Hence a positive sign on the coefficient of the human capital

(lnhumc) is expected.

There is a strong consensus within the economics profession of a positive relationship

between trade openness and economic growth in the long-run. According to the Washington

Consensus, trade openness is expected to have significant positive role on growth since it argues

that the trade-openness promotes growth in LDCs. (Sarkar, 2007) Another argument is the

protection of infant industries in least developed countries. In this case protectionist trade policies

can boost domestic firms’ prices and profitability, facilitating their investment in capital and

technology. (Slaughter, 2004) If this is the case, then negative relationship is expected between

trade openness and growth.

High rank of import penetration in the sense that increased foreign competition followed by

significant trade liberalizations in LDCs lead to increase in the volume of international trade

resulting in a higher per capita income thus growth in LDCs, considering that the domestic

sectors in these countries are capable to compete with foreign goods and services.

According to the poverty trap argument in the literature, it is expected that the aid has a

significant positive role on growth in LDCs by transferring of resources from rich countries could

set LDCs, especially those with good policies and institutions, on the path to growth. (Rajan and

Subramanian, 2005)

54

6.4. Estimation Results

Two difference GMM techniques are employed in the panel regressions for both models as

“one step robust difference GMM” and “two step difference GMM”. In the second technique, the

error terms are not assumed independent and identically distributed (i.i.d.), but νit are. The

orthogonal deviation transformation is used considering the heteroscedasticity. (Roodman, 2006)

In the first technique, heteroscedasticity is controlled for robust analysis. The one-step and two-

step difference GMM estimators differ with respect to weighting matrix used in the estimation.

For one-step estimation, the code “robust” specifies that the robust estimator of the covariance

matrix of the parameter estimates be calculated. The resulting standard error estimates are

consistent in the presence of any pattern of heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation within panels.

In two-step estimation, the standard covariance matrix is already robust in the theory, but it

typically yields standard errors that are downward biased that may result to significant

coefficients which actually are not significant according to first technique. Windmeijer’s finite-

sample correction for the two-step covariance matrix has not been applied.

Table 6 and Table 7 presents the estimation results for the three governance indicators taken

separately (lnaqi, lnpsi and lndapvi) in columns 2 to 4 for first technique and in columns 6 to 8

for second technique, as well as for the aggregate governance index (lngovi) in column 1 for first

technique and in column 5 for second technique.

According to the estimation results for both models whether first or second technique is used,

the coefficient of lag of per capita income is significant and have positive value against the initial

prediction. Hence, it can be concluded that there is no convergence effect in LDCs with respect to

Solow Growth Model. That is also the explanation of the inability of these low income countries

to gradually catch-up with more developed countries.

Estimation results for both of the models confirms that the governance institutions matter for

economic growth in the difference equation or better governance quality leads to higher per

capita income in the level equation since all the coefficients of governance indicators except

lndapvi in one-step difference GMM for both models are significant at % 5 or % 10 and have

positive values and all the coefficients of governance indicators in two-step difference GMM for

55

both models are significant at % 1 or % 5 and have positive values. Thus, the increase in the

governance performance enhances growth in LDCs by increasing income per capita.

A higher rank of “administrative quality” in the sense of low level of corruption, better

quality of bureaucracy quality, a sound and safe investment profile lowering risks for business

environment and better law and order leads to growth in LDCs according to the estimation results

of both models. This result holds for “political stability” in the sense that more cohesive

government, low ethnic and religious tensions together with diminishing internal and external

conflicts decreasing the occurrence of political violence leading to devotion of resources to

favorable economic objectives resulting in growth in LDCs. Mauro (1995) and Alesina (1998)

found that the sub-indices of administrative quality index in this study; bureaucratic efficiency,

absence of corruption, protection of property rights, and the rule of law are important for growth.

The insignificant coefficient of “democratic accountability political voice index” in both

models when the first technique is applied confirms the argument of skeptical school in the sense

that there is no systematic relationship exists between democracy and economic growth. On the

contrary, the estimation results of both models when the second technique is applied confirms the

argument of compatibility school in the sense that democracy enhances economic growth,

because the existence of fundamental civil liberties and political rights generates the social

conditions most conducive to economic growth. These conflicting results may due to the fact that

there is a downward bias in the standard deviations of the coefficient in second technique leading

to assignment of significance while it is actually insignificant. But, it is also possible that the

insignificance of the coefficient may be the result of counteracting effects of sub indices

(democratic accountability, military in politics, political rights and civil liberties) composing the

aggregate index. In both case the results deny the argument of conflict school favoring that

democracy hinders economic growth, mainly in LDCs, by creating consumption pressures,

fuelling distributional conflicts and inhibiting capital accumulation. (eg., Feng, 2003 cited by

Avellaneda, 2009)

A high rank of overall governance quality index leads to growth in LDCs in both models

whether first or second techniques are used. Even the insignificant result found for democratic

accountability political voice index when first technique is applied do not suppress the

significance of other aggregate governance indices.

56

The significant positive coefficient of human capital index confirms that a high rank of

human capital leads to growth in LDCs. Since the better performance in the health sub index

results in the use of human capital more effectively together with the higher performance in the

education sub index results in the use of human capital more efficiently. Human capital especially

the education sub index does not only enhances growth but also leads to better designed and

functioning governance institutions in LDCs.

The estimation results are robust for the variables of lag of income per capita, aggregate

governance indices and human capital index. Only democratic accountability political voice

index is not robust for the alternative usage of first and second techniques. But it is robust for

both models when only one of both techniques is used in the estimations.

Since there is a significant positive relationship between aid and growth as governance

quality and growth, the estimation results of both models when the second technique is applied

confirm the argument that the transfer of resources from rich countries could set LDCs, especially

those with good policies and institutions, on the path to growth. (Rajan and Subramanian, 2005)

But it is not robust since the significant relationship turns into an insignificant one when first

technique is applied. The insignificant coefficient of the variable opposes the argument that it is

possible for LDCs to escape from poverty trap by foreign aid. These conflicting results may due

to the fact that there is a downward bias in the standard deviations of the coefficient in second

technique leading to assignment of significance while it is actually insignificant. In both case the

results deny the argument that foreign aid depresses growth in LDCs by relying them on foreign

aid to overcome the structural weaknesses in their domestic economies.

There is a significant negative relationship between import penetration and growth in 3 out of

8 estimations. In other cases, the relationship is always negative even not significant. These non-

robust results suggest that increased foreign competition followed by significant trade

liberalizations in LDCs, most of the import-competing sectors shrunk and suffered from

declining value-added growth, which has not been compensated by increasing growth in the non-

import competing sectors, i.e., the export-oriented sectors in LDCs. (Raihan, 2004) Thus,

increasing foreign competition in LDCs do not promote growth, even it may reduce their growth

performance.

57

Table 7: Estimation Results of Model 1 (All of the Variables are in First Differences)

Dependent Variable: lngpc

Independent Variables Difference GMM 1 Step Robust Difference GMM 2 Step

lngpcL1 0.845*** 0.846*** 0.849*** 0.807*** 0.804*** 0.785*** 0.802*** 0.776***

(0.051) (0.059) (0.051) (0.050) (0.031) (0.034) (0.039) (0.031)

Lngovi 0.131* 0.115***

(0.066) (0.025)

Lnaqi 0.070** 0.055***

(0.030) (0.018)

Lnpsi 0.105* 0.093***

(0.056) (0.017)

Lndapvi 0.057 0.063***

(0.056) (0.020)

Lnhumc 0.450** 0.551*** 0.495*** 0.685*** 0.575*** 0.751*** 0.688*** 0.734***

(0.163) (0.174) (0.164) (0.176) (0.111) (0.114) (0.127) (0.096)

Lnimpen -0.040 -0.036 -0.033 -0.046* -0.007 -0.036** -0.045*** -0.028

(0.026) (0.028) (0.023) (0.024) (0.021) (0.014) (0.012) (0.024)

Lnaa 0.009 0.009 0.011 0.007 0.011*** 0.009*** 0.009*** 0.009**

(0.010) (0.010) (0.009) (0.014) (0.003) (0.002) (0.003) (0.004)

Number of obs. 432 432 432 432 432 432 432 432

AR(1) test (p-value) 0.006 0.004 0.005 0.006 0.009 0.010 0.009 0.011

AR(2) test (p-value) 0.861 0.687 0.773 0.961 0.815 0.696 0.788 0.987

Hansen test of over-identification (p-value) 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000

Diff-in-Hansen tests of exogeneity (p-value) 1.000 0.695 0.561 0.334 1.000 0.695 0.561 0.334

Notes: Standard errors are in parenthesis. ***, ** and * denote significance levels at % 1, % 5 and % 10 respectively. AR(1) and

AR(2) are tests for first-order and second-order serial correlation in the first-differenced residuals, under the null of no serial

correlation. Hansen test of over-identification is under the null that all instruments are valid. Diff-in-Hansen tests of exogeneity is

under the null that instruments used for the equations in levels are exogenous.lngpcL1, lngovi, lnaqi, lndapvi and lnhumc were treated

endogenously. First and deeper than first lags were used as instruments in the level equations. lnimpen and lnaa were treated

exogenously. Their first differences were used as instruments in the first-difference equations.

58

Table 8: Estimation Results of Model 2 (All of the Variables are in First Differences)

Notes: Standard errors are in parenthesis. ***, ** and * denote significance levels at % 1, % 5 and % 10 respectively. AR(1) and

AR(2) are tests for first-order and second-order serial correlation in the first-differenced residuals, under the null of no serial

correlation. Hansen test of over-identification is under the null that all instruments are valid. Diff-in-Hansen tests of exogeneity is

under the null that instruments used for the equations in levels are exogenous.lngpcL1, lngovi, lnaqi, lndapvi and lnhumc were treated

endogenously. First and deeper than first lags were used as instruments in the level equations. lnimpen and lnaa were treated

exogenously. Their first differences were used as instruments in the first-difference equations.

Dependent Variable: lngpc

Independent Variables Difference GMM 1 Step Robust Difference GMM 2 Step

lngpcL1 0.862*** 0.862*** 0.865*** 0.829*** 0.822*** 0.781*** 0.815*** 0.795***

(0.047) (0.054) (0.046) (0.046) (0.030) (0.040) (0.041) (0.033)

Lngovi 0.135* 0.129***

(0.071) (0.019)

Lnaqi 0.070** 0.047**

(0.032) (0.020)

Lnpsi 0.107* 0.094***

(0.059) (0.018)

Lndapvi 0.061 0.064***

(0.058) (0.022)

Lnhumc 0.410** 0.513*** 0.454*** 0.630*** 0.549*** 0.751*** 0.665*** 0.676***

(0.164) (0.166) (0.163) (0.173) (0.099) (0.125) (0.147) (0.114)

Lntrop -0.030 -0.025 -0.023 -0.033 -0.033** -0.024* -0.036*** -0.019

(0.024) (0.025) (0.020) (0.023) (0.013) (0.013) (0.013) (0.023)

Lnaa 0.010 0.010 0.011 0.008 0.008*** 0.009*** 0.009*** 0.010***

(0.010) (0.009) (0.009) (0.014) (0.003) (0.002) (0.003) (0.004)

Number of obs. 432 432 432 432 432 432 432 432

AR(1) test (p-value) 0.007 0.005 0.006 0.007 0.013 0.018 0.010 0.012

AR(2) test (p-value) 0.835 0.662 0.749 0.959 0.844 0.677 0.762 0.977

Hansen test of over-identification (p-value) 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000

Diff-in-Hansen tests of exogeneity (p-value) 0.488 1.000 0.392 1.000 0.488 1.000 0.392 1.000

59

0

20

40

60

80

100

120

140

160

180

1985

1986

1987

1988

1989

1990

1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

Billions, $

Exports of Goods Exports of Services Imports of Goods Imports of Services

There is a significant negative relationship between trade openness and growth in 3 out of 8

estimations. In other cases, the relationship is always negative even not significant. Even, these

results are not robust; they lead to serious doubts on one aspect of neo-liberal paradigm of the

Washington Consensus which argues that the trade-openness promotes growth. (Sarkar, 2007)

The results support the argument of protectionist trade policies especially for infant industries in

LDCs.

The reason for both increased trade openness and foreign competition have no significant

positive effect on growth is that the huge trade deficits in both the goods and service sectors in

LDCs as in Figure 11. These huge trade deficits especially for the deficit in goods sector are

based on two facts. First; the manufacturing sectors in LDCs are so insufficient; they export

labor-abundant products and natural resources to foreign countries in exchange of technologically

advanced capital-abundant products. Second; the gaps between imports and exports are actually

more serious considering the oil-export growth in five LDCs of Angola, Equatorial Guinea,

Myanmar, the Sudan and Yemen since the combined share of these five LDCs in world oil

production rose from 0.14 per cent in 1995 to 0.54 percent in 2008.

Figure 11: Foreign Trade in LDCs (1985-2010)

Source: Author’s Own Calculation based on World Bank, World Development Indicators (2012)

60

CHAPTER 7: CONCLUSION

The positive correlations between our aggregate governance indicators and GDP per capita

suggest that better governance leads to higher income per capita thus growth. The separate block

dispersion of corresponding High Income OECD and LDC scores in Figure 1 also illustrates the

hypothesis that “Rich countries can afford better institutions”. (Acemoglu et all, 2001, p 1369)

When the aggregate governance indicators of LDCs are compared with High Income OECD

countries, LDCs have performed worse. This result also justifies the rationale behind the

categorization of these countries as LDCs.

The decreasing trend in the standard deviation of “administrative quality” indicates the

convergence of LDCs with respect to this indicator. The increasing trend in the average value

together with the convergence shows that LDCs were generally improved with respect to this

indicator. Compared with the high income OECD countries, LDCs have poor performance in

administrative quality index because of inadequate control over corruption leading to unrealistic

and inefficient controls on the economy and encouraging the development of black market, low

bureaucracy quality indicating deficient public services, high political pressures on bureaucrats

and inefficient mechanism for recruitment and training (World Bank, 2003, p.184), low

investment profile indicating to high risks for business environment in the form of lack of

contract viability, overregulation and over-taxation and poor performance on law and order

indicates the weak, partial, unequal, inconsistent legal system and also the common disobedience

to the law which protecting private property. (Aysan et al., 2006)

The decreasing trend in the standard deviation of “political stability” indicates the

convergence of LDCs with respect to this indicator. The increasing trend in the average value

together with the convergence shows that LDCs were generally improved with respect to this

indicator. Compared with the High Income OECD countries, even the performance of LDCs

seem to be improved they are still behind the High Income OECD countries in political stability

index because of the inability of governments in LDCs to carry out their declared program(s),

popular disapproval of government policies, trade restrictions and embargoes, political violence

61

arising from civil war, civil disorder, terrorism, warfare, ethnic and religious tensions. (Aysan et

al., 2006 and ICRG Variables, 2012)

The non-decreasing trend in the standard deviation of “democratic accountability public

voice” indicates the divergence of LDCs with respect to this indicator. The increasing trend in the

average value together with the divergence show that while some LDCs are improved, some of

the others are deteriorated with respect to this indicator. Compared with the high income OECD

countries, LDCs have poor performance in this index because of unfair elections and electoral

laws, irresponsiveness of governments to their citizens, coups and dicta regimes, inability of

people to organize in different political parties or groups, partial press, inequality of citizens

under the law, unjustified imprisonments, gender inequality, less freedom of movement and

inequality of opportunity for the citizens. (ICRG Variables, 2012)

This study empirically shows that the governance institutions have positive significant effect

on income per capita growth in the long-run or income per capita in the short-run in LDCs with

the control variables of lag of per capita income, human capital, trade openness, import

penetration and net official development assistance and official aid received for a panel of 24

LDCs between the period of 1991 and 2010.

According to the estimation results it was found that overall governance quality together with

“administrative quality” and “political stability” as aggregate governance indices have positive

significant effect on growth when one-step robust difference GMM was applied and all the

aggregate governance indices have positive significant effect on growth when the two-step

difference GMM was applied. A high rank for “administrative quality” corresponding to low

level of corruption, better quality of bureaucracy quality, a sound and safe investment profile

lowering risks for business environment and better law and order and a high rank for “political

stability” corresponding to more cohesive government, low ethnic and religious tensions together

with diminishing internal and external conflicts decreasing the occurrence of political violence

leading to devotion of resources to favorable economic objectives resulting in growth in LDCs.

The estimation results deny the argument of conflict school favoring that democracy hinders

economic growth, mainly in less developed countries, by creating consumption pressures,

fuelling distributional conflicts and inhibiting capital accumulation. (eg., Feng, 2003 cited by

Avellaneda, 2009).

62

According to the estimation results, there is no convergence effect in LDCs with respect to

Solow Growth Model. That is also the explanation of the inability of these low income countries

to gradually catch-up with more developed countries.

The significant positive coefficient of human capital index confirms that a high rank of

human capital leads to growth in LDCs. Since the better performance in the health sub index

results in the use of human capital more effectively together with the higher performance in the

education sub index results in the use of human capital more efficiently. Human capital especially

the education sub index does not only enhances growth but also leads to better designed and

functioning governance institutions in LDCs.

The estimation results do not support the argument that foreign aid depresses growth in LDCs

by making them rely on foreign aid to overcome the structural weaknesses in their domestic

economies.

According to the estimations, as a result of increased foreign competition followed by

significant trade liberalizations in LDCs, most of the import-competing sectors shrunk and

suffered from declining value-added growth, which has not been compensated by increasing

growth in the non-import competing sectors, i.e., the export-oriented sectors in LDCs. (Raihan,

2004) Thus, increasing foreign competition in LDCs do not promote growth, even it may reduce

their growth performance.

The estimation results also lead to serious doubts on one aspect of neo-liberal paradigm of the

Washington Consensus, which argues that the trade-openness promotes growth. (Sarkar, 2007)

63

REFERENCES

Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S. and Robinson, J. A., 2001. “The Colonial Origins of Comparative

Development: An Empirical Investigation” The American Economic Review. Vol.91,

No.5, pp. 1369-1401. <http://economics.mit.edu/files/4123> (accessed 23 April 2012)

Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S. and Robinson, J. A., 2005. “Institutions as a Fundamental

Cause of Long-Run Growth” in Aghion, P. and. Durlauf, S. N. (Eds.) Handbook of

Economic Growth, Volume IA. Elsevier B.V. pp. 385-472.

<http://economics.mit.edu/files/4469> (accessed 23 April 2012)

Alesina, A., 1998. “The Political Economy of High and Low Growth,” in Pleskovic, B. and

Stiglitz, J. (Eds.) Annual World Bank Conference on Development Economics 1998.

World Bank, Washington, D.C.

Arellano, M. and Bond, S., 1991. “Some Tests of Specification for Panel Data: Monte Carlo

Evidence and an Application to Employment Equations,” The Review of Economic

Studies, Vol. 58, No. 2, pp. 277-297.

Avellanada, S. D., 2009. “Good Governance, Institutions and Economic Development:

Beyond the Conventional Wisdom” Cambridge University Press, B.J.Pol.S. 40, 195–224.

Aysan, A. F., Nabli, M. K. and Varoudakis, M. A. V., 2006. “Governance and Private Investment

in the Middle East and North Africa” CERDI, Etudes et Documents, E 2006.27.

http://www-wds.worldbank.org/servlet/WDSContentServer/WDSP/IB/2006/05/30/

000016406_20060530161214/Rendered/PDF/wps3934.pdf (accessed 1 May 2012)

CDP, 2004. “Report on the Sixth Session (29 March-2 April 2004)” United Nations Economic

and Social Council Official Records, No. 13.

<http://www.un.org/special-rep/ohrlls/ldc/E-2004-33.pdf> (accessed 1 May 2012)

CDP, 2008. “Handbook on the Least Developed Country Category: Inclusion, Graduation and

Special Support Measures” United Nations Publication, New York. No.E.07.II.A.9.

<http://www.un.org/en/development/desa/policy/cdp/cdp_ldcs_handbook.shtml>

(accessed 25 February 2012)

CDP, 2010. “Strengthening International Support Measures for the Least Developed Countries”

United Nations Publication, Sales No. E.10.II.A.14.

Dollar, D. and Kraay, A., 2002. “Institutions, Trade, and Growth” The World Bank. ,Washington,

D.C. <http://s12.middlebury.edu/ECON0424A/dollar2.pdf>-(accessed 1 May 2012)

FRH Online Database, 2012. “Civil Liberties and Political Voice Index” Freedom House,

Washington. D.C. <http://www.freedomhouse.org/>-(accessed 2 January 2012)

64

Guillaumont, P. and Chauvet, L., 1999. “Aid and Performance: A Reassessment” Journal of

Development Studies, 37, pp. 66-92.

ICRG Database, 2010. “International Country Risk Guide” The PRS Group, New York.

ICRG Variables, 2012. “Guide to Data Variables” The PRS Group, New York.

<http://www.prsgroup.com/VariableHelp.aspx> (accessed 16 April 2012)

Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A. and Lobaton,P.Z., 2000. “Governance Matters: From Measurement to

Action”. Finance & Development, 37. <http://siteresources.worldbank.org/ INTWBIGO

VANT CORINSPA/Resources/1745261-1163704849223/fandd_english.pdf>

(accessed 1 May 2012)

Kaufmann, D and Kraay, A., 2002. “Growth Without Governance” The World Bank,

Washington, D.C. <http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTWBIGOVANTCOR/

Resources/growthgov.pdf>. (accessed 1 May 2012)

Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A. and Mastruzzi, M., 2003. “Governance Matters III: Governance

Indicators for 1996-2002” The World Bank. ,Washington, D.C.

<http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTWBIGOVANTCOR/Resources/govmatters3_wbe

r.pdf> (accessed 1 May 2012)

Mauro, P., 1995. “Corruption and Growth” The Quarterly Journal of Economics.Vol. 110, No. 3,

pp. 681-712. <http://homepage.ntu.edu.tw/~kslin/macro2009/Mauro%201995.pdf>

(accessed 1 May 2012)

North, D. C. and Thomas, R. P., 1973. “The Rise of the Western World: A New Economic

History” Cambridge University Press,1976.

North, D. C., 1991. “Institutions” The Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 5, No. 1,

pp. 97-112. <http://www.econ.uchile.cl/uploads/documento/94ced618aa1aa4d59bf48

a17b1c7f605cc9ace73.pdf> (accessed 1 May 2012)

Raihan, S., 2004. “Foreign Competition and Growth Nexus: A Study in the context of

Bangladesh Manufacturing Industries” The World Bank. ,Washington, D.C.

<http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTCOMPLEGALDB/Resources/raihan.pdf>

(accessed 9 May 2012)

Rajan, R. G. and Subramanian,A., 2005. “Aid and Growth: What Does the Cross-Country

Evidence Really Show?” IMF Working Paper, WP/05/127.

Roodman, D., 2006. “How to Do xtabond2: An Introduction to Difference and System GMM

in Stata” Center for Global Development,103.

Sarkar, P., 2007. “Trade Openness and Growth: Is There Any Link?” MPRA Paper, No. 4997.

<http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/4997/> (accessed 16 April 2012)

65

Slaughter, M. J., 2004. “Infant-Industry Protection and Trade Liberalization in Developing

Countries” USAID Research Report, Washington, Task Order 13.

<http://www.nathaninc.com/sites/default/files/Infant%20Industries%20Paper%20(Final).

pdf> (accessed 1 May 2012)

UN Conference, 2001. “Programme of Action for the Least Developed Countries”

United Nations General Assembly, Brussels, Belgium, 14-20 May 2001,A/CONF.191/11.

World Bank, 2003. “Mena Development Report, Enhancing Inclusiveness and Accountability”

The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development. The World Bank,

Washington D.C.

World Development Indicators (WDI), 2012. “Data” The World Bank, Washington, D.C.

<http://data.worldbank.org/indicator> (accessed 23 April 2012)

66

APPENDIX 1

CURRENT LIST OF LDCs

Africa (33)

Angola Ethiopia Niger

Benin Gambia Rwanda

Burkina Faso Guinea São Tomé and Príncipe

Burundi Guinea-Bissau Senegal

Central African Republic Lesotho Sierra Leone

Chad Liberia Somalia

Comoros Madagascar Sudan

Democratic Republic of the Congo Malawi Togo

Djibouti Mali Uganda

Equatorial Guinea Mauritania United Republic of Tanzania

Eritrea Mozambique Zambia

Asia (14)

Afghanistan Lao People’s Democratic Republic Timor-Leste

Bangladesh Myanmar Tuvalu

Bhutan Nepal Vanuatu

Cambodia Samoa Yemen

Kiribati Solomon Islands

Latin America and the Caribbean (1)

Haiti

COUNTRIES GRADUATED FROM THE LIST OF THE LDCs

Botswana (1994) Cape Verde (2007) Maldives (2011)

COUNTRIES REJECTED TO BE ENLISTED AS LDC

Ghana Papua New Guinea Zimbabwe

67

APPENDIX 2

LIST OF LDCS COVERED IN THE STUDY

Africa (20 of 33)

Angola Liberia Sierra Leone

Burkina Faso Madagascar Sudan

Democratic Republic of the Congo Malawi Togo

Ethiopia Mali Uganda

Gambia Mozambique United Republic of Tanzania

Guinea Niger Zambia

Guinea-Bissau Senegal

Asia (3 of 14)

Bangladesh Myanmar Yemen

Latin America and the Caribbean (1 of 1)

Haiti

LIST OF HIGH INCOME OECD COUNTRIES COVERED IN THE STUDY

27 of 31 Countries

Australia Hungary New Zealand

Austria Iceland Norway

Belgium Ireland Poland

Canada Israel Portugal

Denmark Italy Spain

Finland Japan Sweden

France Korea, South Switzerland

Germany Luxembourg United Kingdom

Greece Netherlands United States

68

APPENDIX 3

Administrative Quality Index (AQI)

Component Eigenvalue Cumulative R

2

P1 3.047 0.762

P2 0.627 0.919

P3 0.174 0.962

P4 0.152 1

Loadings P1 P2 P3 P4

Corruption 0.499 -0.499 0.654 0.273

Bureaucracy Quality 0.540 -0.073 -0.122 -0.829

Investment Profile 0.415 0.855 0.270 0.156

Law and Order 0.536 -0.124 -0.696 0.462

AQI = P1 * 0.762 + P2 * 0.157 + P3 * 0.043 + P4 * 0.038

Political Stability Index (PSI)

Component Eigenvalue Cumulative R

2

P1 3.032 0.606

P2 0.805 0.768

P3 0.547 0.877

P4 0.424 0.962

P5 0.192 1

Loadings P1 P2 P3 P4 P5

Government Stability 0.333 0.851 0.367 0.028 0.170

Internal Conflicts 0.527 0.044 -0.192 -0.145 -0.814

External Conflicts 0.463 -0.008 -0.603 0.552 0.343

Ethnic Tensions 0.479 -0.233 -0.043 -0.723 0.437

Religious Tensions 0.409 -0.468 0.681 0.388 0.010

PSI = P1 * 0.606 + P2 * 0.161 + P3 * 0.109 + P4 * 0.085 + P5 * 0.038

69

Democratic Accountability Political Voice Index (DAPVI)

Component Eigenvalue Cumulative R

2

P1 3.607 0.902

P2 0.182 0.947

P3 0.157 0.987

P4 0.054 1

Loadings P1 P2 P3 P4

Democratic Accountability 0.494 0.032 0.868 0.025

Political Rights 0.506 -0.459 -0.290 0.670

Civil Liberties 0.510 -0.356 -0.256 -0.740

Military in Politics 0.490 0.813 -0.310 0.054

DAPVI = P1 * 0.902 + P2 * 0.046 + P3 * 0.039 + P4 * 0.014

Governance Index (GOVI)

GOVI = (AQI + PSI + DAPVI) / 3

Note: Principal Component Analysis (PCA) is a statistical technique used for data reduction

that uses an orthogonal transformation to convert a set of observations of possibly correlated

variables into a set of values of linearly uncorrelated variables called principal components. The

number of principal components is less than or equal to the number of original variables. This

transformation is defined in such a way that the first principal component has the largest possible

variance (that is, accounts for as much of the variability in the data as possible), and each

succeeding component in turn has the highest variance possible under the constraint that it be

orthogonal to (i.e., uncorrelated with) the preceding components. The leading eigenvectors from

the eigen decomposition of the correlation or covariance matrix of the variables describe a series

of uncorrelated linear combinations of the variables that contain most of the variance. In addition

to data reduction, the eigenvectors from a PCA are often inspected to learn more about the

underlying structure of the data.

Source: Wikipedia - PCA and Stata 10 – Help - Contents - PCA

70

Table 1: Colonial Origins and Last Disturbances on Governance in LDCs

Country Date of

Colonial Origin Historical Events Affecting Governance Type of Government Freedom

Afghanistan 1919 British Colony in 1800s Marxist Revolution in 1978 Islamic republic since 1992

Soviet Invasion in 1979 Civil War in 1989-1992, 1992-1996 and 1996-2001 Communist regime in 1978-1992

Angola 1975 Portuguese Colony in 1500s Civil War in 1975-2002 Unitary presidential republic

since 1992

Bangladesh 1971 British Colony in 1800s Coup in 1982 Unitary state and parliamentary

Pakistan Invasion in 1947 democracy since 1990

Dicta regime in 1982-1990

Benin 1960 French Colony in 1800s Coup in 1972 Republic with multiparty democracy

since 1990

Marxist-Leninist dicta regime in

1972-1990

Bhutan 1907 British Colony in 1800s Wangchuk Dynasty in 1907 Unitary parliamentary democracy and

Britain Power on Foreign Relations in 1949 Constitutional monarchy since 2007

Constitutional Monarchy in 2007

Burkina Faso 1960 French Colony in 1800s Coup in 1966, 1980, 1983 and 1987 Semi-presidential parliamentary

republic since 1991

Dicta regime in 1966-1970

Burundi 1962 Belgian Mandate after WWI Genocide of Hutus in 1972 Presidential representative democratic

Coup in 1976 and 1996 republic since 1998

Overthrown in 1987

Civil War in 1992

Genocide of Tutsi in 1993

Cambodia 1953 French Colony in 1800s Coup in 1970 Unitary parliamentary democracy and

Japanese Occupation in Civil War in 1970-1975 Constitutional monarchy since 1993

WWII Genocide in 1975-1979 Maoist dictatorship in 1975-1979

Central African 1960 French Colony in 1800s Coup in 1965, 1979 and 1981 Presidential republic since 2003

Republic Overthrown in 2003 Dicta regime in 1981-1985

Source: CIA The World Factbook (2012), Wikipedia (2012) and History World (2012)

71

Table 1: Continued

Country Date of

Colonial Origin Historical Events Affecting Governance Type of Government Freedom

Chad 1960 French Colony in 1900s French Invasion in 1920 Presidential republic since 1996

Civil War in 1965-1979

Overthrown in 1990

Coup Attempt in 2006 and 2008

Comoros 1978 French Colony in 1800s Coup in 1975 and 1999 Federal presidential republic since

7 Coup attempts in 1976-1978 2002

Rebellions in 1997 and 2008

Congo Dem. 1960 Belgian Colony in 1800s First Congo War in 1996-1997 Semi-presidential republic since 2005

Republic Second Congo War in 1998-2003

Kivu Conflict in 2004-2009

Djibouti 1977 French Colony in 1800s Civil War in 1991-2001 Semi-presidential republic since 1981

Equatorial 1968 Spanish Protectorate in 1885 1/3 of Population were killed or exiled in 1968-1979 Unitary presidential republic since

Guinea Spanish Colony in 1900 Coup in 1979 1982

British Slavery Base in 12 Coup Attempts since 1979

1827-1843

Eritrea 1993 Italian Colony in 1800s Ethiopia's Province in 1952-1991 Presidential republic with unicameral

British Administration in War with Ethiopia in 1961-1991 and 1998-2000 parliamentary democracy since 1997

1941-1951 Private media is closed down and outspoken critics

of the government arrested without trial in 2001

Ethiopia Not a European Colony War with Eritrea in 1961-1991 and in 1998-2000 Federal parliamentary republic since

Italian Occupation in Marxist Coup in 1974 1991

1936-1941 Civil War in 1974-1991

Red Terror in 1977-1978

Gambia 1965 British Colony in 1800s Bloodless Coup in 1994 Presidential republic since 1970

Coup Attempt in 2006 and 2009

Guinea 1958 French Colony in 1800s Concentration Camps in 1960-1984 Presidential republic since 2010

Coup in 2008 Dictatorship in 1958-2010

Coup Attempt in 2011

Source: CIA The World Factbook (2012), Wikipedia (2012) and History World (2012)

72

Table 1: Continued

Country Date of

Colonial Origin Historical Events Affecting Governance Type of Government Freedom

Guinea Bissau 1974 Portuguese Colony in 1800s Independence War in 1963-1974 Semi-presidential republic since 1994

Coup Attempt in 1998 Revolutionary Council in 1974-1984

Civil War in 1998

Coup in 1999 and 2003

Military Unrest in 2010

Haiti 1825 Spanish Colony in 1500s Coup Attempts in 1949 and 1950 Unitary semi-presidential republic

French Colony in 1600s Coup in 2004 since 1990

US Occupation in 1915-1934 Dictatorship in 1957-1986

Kiribati 1979 British Colony in 1800s Shut Down of Newspapers in 2002 Parliamentary republic since 1979

Japanese Invasion in WWII

Laos 1953 French Colony in 1800s Civil War in 1953-1975 Unitary communist and single-party-

Japanese Occupation in US Bombardment in 1964-1973 Vietnam War led state since 1975

WWII Overthrown in 1975 Constitutional monarchy in 1954-1975

Lesotho 1966 British Colony in 1800s Coup in 1986 and 1994 Unitary parliamentary democracy and

Constitutional monarchy since 1993

Liberia 1847 American Colony in 1800s Coup in 1980 Unitary presidential constitutional

Coup Attempt in 1985 republic since 1986

Civil War in 1989-1996 and 1999-2003

Madagascar 1960 French Colony in 1800s Rebellion against France in 1947-1948 Semi presidential representative

Coup in 2009 leading to Political Crisis democratic multi-party republic since

1992

Malawi 1964 British Colony in 1800s Multi-party democracy since 1993

Single party state in 1966-1993

Mali 1960 French Colony in 1800s Coup in 1968 and 1991 Unitary semi-presidential republic

Rebellion in 2012 leading to internal conflict since 1992

Mauritania 1960 French Colony in 1800s Coup Attempt in 1987 Islamic republic with multi-party

War with Senegal in 1989-1991 elections since 1991

Massacre of 1990-1991 Single party state in 1960-1978

Coup in 2005 and 2008 Military governments in 1978-1984

Source: CIA The World Factbook (2012), Wikipedia (2012) and History World (2012)

73

Table 1: Continued

Country Date of

Colonial Origin Historical Events Affecting Governance Type of Government Freedom

Mozambique 1975 Portuguese Colony in 1500s Civil War in 1977-1992 Presidential republic with multi-party

democracy since 1990

Myanmar 1948 British Colony in 1800s Coup in 1962 Unitary presidential republic since 2011

(Burma) Japanese Rule in 1942-1945 Uprising against regime in 1988 Democratic republic in 1948-1962

Civil Resistance in 2007-2008 Socialist republic in 1974-1988

Military junta in 1988-2011

Nepal 2007 Not a European Colony Civil War in 1996-2006 Federal democratic republic as of 2008

Royal Massacre in 2001 Kingdom of Nepal in 1768-2007

Niger 1960 French Colony in 1800s Coup in 1999 and 2010 Semi-presidential republic since 1999

Military Unrest in 2002 Military rule in 1961-1991 and 1996-1999

Republic with multi-party system in

1991-1996

Rwanda 1962 German Colony in 1800s Civil War in 1990-1993 Unitary parliamentary democracy and

Belgium Colony in 1900s 800,000 killed in Genocide of 1994 Presidential republic since 2003

Samoa 1962 German and New Zealand Parliamentary republic since 2007

Colony in 1900s Constitutional monarchy in 1962-2007

Sao Tome and 1975 Portuguese Colony in 1500s Coup Attempt in 2009 Democratic semi-presidential republic

Principe since 1990

Senegal 1960 French Colony in 1500s Separatist movement since 1982 Semi-presidential republic since 1983

Youth opposition movements in 2011

Sierra Leone 1961 British Colony in 1700s Coup in 1967, 1968, 1996 and 1997 Unitary presidential constitutional

Coup Attempt in 1971, 1987 and 1992 republic since 1991

Nationwide student demonstration against One-party state in 1968-1985

government in 1977 Military junta in 1992-1996 and 1997-1998

Civil War in 1991-2002 Multi-party constitution in 1991-2001

Solomon Islands

1978 British Colony in 1800s Ethnic tensions leading to Civil War in 1998-2001 Parliamentary democracy and a

Commonwealth realm since 1978

Source: CIA The World Factbook (2012), Wikipedia (2012) and History World (2012)

74

Table 1: Continued

Country Date of

Colonial Origin Historical Events Affecting Governance Type of Government Freedom

Somalia 1960 British Colony in 1800s Assassination of president 1969 Transitional parliamentary federal

Italian Colony in 1900s Coup in 1969 government since 1991

War with Ethiopia in 1977-1978 Totalitarian communist rule in 1969-1991

Civil War since 1991

Sudan 1956 British Colony in 1800s Civil War in 1955-1972 and 1983-2005 Federal presidential republic since 2005

Coup in 1969 and 1989 Islamic authoritarian single party

480,000 deaths in Genocide in 2003-2006 system in 1993-2005

Conflict with Chad in 2005-2007

Tanzania 1964 German Colony in 1800s War with Uganda in 1978-1979 Federal presidential constitutional

British Mandate in 1900s republic

Timor-Leste 1975 Portuguese Colony in 1500s Coup Attempt in 1975 Unitary parliamentary democracy and

2002 Japanese Invasion in WWII Massacre of 1991 Democratic republic since 2002

Indonesian Occupation in Anti-independence militia attacks on civilians in 1999

1975-1999 Assassination attempt to president in 2008

Togo 1960 German Colony in 1800s Coup in 1963 and 1967 Republic under transition to multiparty

French Colony in 1900s Political Violence in 2004 democratic rule since 2005

Tuvalu 1978 British Colony in 1800s Parliamentary democracy and a

Commonwealth realm since 1978

Uganda 1962 British Colony in 1800s Coup in 1971 Democratic republic dominant-party

War with Tanzania in 1978-1979 system since 2005

Military rule in 1971-1979

Commonwealth realm in 1962-1967

Vanuatu 1980 British and French Colony in Clash with Papua New Guinea in 1980 Unitary parliamentary republic since

1900s Political Instabilities of 1990s leading to more 1997

decentralized government

Coup Attempt in 1996

Source: CIA The World Factbook (2012), Wikipedia (2012) and History World (2012)

75

Table 1: Continued

Country Date of

Colonial Origin Historical Events Affecting Governance Type of Government Freedom

Yemen 1990 British Colony in 1800s North Yemen Civil War in 1962-1970 Unitary presidential system since 1990

Independence of North Civil War in 1994 Communist governmental system in

Yemen from Ottoman in 1918 Uprising in 2007 1970-1990

Independence of South Revolution in 2011-2012

Yemen from UK in 1967

Unification in 1990

Zambia 1964 British Colony in 1800s Riots in 1990 Presidential representative democratic

Coup Attempt in 1990 republic since 1991

One-party state in 1964-1991

Source: CIA The World Factbook (2012), Wikipedia (2012) and History World (2012)

76

Table 2: Income per capita and Governance Comparison of LDCs and High Income OECD

Countries

Country

Groupings Countries

ln GDP

per capita,

PPP (2005 $)

Average Governance

Indices (1991-2010)

GDP per capita,

PPP (2005 $)

GOVI AQI PSI DAPVI 1991 2009

Angola 8.103 -1.272 -1.189 -0.437 -2.190 3154 5390

Bangladesh 6.869 -0.958 -1.303 -0.800 -0.771 754 1419

Burkina Faso 6.738 -0.720 -0.632 -0.211 -1.316 722 1062

Congo, DR 6.025 -2.245 -2.354 -1.498 -2.883 556 298

Ethiopia 6.366 -1.089 -0.883 -0.670 -1.716 489 866

Gambia 7.040 -0.439 -0.233 0.313 -1.396 1118 1238

Guinea 6.788 -1.404 -0.863 -1.108 -2.242 837 981

Guinea-Bissau 7.033 -1.150 -1.390 -0.505 -1.557 1244 1050

Haiti 7.010 -1.626 -2.107 -0.427 -2.345 1377 1063

Liberia 6.257 -1.725 -2.167 -1.267 -1.740 430 371

Madagascar 6.825 -0.456 -0.672 -0.118 -0.578 943 881

L Malawi 6.463 -0.565 -0.589 -0.517 -0.589 606 762

D Mali 6.633 -0.625 -1.199 -0.347 -0.329 661 942

C Mozambique 6.247 -0.538 -0.946 0.312 -0.979 410 807

Myanmar 6.551 -1.778 -1.713 -0.110 -3.512 336 1596

Niger 6.477 -1.139 -1.411 -0.945 -1.060 697 622

Senegal 7.342 -0.704 -0.808 -0.703 -0.600 1471 1712

Sierra Leone 6.438 -1.322 -1.604 -0.675 -1.686 718 723

Sudan 7.222 -2.727 -2.544 -2.405 -3.231 1080 1986

Tanzania 6.846 -2.343 -1.636 -2.206 -3.187 849 1237

Togo 6.777 -1.338 -1.303 -0.481 -2.230 890 885

Uganda 6.623 -1.073 -0.596 -0.801 -1.823 574 1121

Yemen 7.627 -0.744 -0.911 -0.199 -1.121 1779 2267

Zambia 7.073 -0.288 -0.683 0.056 -0.238 1216 1323

Source: Author’s Own Calculation based on World Bank World Development Indicators

(WDI) 2012, ICRG Database (2010) and Freedom House Online Database (2012).

77

Table 2: Continued

Country

Groupings Countries

ln GDP

per capita,

PPP (2005 $)

Average Governance

Indices (1991-2010)

GDP per capita,

PPP (2005 $)

GOVI AQI PSI DAPVI 1991 2009

Australia 10.226 1.236 1.269 0.757 1.683 23608 34139

Austria 10.289 1.253 1.431 0.777 1.552 26012 34681

Belgium 10.248 0.992 1.054 0.357 1.565 25461 32377

Canada 10.319 1.249 1.511 0.558 1.677 26021 34516

Denmark 10.285 1.315 1.527 0.736 1.683 25708 32063

Finland 10.154 1.483 1.599 1.167 1.683 21633 30755

H France 10.184 0.860 0.921 0.311 1.347 24444 29367

I Germany 10.262 1.146 1.253 0.747 1.438 27006 32176

G Greece 9.913 0.590 0.363 0.433 0.972 17683 25162

H Hungary 9.547 0.835 0.701 0.446 1.358 11560 16710

Iceland 10.269 1.337 1.298 1.030 1.683 25258 34093

I Ireland 10.197 1.144 1.089 0.696 1.648 17844 35733

N Israel 9.953 -0.076 0.639 -1.530 0.662 18115 25325

C Italy 10.152 0.669 0.402 0.430 1.176 24123 26539

O Japan 10.225 0.951 0.898 0.744 1.210 26914 29372

M Korea, South 9.748 0.551 0.314 0.474 0.863 12337 25525

E Luxembourg 10.899 1.511 1.631 1.273 1.631 45758 68188

Netherlands 10.332 1.299 1.572 0.640 1.683 26705 36570

O New Zealand 9.979 1.280 1.453 0.730 1.657 18237 24649

E Norway 10.595 1.230 1.362 0.645 1.683 32958 47118

C Poland 9.373 0.756 0.489 0.482 1.296 7581 16708

D Portugal 9.830 1.086 0.856 0.851 1.551 16944 21392

Spain 10.041 0.806 0.828 0.268 1.323 20219 27075

Sweden 10.228 1.327 1.460 0.887 1.635 24127 32251

Switzerland 10.428 1.303 1.287 0.939 1.683 32673 36978

UK 10.223 1.080 1.309 0.406 1.524 23295 32004

US 10.505 1.054 1.218 0.495 1.450 31393 41378

Source: Author’s Own Calculation based on World Bank World Development Indicators

(WDI) 2012, ICRG Database (2010) and Freedom House Online Database (2012).

78

Table 3: Variables and Sources

Variable Source

GDP per capita, PPP

(constant 2005 international $) World Bank, World Development Indicators Online Database (2012)

Aggregate Governance Index (GOVI)

Administrative Quality Index (AQI)

Corruption International Country Risk Guide (ICRG), 2010 Database from The PRS Group

Bureaucracy Quality International Country Risk Guide (ICRG), 2010 Database from The PRS Group

Investment Profile International Country Risk Guide (ICRG), 2010 Database from The PRS Group

Law and Order International Country Risk Guide (ICRG), 2010 Database from The PRS Group

Political Stability Index (PSI)

Government Stability International Country Risk Guide (ICRG), 2010 Database from The PRS Group

Internal Conflict International Country Risk Guide (ICRG), 2010 Database from The PRS Group

External Conflict International Country Risk Guide (ICRG), 2010 Database from The PRS Group

Ethnic Tensions International Country Risk Guide (ICRG), 2010 Database from The PRS Group

Religious Tensions International Country Risk Guide (ICRG), 2010 Database from The PRS Group

Democratic Accountability Public Voice Index (DAPVI)

Democratic Accountability International Country Risk Guide (ICRG), 2010 Database from The PRS Group

Military in Politics International Country Risk Guide (ICRG), 2010 Database from The PRS Group

Political Rights Freedom House (FRH), 2012 Online Database

Civil Liberties Freedom House (FRH), 2012 Online Database

Import Penetration and Trade Openness Index

Exports of goods and services (current US$)

World Bank, World Development Indicators Online Database (2012), United

Nations Commodity Trade Statistics (UN Comtrade) Online Database (2012)

and International Monetary Fund (IMF) Online Database (2012)

Imports of goods and services (current US$)

World Bank, World Development Indicators Online Database (2012), United

Nations Commodity Trade Statistics (UN Comtrade) Online Database (2012)

and International Monetary Fund (IMF) Online Database (2012)

Exports of goods and services (% of GDP) World Bank, World Development Indicators Online Database (2012)

Imports of goods and services (% of GDP) World Bank, World Development Indicators Online Database (2012)

GDP (current US$) World Bank, World Development Indicators Online Database (2012)

79

Table 3: Continued

Variable Source

Human Capital Index

Health Index

Life expectancy at birth, total (years) World Bank, World Development Indicators Online Database (2012) and World Health Organization (WHO) Online Database (2012)

Prevalence of undernourishment

(% of population)

World Bank, World Development Indicators Online Database (2012) and

World Health Organization (WHO) Online Database (2012)

Mortality rate, under-5 year old (per 1,000) World Bank, World Development Indicators Online Database (2012) and

World Health Organization (WHO) Online Database (2012)

Education Index

Literacy rate, adult total

(% of people ages 15 and above)

World Bank, World Development Indicators Online Database (2012) and

United Nations Educational, Scientific and Cultural Organization (UNESCO)

Online Database (2012)

School enrollment, primary (% gross)

World Bank, World Development Indicators Online Database (2012) and

United Nations Educational, Scientific and Cultural Organization (UNESCO)

Online Database (2012)

School enrollment, secondary (% gross)

World Bank, World Development Indicators Online Database (2012) and

United Nations Educational, Scientific and Cultural Organization (UNESCO)

Online Database (2012)

School enrollment, tertiary (% gross)

World Bank, World Development Indicators Online Database (2012) and

United Nations Educational, Scientific and Cultural Organization (UNESCO)

Online Database (2012)

Net official development assistance and official aid received

(constant 2009 US$) World Bank, World Development Indicators Online Database (2012)

80

Table 6: Summary Statistics of All Variables In Panel Regressions (1991-2010)

Variable # Obs Mean Std. Dev. Min Max

lngpc 480 6.78 0.55 4.94 8.62

lngpcL1 456 6.77 0.54 4.94 8.61

lngovi 480 3.82 0.33 2.33 4.31

lnaqi 480 3.56 0.45 1.43 4.17

lnpsi 480 4.12 0.29 2.46 4.49

lndapvi 480 3.61 0.56 1.97 4.43

lnhumc 480 4.09 0.10 3.82 4.31

lnimpen 480 3.22 0.97 -2.70 4.47

lntrop 480 3.83 0.98 -1.71 5.50

lnaa 480 20.09 0.97 17.55 22.68