The Chinese Special Economic Zones - IBP Union · PDF fileAuthors: Emilie C. L. Jaillot -...

47
Authors: Emilie C. L. Jaillot - 0604952700 Oskar B. Krabbe - 0503932687 Advisor: Professor Aradhna Aggarwal [email protected] +45 3815 3374 Second Year Project BSc International Business Politics Copenhagen Business School 2015 Number of pages: 46 STU Count: Submission accepted by: _______________________________________ Date: 27/05/2015 . The Chinese Special Economic Zones - Key factors for sustainable growth in the future?

Transcript of The Chinese Special Economic Zones - IBP Union · PDF fileAuthors: Emilie C. L. Jaillot -...

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

     

     

 

       

Authors: Emilie C. L. Jaillot - 0604952700 Oskar B. Krabbe - 0503932687

Advisor: Professor Aradhna Aggarwal [email protected] +45 3815 3374

Second Year Project BSc International Business Politics Copenhagen Business School 2015 Number of pages: 46 STU Count: Submission accepted by: _______________________________________ Date: 27/05/2015

. The Chinese Special Economic Zones - Key factors for sustainable growth in the future?

 

Oskar  Borup  Krabbe,  0503932687     Second  Year  Project  Emilie  Christine  Lucie  Jaillot,  0604952700        

     

1  

 

Table  of  Contents  

 Table  of  Contents  ...............................................................................................................................  1  

1.  Introduction  ....................................................................................................................................  2  1.1.  Contextualization  and  Research  Question  .................................................................................  2  1.2.  Structure  of  the  assignment  ............................................................................................................  4  1.3.  Key  concepts  .........................................................................................................................................  4  

2.  Analytical  Framework  .................................................................................................................  6  2.1.  Philosophy  of  Science  ........................................................................................................................  7  2.2.  Naturalism  .............................................................................................................................................  7  2.3.  Constructivism  .....................................................................................................................................  8  2.4.  Critical  Realism  ..................................................................................................................................  10  2.5.  Chosen  perspective  ...........................................................................................................................  11  

3.  Sustainability  of  Chinese  SEZs:  Theoretical  Perspectives  ............................................  11  4.  Identifying  the  issue  ..................................................................................................................  15  

5.  Methodology  ................................................................................................................................  17  5.1.  Empirical  data  and  Sources  ...........................................................................................................  17  

6.  Analysis  .........................................................................................................................................  18  6.1.  Organization  Theory  application:  Institutionalism  ..............................................................  18  6.2.  Political  Economy  of  Development  theory  application:                      Developmental  State-­‐  and  Neo-­‐liberalist  theory  ...................................................................  24  6.3.  Comparative  Political  Economy  theory  application:  Constructivism  .............................  32  

7.  Limitations  of  the  study  ...........................................................................................................  37  

8.  Conclusion  and  strategic  recommendations  ....................................................................  38  9.  Bibliography  ................................................................................................................................  41  9.1.  Books  .....................................................................................................................................................  41  9.2.  Webpages  .............................................................................................................................................  44  

Appendix  I  .........................................................................................................................................  45  

Appendix  II  .......................................................................................................................................  46      

Oskar  Borup  Krabbe,  0503932687     Second  Year  Project  Emilie  Christine  Lucie  Jaillot,  0604952700        

     

2  

1.  Introduction      

1.1.  Contextualization  and  Research  Question  

In  2014,  the  People’s  Republic  of  China  (PRC)  officially  became  the  world's  number  one  

economy-­‐   its   real   gross   domestic   product   (GDP)   in   terms   of   purchasing   power   parity  

exceeding  the  US's  one1  -­‐,  and  the  previsions  for  its  future  are  not  any  less  optimistic  (IMF  

in   Duncan   &   Martosko   2014).   China’s   GDP   has   grown   with   an   average   annual   rate   of  

around   10   percent   for   several   decades 2  (World   Bank   2015)   and   this   economic  

development  has  not  only  made  the  country  an  important  growth  engine  and  a  “leader  in  

international   trade   and   investment”   (Zeng,   p.3),   but   has   also   led   to   profound   social  

progress.  Since  1990,  more  than  650  million  Chinese  have  been  lifted  out  of  poverty,  the  

child  mortality  has  been  reduced  with  up  to  70%  and  the   life  expectancy  has   increased  

with  six  years  (Forbes  2014).  China  attaining  this  “unprecedented  growth  miracle”  (Zeng,  

p.1)  is  described  as  a  result  of  Deng  Xiaoping’s  groundbreaking  Open  Door  Policy  reform  

of  1978,  which  shifted  the  country’s  economy  away  from  being  centrally  planned  towards  

being  market-­‐based.  Some  actual  policy  tools  of  the  Chinese  economic  expansion  played  a  

crucial   role.   This   is   the   case   of   the   Special   Economic   Zones   (SEZs),   considerable  

contributors   to   turning   China   into   a  magnet   for   foreign   direct   investments   (FDIs)   and  

more   generally   for   enhancing   economic   development.   However,   in   more   recent   times,  

SEZs   face  an   increasing  number  of   challenges   threatening   their   success   (Ibid.,  p.39).  As  

economic   competitiveness   in   China   increasingly   moves   away   from   low-­‐tech   labor-­‐

intensive  sectors  towards  competition  on  knowledge-­‐,  innovation-­‐  and  technology-­‐based  

ones,   the  Chinese   industry  can  be  said   to  be  moving  up   the  Global  Value  Chain   -­‐  which  

provides   a   genuine   challenge   for   the   Chinese   SEZs.   Simultaneously,   growing   ecological  

challenges,  particularly  the  deterioration  of  natural  resources  together  with  the  Chinese  

population’s  socio-­‐political   structural  changes,   call   for  new  action  strategies  so   that   the  

                                                                                                                   1  See  Appendix  I  2  See  Appendix  II  2  See  Appendix  II  

Oskar  Borup  Krabbe,  0503932687     Second  Year  Project  Emilie  Christine  Lucie  Jaillot,  0604952700        

     

3  

Chinese  SEZs  remain  sustainable  as  an  industrial  policy-­‐tool  for  growth  creation.  Through  

an  analysis  constructed  by  applicable  theoretical  structures  from  economic,  political  and  

management  perspectives,  this  paper  aims  to  answer  the  following  research  question:  

As  the  core  engine  for  economic  growth  and  openness  in  the  1980s,  how  can  Chinese  SEZs  

remain  a  viable  source  of  economic  growth  in  the  current  context  of  sustainability  concerns  

rising  from  the  environmental  degradation  and  changing  social  structures?  

The  research  question  will  be  answered  by  creating  an  analytical  framework  consisting  of  

key   theories  provided  by   relevant   courses   from   the   International  Business   and  Politics  

(IBP)   program.   The  Organization  Theory   (OT)   course,   through   the   Institutional   theory,  

will  allow  us  to  grasp  the  challenges  faced  by  SEZs  in  the  form  of  coercive,  mimetic  and  

normative  pressures.  Based  on  the  theoretical  assessment  that  organizations  are  not  only  

depending  on  traditional  resources,  that  is  to  say  raw  materials,  capital,  labor,  knowledge  

and   equipment,   but   also   on   the   acceptance   of   the   societies   in   which   they   operate,  

conforming  to  those  pressures  enables  organizations  to  ensure  their  legitimacy  and  their  

survival.   Thus,  we  will   study  which   pressures   the   SEZs  would   be   better   off   complying  

with,  and  what  kind  of  growth  those  pressures  advocate.  From  the  Political  Economy  of  

Development  (PED)  course,  the  Developmental  State  (DS)  theory  with  its  rationale  for  the  

relevancy  of   interventionist   behavior  will   be  used   to  discuss   the  Chinese   government’s  

political-­‐economic   agenda   that   lead   to   the   implementation   of   SEZs.   From   the   same  

course,   the   opposing   theory   of   Neo-­‐liberalism   will   be   brought   into   the   discussion,   in  

order  to  perceive  a  complete  understanding  of  the  use  of  SEZs  as  industrial  policy  tools  

and  their  function  as  “windows”  to  promote  exchange  between  the  PRC  and  the  outside  

world  market.  The  DS  theory  will  also  help  us  identifying  some  of  the  actions  the  Chinese  

government  could  take  to  ensure  the  future  sustainability  of  the  Chinese  SEZs.  The  third  

and  final  course  contributing  with  theories  enabling  us  to  answer  our  research  question  

is  the  Comparative  Political  Economy  (CPE)  course.  Here,  the  Constructivist  approach  will  

allow  us   to  explicit  and   justify   the  shift   in   ideas   from  growth   to   sustainable  growth  we  

believe  to  be  essential  for  SEZs  to  efficiently  transform  and  consequently  remain  viable.    

Oskar  Borup  Krabbe,  0503932687     Second  Year  Project  Emilie  Christine  Lucie  Jaillot,  0604952700        

     

4  

1.2.  Structure  of  the  assignment    

This   paper   aims   to   answer   the   research   question   by   constructing   a   line   of   argument  

developed   through   the   following   structural   framework:   First   of   all  we  will   introduce   a  

number  of  key  concepts  deemed  fundamental  to  define  before  being  able  to  conduct  an  

analysis.  These  consist  of  the  Special  Economic  Zones,  Sustainable  growth,  Foreign  Direct  

Investment  and  finally  the  Lewis  turning  point  concepts.  Then  follows  an  in-­‐depth  outline  

of  the  Philosophy  of  Science  course  and  a  development  of  its  three  theoretical  schools  of  

thought;  Naturalism,  Constructivism  and  Critical  realism,  proceeded  by  a   justification  of  

our   chosen   perspective,   to   construct   our   argument.   This   will   lead   us   to   introduce   the  

theoretical  framework  that  will  be  applied,  from  the  selected  courses  of  the  International  

Business   and   Politics   program   including   Organization   Theory,   Political   Economy   of  

Development   and   Comparative   Political   Economy.   Subsequently,   we   will   identify   the  

issues   of   growing   social   and   environmental   challenges   the   Chinese   Special   Economic  

Zones  are  facing.  This  will  be  proceeded  with  a  discussion  of  which  methodology  we  find  

applicable   to   the   paper,   that   being   the   empirical   data   and   sources   we   will   base   our  

argument   on   so   as   the   delimitations   of   the   scope   of   the   analysis.  Having   identified   the  

theoretical  paradigm,  the  issues  the  SEZs  are  facing  and  finally  which  empirical  data  the  

paper  will  be  build  on,  a  clarified   foundation  will  have  been  constructed   for  us   to  build  

our  analysis  on.  This  part  will  consist  of  the  application  of  the  previously  mentioned  IBP-­‐

courses  in  order  to  identify  how  SEZs  can  remain  a  viable  source  for  sustainable  growth  

for   China.   In   the   end,   this   will   be   furthered   into   our   conclusion   and   strategic  

recommendations  to  the  Chinese  policy-­‐makers  and  the  SEZs.    

 

1.3.  Key  concepts    

Special  Economic  Zones  (SEZs)

Finding  a  universally  accepted  definition  of  Special  Economic  Zones  can  be  very  difficult  

as  there  are  many  different  versions  of  the  concept  depending  on  where  in  the  world  the  

policy  tool  is  used  or  by  which  author  it  is  being  described.  Falling  under  the  classification  

as   a   Special   Economic   Zone   are   subdivisions   such   as   Export   Processing   Zones   (EPZs),  

Free  Trade  Zones  (FTZs),  Freeports,  Enterprise  Zones  (EZs),  and  finally  the  more  recent  

Oskar  Borup  Krabbe,  0503932687     Second  Year  Project  Emilie  Christine  Lucie  Jaillot,  0604952700        

     

5  

additions   such   as   Economic   and   Technological   Development   Zones   (ETDZs)   and   High-­‐

Tech   Industrial   Development   Zones   (HIDZs)   etc.   (Zeng,   p.5).   Although   differing   in  

configuration  and  aim,   there  are  a   few  essential   features  all  SEZs  have   in  common.  The  

definition   we   have   decided   to   recognize   for   this   paper   is   the   one   developed   by   the  

Foreign   Investment  Advisory  Service   (FIAS),  a   joint   facility  of   the   International  Finance  

Corporation  and  the  World  Bank  in  2008.  FIAS  has  defined  a  generic  term  for  the  modern  

SEZ   aiming   to   capture   the   core   elements   of   all   the   subdivisions.   1)   a   SEZ   consists   of   a  

geographically   delimited   area,   usually   physically   secured,   2)   it   has   a   single  

management/administration,  3)  it  offers  benefits  based  upon  physical  location  within  the  

zone,   and   finally   4)   it   has   a   separate   customs   area   offering   duty-­‐free   benefits   and  

streamlined  procedures  (FIAS  World  Bank  2008).  Due  to  the  limitations  imposed  by  the  

required  maximum  length  and  the  scope  of  this  paper,  we  will  not  elaborate  on  each  of  

the  specific  subdivisions.  Instead  we  will  consider  FIAS’s  generic  term  in  a  broad  sense  as  

an   overall   concept   when   conducting   our   analysis,   hence   addressing   our   strategic  

recommendations  to  the  modern  Chinese  SEZ,  whether  it  being  an  EPZ,  ETDZ  or  an  even  

third  configuration.  Finally  the  main  characteristics  and  initial  aims  of  the  Chinese  Special  

Economic   Zones  will   be   defined   by   drawing   on   the   explanations   found   in   Zeng’s   2010  

Building   Engines   for   Growth   and   Competitiveness   in   China.   As   stated   here,   SEZs   are  

industrial   policy   tools   with   the   main   objective   to   attract   foreign   direct   investment,  

promote  exports  and  finally  generate  employment  that  can  spillover  to  the  local  economy  

(p.8).  

Sustainable  growth  

It  appears  essential  to  characterize  what  this  paper  refers  to  when  using  the  concept  of  

sustainable   development,   since  we   investigate   how   it   can   be   pursued   in   China   via   the  

SEZs.   In   order   to   do   so,   the   characterization   provided   by   the   World   Bank   will   be  

combined   to   the   definition   of   sustainable   development   given   by   the   Brundtland  

Commission.  We  thus  define  sustainable  development  as  a  "development  that  meets  the  

needs  of  the  present  without  compromising  the  ability  of  future  generations  to  meet  their  

own  needs"  (Brundtland,  1987),  which  can  be  achieved  by  balancing  properly  economic,  

social  and  environmental  needs  today  (World  Bank,  2001).    Thus,  sustainable  economic  

Oskar  Borup  Krabbe,  0503932687     Second  Year  Project  Emilie  Christine  Lucie  Jaillot,  0604952700        

     

6  

growth  differs  from  simply  economic  growth,  the  latter  focusing  primarily  and  essentially  

on  economic  needs  and  performance.    

Foreign  Direct  Investment  (FDI)

As   one   of   the   core  motives   of   SEZs   existence,   it   is   found   relevant   to   introduce   the   key  

concept   of   FDI.   Once   again  we   shall   turn   to   the  World   Bank’s   definition.   Here   Foreign  

Direct   Investments   are   explained   as   the   net   inflows   of   investment   aimed   to   acquire  

lasting  management  interest  in  an  enterprise  functioning  in  an  economy  other  than  that  

of   the   investor   (World   Bank   2008,   p.355),   which   will   henceforth   be   the   definition  

applied.      

 

The  Lewis  turning  point  

This  concept,  developed  by  A.  Lewis  in  1972,  characterizes  the  point  an  economy  reaches  

when  the  pool  of  labor  supply  that  the  rural  areas  constitute  is  exhausted  and  thus  when  

demand  for  labor  is  exceeding  the  supply  of  labor,  engendering  an  increase  in  the  general  

level  of  wages  (Song  &  Zhang,  p.209).  This  concept  will  not  be  developed  further  since  it  

will  mainly  be  used  as  a  point  of  reference  rather  than  studied  it  in  depth  in  this  paper.    

2.  Analytical  Framework      

Before  moving   on   to   conduct   the   actual   analysis   on   the   viability   of   SEZs   for   sustaining  

Chinese   growth,   an   introduction   to   Philosophy   of   Science   and   an   assessment   of   the  

relevance  and  limitations  of  its  three  major  fields;  naturalism,  constructivism  and  critical  

realism,  will  be  provided.  This  will  lead  to  a  justification  of  the  rationale  for  choosing  the  

constructivist  paradigm  to  analyze  the  development  of  Chinese  SEZs  and  provide  action  

strategies   for   their   future   sustainability.   Afterwards,   the   theoretical   framework,   falling  

under   the   constructivist   perspective   used   to   conduct   this   academic   paper,   will   be  

introduced  and  explained.    

Oskar  Borup  Krabbe,  0503932687     Second  Year  Project  Emilie  Christine  Lucie  Jaillot,  0604952700        

     

7  

2.1.  Philosophy  of  Science  

The  study  of  Philosophy  of  Science  is  concerned  with  the  existence  of  the  world,  what  it  

consists  of  and  how  we  understand   it  and  obtain  knowledge  about   it.   It   is  an  academic  

frame   within   social   science   that   explores   the   relationship   between   truth   and   science  

through   three   fundamental   building   blocks;   ontology,   epistemology   and   methodology  

(Moses   &   Knutsen,   p.4).   Ontology   means   “theory   of   being”   and   is   the   branch   of  

Philosophy   of   Science   studying   the   assumptions   about   existence   and   the   definition   of  

reality.  Epistemology  on  the  other  hand  studies  what  defines  knowledge.  It  is  interrelated  

with   ontology,   as   it   is   the   epistemological   assumptions   of   knowledge   that   are   used   to  

address  what  our  ontological  assumptions  define  as  real  (Hatch,  p.11).  The  third  and  final  

branch  of  the  Philosophy  of  Science  framework  is  methodology,  which  refers  to  the  ways  

in  which  knowledge  is  acquired.  Methodology  is  the  study  of  which  methods  are  deemed  

suitable   to   acquire   and   produce   trustworthy   knowledge   (Moses   &   Knutsen,   p.5).   It   is  

these   three   essential   questions   that   naturalism,   constructivism   and   critical   realism  

disagree  on.  Having  introduced  the  study  of  Philosophy  of  Science,  a  concise  outline  of  the  

three  major   fields’   position   towards  ontology,   epistemology   and  methodology  will   now  

follow,  with  an  especial  comprehensive   introduction  of   the  constructivist   framework  as  

this  will  be  the  overall  paradigm  in  which  this  paper’s  line  of  argument  will  be  construed.  

Subsequently,   a   discussion   of   this   particular   choice   so   as   the   limitations   of   each   of   the  

three  fields’  analytical  structures,  will  be  developed.    

2.2.  Naturalism  

Naturalism  is  an  overall  paradigm  capturing  a  number  of  traditions  rooted  in  the  belief  of  

the  presence  of  a  Real  World  independent  of  our  experience  of  it,  with  an  existing  reality  

explainable  by  natural  sciences.  Therefore  the  methodological   features  of   its   theoretical  

structure  are  based  on  observations  of  the  nature.  This  process  allows  scientists  to  reveal  

explainable  patterns  and  thereby  move  further  towards  fully  comprehending  the  reality  

in   which   we   exist   (Moses   &   Knutsen   2007).   The   prevailing   methodology   used   in  

naturalism   stems   from   Sir   Francis   Bacon,   and   uses   the   methods   of   deduction   and  

induction.   Deduction   being   a   top-­‐down   approach  where   general   principles   are   used   to  

explain  events  moving  to  concrete  conclusions,  and  induction  being  the  bottom-­‐up  mode  

Oskar  Borup  Krabbe,  0503932687     Second  Year  Project  Emilie  Christine  Lucie  Jaillot,  0604952700        

     

8  

of   reasoning   where   empirical   details   generates   more   general   theories.   Thereby   it   is  

believed   that   the   Real   World   exists   and   we   can   access   knowledge   about   it   through  

inductive   and   deductive   methods   of   observation   and   thinking.   Contributing   to   the  

naturalist   methodological   position,   Karl   R.   Popper   developed   the   position   known   as  

falsificationism.  The  main  proposition  of  the  falsification  principle  is  that  the  world  is  too  

varied  and  diverse  for  anyone  to  conclude  a  general  claim  to  be  true.  Instead  the  scientist  

can  create  a  deductive  hypothesis  and  then  see  if  it  can  be  proven  false.  It  is  through  the  

falsification  process   of   questioning  hypotheses,   that   scientists   can   gain   true  knowledge  

about  the  Real  World  (Popper,  p.19).    

 

Ontologically,   naturalists   believe   that   the   Real   World   is   based   on   “independent  

particulars”  (Moses  &  Knutsen,  p.48).  Thereby  it  is  considered  that  there  exists  a  reality  

even  without  human  observation.  Epistemologically,  naturalists  believe   that  knowledge  

can  only  be  obtained  by  observing  and  documenting  the  regularities  of  nature  and  then  

re-­‐state  them  as  natural  laws.  Finally  the  naturalist  position  adopted  on  methodology  is  

that  the  regularities  and  repetitions  in  the  Real  World  can  be  explained  scientifically,  and  

that  it  is  the  main  purpose  of  naturalist  science  to  identify  these  regularities  (Ibid.,  p.49)  

 

2.3.  Constructivism  

Directly   opposable   to   Naturalism   is   the   Constructivist   perspective   in   Philosophy   of  

Science.  Indeed,  even  though  it  shares  a  common  goal  with  Naturalism  in  "mapping  and  

explaining   the  patterns   in   the  world"   (Moses  &  Knutsen,  p.169),  Constructivism  can  be  

considered   as   Naturalism's   antagonist   to   the   extent   that   it   provides   strong   criticisms  

against  it.  Some  of  the  main  points  of  dissension  between  the  two  perspectives  regarding  

ontology,  epistemology  and  methodology  will  be  explicated  in  the  following  paragraph.  

The  main  Constructivist   divergence   from  Naturalism   comes  with   ontological   doubts,   in  

other   words  what   falls   upon   the   conception   of   reality   and   Empiricism.   Constructivists  

refute  the  vision  of  patterns  existing  as  a  part  of  the  real  world;  they  allude  to  the  role  of  

the  observer  and  to  its  impact  on  those  patterns  (Moses  &  Knutsen,  p.147).    Both  William  

Oskar  Borup  Krabbe,  0503932687     Second  Year  Project  Emilie  Christine  Lucie  Jaillot,  0604952700        

     

9  

Whewell  and  Immanuel  Kant  stress  the  impossibility  to  be  neutral  when  observing  a  fact:  

Kant   writes   about   the   active   role   of   the   mind,   which   organizes   the   perception   (Ibid.,  

p.175),   and  Whewell   states   "all   facts   involve   ideas   unconsciously"   (Ibid.,   p.185).   Ideas  

affect   perception,   and   some   ideas   are   shared   by   all   (Ibid.,   p.175).  Thus,   there   are   no  

existing   patterns   in   the   real   world;   they   are   instead   made   by   human   minds   through  

experiences  and  perceptions,  which  are   in   turn  strongly   influenced  by   ideas.   It   is   those  

ideas   that   prevent   knowledge   from   being   objective,   as   Kant   highlights   (Ibid.,   p.176).  

Those   assumptions   also   go   against   the   Naturalist   presumption   that   there   is   a   truth,  

insinuated   for   instance   by   Descartes   emphasizing   the   need   for   verification   in   Science  

(Ibid.,   p.31).   The   doubt   about   the   realness   of   one   universal   truth   implied   by  

Constructivism,  as  well  as  other  Constructivist  elements  about  reality,  have  provided  the  

main  pointers  for  the  epistemology  specific  to  this  perspective  of  Philosophy  of  Science  -­‐  

ontological   and   epistemological   assumption   being   related   (Hatch,   p.11),   as   mentioned  

earlier.      

 

Finally,   the  methodology   advocated   by   Constructivists   is   equally   distinct   from   the   one  

suggested  by  Naturalists.  Constructivists  demonstrate  the  inappropriateness  of  Naturalist  

science   and   methods   when   studying   the   social   world,   by   revealing   the   differences  

between  the  natural  and  the  social  worlds.  Firstly,  the  subjects  studied  are  not  the  same  

in   the   social   world   than   in   the   natural   world   (Moses   &   Knutsen,   p.150).   Secondly,  

Fereyabend   argues   that   there   is   no   elements   proving   the   superiority   of   the   scientific  

knowledge;   this   approach   should   consequently  not   be  used   to   study   social   phenomena  

(Ibid.,   p.167).   Thirdly,   the   disagreements   between   Constructivists   and   Naturalists   on  

methodology   itself   are   used   as   an   argument   against   using   Naturalist   methodology   in  

Social   sciences.    Kuhn   contradicts   Popper's   argument   about   obtaining   knowledge   via  

testing  hypotheses  with  the  notion  of  incommensurability,  which  assess  that  even  testing  

hypotheses   cannot   be   purely   objective   and   obviously   includes   some   degrees   of  

interpretation.  In  a  nutshell,  Constructivists  either  opt  for  methodological  pluralism  and  

acknowledge   that   the   study   different   phenomena   presupposes   the   use   of   various  

methodologies,  such  as  Michel  Foucault   (Ibid.,  p.165),  or  are  against  methodology,  such  

Oskar  Borup  Krabbe,  0503932687     Second  Year  Project  Emilie  Christine  Lucie  Jaillot,  0604952700        

     

10  

as   Fereyabend.   One   thing   is   certain;   Constructivism   rejects   the   use   of   Naturalist  

methodology  when  studying  the  social  world.  

The  Constructivist  ontology   is   thus  complex  and  assesses  that  there   is  a  real  world,  but  

that  we  cannot  access  it.  As  for  the  social  world  we  have  access  to,  it  is  the  product  of  our  

minds  (Ibid.,  p.  169).  Constructivists  conceive  epistemology  as  subjective;  because  of  our  

ideas   and   perceptions,   the   phenomena   we   observe   cannot   be   completely   free   of   all  

judgment  or  of  all  personal  believes.  Knowledge  depends  on  the  context  (Ibid.).  Finally,  

because   of   the   influence   of   the   observer   and   of   the   society   on   knowledge,   which   then  

becomes   subjective,   Constructivists   are   aware   that   experiences   as   ways   to   access  

knowledge  are  not  neutral  (Ibid.,  p.10).  It  is  the  reason  why  they  advise  the  use  of  various  

methodologies,  or  epistemological  tools.  

 

2.4.  Critical  Realism  

Critical  Realism  can  be  considered  as  a  third  perspective  in  Philosophy  of  Science,  which  

includes   some   elements   of   both   Naturalism   and   Constructivism   (Ibid.,   p.12).   If   they  

acknowledge   the   complexity   of   the   social   world   and   are   in   this   matter   closer   to  

Constructivists,   Critical   Realists   assume   that   a   real  world   exists   separately   of  what  we  

experience  and  of  our  ideas.  In  that  sense  the  Critical  Realist  perspective  is  agreeing  with  

the  Naturalist  one  in  terms  of  basic  ontology  (Ibid.).  Critical  Realism  could  have  been  an  

interesting  approach  since  it  combines  features  from  the  Constructivist  and  the  Naturalist  

approach,  and  thus  seems  less  intransigent,  in  particular  when  it  comes  to  methodology.  

Indeed,  Critical  Realists  do  not  advocate  any  specific  methodology,  they  simply  advise  to  

use   questions   rather   than   methods   (Ibid.,   p.13).   However,   since   this   paper   aims   to  

investigate  how  a  potential  change  in  ideas  could  affect  growth  in  China  positively  rather  

than  what  effects  a  change  in  mechanisms  could  cause,  the  Critical  Realist  perspective  is  

therefore  not  the  one  retained.    

 

Oskar  Borup  Krabbe,  0503932687     Second  Year  Project  Emilie  Christine  Lucie  Jaillot,  0604952700        

     

11  

2.5.  Chosen  perspective  

The  Constructivist  approach  to  Philosophy  of  Science  seems  to  be  the  most  appropriate  

perspective   to   build   this   paper   onto,   rather   than   the   Naturalist   or   Critical   Realist   one,  

given   the   role   of   ideas   in   the   case   studied.   Indeed,   the   aim   of   this   assignment   is   to  

investigate  how  the   institution,  embodied  by  SEZs,  can  be  a  vector  of  change  and  a  key  

driver  for  sustainable  growth  in  China.  The  transition  from  growth  to  sustainable  growth  

represents   in   itself   an   important   shift   in   ideas   and   conceptions,   which   can   be   best  

analyzed   through   theories   presenting   some   Constructivist   features   such   as  

Institutionalism.  Moreover,  the  scope  of  our  analysis  goes  beyond  what  we  can  describe  

as   the   Natural   World,   that   is   to   say   resources   and   raw   materials,   hence   leaving   out  

Naturalism   as   an   accurate   approach.   Both   the   research   question   and   the   concept   of  

sustainable   growth   imply   a   focus   on   components   of   the   Social   world,   such   as   social  

capital   or   social   inclusion.   Those   are   best   studied   with   the   methodological   pluralism  

advocated   by   Constructivists,   rather   than   with   Naturalist   methodology.     To   the   same  

extent,   Critical   Realists   are   said   to   favor   Naturalist   approaches   when   studying   the  

complexity   of   the   Social  world   (Moses  &  Knutsen,   p.13),  which   is  why   this   perspective  

appears  to  be  less  suitable  for  this  paper.    

 

3.  Sustainability  of  Chinese  SEZs:  Theoretical  Perspectives    

To  conduct  the  analysis  of  the  sustainability  of  the  Chinese  Special  Economic  Zones  and  

provide   a   strategic   recommendation   for   its   future   success   as   a   key   growth   factor,   it   is  

found  adequate   to   introduce  a  number  of   relevant   theories   from   the  academic   fields  of  

PED,   OT   and   finally   CPE,   all   arguably   allowing   analysis   conducted   through   the  

constructivist   position.   In   this   section   the   theories  will   be   introduced   and  described   in  

order  to  provide  an  inherent  basis  for  understanding  their  features  and  contributions  to  

the  line  of  argument  furthered  in  this  academic  paper.    

 

 

 

Oskar  Borup  Krabbe,  0503932687     Second  Year  Project  Emilie  Christine  Lucie  Jaillot,  0604952700        

     

12  

Developmental  State  theory  

The   first   theoretical   perspective   introduced   stems   from   the   PED-­‐course   and   was   first  

conceptualized  by  the  American  professor  Chalmers  Johnson  in  his  1982  work  MITI  and  

the   Japanese   Miracle.   According   to   Johnson   the   success   of   the   country’s   development  

could   be   traced   in   the   Japanese   state’s   intervention-­‐strategy   where   especially  

bureaucratic  involvement  from  the  Ministry  of  International  Trade  and  Industry  (MITI)  in  

the  country’s  private  sector  affairs  and  the  market  that  led  to  the  rapid  economic  growth  

(Leftwich,   p.403).   From   the   initial   use   of   the   theory   to   explain   Japan’s   development,  

towards  a  more  general  explanatory  framework  to  understand  all  of  the  South  East  Asian  

“miracle”,   the  Developmental  State   (DS)   theory   is,  by   its   scholars,   capable  of  explaining  

the   best  way   for   an   underdeveloped   state   to   achieve   rapid   economic   growth   (Bolesta,  

p.105).  The  theory  postulates  that  if  a  state  adopts  five  features  from  the  DS  theory  into  

its  mainstream  policies,  the  state  will  eventually  be  able  to  “combat  Western  imperialism  

and  ensure  national  survival”  (Ibid.,  p.108).    

 

As  portrayed  in  Bolesta’s  China  as  a  Developmental  State,  these  five  features  agreed  in  the  

course  of  international  research  on  the  subject  are  as  following:  1)  the  states  authorities’  

objectives  must  be  to  achieve  fast  socio-­‐economic  development,  2)  these  objectives  must  

be   achieved   through   the   process   of   industrialization,   3)   although   strategies   and   goals  

might   be   drafted   by   ruling   elites,   the   transformation   of   the   state   in   itself   must   be  

conducted   by   competent   bureaucracies,   state   administrations   where   the   agenda   is  

independent  from  possible  democratic  choices  of  the  society,  4)  the  processes  of  change  

must   take  place   in  an   institutional  environment  where   the   state  has   full   authority  over  

the  norms  and  rules  of  the  social,  economic  and  political  existence  so  as  the  directions  of  

development.   Therefore   the   DS   must   be   an   interventionist   state.   5)   The   economic  

environment  must  be  capitalistic  with  a  strong  private  sector  leading  the  development  of  

the   country   (p.109).   Following   these   structures   recommended   by   the   DS   theory,   the  

country  can  become  and  exporter  of   its  own  products  and  might  eventually   reach  such  

standards   of   living   that   it   can   be   the   domestic   consumption   generating   the   economic  

growth.  With   such   progresses,   the   developmental   state   has   become   a   developed   state,  

Oskar  Borup  Krabbe,  0503932687     Second  Year  Project  Emilie  Christine  Lucie  Jaillot,  0604952700        

     

13  

and  the  DS  theory  has  proven  accurate  in  explaining  the  key  from  underdevelopment  to  

economic  prosperity  (Ibid.).    

 

Neo-­‐liberalism  

From   the   same   theoretical   framework   presented   in   the   PED-­‐course,   follows   the   Neo-­‐

liberalist   argument,   which   opposes   the   view   of   the   DS   theory   as   the   prevailing   key   to  

economic  development  as  they  believe  interventionist  behaviorism  should  be  avoided  at  

all  costs.  Neo-­‐liberalist  theory  instead  argues  that  it  is  through  the  opening  of  the  market,  

privatization   of   companies   and   with   the   removal   of   unnecessary   barriers   to   free  

movement   of   capital   that   countries   can   gain   economic   growth   (Chang,   p.25).   Extensive  

development   goals   are   better   reached   in   an   environment  where   authorities   have   very  

limited   power   over   the   market,   which   is   instead   controlled   by   the   “invisible”   market  

forces  of  supply  and  demand  (Corrales,  p.133).  

 

Institutional  theory  

Organizational  institutionalism  can  be  classified  as  being  part  of  the  symbolic  interpretive  

perspective  in  Organization  Theory,  perspective  that  in  turn  presents  some  Constructivist  

features.   Indeed,   this   theory   views   the  organization  more  broadly   than   a   theory   falling  

under  the  Naturalist  approach  would  do.  This  is  done  by  for  instance  granting  importance  

to  the  society  and  the  environment  in  which  the  organization  operates,  as  well  as  taking  

into  account  abstract   concepts   such  as   legitimacy  and  political  power,   rather   than  only  

focusing   on   the   material   dependencies   of   the   organization   that   raw   materials,   labor,  

capital  and  equipment  represent  (Hatch,  p.74).    

 

More  specific  and  most  relevant  for  our  study  of  the  Chinese  SEZs,  is  the  Institutionalism  

and  isomorphism  theory  developed  by  Paul  DiMaggio  and  Walter  W.  Powell   in  order  to  

explain   similarities   and   changes   in   the   structures   of   organizations.   They   define  

isomorphism  as  a  concept  that  describes  the  homogenization  mechanism  taking  place  for  

organizations  that  are  part  of  the  same  environment  (Di  Maggio  &  Powell,  p.149).  Three  

pressures   emanating   from   the   organization's   environment   that   affect   its   structure   are  

Oskar  Borup  Krabbe,  0503932687     Second  Year  Project  Emilie  Christine  Lucie  Jaillot,  0604952700        

     

14  

identified:   coercive   isomorphism   that   occurs   as   a   result   of   political   pressures,  mimetic  

isomorphism   that   happens   as   an   answer   to   uncertain   situations,   and   normative  

isomorphism  that  is  due  to  expectations  from  the  organization's  members  (Ibid.,  p.152).  

Organizations   have   an   interest   in   conforming   to   those   pressures   to   the   extent   that   it  

would   guarantee   them   legitimacy   as   well   as   approval   from   the   society   in   which   they  

operate  and   thus  ensure   their   stability   (Hatch,  p.74).   In  overall,   this   theory   is  part  of   a  

more   general   school   of   thought,   Institutionalism,   and   contributes   to   develop   a   more  

sociological  perspective  of  institutions  by  studying  their  interactions  with  one  another  as  

well  as  with  society.  

 

Constructivist  theory  

The  fourth  and  final  theory  deemed  relevant  for  the  scope  of  analysis  in  this  project,  is  the  

Constructivist   theory   as   it   is   developed   in   the   CPE-­‐course.   Constructivist   theory  

acknowledges  institutional  change  through  the  illumination  of  the  role  of  economic  ideas  

as  key  drivers.  At  the  center  of  the  argument,  the  theory  treats  actors,  not  as  mediums  of  

institutions   following   pre-­‐programmed   scripts,   but   instead   as   contemplative   entities  

capable  of  reinterpreting  and  restructuring  their  environment  (Campbell,  p.382).  As  one  

of  the  main  contributors  to  the  Constructivist  approach  to  CPE,  Mark  Blyth  explicates  the  

role   of   actors’   economic   ideas   as   influential   in   three   different   ways;   as   institutional  

blueprints,  -­‐  weapons  and  cognitive  locks  (Blyth,  p.2-­‐5).  Ideas  as  institutional  blueprints  

are   defined   as   the   agents   involved   in   the   changing   institutions’   economic   ideas   (Blyth,  

p.3)  and  explain  how  these  have   the  power   to  drive   institutional   change.  The  notion  of  

ideas   as  weapons   describes   how   economic   ideas   under   distributional   struggles   can   be  

used  to  restructure  institutions,  as  the  existing  ones  are  outcomes  of  past  economic  ideas.  

Therefore,  by  questioning  and  analyzing  the  current,  agents  can  replace  the  old  ideas  and  

help  shape  a  new  set  of  institutions  (Blyth,  p.4).  The  third  and  final  concept  granting  great  

importance  to  economic   ideas   in  driving  institutional  change  is   ideas  as  cognitive   locks.  

This   concept   claims   that   if   path   dependency   appears   in   policy   making,   it   might   be  

explained   as   a   result   of   cognitive   locking.   Therefore   it   must   be   seen   as   an   ideational  

rather  than  an  institutional  phenomenon  (Ibid.).    

Oskar  Borup  Krabbe,  0503932687     Second  Year  Project  Emilie  Christine  Lucie  Jaillot,  0604952700        

     

15  

                 

4.  Identifying  the  issue  

 

As   mentioned   earlier,   SEZs   have   without   a   doubt   been   huge   contributors   to   China's  

dazzling   economic   growth,   focused   essentially   on   manufacturing-­‐oriented   exports   and  

investments,   both   foreign   and   domestic.   Thanks   to   preferential   policies   such   as   tax  

exemptions   and   research   funding,   the   SEZs   became   the   most   efficient   tool   of   Chinese  

industrial   policy   by   appealing   considerably   to   investors   (Carter   &   Harding,   p.4).   This  

paper   will   refer   to   the   expansion   phase   of   China   characterized   by   the   focus   on   pure  

economic  growth  with  attraction  of  FDIs  through  low-­‐cost  labor  and  physical  capital,  as  

the  first  development  stage.  Since  the  Chinese  growth  is  facing  emerging  challenges  from  

the   internal   and   external   environment,   it   is   essential   to   shed   light   upon   some   of   the  

biggest  concerns  before  being  able  to  conduct  our  analysis.    

 

Social  concerns  

China's  reach  of  the  Lewis  turning  point  in  2003  (Cai  &  Du,  p.602)  marks  the  emergence  

of  new  challenges   in  terms  of   labor  and  of  social   issues  and  is   therefore  a  step  towards  

what  we  describe   as   the   second  development   stage.   Indeed,   China  has   reached   a   point  

where   the   majority   of   the   migrant   and   unskilled   labor   force   is   working   in   non-­‐

agricultural  sectors  in  urban  areas  (Ibid.).  This  phenomenon  can  thus  be  compared  to  a  

labor  shortage,  agricultural  sectors  having  been  until   then   the  source   from  which   firms  

would   draw   extra   workforce.   The   slow   down   of   the   increase   in   Chinese   working   age  

population,  due  to  the  demographic  transition,  is  reinforcing  the  exhaustion.  Additionally,  

the   unemployment   rate   being   supposedly   lower,   we   can   deduce   thanks   to  

macroeconomic  insight  that  the  workers  obtain  stronger  bargaining  power  and  that  the  

wages   consequently   increase,   because   of   the  demand   for   labor  being  unappeased.  This  

last   assumption   is   supported   empirically:   between   2003   and   2009,   the   annual   growth  

rate  of  migrant  workers'  wages  was  of  10.2%  (Ibid.).  It  seems  logical  to  think  that  a  rise  in  

workers'  bargaining  power  is  accompanied  by  more  focus  on  social  issues  from  firms  and  

authorities,   and   that   a   shortage   in   unskilled   labor   implies   an   increase   in   skilled   labor  

resulting   from   China's   development   and   shift   towards   a   knowledge   and   intellectual-­‐

Oskar  Borup  Krabbe,  0503932687     Second  Year  Project  Emilie  Christine  Lucie  Jaillot,  0604952700        

     

16  

based  industry  (Zhao  2008,  p.803).  Because  of  those  evolutions,  the  Chinese  economy  is  

not  able  to  rely  on  its  low  cost  labor  to  attract  investments  anymore.  What  was  "made  in  

China"   is   progressively   becoming   "created   in   China"   (Wuwei   &   Keane,   p.50),   which  

represents   a   considerable   shift   away   from   what   initially   impulsed   China's   economic  

growth   and   thus   from  what   constituted   the   original   strength   of   the   SEZs.   The   second  

development   phase   we   model   would   thus   be   reached   when   the   focus   is   set   on   social  

concerns  and  development,  as  well  as  when  social  capital  is  valued  and  constitutes  if  not  

the  main,  an  important  source  of  economic  growth.    

 

Environmental  concerns  

Another  desirable  evolution   that  Chinese  development  we  believe  hasn't   reached  yet   is  

one  concerning  the  environment  and  the  ecology;  this  evolution  is  modeled  in  this  paper  

as  the  third  development  phase.  The  impressive  economic  development  of  China  during  

the  past  decades  did  imply  important  environmental  degradations,  whose  consequences  

are   felt  more   and  more   and  are   gradually   turning   into   threatening   issues   for  China,   its  

population  and   its  economic  growth.   If   some  steps  have  been   taken  by   the  government  

towards   environmental   impact   reduction   through   for   instance   the   establishment   of  

concrete   objectives,   like   the   environmental   targets   for   the   10th   five   year   plan   (World  

Bank  2007,  p.I),  some  new  environmental  challenges  keep  on  emerging  simultaneously,  

in   both   rural   and   urban   areas   (Ibid.,   p.XI).   This   is   affecting   the   Chinese   population   in  

terms   of   health,   but   it   is   also   likely   to   negatively   impact   economic   growth   on   the   long  

term,  via   the  deterioration  of  natural  resources.  As  an  example,  water  surface  pollution  

contributes   to  water   scarcity,  particularly   in  Northern  China   (Ibid.,  p.81).   It   thus  seems  

pretty   rational   to   think   that   Chinese   SEZs   cannot   base   their   contribution   to   economic  

growth   on   low   environmental   and   pollution   regulations   anymore,   at   risk   of  

compromising  economic  growth   itself   in   the  near   future.  There   is  a  need   for  redefining  

the  role  of  SEZs  at  the  environmental   level.  Therefore,  we  define  the  third  development  

phase   we   introduced   earlier   as   a   phase   characterized   by   the   focus   on   ecology   and  

environment   concerns   and   improvements   in   growth,   leading   ideally   to   a   more  

responsible  type  of  growth.      

Oskar  Borup  Krabbe,  0503932687     Second  Year  Project  Emilie  Christine  Lucie  Jaillot,  0604952700        

     

17  

Concluding  remarks  

As  a  conclusion,  in  such  a  social  and  environmental  changing  context,  it  seems  adequate  

to   investigate   why   the   Chinese   SEZs   have   to   contribute   differently   to   growth   whose  

nature  is  also  evolving,  and  how  they  can  do  so.  However  before  being  able  to  move  on  to  

the   analysis   of   the   SEZ’s   potential   new   role   in   this   altering   setting,   the  methodological  

considerations  and  rationale  of  the  use  of  certain  empirical  data  to  conduct  the  analysis,  

so  as  the  delimitations  of  this  paper,  will  briefly  be  discussed.  

5.  Methodology    

5.1.  Empirical  data  and  Sources  

The  empirical  material  that  will  be  draw  upon  is  mainly  constituted  of  2nd  degree  sources  

where   the   authors   use   qualitative   methods   to   compose   their   arguments.   These   will  

consist  of  academic  articles   like,  papers,  books,   expert   statements  and  speeches,  where  

the   last   two   are   especially   useful   for   conducting   our   analysis   under   the   constructivist  

theoretical  perspective   this  paper  will   take.  Passages   from  selected  speeches  by   former  

chairman   Deng   Xiaoping   will   for   instance   be   relevant   to   analyze   the   discourses   and  

economic   ideas   behind   China’s   fast   economic   development.  When   it   comes   to   defining  

economic   and   political   terms,   we   will   mainly   turn   towards   the   World   Bank   for   their  

definitions   of   these   indicators.   We   will   also   make   use   of   acknowledged   works  

investigating   Special   Economic  Zones,   including  Zeng’s  Building  Engines   for  Growth  and  

Competitiveness   in  China:  Experience  with  Special  Economic  Zones  and  Industrial  Clusters  

and  Mohiuddin  et  Al.’s  The  Special  Economic  Zone  as  a  Locomotive  for  Green  Development  

in   China   in   order   to   analyze   their   development   and   possible   future   sustainability   as  

growth   vectors.   The   selected   books   and   articles   have   been   chosen   by   primarily   using  

authors   basing   their   argument   on   relevant   fieldwork   such   as   interviews   and   field  

investigations,  or  deemed  experts  in  their  academic  fields.    

 

Oskar  Borup  Krabbe,  0503932687     Second  Year  Project  Emilie  Christine  Lucie  Jaillot,  0604952700        

     

18  

6.  Analysis    

6.1.  Organization  Theory  application:  Institutionalism  

Introduction  

The   application   of   institutional   theory  will   provide,   through   an   analysis   of   the   current  

situation  of  Chinese  SEZs  and  of   the   challenges   they  are   facing,   important  elements   for  

answering  the  research  question  as  well  as  landmarks  on  which  we  will  be  able  to  base  

our  strategic  recommendations.  Taking  a  close  look  at  the  various  pressures  exerted  on  

SEZs   will   allow   us   to   first   analyze   to   what   extent   Chinese   SEZs'   configuration   and  

contribution  to  growth  can  be  considered  as  obsolete,  and  second  to  determine  to  which  

pressures  SEZs  henceforth  should  conform  in  order  to  generate  viable  growth  and  still  be  

efficient  tools  of  industrial  policy.  Indeed,  as  evocated  previously,  the  institutional  theory  

assesses   that   the   survival   and   the  well   functioning   of   the   organization   depends   on   the  

degree   of   compliance   with   the   environment's   and   the   society's   expectations   and  

pressures.   In   the   present   context   of   social   changes   in   China   and   rising   environmental  

degradation   problems,   getting   inspiration   from   the   requests   emanating   from   the   SEZs  

environment  could  constitute  an  excellent  basis  for  re-­‐orienting  and  reforming  SEZs  in  a  

sustainable   way.   The   following   section   will   thus,   after   having   explicated   the   interest  

residing   in   viewing   SEZs   as   organizations   in   the   symbolic   sense,   identify   some   of   the  

different   coercive,   mimetic   and   normative   pressures   operating   on   SEZs   thanks   to   the  

framework   of   institutional   theory.   Both   the   actual   and   the   possible   effects   of   those  

pressures  on   SEZs  will   be   studied,   finally   leading   to   the   conclusion,  which  will   provide  

some  components  to  construct  an  answer  to  the  research  question,  thanks  to  the  analysis  

of  what  developmental  path  the  pressures  encourage  SEZs  to  take.    

 

SEZs  as  organizations  

SEZs   fit   into   the  modern   concept   of   organizations   presented   in   the  OT-­‐course   to   some  

pretty  limited  extent.  If  they  possess  some  features  of  it,  since  they  are  entities  interacting  

with  their  environment  and  economic  agents,  and  as  they  are  subject  to  competition,  only  

considering  those  characteristics  and  using  the  modern  concept  of  organizations  for  SEZs  

Oskar  Borup  Krabbe,  0503932687     Second  Year  Project  Emilie  Christine  Lucie  Jaillot,  0604952700        

     

19  

would   be   simplistic   and   the   analysis   could   become   incomplete.   The   conception   of  

organization  we  will  thus  apply  to  SEZs  differs  from  the  modern  or  naturalist  definition  of  

the   organization.   Indeed,   SEZs'   structure   is   not   similar   to   the   one   of   the   traditional  

organization,   it   is   not   physical,   but   abstract.   We   thus   rather   argue   for   the   use   of   the  

symbolic   approach,  which   sets  no  objective  boundaries   to   the   concept  of   organizations  

(Hatch,   p.33)   and   which   is   in   line   with   the   constructivist   perspective   of   paper.   Some  

scholars  embracing  the  symbolic  perspective,  such  as  Karl  Weick,  developed  a  concept  of  

the   organization   based   on   the   enactment   theory   and   consequently   assumed   that  

organizations  were  to  some  extent  equivalent  to  cognitive  processes  (Ibid.,  p.34).  Having  

found  some  evidence  in  Hazakis'  work  that  SEZs  components  such  as  their  structures  or  

patterns   are   steeped   in   cognitive   values   (Hazakis,   p.88)   makes   applying   the   symbolic  

concept  of  organizations  to  SEZs  justifiable.    

 

Coercive  pressures  

As  defined  in  the  theoretical  part  of  this  paper,  coercive  isomorphism  is  a  consequence  of  

the   pressures   exerted   by   agents   that   possess   a   form   of   authority   on   the   organization  

(DiMaggio  &  Powell,  p.150).  The  actors  on  which  the  SZEs  are  directly  dependent  on  will  

be  identified,  as  well  as  the  claims  that  are  conveyed  via  the  exerted  coercive  pressures.  

In   December   2001,   China's   accession   to   the  World   Trade   Organization   (WTO)   implied  

that  the  country  complied  with  some  specific  regulations  directly  touching  on  SEZs,  such  

as   the   Agreement   on   Subsidies   and   Countervailing  Measures   (SCM   Agreement),   which  

forbid  to  some  extent  manufacturing-­‐oriented  export  subsidies  (Carter  &  Harding,  p.21).  

As  a  result,  the  Chinese  government  had  to  make  some  alterations  of  the  incentive  system  

for  domestic  companies  that  was  based  on  export  performance,  as  well  as  of  the  limited  

volume  of  sales  that  the  subsidies  were  allowed  to  make  on  the  domestic  territory  (Ibid.,  

p.22).   According   to   DiMaggio   and   Powell,   a   government   mandate   can   directly   create  

organizational   change,   and   thus   be   considered   as   a   coercive   pressure   (DiMaggio   &  

Powell,   p.150).   To   the   extent   that   SEZs   enjoy   government   support   (Zeng,   p.8),   them  

conforming  to  the  new  norms  constitutes  a  coercive  pressure,  coming  directly   from  the  

Chinese  national  authorities  and  indirectly  from  an  international  organization,  the  WTO.  

Oskar  Borup  Krabbe,  0503932687     Second  Year  Project  Emilie  Christine  Lucie  Jaillot,  0604952700        

     

20  

Finally,  on  a  more  abstract  level  but  not  less  important,  it  seems  rational  to  think  that  the  

political   instances   responsible   for   the   administration   of   SEZs   such   as   the   national,   but  

also  provincial  or   local  governments  exert   some  kind  of   coercive  pressure  on   the  SEZs,  

since  they  provide  infrastructures  and  financing  with  the  objective  that  the  development  

of  SEZs  is  successful.  If  finding  concrete  empirical  data  regarding  this  pressure  for  SZEs  to  

perform  economically  is  difficult,  we  still  consider  this  coercive  pressure  relevant.    

 

Thereupon,  we   identified   coercive   pressures   exercised   on   SEZs   by  political   institutions  

that  are   to  some  dimension  contradictory.  Whereas   the  pressure  coming   from  the   local  

and   provincial   governments   encourages   the   economic   performance   of   SZEs   through  

exports   and   low-­‐cost   strategies,   the   WTO   SCM   Agreement   condemned   the   actual  

configuration   of   SEZs   in   those   points,   constraining   the   Chinese   government   in  making  

some  changes   in   the   regulations.  The  coercive  pressures  originating   from   the   local   and  

provincial   political   institutions   hence   intend   to  maintain   the   SEZs'   strategy  within   the  

scope  of   the   first  development  stage  we   identified  earlier   in   this  assignment,  whilst   the  

WTO   pressures,   in   spite   of   criticizing   this   SEZs'   strategy,   do   not   provide   any   concrete  

elements  on  what  other  strategy   it  could  be  substituted   for,  such  as  a  more  sustainable  

one.    

 

Mimetic  pressures  

Mimetic   isomorphism,   that   is   to   say   when   organizations   tend   to   imitate   other  

organizations   in   their   environment,   is   described   as   a   consequence   of   uncertainty  

(DiMaggio   &   Powell,   p.151).   Different   levels   of   governments,   -­‐local,   provincial   and  

national-­‐,  play  a  crucial  role  in  developing  Chinese  SEZs,  since  they  ensure  their  financing  

and   sometimes   administration   (Zeng,   p.37).   It   has   been   found   that   competitiveness  

among  local  governments  responsible  for  SEZs  is  very  high,  each  of  them  trying  to  supply  

the  best   infrastructures  and  business  environment  for  the  SEZs  (Nee  et  al.,  p.43).   In  the  

case   of   Chinese   SEZs,   as   industrial   policy   tools,   their   aim   is   to   be   great   sources   of  

economic  development;  the  uncertainty  leading  to  mimetic  behavior  could  consequently  

be  embodied  by  this  competition  about  the  degree  of  growth  SEZs  end  up  generating,  as  

Oskar  Borup  Krabbe,  0503932687     Second  Year  Project  Emilie  Christine  Lucie  Jaillot,  0604952700        

     

21  

well  as  how  attractive  for  investments  every  special  zone  is.  In  a  way,  what  is  at  stake  for  

SEZs   is   their   own   survival.   Because   local   governments   attempt   to   provide   the   best  

conditions   to   the   SEZs   and   that   competition   makes   them   willing   to   keep   up   with   the  

general   standards,   we   assume   that   the   comparison   with   the   performance   and  

configuration   of   other   SEZs'  must   lead   to   a   homogenization   process   of   SEZs.   Logically,  

once   a   certain   feature   designed   to   attract   investors,   such   as   import   duty   exemptions,  

proves  to  be  efficient,  the  SEZs  that  haven't  implemented  it  yet  have  a  strong  incentive  to  

do  so.  Indeed,  organizations  imitate  other  organizations  from  their  environment  that  they  

perceive  as  successful  or  legitimate  (DiMaggio  &Powell,  p.152).    

 

In  order   to   conclude  on  how   the  mimetic  behavior  of   SEZs   as  organizations   affects   the  

transition  from  SEZs  as  vehicles  for  growth  to  vehicles  for  sustainable  growth,  two  trends  

of   the  mimetic   pressures   among   SEZs  will   be   studied.   If   those  we  will   study   occurred  

especially  during  what  we  refer  to  as  the  first  development  stage  and  explains  the  "racing  

to   the   bottom"   process,   we   will   also   stress   afterwards   the   potential   of   the   mimetic  

pressures  in  between  SEZs  for  facilitating  the  transition  from  the  first  development  stage  

to   the   two  next   ones  which  were  defined   earlier   in   this   paper,   and   thus   to   sustainable  

growth.    The  trend  studied  is  the  one  of  relaxing  regulations  within  the  Chinese  SEZs  as  

an   incentive   for   investors.  Here  we  will   pay   attention   to  what   are   the   consequences  of  

having  lax  social  and  environmental  regulations,  and  we  will  examine  what  effects  it  has  

on  growth  and  sustainable  growth.   If   lowering  the  labor  and  environmental  regulations  

attracts  investors  to  the  SEZs  because  the  costs  are  generally  reduced  and  it  is  easier  to  

settle  production  facilities  as  well  as  to  hire  and  fire  workers,  it  can  also  lead  to  a  "race  to  

the  bottom"  provoked  by  the  competition  phenomenon  and  mimetic  pressures  between  

SEZs,  and  consequently  not  lead  to  as  much  growth  as  wished  for  in  the  long  term.    For  

instance,  the  few  rules  in  terms  of  working  conditions  led  subsidiaries  operating  in  SEZs  

to  initiate  what  is  known  as  the  "dormitory  labor  regime"  (Ngai,  p.33),  a  practice  which  

can  probably  be  positive  for  creating  "just  growth"  but  which  is  not  converging  towards  a  

socially-­‐responsible   growth   The   same   goes   for   the   environmental   aspect;   if   SEZs   with  

high   pollution   tolerance   and   low   environmental   norms   contributes   to   immediate  

Oskar  Borup  Krabbe,  0503932687     Second  Year  Project  Emilie  Christine  Lucie  Jaillot,  0604952700        

     

22  

economic  growth,  it  definitely  also  has  a  cost  and  prevents  the  transformation  of  SEZs  as  

vectors  for  sustainable  development.    

 

However,  only  stating  the  negative  effects  of  the  mimetic  pressures  at  force  between  SEZs  

as   organizations   would   be   a   mistake.   As   a   matter   of   fact,   the   homogenization   of  

organizations   resulting   from   the   competition   has   some   potential   in   initiating   a  

sustainable  growth  process.   If   a   few  SEZs   changed   the  nature  of   the   incentives  used   to  

attract  investors,  the  mimetic  pressures  would  probably  spread  the  trend  generally,  and  

ideally  all  SEZs  could  become  promoters  of  a  new  kind  of  growth,  more  responsible  and  

ensuring  future  rents  thanks  to  a  better  management  of  resources  and  of  labor  relations.  

The   kind   of   incentives  we   are   talking   about   here   could   for   instance   be   of   the   form   of  

bonuses   allocated   to   firms   operating   in   SEZs   to   the   condition   that   those   comply   with  

environmental  and  social  standards.  In  a  large  time  scale,  such  an  action  plan  could  avoid  

a   race-­‐to-­‐the-­‐bottom   effect   and   instead   result   in   an   efficient   leveling   upwards,   turning  

SEZs  into  vehicles  for  viable  growth  and  accessing  the  development  stages  2  and  3.  As  a  

conclusion,   it   is   important   to   see   the   positive   capability   in   the   homogenization  

mechanisms  affecting  SEZs,  and  not  only  the  negative  one,  which  is  too  often  highlighted.      

 

Normative  pressures  

We   have   now   reached   the   last   kind   of   pressures   operated   on   SEZs   we   will   analyze:  

normative   pressures.   The   main   source   of   those   pressures   is   what   Larson   and   Collins  

define   as   professionalization,   that   is   to   say   the   "collective   struggle   of   members   of   an  

occupation  to  define  the  conditions  and  methods  of  their  work,  to  control  the  production  

of   producers   and   to   establish   a   cognitive   base   and   legitimation   for   their   occupational  

autonomy"   (DiMaggio   &   Powell,   p.152).   In   short,   the   pressures   exerted   on   the  

organization   emanate   from   the   organization's   members.   In   the   present   case,   the  

pressures  we  will   analyze   are   those   deriving   from   the  workers   employed   in   firms   and  

subsidies   located   in  SEZs.  Even   though   those  pressures  only  affect   SEZs   indirectly,   it   is  

still   accurate   to   study   them   to   the   extent   that   workers   exert   pressures   on   their  

companies,  which  have   to  conform  to   those  requests   -­‐   Institutionalism  stating   that   it   is  

Oskar  Borup  Krabbe,  0503932687     Second  Year  Project  Emilie  Christine  Lucie  Jaillot,  0604952700        

     

23  

for   the   organizations   a   matter   of   survival   -­‐   and   therefore   impact   SEZs.   Through   the  

analysis  of  workers'  social  claims,  this  section  of  the  application  of  Institutionalism  aims  

to   conclude   how   normative   pressures   can   impact   SEZs   in   their   role   as   promoters   of  

economic  growth,  and  possibly  of  sustainable  growth.      

 

Our   example   of   normative   pressures   will   be   the   wave   of   protests   occurring   in   2010,  

known   as   the   Chinese   Labor   unrest.   This  was   one   of   the   biggest  movements   of   strikes  

indexed   in   China,   involving   among   others   Foxconn,   Honda   and   Toyota   factories.   The  

workers  had  proactive  demands,  notably  a  rise  in  wages  and  more  power  for  the  workers  

union  (Gray  &  Jang,  p.9).  Seeing  as  the  claims  touched  upon  the  conditions  and  methods  

of  work,  the  pressures  fall  under  the  normative  classification.  Unlike  what  has  happened  

before,   the  management   authorities   of   those   striking   factories   engaged   in  negotiations,  

and   their   answer   was   described   as   conciliatory   (Ibid.,   p.3).   The   organizations   hence  

conceded  to  the  normative  pressures;  In  Nanhai  Honda,  a  raise  in  wage  of  800  Yuan  was  

decided   (Ibid.,   p.11).   The   movement   of   strikes   propagated   to   several   production   sites  

within   SEZs,   consequently   affecting   the   SEZs'   labor   standards   as   well.   This   normative  

pressure  was  in  line  with  the  social  challenges  faced  by  SEZs  identified  in  the  "Identifying  

the  issue"  part  of  this  paper,  and  could  be  explained  by  China's  reach  of  the  Lewis  turning  

point,  as  well  as  by  the  emergence  of  a  class  consciousness  (Ibid.,  p.2).  It  is  probable  that  

pressures   aiming   to   improve   the   social   conditions   will   be   more   and   more   frequent,  

emphasizing  that  SEZs  strategy  of  low-­‐wage  production  is  now  obsolete.  When  aiming  to  

improve  social  standards,  such  as  working  conditions,  normative  pressures  can  more  or  

less  directly  shape  SEZs  so   that   they  become  more  sustainable  and  socially   responsible  

industrial  policy  tools.    

 

Concluding  remarks  

The  analysis  of   the  coercive,  mimetic  and  normative  pressures  exerted  on  SEZs  enables  

us   to   reach   a   conclusion   about   their   effects   on   the   configuration   and   strategy   of   SEZs.  

Some   of   the   pressures   convey   the   increasing   social   and   environmental   concerns,   but  

others   do   not   take   those   issues   into   account,   giving   instead   priority   to   immediate  

Oskar  Borup  Krabbe,  0503932687     Second  Year  Project  Emilie  Christine  Lucie  Jaillot,  0604952700        

     

24  

economic   performance.   Concluding   about   a   general   trend   towards   which   SEZs   are  

heading   might   at   first   seem   complex,   given   that   the   pressures   operating   on   SEZs   are  

different  and  encourage  different  strategies  and  kinds  of  growth.  However,   it   is  rational  

to  think  that  the  pressures  that  are  advocates  of  the  social  and  environmental  causes  are  

not   going   to   diminish;   they  will   intensify   in   a   context   of   resources   rarefication   and   of  

increase   in   the   structural   power   of   labor,   engendering   organizational   changes.   In   that  

sense,  the  SEZs  as  organizations,  having  an  interest  in  conforming  to  those  pressures  to  

ensure  their  survival  via  societal  acceptance,  should  and  will  probably  increasingly  take  

steps  towards  a  more  sustainable  development  strategy.  If  we  are  less  certain  about  SEZs  

having  yet  conformed  their  growth  strategy  to  pressures  advising  more  preoccupations  

about   the  preservation  of   the  environment,   some  empirical  data   shows   that   some  SEZs  

have  already  become  more  sustainable  socially,  presenting  some  pioneer  social  standards  

for  China.  For  example,   in   the   late  1990s,   the  SEZ  of  Shenzhen  put   in  place  a  minimum  

wage  and  a  social  insurance  package  (Zeng,  p.17).  Additionally,  the  mimetic  isomorphism,  

which   is  operating  between  SEZs,  has   some  potential   in   spreading  and  accelerating   the  

transition   from   SEZs   facilitating   growth   to   them   encouraging   sustainable   growth.  

However,   initiating   the   transition   to   a   more   sustainable   growth   strategy   can   be   a  

challenge   as   the   high   competition   between   SEZs   reinforces   the  mimetic   patterns,   from  

which  it  is  consequently  difficult  to  be  the  first  one  to  break  out.  The  following  part  of  this  

assignment   will   thus   investigate   the   potential   of   state   intervention   in   helping   SEZs   in  

their  transition  to  become  sustainable  industrial  policy  tools  through  the  DS  theory.    

 

6.2.   Political   Economy   of   Development   theory   application:   Developmental   State-­‐  

and  Neo-­‐liberalist  theory  

 

Introduction  

As  developed  in  the  part  where  we  identify  the  issue,  China  has  shifted  into  a  new  stage  of  

development,   as   low   cost   labor   and   low   environmental   and   pollution   regulations   no  

longer  remain  sustainable  solutions  for  the  future  of  the  Chinese  SEZs.  The  rationale  for  

conducting   further   analysis   using   the   DS   theory,   as   presented   in   the   PED   course,   is   to  

Oskar  Borup  Krabbe,  0503932687     Second  Year  Project  Emilie  Christine  Lucie  Jaillot,  0604952700        

     

25  

investigate  how  the  Chinese  government  might  amend  and  re-­‐implement  certain  features  

of  the  DS  model  for  their  contemporary  development  trajectory  through  the  use  of  SEZs  

to  remain  sustainable.  The  contradicting  Neo-­‐liberalist  theory  will  also  be  included  in  the  

analysis   to   act   as   a   counterbalancing   argument   ensuring   that   the   full   perspective   is  

reached.  Although  continuing  the  focus  on  SEZs,  the  subsequent  analysis  will  now  move  

up  from  the  organizational  level  towards  the  governmental  level,  by  seeing  the  SEZs  not  

as  autonomous  organizations,  but  as  an  industrial  policy  tool  of  the  government.  We  do  

not  use  the  DS  theory  to  contradict  the  perception  that  SEZs  are  capable  of  orchestrating  

their  own  development  directions  by  taking  measures  to  avoid  for   instance  race-­‐to-­‐the-­‐

bottom  trends,  as  portrayed  in  the  findings  from  the  institutional  theory.  Instead,  the  use  

of   the   DS  model   should   be   seen   as   a   complementary   theory   used   to   assess   how   state  

intervention   through   industrial   policy   measures   might   or   might   not   contribute   to   the  

future  success  of  Special  Economic  Zones  as  vectors  for  growth,  by  once  again  making  use  

of   their   unique   features   to   reach   a   higher   stage   of   development.   Before   being   able   to  

conduct   this   analysis,   we   find   it   of   great   importance   to   explicate   the   initial   role   and  

development   of   SEZs   as   seen   through   the   lens   of   the   DS-­‐   and   Neoliberal   theoretical  

arguments.   The   first   segment   of   this   part   of   the   analysis   will   therefore   constitute   an  

investigation  of  how  these  PED  theories  can  contribute  to  the  enlightening  of   the   initial  

reasons  for  the  implementation  of  SEZs  in  China.  Afterwards  this  will  allow  us  to  analyze  

if  the  Chinese  government  still  has  the  ability  to  use  certain  aspects  of  the  DS  model,  to  

promote  future  sustainable  growth  with  SEZs  as  instruments.      

 

Rationale  for  the  use  of  DS-­‐theory  in  a  constructivist  framework  

The   DS   theory   is   considered   a   collection   of   several   theories   capturing   a   number   of  

economic   ideas   constituting   the   conception   of   the   best   way   for   an   underdeveloped  

country  to  reach  fast  development  (Gilpin,  p.317).  Thereby  the  theory  is  to  some  extent  

falling   under   the   field   of   constructivism   as   it   relates   to   the   ideas   about   how   economic  

performance   is   best   achieved   and   thus   about   the   economic   reality.   It   is   with   this  

perception  of  the  DS-­‐theory  the  upcoming  analysis  will  be  conducted.    

 

Oskar  Borup  Krabbe,  0503932687     Second  Year  Project  Emilie  Christine  Lucie  Jaillot,  0604952700        

     

26  

A  Chinese  Developmental  State  

As   introduced   in   the   theoretical   framework,   DS   theory  was   first   described   by   Johnson  

(1982)  and  encompassed  the  opinion  that  state  should  be  the  very  center  of  the  solutions  

to  underdevelopment.   Later  Bolesta   (2007)   contributed   to   this  notion  by   clarifying   the  

five  characteristics  of  a  Developmental  State  likewise  presented  in  the  theory  section  of  

the  paper.    It  is  indeed  with  these  five  features  we  will  aim  to  analyze  to  conclude  if  China  

can  be  considered  to  have  followed  the  Developmental  State  model  to  reach  its  economic  

growth.  Once  it  has  been  determined  if   the  Chinese  development  can  be  explained  with  

the   DS   theory,   it   will   be   possible   to   further   the   analysis   into   including   the   rationale  

behind  the  implementation  of  SEZs.    

 

The  first  feature  of  the  model  argued  how  the  government’s  aim  had  to  be  achieving  fast  

socio-­‐economic  development  for  it  to  be  considered  following  the  DS  model.  Proceeding  

along  Dirlik’s  argument  on  China’s  developmental  successes,  the  country’s  post-­‐socialist  

transformation  should  be  seen  as  a  product  of  the  legacy  of  revolution  where  an  efficient  

party  state,  successfully  transformed  itself  from  an  instrument  of  revolution  to  a  manager  

of   fast  development;  a  Chinese  state  which  trained  and  mobilized  workers  to  efficiently  

achieve   the   collective   goals   of   national   socio-­‐economic   progression   thereby   creating   a  

“functioning  machinery  of  development  within   the   context  of   global   capitalism”   (Dirlik,  

p.301).  Supporting  this  conception,  Lin  (2006)  noted  how  the  primary  aim  of  the  Chinese  

Communist  Party  (CCP),  was  to  defeat  backwardness  and  reach  state  development  as  fast  

as  possible  (Bolesta  2007,  p.  109).  Hence  the  first  feature  of  the  DS-­‐theory  appears  to  be  

met.   The   second   feature   proclaims   how   the   development   objectives  must   be   achieved  

through   an   industrialization   process,   and   can   also   easily   be   deemed   obtained   when  

conferred  with  pertinent  academic   sources   like  Grivoyannis’  The  New  Chinese  Economy,  

Dynamic  Transitions  into  the  Future.  Here  it  is  stated  how  the  process  of  industrialization  

emerged  when  the  state  opened  the  market,  which  lead  to  the  rapid  development  of  the  

secondary  sector  driving  the  socio-­‐economic  progress  (p.54).    

 

Oskar  Borup  Krabbe,  0503932687     Second  Year  Project  Emilie  Christine  Lucie  Jaillot,  0604952700        

     

27  

The   third   factor   consists   of   the   requirement   that   the   transformation   is   facilitated   by   a  

bureaucratic  state   independent  of  democratic  choices  of  the  society.  Already  in  the  first  

stages   of   Chinas   restructuring   through   the   economic   reform,   the   influential   American  

sociologist   and   political   scientist   of   Harvard   University   Theda   Skocpol   called   China’s  

Leninist  regime  for  “an  affective  Weberian  bureaucracy”  (Skocpol,  p.279),  and  praised  the  

government’s  role   in  creating  an  extraordinary  evolution   in  economic  development  and  

social  equality  in  her  1979  book  on  social  revolutions  (Ibid.,  p.274).  Of  more  recent  data,  

Gilley’s  Two  Passages  to  Modernity   explains   the  Chinese  state’s  autonomy  of  democratic  

choices   from   the   society   by   stating   that   it   is   “difficult   to   speak   of   the   existence   of   any  

rights   in   China   given   that   the   party   [CCP]   reserves   the   right   to   override   them   all”  

(Friedman   &   Gilley,   p.31).   The   fourth   aspect   dictates   that   the   DS   needs   to   be  

interventionist,  which  also  seems  to  hold  true  in  the  case  of  China,  when  referring  to  Nee  

et   al.’s  Developmental  State  and  Corporate  Governance   in  China.  Their   findings   conclude  

that   the   Chinese   state   did   indeed   play   a   strong   and   developmental   role,   having   all   the  

tools   to   intervene   in   multiple   aspects   of   political,   economic   and   social   life   (p.42-­‐43).  

Fifthly  and  finally  it  was  argued  that  a  state  is  a  developmental  state  only  if  the  economic  

environment   is  capitalist.  To  analyze   if   this  aspect   is  met,  we  will  now  turn  to  Bolesta’s  

own  findings  on  the  matter  where  it  is  concluded  that  although  communist  and  thereby  

social,   China’s   economic   system   is   a   type   of   capitalism   where   the   rights   of   private  

production,   an   important   part   of   every   capitalist   system,   are   “extremely   unlikely   to   be  

abolished,   regardless   of   the   ideological   and   institutional   direction   the   PRC   decides   to  

follow”  (Bolesta  2007,  p.110).    

 

This  analysis  shows  that  the  Chinese  state  undeniably  possesses  an  active  developmental  

role.   Although   this   opinion   is   contested   and   conceived   differently   by   many   different  

academic   scholars,   including   Breslin   (1996)   and   Howel   (2006),   there   are   also   many  

voices   including   Bolesta   (2007),   White   (1988)   and   Baek   (2005)   who   argues   that   the  

contemporary  China  is  a  genus  of  the  developmental  state.  This  is  substantiated  by  Baek  

in  his  Does  China  Follow  "the  East  Asian  Development  Model"?,  where  the  Chinese  aspects  

of  the  DS  model  are  developed  and  found  to  include,  among  other  features,  the  high  rate  

Oskar  Borup  Krabbe,  0503932687     Second  Year  Project  Emilie  Christine  Lucie  Jaillot,  0604952700        

     

28  

of  domestic  savings,  the  enormous  infrastructure  of  heavy  industry,  the  legacy  of  central  

planning,   labor-­‐intensive   industry   followed   by   import-­‐substitutive   capital-­‐intensive  

industry,   a   strong   central   government   with   huge   bureaucracy   and   corporatist   control  

over  the  society,  and  finally  the  promotion  of  industrial  policy  (p.487).    

 

SEZs  as  tools  of  the  DS-­‐model  

Our  findings  of  the  analysis  on  the  aspects  of  Chinese  development  explainable  by  the  DS  

theory,  makes  the  initial  reasoning  behind  the  implementation  of  SEZs  clear.  As  it  is  now  

deemed  rational  to  consider  the  post-­‐reform  PRC  a  genus  of  a  developmental  state,  it  thus  

also  holds  that  the  DS  theory  of  the  PED  course  proves  applicable  in  explaining  parts  of  

China’s  initial  economic  success.  As  mentioned  by  Baek  (2005)  one  of  the  main  aspects  of  

the   interventionist  behavior   following  the  DS  model   is   the   implementation  of   industrial  

policies.   As   stated   in   Zeng’s   Building   Engines   for   Growth   and   Competitiveness   in  China,  

when  China  launched  its  Open  Door  reforms  in  1978,  Deng  Xiaoping,  the  main  architect  

behind   the   systemic   change,   decided   to   implement   special   industrial   policies   as   a   key  

feature   of   their   economic   development   model,   aiming   to   kick   start   socio-­‐economic  

expansion   (p.9).   As   the   World   Bank   (2008)   states,   Special   Economic   Zones   can   be   a  

“useful   tool   as   part   of   an   overall   economic   growth   strategy   to   enhance   industry  

competitiveness   and   attract   foreign   direct   investment”   (p.1).   These   immediate   reasons  

for  the  implementation  of  SEZs  thus  seem  perfectly  aligned  with  Xiaoping’s  wish  for  rapid  

economic  expansion.  However,  moving   further   into  an  analysis  of   the  reasoning  behind  

the   development   of   Chinese   SEZs,   we   find   that   there   is   more   to   it   than   the   usual  

objectives  of   implementing  SEZs,  which  was   touched  upon  when  we  developed   the  key  

concept   of   SEZ,   such   as   attracting   foreign   direct   investment,   promoting   exports   and  

generating   employment   that   can   spillover   to   the   local   economy   (Zeng,   p.8).   The  

additional  intensions  can  be  traced  to  Xiaoping’s  famous  words  from  1978,  “crossing  the  

river  by  touching  the  stones”,  which  can  be  analyzed  to  rather  accurately  explain  China’s  

pragmatic   and   gradualist   approach   to   economic   reform   over   the   past   three   decades  

(Chen   &   Scotland,   p.1).   The   first   SEZs   were   therefore   not   only   used   as   “windows”   to  

promote  exchange  between  the  PRC  and  the  outside  world,  but  also  as  vectors  of  change  

Oskar  Borup  Krabbe,  0503932687     Second  Year  Project  Emilie  Christine  Lucie  Jaillot,  0604952700        

     

29  

and   laboratories   which   could   experiment   with   economic   and   political   reforms  

(Mohiuddin  et  al.,  p.109).    

 

SEZs  as  Neo-­‐liberal  testing  labs  for  the  market  economy  

To  understand  the  benefits  of  using  the  SEZs  as  “testing  labs”  we  find  it  relevant  to  draw  

in   the  Neo-­‐liberal   economic   thought   as   it   has   been   depicted   in   the   introduction   of   our  

theoretical  framework.  Seeing  the  Chinese  development  through  this  perspective,  it  was  

the   post-­‐reform   Chinese   government’s   neo-­‐liberal   policy   pursuit   of   “market   adapting”  

economic  development  strategies,   the  reduction  of   the  role  of   the  state   in   the  economy  

and   the   implementations   of   export-­‐led   growth   strategies   that   led   the   extraordinary  

Chinese  economic  success  (Gilpin,  p.317).  We  find  that   this  conception  of   the  reasoning  

behind   the   growth,   seems   evident   to   a   certain   extent   with   the   concept   of   the  

liberalization  of  the  markets,  but  forget  to  encompass  the  crucial  role  played  by  the  state  

through  the  application  of  industrial  policies.  We  believe  Neo-­‐liberalism  proves  relevant  

to  explain  the  market  forces  emerging  from  their  political  and  economic  actions  leading  

to   FDI   attracting   incentives,   like   tax   holidays,   but   on   the   other   hand   these   neo-­‐liberal  

qualities  would  not  have  happened  in  the  first  place  had  China  not  followed  the  DS-­‐model  

with  a  state  controlled,  pragmatic  and  gradual  implementation  of  Special  Economic  Zones  

to  test  and  explore  its  own  way  towards  an  open  market  economy.    

 

A  future  for  state  intervention  in  SEZs?    

So   far  our  analysis  has   led  us   to   the   conclusion   that  China’s  economic   success  partially  

can   be   explained   by   its   Developmental   State   features   combined   with   the   Neo-­‐liberal  

opening  of  the  market.  We  have  explained  how  SEZs  were  initiated  as  an  industrial  policy  

tool,   created  and  used   through  committed  and  controlled  state   intervention.  Finally  we  

argued   how   the   implementation   of   SEZs   could   be   explained   by   objectives   stretching  

beyond   the   usual   aims   of   such   zones,   by   acting   as   a   testing   lab   for   new   policies   and  

institutions  for  a  marked-­‐oriented  economy.  We  now  aim  to  investigate  if  there  still  is  a  

potential  for  the  Chinese  state  to  make  use  of  certain  aspects  of  the  DS  model  to  promote  

future  sustainable  growth  through  the  use  of  SEZs,  or  if  it  would  be  better  off  completely  

Oskar  Borup  Krabbe,  0503932687     Second  Year  Project  Emilie  Christine  Lucie  Jaillot,  0604952700        

     

30  

giving   in   to   the  market   forces  of   the  Neo-­‐liberal  open  market   capitalist   system.  Quite  a  

few   scholars   have   concluded   that   the   times   where   East   Asian   developing   states   could  

benefit   from   following   the   model   proposed   by   the   DS-­‐theory   were   over,   and   that   the  

triumph  of   the  Neo-­‐liberal  economic   ideology  “rendered   interventionist  policies  useless  

and   wrong   in   achieving   economic   prosperity”   (Bolesta   2007,   p.111).   In   line   with   this  

argument  professors  including  Hayashi  (2010)  and  Evans  (1998),  seems  to  highlight  that  

in  the  post-­‐WTO  global  context  as  a  result  of  globalization,  the  role  of  the  state  in  national  

economies   is   diminishing   as   governments   are   incapable   of   controlling   the   economic  

processes  when  situations  in  one  part  of  the  world  influences  the  conditions  in  another  

(Bolesta  2012,  p.60).  Beeson  (2004)  even  go  as  far  as  stating  in  his  The  Rise  and  Fall  (?)  of  

the  Developmental  State:  The  Vicissitudes  and   Implications  of  East  Asian   Interventionism,  

that   extensive   interventionism   hinders   the   innovative   behavior   of   private   companies  

necessary  for  survival  in  a  competitive  global  economy  (p.33).  It  must  thus  be  noted  that  

several  scholars  appears  to  believe  that  the  role  of   the  states   is  diminishing  on  a  global  

level.   Does   that   mean   the   Chinese   state   is   best   advised   to   remove   all   interventionist  

behavior   and   their   control   of   the   SEZs   thereby   removing   some   vital   features   of   the  DS  

model?    

 

SEZs  as  social  and  environmental  testing  labs  for  the  market  economy  

As   explicated   in   our   issue   identification   part   and   backed   by   the   findings   through   the  

application   of   the   institutional   theory   from   the   Organization   Theory   course,   China   has  

entered  a  new  stage  of  development  and  can  thus  no   longer  rely  on   low  cost   labor  and  

low  environmental  regulations  to  attract   investments.  This  arguably  has  a  big   influence  

on  the  Chinese  SEZs  as  these  were  some  of  the  main  strengths  constituting  their  success  

as  growth  vectors  in  the  past.  Having  previously  identified  some  of  the  actions  SEZs  can  

take  themselves  by  conducting  an  analysis  composed  on  the  organizational  level,  we  now  

turn   the   analysis   to   the   governmental   level   by  making  use  of   the  DS   theory   to   identify  

some   of   the   actions   the   Chinese   state   can   take   to   amend   the   use   of   SEZs   towards   a  

sustainable  engine  for  China’s  progress,  leading  in  the  direction  of  the  introduced  higher  

stages  of  development.    

Oskar  Borup  Krabbe,  0503932687     Second  Year  Project  Emilie  Christine  Lucie  Jaillot,  0604952700        

     

31  

 

Having   previously   been   used   as   experimental   grounds   for   testing   new   policies   for   an  

open   market   economy,   SEZs   proved   useful   for   conducting   a   pragmatic   and   gradualist  

approach  to  the  economic  reform  of  China  by  “crossing  the  river  by  touching  the  stones”,  

(Chen   &   Scotland,   p.1).   This   ideology  might   still   prove   effective   when   it   comes   to   the  

sustainable   actions   China   allegedly   has   to   take   to   fight   the   increasing   social   and  

environmental  pressures  encompassing  the  emergence  towards  entering  the  second  and  

third  stage  of  development.  Australian  Professor  Hans  Hendrischke  visited  China  at   the  

SEZs  30th  anniversary  in  2010,  with  the  primary  aim  to  investigate  the  potential  for  a  new  

generation   of   Special   Economic   Zones   to   drive   social   justice   and   welfare   leading   the  

country  into  the  next  stage  of  development  (People’s  Daily,  2010).  Instead  of  abandoning  

the   DS   model’s   trajectory   of   active   industrial   policies   conducted   through   state  

intervention,  the  Chinese  government  can  once  again  let  the  SEZs  play  a  significant  role  

for   the   country’s   future   development.   As   proposed   by   Mohiuddin   et   al.’s   The   Special  

Economic  Zone  as  a  Locomotive  for  Green  Development  in  China   the  Chinese  SEZ’s,  being  

relatively  small  geographic  areas  and  well  organized  in  terms  of  administrative  services  

and   infrastructures,   can   be   once   again   used   as   prototypes   to   address   the   social   and  

environmental  issues  on  a  small  scale  and  “then  expand  their  experience  to  the  country  

as  a  whole  in  the  same  way  as  the  foreign  investment  capitalistic  product  model  was  first  

introduced  in  the  SEZs  and  then  to  whole  of  China”  (p.113).  This  would  require  that  the  

Chinese  government  sees  SEZs  as  dynamic  and  organic  entities  with  the  ability  to  quickly  

adapt   to   market   fluctuations,   rather   than   sees   them   as   static   and   fixed   organizational  

entities  who  do   not   have   the   autonomy   to   regulate   and   change   their   features  with   the  

market  demand  in  order  to  stay  competitive  (Hazakis,  p.87).  It  appears  possible  that  the  

SEZs   can   act   as   an   engine   of   the   gradual   move   towards   social   and   environmental  

sustainable  development  and  help  China  enter  the  next  stage  of  social  inclusion  and  eco-­‐

friendly  growth.    

 

As  previously   touched  upon,   the   contemporary  Shenzhen  SEZ  has   continued   to  play  an  

important  role  as  an  experimental  zone  for  innovative  and  technological  methods.  As  we  

Oskar  Borup  Krabbe,  0503932687     Second  Year  Project  Emilie  Christine  Lucie  Jaillot,  0604952700        

     

32  

see  it,  it  seems  rational  that  the  Chinese  state  should  allow  these  experimentations  to  be  

conducted  in  not  only  a   few  selected  zones,  but  actively   in  all  of   the  SEZs  to   investigate  

which  innovative  environmentally  and  socially  sustainable  policies  works  best  and  then  

let  them  spill  over  to  the  rest  of  the  country.  As  these  actions  arguable  wouldn’t  happen  

on  their  own  through  the  market  powers,  we  can  thereby  recommend  the  Chinese  state  

to   continue   the   use   of   interventionist  methods   through   an   active   and  market   dynamic  

industrial  policy  as  explicated  by  the  DS  theory  with  SEZs  as  experimental  zones  driving  

the  development.    

 

Concluding  remarks  

To  sum  up  our  argument  and  clarify  our   findings  of   the  analysis,   the  government  could  

develop  both   innovative   labor  and  environment  policies  and   test   their  ability   to  attract  

skilled   labor,   technology   and   FDI,   and   if   successful,   let   it   spill   over   to   the   local  

environment   by   implementing   the   policies   on   the   national   level.   The   creation   and  

execution   of   innovative   environmental   standards   in   SEZs   could   even   “help   create   a  

market  and  training  ground  for  entrepreneurs  and  firms  in  environmental  management,  

while  also  creating  better  living  conditions  that  will  help  attract  a  well  educated,  affluent  

workforce”  according  to  Krusekopf  in  his  SEZs  and  improved  environmental  management  

(p.96).  This  would  indeed  require  a  dynamic  and  strategic  state  intervention  executed  by  

a  state  promoting  the  use  of  industrial  policies  to  achieve  socio-­‐economic  growth,  leading  

to   our   overall   conclusion   to   this   part   of   our   SEZ   sustainability-­‐analysis.   Using   the   DS  

theoretical   framework,   which   we   have   deemed   prevailing   to   understand   the   Chinese  

economic   “miracle”,   the   Chinese   government   should   keep   certain   aspects   from   the  DS-­‐

model  allowing  them  to  intervene  on  the  market  through  SEZs  by  using  them  as  dynamic  

experimental  grounds  for  sustainable  policy  implementations.      

 

6.3.  Comparative  Political  Economy  theory  application:  Constructivism  

Introduction  

The  Constructivist  approach  in  CPE  applied  to  the  case  of  Chinese  SEZs,  will  allow  us  to  

study   the   evolution   of   the   ideas   behind   those   industrial   tools   and   thus   to   explain   the  

Oskar  Borup  Krabbe,  0503932687     Second  Year  Project  Emilie  Christine  Lucie  Jaillot,  0604952700        

     

33  

evolution  of  their  configuration.  We  aim  to  reach  a  conclusion  about  which  conceptions  of  

the  Chinese  economy  and  of  SEZs’  role  would  induce  SEZs  to  change  their  configuration  

to   become   vectors   of   sustainable   development,   and   how   this   arrangement   could   be  

instituted.  This  will  be  done  by  comparing  conceptions  about  SEZs  and  their  objectives,  as  

well   as   economic   ideas   in   two   time   periods,   the   first   period   being   around   1978,   the  

introduction  of  the  Open  Door  reform,  and  the  second  one  being  more  recent,  after  2001,  

China’s  accession   to   the  WTO.  The   theoretical   tool  which  will   enable  us   to   characterize  

the  two  time  periods  and  consequently  to  compare  them  is  Marc  Blyth’s  framework  about  

economic   ideas   as   institutional   blueprints,   as   weapons   and   as   cognitive   locks.   To  

complete   this   comparison,  we  will   integrate   an   analysis   of   the   discourse   presented   by  

Deng  Xiaoping  in  1978,  a  method  in  line  with  the  Constructivist  approach.    

 

Economic  ideas  in  1978

To   start   of   the   comparative   Constructivist   analysis,   we   will   investigate   some   of   the  

economic   ideas   behind   the  Open  Door   reform   of   1978   by   using   components   of   Blyth’s  

theoretical   framework.  Turning  to  empirical  sources  depicting  the  events   leading  to  the  

socio-­‐economic  reforms  and  the  opening  of  the  market  enables  us  to  analyze  some  of  the  

economic  ideas  behind  this  change.  In  Yeung  et  Al.’s  China’s  Special  Economic  Zones  at  30,  

it  is  portrayed  how  with  the  ending  of  the  decade-­‐long  struggle  of  the  Cultural  Revolution,  

the   Chinese   people  were   “physically   and   emotionally   drained”   (p.222).   It   is   also   stated  

how  this  time  of  crisis  led  the  path  to  the  emergence  of  new  ideas  (Ibid.).  With  the  launch  

of  the  1978  Open  Door  reform,  Xiaoping  took  action  of  these  emerging  ideas  and  created  

a   fundamentally  new  path   for  China   to   follow.  Conducting  a  discourse  analysis,  we   find  

that  Xiaoping  at  the  previously  mentioned  speech  where  he  said  his  famous  phrase  on  his  

vision  for  future  development:  “crossing  the  river  by  touching  the  stones”,  also  promised  

the  Chinese  residents  that  “the  national  economy  [would],  wave-­‐like,  surge  forward,  with  

all   the   people   becoming   relatively   well-­‐off”   (Deng   Xiaoping   1978   as   quoted   in   Xu   and  

Chen,  p.14),  and  that  this  would  happen,  as  stated  in  a  speech  one  year  later,  through  the  

liberalization   of   the   market   with   an   agenda   focusing   on   “economics   and   less   about  

politics”  (Deng  Xiaoping  1979  as  quoted  in  Tisdell,  p.6).  Thereby  representing  a  change  of  

Oskar  Borup  Krabbe,  0503932687     Second  Year  Project  Emilie  Christine  Lucie  Jaillot,  0604952700        

     

34  

ideational   agenda,   away   from   Chairman   Mao   Zedong’s   focus   on   political   power  

demonstrations   such   as   during   ‘The  Great   Leap   Forward’   and   the   ‘Cultural   Revolution’  

which   involved   heavy   costs   to   China   (Ibid.,   p.2),   towards   a   focus   on   economic   power  

demonstrations  to  create  a  strong  growth  engine  for  the  Chinese  economy  (Ibid.,  p.6).  By  

applying  theories   from  the  CPE  Constructivist   framework,   this   line  of   thought  emerging  

from  the  leaders  of  the  CPC  can  be  analyzed  as  a  new  set  of  economic  ideas  as  a  response  

to   periods   of   uncertainty   (Blyth,   p.2)   which   we   believe   is   best   described   by   Blyth’s  

concept  of   institutional  blueprints.  The  theory  claims  how  new  ideas  about  institutional  

changes   constitutes   a  way   out   of   a   period   of   crisis   eventually   ending   up   being   used   as  

institutional   blueprints   for   the   foundation   of   a   new   set   of   institutions   (Blyth,   p.3-­‐4).  

Xiaoping   did   indeed   follow   suit   on   his   promises   of   liberalizing   the   Chinese   economy  

through  a  pragmatic  and  gradualist  approach  to  economic  reform,   thereby  allowing  the  

economic  ideas  to  form  new  institutional  settings.  

 

In  his  1978  speech  he  introduced  the  concept  of  SEZs  as  a  core  engine  for  this  change  and  

explained   how   “they   will   engender   powerful   demonstrative   effects   on   their   neighbors  

and   lead  people   in   other   regions,  work  units   to   follow   their   examples”   (Deng  Xiaoping  

1978  as  quoted  in  Xu  and  Chen,  p.14).  Thereby  arguing  for  their  applicability  to  work  as  

experimental  grounds  that  could  eventually  spill  over  to  the  local  economy.  The  economic  

ideas  of  1978  were  however  not  focusing  on  the  importance  of  sustainable  development  

whatsoever.   As   there   were   no   talks   of   environmental   degradation   and   an   almost  

inexhaustible  supply  of  cheap  labor  from  rural  china  (Yeung  et  Al.,  p.224),  the  first  SEZs  

and   in   particular   Shenzhen   acted   as   powerful   economic   growth   engines   through   their  

ability   to   provide   favorable   conditions   for   FDI.   Thereby   we   can   conclude   that   the  

institutional  blueprints  behind  the  1978  Open  Door  reform  were  solely  embodied  in  the  

initial   configurations   and   functions   of   SEZs   as   drivers   for   economic   success,   with   few  

attributes   paid   to   sustainability   of   neither   the   ecological   environment   nor   social  

inclusions  of  the  workforce.    

 

 

Oskar  Borup  Krabbe,  0503932687     Second  Year  Project  Emilie  Christine  Lucie  Jaillot,  0604952700        

     

35  

Ideas  as  cognitive  locks  

The  concept  of   ideas  as  cognitive   locks  emphasizes   the   important   impact  of   ideas,  once  

they  are  institutionalized,  on  future  policy-­‐making  (Blyth,  p.4).  It  is  related  to  the  notion  

of   intellectual  path  dependency,   implying   that   the   ideas  behind  a   set  of   institutions  are  

cognitive  locks  to  the  extent  that  the  principles  they  embodied  will  be  found  in  all  future  

policies  within  a  country.   In  our  case,   the  cognitive   locks  are   the   ideas  described   in   the  

ideas  as  institutional  blueprints  part,  that  is  to  say  the  ideas  about  economic  reality  and  

the  role  of  SEZs  that  led  China  to  its  economic  “miracle”.  Those  ideas  about  the  initial  role  

of   SEZs   and   about   the   way   to   achieve   economic   performance   are   linked   to   the  

manufacturing-­‐oriented  exports  as  the  main  source  of  economic  growth  creation,  which  

has  been  for  that  matter  one  of  SEZs'  most  used  strategies.  As  previously  mentioned,  the  

notion   of   development   as   conceived   when   SEZs   were   introduced   thus   did   see  

development   as   first   and   foremost   economic,   and   did   not   consider   any   social   or  

environmental  aspects,  economic  growth  as  being  based  on  low  cost  labor  as  well  as  high  

energy   consumption,   and   not   implying   any   direct   social   improvement   or   responsible  

management  of  resources  whatsoever.    

 

If   a   great   number   of   SEZs   seem   to   have   moved   towards   more   technological   and  

innovation  activities,  some  others,  and  China  in  general,  still  use  low  cost  manufacturing  

strategies,  consequently  competing  at  the  "low  end  of  the  global  value  chain"  (Zeng,  p.39).  

Hence  Zeng   identifies   the   causes  of   this  difficult   transition  as  being   the   low   technology  

equipment   of   those   industrial   zones.   The   concept   of   cognitive   locks   allows   using   the  

previous   ideas   about   economic   performance   in   China   and   about   SEZs'   role   as   an  

explanation.  Indeed,  the  transition  to  high  value  added  activities  might  be  restrained  by  

the  ideas  at  the  very  root  of  China's  impressive  economic  development,  which  are  not  yet  

fully  adapted  to  the  contemporary  context.  Regarding   ideas  about  a  social  dimension  of  

growth  and  SEZs,  we  will  briefly  analyze  some  empirical  data  from  an  investigation  led  in  

2004   by   the   Hong   Kong   Christian   Industrial   Committee   (HKCIC)   which   interviewed  

Chinese   employees   working   at   some   Swedish   toy   retailers   located   in   SEZs   in   the  

Guangdong  province.  The  investigation  was  about  to  what  extent  subsidies  complied  with  

Oskar  Borup  Krabbe,  0503932687     Second  Year  Project  Emilie  Christine  Lucie  Jaillot,  0604952700        

     

36  

the   Codes   of   Conduct,   which   are   among   others   imposing   regulations   for   improved  

working   conditions.   The   results   showed   that   none   of   the   nine   suppliers   completely  

complied   with   the   regulations   on   working   time   and   minimum   wage   allowed   (Egels-­‐

Zandén,  p.51).  From  that  we  can  conclude  that  even  after  2001,  social  concerns  are  still  

not   shared   equally   among   SEZs   members   and   that   the   ideas   about   how   to   perform  

economically   rather   than   sustainably,   definitely   still   constitute   to   some   extent   active  

cognitive  locks.    

 

Ideas  as  weapons  

If   there   still   is   some   non-­‐negligible   constraints   to   SEZs   turning   entirely   towards  

sustainable  development,  we   cannot  deny   some  crucial  progress  has  been  made  and   is  

gaining  ground.  Blyth’s  concept  of  ideas  as  weapons  stresses  the  role  of  contesting  ideas,  

which  can  become  genuine  motors  for  institutional  restructuration  (Blyth,  p.4).  The  ideas  

we   judge   as   having   the   potential   to   carry   this   function,   are   about   an   evolution   in   the  

function  of  the  SEZs,  as  well  as  ideas  about  environmental  and  social  awareness.  We  will  

analyze   them  and   explain  how   they   can   induce   SEZs   to   become  vehicles   of   sustainable  

development.    

 

The  challenges  to  SEZs’  contribution  to  growth  we  identified  in  this  paper  as  being  social  

and  environmental  issues  are  gradually  becoming  advocated  for  in  China.  Because  of  the  

growing  middle  class  and  the   increasing  number  of  skilled  workers,   thoughts  about  the  

ability  to  conciliate  growth  with  higher  social  standards  are  more  frequent.  Likewise  for  

environmental   causes:   the   concern   about   environment   is   higher,   and   the   idea   that  

preserving  resources  and  fighting  environmental  degradation  has  become  a  necessity,  is  

spreading.   A   good   example   of   this   growing   awareness   is   the   creation   in   2008   of   the  

Chinese   Ministry   of   Environmental   Protection   (MEP).     Besides   that,   the   experience   of  

SEZs  in  China  in  terms  of  the  initial  objective  of  being  points  of   impulsion  for  economic  

growth  has   long  been  considered  as  a  success.  The  vision  of  SEZs  as  symbols  of  China’s  

emergence   as   a   whole   (Mohiuddin   et   al.,   p.113),   is   responsible   for   the   rise   of   a   new  

conception   about   SEZs’   utility,   which   transposes   the   traditional   role   of   SEZs   to   the  

Oskar  Borup  Krabbe,  0503932687     Second  Year  Project  Emilie  Christine  Lucie  Jaillot,  0604952700        

     

37  

contemporary  context.  As  explicated  in  the  DS  analysis,  some  argue  that  SEZs  should  be  

used   again   as   pioneer   laboratories,   but   this   time   for   policies   leading   towards   a  

sustainable   kind   of   growth,   through   empathic   social   development   and   green   policies  

(Ibid.).  To  conclude,  as  weapons,  the  trends  in  ideas  we  identified  can  certainly  shape  the  

future  direction  of  SEZs,  which  will  hopefully  include  more  dimensions  than  the  economic  

one.    

Concluding  remarks  

Through   the   application   of   the   Constructivist   approach   and   of   Blyth’s   framework   as  

developed   in   the   CPE   course,   we   have   examined   how   the   economic   ideas   behind   the  

Chinese   development   processes   and   SEZs   have   changed   over   time.   First   analyzed   as  

institutional   blueprints,   the   economic   ideas   of   1978’s   China   can  be   found   in  Xiaoping’s  

rationale  for  the  Open  Door  policy  reform  liberalizing  the  market  through  a  gradual  and  

pragmatic  opening  with  the  development  of  SEZs  as  an  industrial  policy  tool  to  act  as  its  

core  engine.   It  was  concluded  that   the   institutional  blueprints  with  their   focus  on  rapid  

growth  by  no  means  comprised   focus  on  sustainability,   since  natural  resources  seemed  

plentiful  and  there  appeared  to  be  an  almost  inexhaustible  supply  of  cheap  labor  from  the  

primary   sector   (Yeung   et   Al.,   p.224).   Those   same   ideas   about   economic   performance  

thereafter  became  cognitive  locks,  anchoring  the  concept  of  growth  in  China  and  of  SEZs  

in   the   pure   economic   dimension,   thus   ignoring   the   rising   social   and   environmental  

claims.  Finally,  some  challengers  of  the  cognitive  locks  were  identified,  embodied  in  the  

innovative  conceptions  of  a  new  role  for  SEZs,  which  would  combine  economic-­‐efficiency  

with   social-­‐efficiency   and   eco-­‐efficiency   (Mohiuddin   et   al.,   p.113).   Therefore,   the  

Constructivist  perspective  highlighted  the  responsibility  of  ideas  about  economic  reality  

in  the  setting  of  SEZs  as   just  growth  contributors,  as  well  as   their  promising  role  as   for  

restructuring  SEZs'  configuration  in  a  viable  way.  

7.  Limitations  of  the  study    First  of  all,  if  generalizing  and  gathering  all  sorts  of  SEZs  under  one  terminology  seemed  

the  most  convenient  thing  to  do  regarding  the  allowed  length  of  this  paper,  it  might  have  

Oskar  Borup  Krabbe,  0503932687     Second  Year  Project  Emilie  Christine  Lucie  Jaillot,  0604952700        

     

38  

occulted   some   important   elements   to   our   research.   Indeed,   there   is   a   ground   for   the  

existence   of   such   a   variety   of   SEZs   names;   all   those   appellations   "display   very   real  

differences   in   terms   and   function"   between   the   SEZs   (Hazakis,   p.86),   and   this  

classification   we   had   to   ignore,   if   studied,   could   have   brought   more   nuances   to   our  

analysis.   Second,  had   the  maximum  page   requirement  been  greater,   it   could  have  been  

interesting  to  analyze  the  case  of  the  Shenzhen  SEZ  in  depth  as  this   is  not  only  the  first  

zone   to   be   developed,   but   also   the   leading   one   acting   as   China’s  main   “window   to   the  

world”  and  “an  experimentation  field”  ever  since  the  Open  Door  reform  (Zeng,  p.55).  As  

Shenzhen  still   today  plays  as  an  experimental  and  modeling  role  as   it   is  considered  the  

main   frontrunner   in  developing   and  using   innovative   and   technological  methods   (Ibid.,  

p.62),   an   analysis   of   this   particular   zone   could   have   been   used   to   investigate   which  

features   the   competing  SEZs   could   adapt   to   and   refrain   from   in  order   to   stay  viable   as  

future  growth  engines.  Thirdly,  had  we  had  the  option  and  possibility  to  do  so,  the  use  of  

1!"  degree   sources   like   interviews  with  both  officials   involved  with  planning   the   future  

developments   of   SEZs,   as  well   as  with  workers   in   companies   operating   in   these   zones  

could  have  contributed  to  a  more  comprehensive  and  unbiased  analysis.  

8.  Conclusion  and  strategic  recommendations      

As  the  main  engines  behind  the  rapid  development  of  the  Chinese  economy  the  past  three  

decades,   China’s   Special   Economic   Zones   have   proven   very   successful   in   leading   the  

country   to   the   first   development   stage   with   a   focus   on   pure   economic   growth   and  

attraction  of  FDI  through  low-­‐cost  labor  and  physical  capital.  Yet  the  context  has  evolved,  

and   after   identifying   the   social   and   environmental   challenges   SEZs   are   increasingly  

facing,  it  was  concluded  that  some  features  of  SEZs’  initial  configuration  were  henceforth  

obsolete.  This  paper  aimed  to  provide  a  strategy  plan  for  SEZs  to  become  contributors  of  

a   sustainable   growth   in   an   evolving   context   by   answering   the   following   research  

question:   As   the   core   engine   for   economic   growth   and   openness   in   the   1980s,   how   can  

Chinese   SEZs   remain   a   viable   source   of   economic   growth   in   the   current   context   of  

Oskar  Borup  Krabbe,  0503932687     Second  Year  Project  Emilie  Christine  Lucie  Jaillot,  0604952700        

     

39  

sustainability   concerns   rising   from   the   environmental   degradation   and   changing   social  

structures?    

 

The   application   of   the   theoretical   frameworks   provided   by   the   Organization   Theory,  

Political   Economy   of   Development   and   Comparative   Political   Economy   courses,   all  

belonging   to   the   Constructivist   philosophical   perspective,   determined   which   elements  

and   conceptions   of   SEZs   have   the   potential   to   generate   sustainable   growth.   The  

Institutional   theory   investigated   the   nature   and   interest   of   the   different   pressures  

exerted   on   SEZs   as   organizations,   highlighting   which   ones   SEZs   should   conform   to   in  

order   to   ensure   their  own  survival   and  active   role   in   creating  viable  development.  The  

coercive  and  normative  pressures  conveying  social  and  environmental   concerns  should  

be   prioritized,   contrary   to   those   only   centered   on   economic   performance;   while   the  

effects  of  the  mimetic  pressures  could  be  exploited  in  a  positive  way,  if  some  incentive  is  

created   for   some   SEZs   to   be   the   first   ones   leading   the  way,   ultimately   accelerating   the  

transition  to  sustainable  growth  and  making  it  more  efficient.    

 

By   applying   the   Developmental   State   and   Neo-­‐liberal   theory   we   analyzed   how   the  

Chinese   government   have   been   using   interventionist   industrial   policies   to   open   their  

economy   gradually   and   used   SEZs   as   testing   labs   to   experiment   with   economic   and  

political   reforms   and   let   them   spill   over   to   the   rest   of   the   society   if   proven   successful.  

Having  identified  how  China  is   faced  with  emerging  social  and  environmental  concerns,  

we   reached   the   conclusion   that   the   state   should   not   abolish   its   interventionist  

instruments  and  completely  open  up  to  Neo-­‐liberal  market  forces,  but  instead  once  again  

use  the  SEZs  actively  as  dynamic  experimental  grounds  to   test  new  policies   to   fight   the  

increasing   social   and   environmental   pressures   encompassing   the   emergence   towards  

entering  the  second  and  third  stage  of  development  introduced.    

 

Finally,   Blyth’s   framework   of   ideas   as   institutional   blueprints,   cognitive   locks   and  

weapons   allowed  a   study  of   the   evolution  of   the   ideas   about   economic   reality   in  China  

and  about  SEZs’  objectives  in  between  1978,  the  institution  of  the  Open  Door  Reform,  and  

Oskar  Borup  Krabbe,  0503932687     Second  Year  Project  Emilie  Christine  Lucie  Jaillot,  0604952700        

     

40  

2001,   China’s   accession   to   the  WTO.  This   analysis   stressed   the   link  between   the   initial  

ideas  about  how  to  pursue  economic  development  and  the  configuration  of  SEZs  that   is  

not  taking  into  account  any  social  or  environmental  dimension.  Although  these  economic  

ideas  prevailed  for  some  time,  leading  to  institutional  path  dependence  and  in  some  cases  

to  race-­‐to-­‐the-­‐bottom  effects,  they  were  eventually  challenged  by  new  emerging  notions  

advocating   a   renewed   role   for   the   SEZs,   which   would   still   consist   to   create   economic  

growth  while  including  social  and  environmental  improvement  goals.    

 

Summing  up,  our  line  of  argument  have  led  us  to  the  conclusion  that  in  order  for  them  to  

remain  viable  vectors  for  development,  SEZs  have  to  adapt  faster  and  more  efficiently  to  

the  evolving  social  and  environmental  challenges.  This  should  be  done  by   following  the  

next   recommendations.   Firstly,   exploiting   the   potential   of   the   special   status   of   SEZs   to  

once   again   use   them   as   testing   labs   for   policy   implementations   seems   promising.  

Secondly,  in  order  to  remain  updated  and  in  phase  with  the  next  stages  of  development,  

policy  makers  should  adopt  a  more  market  dynamic  state  intervention  by  listening  to  the  

various  pressures   exerted  on   the   SEZs.   Finally,   in   a  more  general  manner,   SEZs   should  

reorient  their  activities  towards  human  capital,   innovation  and  green  technology,  which  

could   be   a   great   way   to   conciliate   economic   growth   creation   while   simultaneously  

responding  to  the  concerns  related  to  environmental  and  social  challenges.  

 

Oskar  Borup  Krabbe,  0503932687     Second  Year  Project  Emilie  Christine  Lucie  Jaillot,  0604952700        

     

41  

9.  Bibliography    

9.1.  Books  

Baek,  Seung-­‐Wook.  “Does  China  Follow  ‘the  East  Asian  Development  Model’?”  Journal  of  Contemporary  Asia  2005:  485–498.  Web.  

Beeson,  Mark.  “The  Rise  and  Fall  (?)  of  the  Developmental  State:  The  Vicissitudes  and  Implications  of  East  Asian  Interventionism.”  Developmental  States:  Relevancy,  Redundancy  or  …  1979  (2004):  29–40.  Web.  

Blyth,  Mark.  “The  Transformation  of  the  Swedish  Model:  Economic  Ideas,  Distributional  Conflict,  and  Institutional  Change.”  World  Politics  2001:  1–26.  Web.  

Bolesta,  Andrzej.  “China  as  a  Developmental  State.”  Montenegrin  Journal  of  Economics  (2007):  n.  pag.  Web.  

-­‐-­‐-­‐.  “China  as  a  Post-­‐Socialist  Developmental  State:  Explaining  Chinese  Development  Trajectory.”  The  London  School  of  Economics  and  Political  Science,  2012.  Print.  

Breslin,  Shaun  Gerard.  China  in  the  1980s:  Centre-­‐Province  Relations  in  a  Reforming  Socialist  State.  Palgrave  Macmillan,  1996.  Print.  

Brundtland  Comission.  “World  Commission  on  Environment  and  Development.”  Our  common  future  1987:  8–9.  Web.  

Cai,  Fang,  and  Yang  Du.  “Wage  Increases,  Wage  Convergence,  and  the  Lewis  Turning  Point  in  China.”  China  Economic  Review  22.4  (2011):  601–610.  Web.  

Campbell,  John  L.  “Institutional  Analysis  and  the  Role  of  Ideas  in  Political  Economy.”  Theory  and  Society  27.3  (1998):  377–409.  Web.  

Carter,  Connie,  and  Andrew  Harding.  Special  Economic  Zones  in  Asian  Market  Economies.  Routledge  Studies  in  the  Growth  Economies  of  Asia,  2010.  Print.  

Chang,  Dae-­‐oup.  “The  Neoliberal  Rise  of  East  Asia  and  Social  Movements  of  Labour :  Four  Moments  and  a  Challenge.”  4.November  (2012):  22–51.  Print.  

Chen,  Tracy,  and  Francis  A.  Scotland.  “Cross  the  River  by  Touching  the  Stones.”  Brandywine  Global  Investment  Management,  LLC  Tropical  Insight  May  (2013):  1–8.  Print.  

Corrales,  Javier.  “Neoliberalism  and  Its  Alternatives.”  Handbook  of  Latin  American  Politics  13859  (2010):  1–43.  Web.  

DiMaggio,  P,  and  W  Powell.  “The  Iron  Cage  Revisited.”  American  Sociological  Review  48  (1983):  147–160.  Web.  

Dirlik,  Arif.  Culture  &  History  in  Post-­‐Revolutionary  China:  The  Perspective  of  Global  Modernity.  The  Chinese  University  Press,  2012.  Print.  

Oskar  Borup  Krabbe,  0503932687     Second  Year  Project  Emilie  Christine  Lucie  Jaillot,  0604952700        

     

42  

Egels-­‐Zandén,  Niklas.  “Suppliers’  Compliance  with  MNCs'  Codes  of  Conduct:  Behind  the  Scenes  at  Chinese  Toy  Suppliers.”  Journal  of  Business  Ethics  75.1  (2007):  45–62.  Web.  

Evans,  Peter.  “Transferable  Lessons?  Re-­‐examining  the  Institutional  Prerequisites  of  East  Asian  Economic  Policies.”  Journal  of  Development  Studies  1998:  66–86.  Web.  

Farole,  Thomas.  “Special  Economic  Zones:  What  Have  We  Learned?”  Economic  Premise  September.64  (2011):  1–5.  Print.  

FIAS  World  Bank.  Special  Economic  Zones:  Performance,  Lessons  Learned,  and  Implications  for  Zone  Development.  World  Bank  Group,  2008.  Print.  

Friedman,  Edward,  and  Bruce  Gilley.  Asia’s  Giants,  Comparing  China  and  India.  Palgrave  Macmillan,  2005.  Print.  

Gilpin,  Robert.  “The  State  and  Economic  Development.”  Global  Political  Economy.  Princeton:  Princeton  University  Press,  2001.  305–321.  Print.  

Gray,  Kevin,  and  Youngseok  Jang.  “Labour  Unrest  in  the  Global  Political  Economy:  The  Case  of  China’s  2010  Strike  Wave.”  New  Political  Economy  May  2015  (2014):  1–20.  Web.  

Grivoyannis,  E,  and  Palgrave  Macmillan.  The  New  Chinese  Economy.  N.p.,  2012.  Web.  

Hatch,  Mary  Jo;  Cunliffe,  A.L.  Organization  Theory.  Modern,  Symbolic,  and  Postmodern  Perspectives.  N.p.,  2013.  Web.  

Hayashi,  Shigeko.  “The  Developmental  State  in  the  Era  of  Globalization:  Beyond  the  Northeast  Asian  Model  of  Political  Economy.”  The  Pacific  Review  2010:  45–69.  Web.  

Hazakis,  Konstantinos  J.  “The  Rationale  of  Special  Economic  Zones  (SEZs):  An  Institutional  Approach.”  Regional  Science  Policy  &  Practice  6.1  (2014):  85–101.  Web.  

Howell,  Jude.  “Reflections  on  the  Chinese  State.”  Development  and  Change  37.2  (2006):  273–297.  Web.  

Krusekopf,  Charles.  “SEZs  and  Improved  Environmental  Management  Krusekopf.”  China  Economic  Review  13.  N.p.,  2002.  297–312.  Print.  

Leftwich,  Adrian.  “Bringing  Politics  Back  in:  Towards  a  Model  of  the  Developmental  State.”  Journal  of  Development  Studies  1995:  400–427.  Web.  

Lightelm,  a  a,  and  a  Wilsenach.  “Special  Economic  Zones  as  an  Instrument  to  Stimulate  Export  Production  and  Economic  Growth  within  South  Africa.”  Development  Southern  Africa  9.4  (1992):  397–410.  Web.  

Lin,  Chu.  The  Transformation  of  Chinese  Socialism.  Duke  University  Press,  2006.  Print.  

Mohiuddin,  Muhammad  et  al.  “The  Special  Economic  Zone  as  a  Locomotive  for  Green  Development  in  China.”  Asian  Social  Science  10.18  (2014):  109–121.  Web.  

Moses,  Jonathon  W.,  and  Torbjørn  L.  Knutsen.  Ways  of  Knowing:  Competing  Methodologies  in  Social  and  Political  Research.  2nd  ed.  Palgrave  Macmillan,  2012.  Print.  

Oskar  Borup  Krabbe,  0503932687     Second  Year  Project  Emilie  Christine  Lucie  Jaillot,  0604952700        

     

43  

Nee,  Victor,  Sonja  Opper,  and  Sonia  Wong.  “Developmental  State  and  Corporate  Governance  in  China.”  Management  and  Organization  Review  3.1  (2007):  19–53.  Web.  

Ngai,  Pun.  “Women  Workers  and  Precarious  Employment  in  Shenzhen  Special  Economic  Zone,  China.”  Gender  &  Development  12.2  (2004):  29–36.  Web.  

Office  of  the  World  Health  Organization  Representative  in  China.  “China:  Health,  Poverty  and  Economic  Development.”  Beijing:  World  Health  Organization;  (2005):  n.  pag.  Web.  

Popper,  K.  R.  The  Logic  of  Scientific  Discovery  (Routledge  Classics).  N.p.,  1959.  Print.  

Skocpol,  Theda.  States  and  Social  Revolutions.  Cambridge  University  Press,  1979.  Print.  

Song,  Ligang,  and  Yongsheng  Zhang.  “Will  Chinese  Growth  Slow  after  the  Lewis  Turning  Point?”  China  Economic  Journal  3.2  (2010):  209–219.  Web.  

Tisdell,  Clem.  Thirty  Years  of  Economic  Reform  and  Openness  in  China:  Retrospect  and  Prospect.  N.p.,  2008.  Print.  ECONOMIC  THEORY  APPLICATIONS  AND  ISSUES.  

White,  Gordon.  Developmental  States  in  East  Asia.  Palgrave  Macmillan,  1988.  Web.  

World  Bank.  World  Development  Indicators.  N.p.,  2008.  Web.  

World  Bank  Office  Beijing.  COST  OF  POLLUTION  IN  CHINA:  Economic  Estimates  of  Physical  Damages.  N.p.,  2007.  Print.  

Wuwei,  Li,  and  Michael  Keane.  How  Creativity  Is  Changing  China.  Bloomsbury  Academic,  2011.  Print.  

Xu,  Xianxiang,  and  Xiaofei  Chen.  “SEZs:  The  Starting  Point  of  Progressive  Revolution  and  Opening  of  China.”  World  Economic  Papers  (2008):  14–26.  Print.  

Yeung,  Yue-­‐man,  Joanna  Lee,  and  Gordon  Kee.  “China’s  Special  Economic  Zones  at  30.”  Eurasian  Geography  and  Economics  2009:  222–240.  Web.  

Zeng,  Douglas  Zhihua.  Building  Engines  for  Growth  and  Competitiveness  in  China:  Experience  with  Special  Economic  Zones  and  Industrial  Clusters.  Vol.  45.  N.p.,  2011.  Web.  

Zhao,  Litao,  and  Peilin  Li.  China’s  Social  Development  and  Policy  Into  the  next  Stage?  Routledge,  2013.  Print.  

Zhao,  Shuming.  “Application  of  Human  Capital  Theory  in  China  in  the  Context  of  the  Knowledge  Economy.”  The  International  Journal  of  Human  Resource  Management  19.5  (2008):  802–817.  Web.  

         

Oskar  Borup  Krabbe,  0503932687     Second  Year  Project  Emilie  Christine  Lucie  Jaillot,  0604952700        

     

44  

9.2.  Webpages  Daily   Mail.   (2014)   Article   [America   usurped:   China   becomes   world's   largest   economy   -­‐   putting   USA   in  second  place  for  the  first  time  in  142  years].  

Retrieved  from  http://www.dailymail.co.uk/news/article-­‐2785905/China-­‐overtakes-­‐U-­‐S-­‐world-­‐s-­‐largest-­‐economy-­‐IMF-­‐says-­‐economy-­‐worth-­‐17-­‐6trillion-­‐America-­‐falls-­‐second-­‐place-­‐time-­‐1872.html.  Accessed  May  9th  2015.  

 Forbes.  (2014)  Forbes  Business  Column.  [Electrify  Africa  and  Save  Hundreds  of  Millions  of  Lives].       Retrieved  from       http://www.forbes.com/sites/judeclemente/2014/06/29/electrify-­‐africa-­‐and-­‐save-­‐hundreds-­‐of-­‐

millions-­‐of-­‐lives/.  Accessed  May  11th  2015.    People’s   Daily.   (2010)   Article.   [Visiting   professor:   After   30   years,   China's   SEZs   ready   for   new   role].  

Retrieved  from    http://en.people.cn/90001/90780/91344/7138679.html.  Accessed  May  22nd  2015.  

 World  Bank.  (2015).  World  databank.  [GDP  growth  (annual  %)].    

Retrieved  from    http://data.worldbank.org/indicator/NY.GDP.MKTP.KD.ZG.  Accessed  May  11th  2015.    

 World  Bank.  (2001).  DEPweb.  [What  is  Sustainable  Development].  

Retrieved  from  http://www.worldbank.org/depweb/english/sd.html.  Accessed  May  14th  2015.          

Oskar  Borup  Krabbe,  0503932687     Second  Year  Project  Emilie  Christine  Lucie  Jaillot,  0604952700        

     

45  

Appendix  I    

   Source:  International  Monetary  Fund  in  Duncan  Hugo,  and  Martosko  David,  October  9th  2014:  America   usurped:   China   becomes  world's   largest   economy   -­‐   putting  USA   in   second  place  for  the  first  time  in  142  years  http://www.dailymail.co.uk/news/article-­‐2785905/China-­‐overtakes-­‐U-­‐S-­‐world-­‐s-­‐largest-­‐economy-­‐IMF-­‐says-­‐economy-­‐worth-­‐17-­‐6trillion-­‐America-­‐falls-­‐second-­‐place-­‐time-­‐1872.html                            

Oskar  Borup  Krabbe,  0503932687     Second  Year  Project  Emilie  Christine  Lucie  Jaillot,  0604952700        

     

46  

Appendix  II      

China's  GDP  growth  (annual  %)  between  2005  and  2013    Note  from  the  source:  GDP  growth  (annual  %):  Annual  percentage  growth  rate  of  GDP  at  market  prices  based  on  constant  local  currency.  Aggregates  are  based  on  constant  2005  U.S  dollars.  GDP  is  the  sum  of  gross  value  added  by  all  resident  producers  in  the  economy  plus  any  product  taxes  and  minus  any  subsidies  not  included  in  the  value  of  the  products.  It   is   calculated  without  making   deductions   for   depreciation   of   fabricated   assets   or   for  depletion  and  degradation  of  natural  resources.    Source:  World  Bank  national  accounts  data,  and  OECD  National  Accounts  data  files,  http://data.worldbank.org/indicator/NY.GDP.MKTP.KD.ZG/countries/CN?display=graph