The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see...

124
The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis Mahias Doepke 1 Moshe Hazan 2 Yishay Maoz 3 1 Northwestern University, NBER and CEPR 2 Tel-Aviv University and CEPR 3 Open University February 2015 Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 1 / 46

Transcript of The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see...

Page 1: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic

Analysis

Ma�hias Doepke1 Moshe Hazan2 Yishay Maoz3

1Northwestern University, NBER and CEPR

2Tel-Aviv University and CEPR

3Open University

February 2015

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 1 / 46

Page 2: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Introduction

Total Fertility Rate in the U.S.

3.5

4

2.5

3

Fer

tili

ty R

ate

1.5

2To

tal

F

1

1910 1915 1920 1925 1930 1935 1940 1945 1950 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980

Calendar Year

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 2 / 46

Page 3: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Introduction

Completed Fertility Rate in the U.S.

1.8

2.0

2.2

2.4

2.6

2.8

3.0

3.2

1910 1920 1930 1940 1950

CompletedFertility

Rate

Year of Birth

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 3 / 46

Page 4: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Introduction

The Traditional View Versus Our View

Traditional view: the baby boom is too big and lasts too long to be

explained by the war.

This argument applies only to “catch up” fertility.

Our view: the war ma�ered because it resulted in a large, temporary

demand shock for female labor.

This shock had an asymmetric e�ect on older and younger women.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 4 / 46

Page 5: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Introduction

The Traditional View Versus Our View

Traditional view: the baby boom is too big and lasts too long to be

explained by the war.

This argument applies only to “catch up” fertility.

Our view: the war ma�ered because it resulted in a large, temporary

demand shock for female labor.

This shock had an asymmetric e�ect on older and younger women.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 4 / 46

Page 6: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Introduction

The Traditional View Versus Our View

Traditional view: the baby boom is too big and lasts too long to be

explained by the war.

This argument applies only to “catch up” fertility.

Our view: the war ma�ered because it resulted in a large, temporary

demand shock for female labor.

This shock had an asymmetric e�ect on older and younger women.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 4 / 46

Page 7: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Introduction

The Traditional View Versus Our View

Traditional view: the baby boom is too big and lasts too long to be

explained by the war.

This argument applies only to “catch up” fertility.

Our view: the war ma�ered because it resulted in a large, temporary

demand shock for female labor.

This shock had an asymmetric e�ect on older and younger women.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 4 / 46

Page 8: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Introduction

The Mechanism

World War II draws women into the labor market. The war generation

accumulates labor market experience.

A�er the war men return but many war-generation women stay at

work, raising female labor force participation.

Higher e�ective labor supply induces young women to leave the labor

market at a younger age and to have children instead.

Crowding-out e�ect reverses when war generation retires from the

labor market.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 5 / 46

Page 9: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Introduction

The Mechanism

World War II draws women into the labor market. The war generation

accumulates labor market experience.

A�er the war men return but many war-generation women stay at

work, raising female labor force participation.

Higher e�ective labor supply induces young women to leave the labor

market at a younger age and to have children instead.

Crowding-out e�ect reverses when war generation retires from the

labor market.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 5 / 46

Page 10: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Introduction

The Mechanism

World War II draws women into the labor market. The war generation

accumulates labor market experience.

A�er the war men return but many war-generation women stay at

work, raising female labor force participation.

Higher e�ective labor supply induces young women to leave the labor

market at a younger age and to have children instead.

Crowding-out e�ect reverses when war generation retires from the

labor market.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 5 / 46

Page 11: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Introduction

The Mechanism

World War II draws women into the labor market. The war generation

accumulates labor market experience.

A�er the war men return but many war-generation women stay at

work, raising female labor force participation.

Higher e�ective labor supply induces young women to leave the labor

market at a younger age and to have children instead.

Crowding-out e�ect reverses when war generation retires from the

labor market.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 5 / 46

Page 12: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Introduction

Labor Supply of Young and Old Women in the U.S.

0.4

0.45

0.5

0.55

0.6

Lab

or

Su

pp

ly

Women 20-32

0.2

0.25

0.3

0.35

1940 1950 1960 1970 1980

Lab

or

Su

pp

ly

Women 33-60

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 6 / 46

Page 13: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Introduction

Ratio of Female to Male Average Wages, Singles 20-24

��

��

��

��

��

���

���� ���� ���� ����

����������

�����

���

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 7 / 46

Page 14: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Introduction

Age Specific Fertility Rates in the U.S.

150

200

250

300

Bir

th R

ate

Women 15-19

Women 20-24

Women 25-29

0

50

100

1940 1950 1960 1970 1980

Bir

th R

ate

Women 30-34

Women 35-39

Women 40-44

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 8 / 46

Page 15: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Introduction

Road Map

1 Existing theories of the baby boom.

2 Cross state evidence from the United-States.

3 Model.

4 World War II and the Baby Boom –�antitative Analysis.

5 International Evidence.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 9 / 46

Page 16: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Introduction

Road Map

1 Existing theories of the baby boom.

2 Cross state evidence from the United-States.

3 Model.

4 World War II and the Baby Boom –�antitative Analysis.

5 International Evidence.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 9 / 46

Page 17: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Introduction

Road Map

1 Existing theories of the baby boom.

2 Cross state evidence from the United-States.

3 Model.

4 World War II and the Baby Boom –�antitative Analysis.

5 International Evidence.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 9 / 46

Page 18: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Introduction

Road Map

1 Existing theories of the baby boom.

2 Cross state evidence from the United-States.

3 Model.

4 World War II and the Baby Boom –�antitative Analysis.

5 International Evidence.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 9 / 46

Page 19: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Introduction

Road Map

1 Existing theories of the baby boom.

2 Cross state evidence from the United-States.

3 Model.

4 World War II and the Baby Boom –�antitative Analysis.

5 International Evidence.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 9 / 46

Page 20: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Literature

Existing Theories

Easterlin (1961), “the relative income hypothesis.”

Greenwood, Seshadri, Vandenbroucke (2005), “the household

technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011))

Albanesi and Olive�i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Zhao (2014), “The fiscal burden of WW II”

Non of these explain why fertility increased mainly among youngwomen:

The increase in fertility among the 20-24 yrs old accounts for more than40 percent of the rise in fertility.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 10 / 46

Page 21: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Literature

Existing Theories

Easterlin (1961), “the relative income hypothesis.”

Greenwood, Seshadri, Vandenbroucke (2005), “the household

technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011))

Albanesi and Olive�i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Zhao (2014), “The fiscal burden of WW II”

Non of these explain why fertility increased mainly among youngwomen:

The increase in fertility among the 20-24 yrs old accounts for more than40 percent of the rise in fertility.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 10 / 46

Page 22: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Literature

Existing Theories

Easterlin (1961), “the relative income hypothesis.”

Greenwood, Seshadri, Vandenbroucke (2005), “the household

technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011))

Albanesi and Olive�i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Zhao (2014), “The fiscal burden of WW II”

Non of these explain why fertility increased mainly among youngwomen:

The increase in fertility among the 20-24 yrs old accounts for more than40 percent of the rise in fertility.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 10 / 46

Page 23: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Literature

Existing Theories

Easterlin (1961), “the relative income hypothesis.”

Greenwood, Seshadri, Vandenbroucke (2005), “the household

technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011))

Albanesi and Olive�i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Zhao (2014), “The fiscal burden of WW II”

Non of these explain why fertility increased mainly among youngwomen:

The increase in fertility among the 20-24 yrs old accounts for more than40 percent of the rise in fertility.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 10 / 46

Page 24: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Literature

Existing Theories

Easterlin (1961), “the relative income hypothesis.”

Greenwood, Seshadri, Vandenbroucke (2005), “the household

technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011))

Albanesi and Olive�i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Zhao (2014), “The fiscal burden of WW II”

Non of these explain why fertility increased mainly among youngwomen:

The increase in fertility among the 20-24 yrs old accounts for more than40 percent of the rise in fertility.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 10 / 46

Page 25: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Literature

Existing Theories

Easterlin (1961), “the relative income hypothesis.”

Greenwood, Seshadri, Vandenbroucke (2005), “the household

technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011))

Albanesi and Olive�i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Zhao (2014), “The fiscal burden of WW II”

Non of these explain why fertility increased mainly among youngwomen:

The increase in fertility among the 20-24 yrs old accounts for more than40 percent of the rise in fertility.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 10 / 46

Page 26: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Cross-State Evidence from the U.S. Data and Empirical Strategy

Cross-State Evidence from the United-States

Pooled census data for 1940 and 1960.

Use the variation in mobilization rate of men to WW II across U.S.

states as in Acemoglu, Autor and Lyle (2004).

Assess the e�ect of WW II on relevant outcomes using a di�erence in

di�erence strategy.

yist = λs + d1960 +X ′istω + µd1960ms + ǫist.

Relevant outcomes, yist:

Fertility and marriage rate among young women.

Labor supply among young and old women.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 11 / 46

Page 27: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Cross-State Evidence from the U.S. Data and Empirical Strategy

Cross-State Evidence from the United-States

Pooled census data for 1940 and 1960.

Use the variation in mobilization rate of men to WW II across U.S.

states as in Acemoglu, Autor and Lyle (2004).

Assess the e�ect of WW II on relevant outcomes using a di�erence in

di�erence strategy.

yist = λs + d1960 +X ′istω + µd1960ms + ǫist.

Relevant outcomes, yist:

Fertility and marriage rate among young women.

Labor supply among young and old women.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 11 / 46

Page 28: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Cross-State Evidence from the U.S. Data and Empirical Strategy

Cross-State Evidence from the United-States

Pooled census data for 1940 and 1960.

Use the variation in mobilization rate of men to WW II across U.S.

states as in Acemoglu, Autor and Lyle (2004).

Assess the e�ect of WW II on relevant outcomes using a di�erence in

di�erence strategy.

yist = λs + d1960 +X ′istω + µd1960ms + ǫist.

Relevant outcomes, yist:

Fertility and marriage rate among young women.

Labor supply among young and old women.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 11 / 46

Page 29: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Cross-State Evidence from the U.S. Data and Empirical Strategy

Cross-State Evidence from the United-States

Pooled census data for 1940 and 1960.

Use the variation in mobilization rate of men to WW II across U.S.

states as in Acemoglu, Autor and Lyle (2004).

Assess the e�ect of WW II on relevant outcomes using a di�erence in

di�erence strategy.

yist = λs + d1960 +X ′istω + µd1960ms + ǫist.

Relevant outcomes, yist:

Fertility and marriage rate among young women.

Labor supply among young and old women.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 11 / 46

Page 30: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Cross-State Evidence from the U.S. Data and Empirical Strategy

Cross-State Evidence from the United-States

Pooled census data for 1940 and 1960.

Use the variation in mobilization rate of men to WW II across U.S.

states as in Acemoglu, Autor and Lyle (2004).

Assess the e�ect of WW II on relevant outcomes using a di�erence in

di�erence strategy.

yist = λs + d1960 +X ′istω + µd1960ms + ǫist.

Relevant outcomes, yist:

Fertility and marriage rate among young women.

Labor supply among young and old women.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 11 / 46

Page 31: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Cross-State Evidence from the U.S. Data and Empirical Strategy

Cross-State Evidence from the United-States

Pooled census data for 1940 and 1960.

Use the variation in mobilization rate of men to WW II across U.S.

states as in Acemoglu, Autor and Lyle (2004).

Assess the e�ect of WW II on relevant outcomes using a di�erence in

di�erence strategy.

yist = λs + d1960 +X ′istω + µd1960ms + ǫist.

Relevant outcomes, yist:

Fertility and marriage rate among young women.

Labor supply among young and old women.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 11 / 46

Page 32: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Cross-State Evidence from the U.S. Data and Empirical Strategy

Cross-State Evidence from the United-States

Pooled census data for 1940 and 1960.

Use the variation in mobilization rate of men to WW II across U.S.

states as in Acemoglu, Autor and Lyle (2004).

Assess the e�ect of WW II on relevant outcomes using a di�erence in

di�erence strategy.

yist = λs + d1960 +X ′istω + µd1960ms + ǫist.

Relevant outcomes, yist:

Fertility and marriage rate among young women.

Labor supply among young and old women.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 11 / 46

Page 33: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Cross-State Evidence from the U.S. Data and Empirical Strategy

Summary Statistics

Variable Age 25–35 Age 25–29 Age 30–35 Age 45–551940 1960 1940 1960 1940 1960 1940 1960

# kids≤ 5 0.48 0.87 0.55 1.10 0.42 0.70(0.75) (0.96) (0.78) (1.02) (0.71) (0.88)

# kids Ever Born 1.68 2.43 1.47 2.25 1.86 2.55(1.56) (1.54) (1.45) (1.46) (1.62) (1.59)

Ever Married 0.83 0.92 0.79 0.90 0.87 0.94(0.38) (0.27) (0.41) (0.30) (0.34) (0.24)

Employed 0.30 0.33 0.32 0.32 0.28 0.34 0.20 0.45(0.46) (0.47) (0.47) (0.47) (0.45) (0.47) (0.40) (0.50)

Weeks Worked 15.5 15.3 16.4 15.4 14.5 15.2 11.0 20.6(22.5) (20.9) (22.8) (20.7) (22.2) (21.0) (20.3) (22.8)

mean s.d. min max

Mobilization rate 0.474 0.034 0.412 0.545

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 12 / 46

Page 34: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Cross-State Evidence from the U.S. Data and Empirical Strategy

Correlation between WWII Mobilization Rates, Fertility &

Marriage Rates

CT ME MA

NH

RI

VTDE

NJNY

PAILINMI OH

WIIA

KSMN

MONESD

VA

AL

AR FLGA LA

MS

NC

SC TXKY MD OKTN WV

AZ

COID

MT

NVNM UTWY

CAOR

WA

0.150.050.050.150.250.350.450.55

0.4 0.45 0.5 0.55

Diff.Fertility

19301940

Mobilization Rate

CT

ME

MANH

RIVTDE

NJNYPA

ILIN

MIOHWI

IA KS

MN

MO NENSSD

VAALAR

FLGA

LA

MS

NC

SC

TX

KY

MD

OKTN

WV

AZ

CO

ID

MT

NV

NM

UTWY

CAOR

WA

0.150.050.050.150.250.350.450.55

0.4 0.45 0.5 0.55

Diff.Fertility

1940

1960

Mobilization Rate

CTME MA

NH

RI

VTDE

NJNY PAIL

INMI OHWI IA KS

MN

MONENS

SD VAALAR

FL

GALA

MSNCSC TXKY MD

OKTN

WV

AZ

COID

MT

NVNMUT

WY

CAOR

WA

0.05

0

0.05

0.1

0.15

0.2

0.4 0.45 0.5 0.55Diff.Marriage19301940

Mobilization Rate

CTME

MA

NH RIVTDE

NJNY

PAILINMI OHWI IA KS

MN

MONE

NS

SD

VA

ALAR

FL

GA

LA

MS

NCSC TXKY

MD

OKTN WV AZ

CO

IDMT

NV

NMUTWY

CA

OR

WA

0.05

0

0.05

0.1

0.15

0.2

0.4 0.45 0.5 0.55Diff.Marriage19401960

Mobilization Rate

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 13 / 46

Page 35: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Cross-State Evidence from the U.S. Results

Impact of WWII Mobilization Rates on Fertility and

Marital Status – Women age 25-35

Dependent variable (1) (2) (3)

Age 25-35 (N = 225,613)

# kids≤ 5 1.403 0.953 0.855

(0.257) (0.237) (0.211)

# kids Ever Born 2.032 0.818 0.825

(0.717) (0.543) (0.543)

Married 0.474 0.488

(0.118) (0.119)

educ & farm status no yes yes

marital status no no yes

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 14 / 46

Page 36: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Cross-State Evidence from the U.S. Results

Impact of WWII Mobilization Rates on Female Labor

Supply – Women age 25-35

Dependent variable (1) (2) (3)

Age 25-35 (N = 225,613)

Employed -0.944 -0.608 -0.385

(0.157) (0.137) (0.098)

Weeks worked -33.358 -23.173 -12.904

(7.903) (7.065) (5.179)

educ & farm status no yes yes

marital status no no yes

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 15 / 46

Page 37: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Cross-State Evidence from the U.S. Results

Impact of WWII Mobilization Rates on Female Labor

Supply – Women age 45-55

Dependent variable (1) (2) (3)

Age 45-55 (N = 164,408)

Employed 0.078 0.231 0.227

(0.082) (0.084) (0.074)

Weeks worked 16.682 18.390 18.143

(3.389) (3.375) (3.735)

educ & farm status no yes yes

marital status no no yes

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 16 / 46

Page 38: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Cross-State Evidence from the U.S. Results

Robustness of Empirical Results

Results are robust to:

Spli�ing the young to 25-29; 30-35.

Assigning mobilization rates by state of residence

Using sample of women who live in the same state in the 5 yrs precedingthe census

Estimating Ordered Probit/Poisson/Negative Binomial models for thefertility outcomes.

Estimating Probit models for Employed and Married.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 17 / 46

Page 39: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Cross-State Evidence from the U.S. Results

Robustness of Empirical Results

Results are robust to:

Spli�ing the young to 25-29; 30-35.

Assigning mobilization rates by state of residence

Using sample of women who live in the same state in the 5 yrs precedingthe census

Estimating Ordered Probit/Poisson/Negative Binomial models for thefertility outcomes.

Estimating Probit models for Employed and Married.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 17 / 46

Page 40: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Cross-State Evidence from the U.S. Results

Robustness of Empirical Results

Results are robust to:

Spli�ing the young to 25-29; 30-35.

Assigning mobilization rates by state of residence

Using sample of women who live in the same state in the 5 yrs precedingthe census

Estimating Ordered Probit/Poisson/Negative Binomial models for thefertility outcomes.

Estimating Probit models for Employed and Married.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 17 / 46

Page 41: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Cross-State Evidence from the U.S. Results

Robustness of Empirical Results

Results are robust to:

Spli�ing the young to 25-29; 30-35.

Assigning mobilization rates by state of residence

Using sample of women who live in the same state in the 5 yrs precedingthe census

Estimating Ordered Probit/Poisson/Negative Binomial models for thefertility outcomes.

Estimating Probit models for Employed and Married.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 17 / 46

Page 42: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Cross-State Evidence from the U.S. Results

Robustness of Empirical Results

Results are robust to:

Spli�ing the young to 25-29; 30-35.

Assigning mobilization rates by state of residence

Using sample of women who live in the same state in the 5 yrs precedingthe census

Estimating Ordered Probit/Poisson/Negative Binomial models for thefertility outcomes.

Estimating Probit models for Employed and Married.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 17 / 46

Page 43: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Cross-State Evidence from the U.S. Results

Robustness of Empirical Results

Results are robust to:

Spli�ing the young to 25-29; 30-35.

Assigning mobilization rates by state of residence

Using sample of women who live in the same state in the 5 yrs precedingthe census

Estimating Ordered Probit/Poisson/Negative Binomial models for thefertility outcomes.

Estimating Probit models for Employed and Married.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 17 / 46

Page 44: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Model

The Model

A version of the neoclassical growth model enriched along threedimensions:

1 Married couple life-cycle decisions on fertility and female labor supply.

2 The production technology features limited substitutability betweenwomen and men.

3 Government that purchases goods, employs soldiers, levies taxes andissues debt.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 18 / 46

Page 45: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Model

The Model

A version of the neoclassical growth model enriched along threedimensions:

1 Married couple life-cycle decisions on fertility and female labor supply.

2 The production technology features limited substitutability betweenwomen and men.

3 Government that purchases goods, employs soldiers, levies taxes andissues debt.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 18 / 46

Page 46: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Model

The Model

A version of the neoclassical growth model enriched along threedimensions:

1 Married couple life-cycle decisions on fertility and female labor supply.

2 The production technology features limited substitutability betweenwomen and men.

3 Government that purchases goods, employs soldiers, levies taxes andissues debt.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 18 / 46

Page 47: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Model

The Model

A version of the neoclassical growth model enriched along threedimensions:

1 Married couple life-cycle decisions on fertility and female labor supply.

2 The production technology features limited substitutability betweenwomen and men.

3 Government that purchases goods, employs soldiers, levies taxes andissues debt.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 18 / 46

Page 48: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Model Households

The Model

Overlapping generations of households consisting of a man and a

woman.

Period corresponds to 2.5 years. People turn adult at age 20, retire at

60, and live until age 70.

Women can have one child per period from age 20 until age 37.5.

Fertility is stochastic: Prob of conceiving =1 if age ≤ 32.5; Prob < 1 if age

> 32.5.

When not having a birth, women decide whether to participate in the

labor market.

Endogenous accumulation of experience.

Men supply labor inelastically.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 19 / 46

Page 49: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Model Households

The Model

Overlapping generations of households consisting of a man and a

woman.

Period corresponds to 2.5 years. People turn adult at age 20, retire at

60, and live until age 70.

Women can have one child per period from age 20 until age 37.5.

Fertility is stochastic: Prob of conceiving =1 if age ≤ 32.5; Prob < 1 if age

> 32.5.

When not having a birth, women decide whether to participate in the

labor market.

Endogenous accumulation of experience.

Men supply labor inelastically.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 19 / 46

Page 50: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Model Households

The Model

Overlapping generations of households consisting of a man and a

woman.

Period corresponds to 2.5 years. People turn adult at age 20, retire at

60, and live until age 70.

Women can have one child per period from age 20 until age 37.5.

Fertility is stochastic: Prob of conceiving =1 if age ≤ 32.5; Prob < 1 if age

> 32.5.

When not having a birth, women decide whether to participate in the

labor market.

Endogenous accumulation of experience.

Men supply labor inelastically.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 19 / 46

Page 51: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Model Households

The Model

Overlapping generations of households consisting of a man and a

woman.

Period corresponds to 2.5 years. People turn adult at age 20, retire at

60, and live until age 70.

Women can have one child per period from age 20 until age 37.5.

Fertility is stochastic: Prob of conceiving =1 if age ≤ 32.5; Prob < 1 if age

> 32.5.

When not having a birth, women decide whether to participate in the

labor market.

Endogenous accumulation of experience.

Men supply labor inelastically.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 19 / 46

Page 52: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Model Households

The Model

Overlapping generations of households consisting of a man and a

woman.

Period corresponds to 2.5 years. People turn adult at age 20, retire at

60, and live until age 70.

Women can have one child per period from age 20 until age 37.5.

Fertility is stochastic: Prob of conceiving =1 if age ≤ 32.5; Prob < 1 if age

> 32.5.

When not having a birth, women decide whether to participate in the

labor market.

Endogenous accumulation of experience.

Men supply labor inelastically.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 19 / 46

Page 53: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Model Households

The Model

Overlapping generations of households consisting of a man and a

woman.

Period corresponds to 2.5 years. People turn adult at age 20, retire at

60, and live until age 70.

Women can have one child per period from age 20 until age 37.5.

Fertility is stochastic: Prob of conceiving =1 if age ≤ 32.5; Prob < 1 if age

> 32.5.

When not having a birth, women decide whether to participate in the

labor market.

Endogenous accumulation of experience.

Men supply labor inelastically.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 19 / 46

Page 54: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Model Households

The Model

Overlapping generations of households consisting of a man and a

woman.

Period corresponds to 2.5 years. People turn adult at age 20, retire at

60, and live until age 70.

Women can have one child per period from age 20 until age 37.5.

Fertility is stochastic: Prob of conceiving =1 if age ≤ 32.5; Prob < 1 if age

> 32.5.

When not having a birth, women decide whether to participate in the

labor market.

Endogenous accumulation of experience.

Men supply labor inelastically.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 19 / 46

Page 55: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Model Households

Preferences and Budget Constraint

Utility:

Ut = Et

T∑

j=0

βj[

ln(ct,j) + σxi ln(xt,j + xWt,j)]

+ σn ln(nt)

.

Budget constraint:

ct,j + at,j+1 = (1 + rt+j)at,j + It,j − Tt+j(It,j , rt+jat,j),

where It = wmt+jemt,j + w

ft+je

ft,j lt,j .

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 20 / 46

Page 56: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Model Households

Preferences and Budget Constraint

Utility:

Ut = Et

T∑

j=0

βj[

ln(ct,j) + σxi ln(xt,j + xWt,j)]

+ σn ln(nt)

.

Budget constraint:

ct,j + at,j+1 = (1 + rt+j)at,j + It,j − Tt+j(It,j , rt+jat,j),

where It = wmt+jemt,j + w

ft+je

ft,j lt,j .

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 20 / 46

Page 57: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Model Households

Female Labor Supply and Time Constraint

Female labor supply decision is discrete: lj ∈ {0, 1}.

Fixed cost zj ∈ {0, z̄} of re-entering the labor market captures

adjustment costs.

The female time constraint:

xj = h− κbj − φ(nyj )ψ − lj − zj .

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 21 / 46

Page 58: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Model Households

Female Labor Supply and Time Constraint

Female labor supply decision is discrete: lj ∈ {0, 1}.

Fixed cost zj ∈ {0, z̄} of re-entering the labor market captures

adjustment costs.

The female time constraint:

xj = h− κbj − φ(nyj )ψ − lj − zj .

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 21 / 46

Page 59: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Model Households

Female Labor Supply and Time Constraint

Female labor supply decision is discrete: lj ∈ {0, 1}.

Fixed cost zj ∈ {0, z̄} of re-entering the labor market captures

adjustment costs.

The female time constraint:

xj = h− κbj − φ(nyj )ψ − lj − zj .

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 21 / 46

Page 60: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Model Households

Endogenous Experience

Initial experience normalized to one for both sexes:

em1 = ef1= 1.

Labor market experience evolves according to:

emj+1 =(1 + ηm,j)emj ,

efj+1

=(1 + ηf,jlj − ν(1− lj))efj .

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 22 / 46

Page 61: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Model Households

Endogenous Experience

Initial experience normalized to one for both sexes:

em1 = ef1= 1.

Labor market experience evolves according to:

emj+1 =(1 + ηm,j)emj ,

efj+1

=(1 + ηf,jlj − ν(1− lj))efj .

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 22 / 46

Page 62: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Model Households

Labor Supply and Fertility Decisions

Implications:

All women work initially since they don’t have children yet.

A�er having children, most women don’t resume work, because time isscarce and presence of adjustment cost.

Heterogeneity in labor supply and fertility due to di�erences in leisureweight σxi.

Timing of fertility:

On the one hand, delay children as late as possible to extend the initial

earnings period.

On the other hand, have children when still young b/c fecundity declineswith age.

Thus, exit from labor market depends on desired number of children.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 23 / 46

Page 63: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Model Households

Labor Supply and Fertility Decisions

Implications:

All women work initially since they don’t have children yet.

A�er having children, most women don’t resume work, because time isscarce and presence of adjustment cost.

Heterogeneity in labor supply and fertility due to di�erences in leisureweight σxi.

Timing of fertility:

On the one hand, delay children as late as possible to extend the initial

earnings period.

On the other hand, have children when still young b/c fecundity declineswith age.

Thus, exit from labor market depends on desired number of children.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 23 / 46

Page 64: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Model Households

Labor Supply and Fertility Decisions

Implications:

All women work initially since they don’t have children yet.

A�er having children, most women don’t resume work, because time isscarce and presence of adjustment cost.

Heterogeneity in labor supply and fertility due to di�erences in leisureweight σxi.

Timing of fertility:

On the one hand, delay children as late as possible to extend the initial

earnings period.

On the other hand, have children when still young b/c fecundity declineswith age.

Thus, exit from labor market depends on desired number of children.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 23 / 46

Page 65: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Model Households

Labor Supply and Fertility Decisions

Implications:

All women work initially since they don’t have children yet.

A�er having children, most women don’t resume work, because time isscarce and presence of adjustment cost.

Heterogeneity in labor supply and fertility due to di�erences in leisureweight σxi.

Timing of fertility:

On the one hand, delay children as late as possible to extend the initial

earnings period.

On the other hand, have children when still young b/c fecundity declineswith age.

Thus, exit from labor market depends on desired number of children.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 23 / 46

Page 66: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Model Households

Labor Supply and Fertility Decisions

Implications:

All women work initially since they don’t have children yet.

A�er having children, most women don’t resume work, because time isscarce and presence of adjustment cost.

Heterogeneity in labor supply and fertility due to di�erences in leisureweight σxi.

Timing of fertility:

On the one hand, delay children as late as possible to extend the initial

earnings period.

On the other hand, have children when still young b/c fecundity declineswith age.

Thus, exit from labor market depends on desired number of children.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 23 / 46

Page 67: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Model Households

Labor Supply and Fertility Decisions

Implications:

All women work initially since they don’t have children yet.

A�er having children, most women don’t resume work, because time isscarce and presence of adjustment cost.

Heterogeneity in labor supply and fertility due to di�erences in leisureweight σxi.

Timing of fertility:

On the one hand, delay children as late as possible to extend the initial

earnings period.

On the other hand, have children when still young b/c fecundity declineswith age.

Thus, exit from labor market depends on desired number of children.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 23 / 46

Page 68: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Model Households

Labor Supply and Fertility Decisions

Implications:

All women work initially since they don’t have children yet.

A�er having children, most women don’t resume work, because time isscarce and presence of adjustment cost.

Heterogeneity in labor supply and fertility due to di�erences in leisureweight σxi.

Timing of fertility:

On the one hand, delay children as late as possible to extend the initial

earnings period.

On the other hand, have children when still young b/c fecundity declineswith age.

Thus, exit from labor market depends on desired number of children.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 23 / 46

Page 69: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Model Households

Labor Supply and Fertility Decisions

Implications:

All women work initially since they don’t have children yet.

A�er having children, most women don’t resume work, because time isscarce and presence of adjustment cost.

Heterogeneity in labor supply and fertility due to di�erences in leisureweight σxi.

Timing of fertility:

On the one hand, delay children as late as possible to extend the initial

earnings period.

On the other hand, have children when still young b/c fecundity declineswith age.

Thus, exit from labor market depends on desired number of children.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 23 / 46

Page 70: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Model Technology

Technology

Production function with limited substitutability between male and

female labor:

Yt = AtKαt

(

θ(LFt )ρ + (1− θ)(LMt )ρ

)

1−α

ρ

Aggregate labor supply is sum of households’ e�iciency units of labor.

Capital depreciates at constant rate δ.

Productivity At grows at constant rate γ.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 24 / 46

Page 71: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Model Technology

Technology

Production function with limited substitutability between male and

female labor:

Yt = AtKαt

(

θ(LFt )ρ + (1− θ)(LMt )ρ

)

1−α

ρ

Aggregate labor supply is sum of households’ e�iciency units of labor.

Capital depreciates at constant rate δ.

Productivity At grows at constant rate γ.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 24 / 46

Page 72: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Model Technology

Technology

Production function with limited substitutability between male and

female labor:

Yt = AtKαt

(

θ(LFt )ρ + (1− θ)(LMt )ρ

)

1−α

ρ

Aggregate labor supply is sum of households’ e�iciency units of labor.

Capital depreciates at constant rate δ.

Productivity At grows at constant rate γ.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 24 / 46

Page 73: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Model Technology

Technology

Production function with limited substitutability between male and

female labor:

Yt = AtKαt

(

θ(LFt )ρ + (1− θ)(LMt )ρ

)

1−α

ρ

Aggregate labor supply is sum of households’ e�iciency units of labor.

Capital depreciates at constant rate δ.

Productivity At grows at constant rate γ.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 24 / 46

Page 74: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Model Government

Government

The tax function:

Tt(Il, Ik) = τl,tmax {Il − ξt, 0} + τk,tIk + τLS,t

The government budget constraint is:

Gt+wmt LD

t +(1+ rt)Bt = Bt+1+

T∑

s=1

Pt−s

0

Tt(It−s,s, rt at−s,s) dF (σx)

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 25 / 46

Page 75: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Model Government

Government

The tax function:

Tt(Il, Ik) = τl,tmax {Il − ξt, 0} + τk,tIk + τLS,t

The government budget constraint is:

Gt+wmt LD

t +(1+ rt)Bt = Bt+1+

T∑

s=1

Pt−s

0

Tt(It−s,s, rt at−s,s) dF (σx)

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 25 / 46

Page 76: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Model Equilibrium

Market Clearing

The market-clearing condition for capital:

Kt +Bt =

T∑

s=1

Pt−s

∫ ∞

0

at−s,s dF (σx)

The market-clearing condition for male labor:

Lmt + LDt =R∑

s=0

Pt−s

∫ ∞

0

emt−s,s dF (σx)

The market-clearing condition for female labor:

Lft =

R∑

s=0

Pt−s

∫ ∞

0

eft−s,s lt−s,s dF (σx)

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 26 / 46

Page 77: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Model Equilibrium

Market Clearing

The market-clearing condition for capital:

Kt +Bt =

T∑

s=1

Pt−s

∫ ∞

0

at−s,s dF (σx)

The market-clearing condition for male labor:

Lmt + LDt =R∑

s=0

Pt−s

∫ ∞

0

emt−s,s dF (σx)

The market-clearing condition for female labor:

Lft =

R∑

s=0

Pt−s

∫ ∞

0

eft−s,s lt−s,s dF (σx)

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 26 / 46

Page 78: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Model Equilibrium

Market Clearing

The market-clearing condition for capital:

Kt +Bt =

T∑

s=1

Pt−s

∫ ∞

0

at−s,s dF (σx)

The market-clearing condition for male labor:

Lmt + LDt =R∑

s=0

Pt−s

∫ ∞

0

emt−s,s dF (σx)

The market-clearing condition for female labor:

Lft =

R∑

s=0

Pt−s

∫ ∞

0

eft−s,s lt−s,s dF (σx)

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 26 / 46

Page 79: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

�antitative Analysis

The�antitative Exercise

The model is calibrated to a balanced growth path:

population, output, capital and consumption are all growing at aconstant rate.

World War II is modeled as an unexpected shock.

The model converges to a new balanced growth path.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 27 / 46

Page 80: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

�antitative Analysis

The�antitative Exercise

The model is calibrated to a balanced growth path:

population, output, capital and consumption are all growing at aconstant rate.

World War II is modeled as an unexpected shock.

The model converges to a new balanced growth path.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 27 / 46

Page 81: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

�antitative Analysis

The�antitative Exercise

The model is calibrated to a balanced growth path:

population, output, capital and consumption are all growing at aconstant rate.

World War II is modeled as an unexpected shock.

The model converges to a new balanced growth path.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 27 / 46

Page 82: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

�antitative Analysis

The�antitative Exercise

The model is calibrated to a balanced growth path:

population, output, capital and consumption are all growing at aconstant rate.

World War II is modeled as an unexpected shock.

The model converges to a new balanced growth path.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 27 / 46

Page 83: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

�antitative Analysis

The War Shock

We model World War II as an unexpected shock, consisting of:

1 The government dra�s men during the war: LDt = 0 before and a�er the

war and LDt > 0 during the war.

2 A permanent increase in taxes and in government debt.

3 A “patriotism” shock that increases female labor supply during the war:xWt,j = 0 before and a�er the war and xW

t,j = x̄W > 0 during the war.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 28 / 46

Page 84: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

�antitative Analysis

The War Shock

We model World War II as an unexpected shock, consisting of:

1 The government dra�s men during the war: LDt = 0 before and a�er the

war and LDt > 0 during the war.

2 A permanent increase in taxes and in government debt.

3 A “patriotism” shock that increases female labor supply during the war:xWt,j = 0 before and a�er the war and xW

t,j = x̄W > 0 during the war.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 28 / 46

Page 85: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

�antitative Analysis

The War Shock

We model World War II as an unexpected shock, consisting of:

1 The government dra�s men during the war: LDt = 0 before and a�er the

war and LDt > 0 during the war.

2 A permanent increase in taxes and in government debt.

3 A “patriotism” shock that increases female labor supply during the war:xWt,j = 0 before and a�er the war and xW

t,j = x̄W > 0 during the war.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 28 / 46

Page 86: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

�antitative Analysis

The War Shock

We model World War II as an unexpected shock, consisting of:

1 The government dra�s men during the war: LDt = 0 before and a�er the

war and LDt > 0 during the war.

2 A permanent increase in taxes and in government debt.

3 A “patriotism” shock that increases female labor supply during the war:xWt,j = 0 before and a�er the war and xW

t,j = x̄W > 0 during the war.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 28 / 46

Page 87: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

�antitative Analysis

Rosie the Riveter

(a) J. Howard Miller for the Westinghouse Company’s

War Production Coordinating Commi�ee

(b) Norman Rockwell for the cover of the Saturday

Evening Post, May 20, 1943

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 29 / 46

Page 88: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

�antitative Analysis

Calibration I

Overall Strategy:

Match technology to U.S. long-run growth observations.

Match fertility rate, female labor force participation, experienceaccumulation, and relative female wages to U.S. data in 1940.

Use the cross-state evidence to pin down the preference parameters thatgovern fertility and labor supply.

This implies that the quantitative results from the model do not provideindependent evidence on the magnitude of the reaction of fertility to thewar shock.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 30 / 46

Page 89: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

�antitative Analysis

Calibration I

Overall Strategy:

Match technology to U.S. long-run growth observations.

Match fertility rate, female labor force participation, experienceaccumulation, and relative female wages to U.S. data in 1940.

Use the cross-state evidence to pin down the preference parameters thatgovern fertility and labor supply.

This implies that the quantitative results from the model do not provideindependent evidence on the magnitude of the reaction of fertility to thewar shock.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 30 / 46

Page 90: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

�antitative Analysis

Calibration I

Overall Strategy:

Match technology to U.S. long-run growth observations.

Match fertility rate, female labor force participation, experienceaccumulation, and relative female wages to U.S. data in 1940.

Use the cross-state evidence to pin down the preference parameters thatgovern fertility and labor supply.

This implies that the quantitative results from the model do not provideindependent evidence on the magnitude of the reaction of fertility to thewar shock.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 30 / 46

Page 91: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

�antitative Analysis

Calibration I

Overall Strategy:

Match technology to U.S. long-run growth observations.

Match fertility rate, female labor force participation, experienceaccumulation, and relative female wages to U.S. data in 1940.

Use the cross-state evidence to pin down the preference parameters thatgovern fertility and labor supply.

This implies that the quantitative results from the model do not provideindependent evidence on the magnitude of the reaction of fertility to thewar shock.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 30 / 46

Page 92: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

�antitative Analysis

Calibration I

Overall Strategy:

Match technology to U.S. long-run growth observations.

Match fertility rate, female labor force participation, experienceaccumulation, and relative female wages to U.S. data in 1940.

Use the cross-state evidence to pin down the preference parameters thatgovern fertility and labor supply.

This implies that the quantitative results from the model do not provideindependent evidence on the magnitude of the reaction of fertility to thewar shock.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 30 / 46

Page 93: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

�antitative Analysis

Calibration II

The added value of the quantitative analysis.

Makes explicit the causal connection between the war and the rise infertility.

Assesses the implications of the theory for changes in female laborsupply (which are not constrained by the calibration).

Assesses the implications of the theory for the timing of the rise and fallin fertility.

Enables us to carry out counterfactual experiments:

The role of labor market experience.

The relative importance of fiscal change.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 31 / 46

Page 94: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

�antitative Analysis

Calibration II

The added value of the quantitative analysis.

Makes explicit the causal connection between the war and the rise infertility.

Assesses the implications of the theory for changes in female laborsupply (which are not constrained by the calibration).

Assesses the implications of the theory for the timing of the rise and fallin fertility.

Enables us to carry out counterfactual experiments:

The role of labor market experience.

The relative importance of fiscal change.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 31 / 46

Page 95: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

�antitative Analysis

Calibration II

The added value of the quantitative analysis.

Makes explicit the causal connection between the war and the rise infertility.

Assesses the implications of the theory for changes in female laborsupply (which are not constrained by the calibration).

Assesses the implications of the theory for the timing of the rise and fallin fertility.

Enables us to carry out counterfactual experiments:

The role of labor market experience.

The relative importance of fiscal change.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 31 / 46

Page 96: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

�antitative Analysis

Calibration II

The added value of the quantitative analysis.

Makes explicit the causal connection between the war and the rise infertility.

Assesses the implications of the theory for changes in female laborsupply (which are not constrained by the calibration).

Assesses the implications of the theory for the timing of the rise and fallin fertility.

Enables us to carry out counterfactual experiments:

The role of labor market experience.

The relative importance of fiscal change.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 31 / 46

Page 97: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

�antitative Analysis

Calibration II

The added value of the quantitative analysis.

Makes explicit the causal connection between the war and the rise infertility.

Assesses the implications of the theory for changes in female laborsupply (which are not constrained by the calibration).

Assesses the implications of the theory for the timing of the rise and fallin fertility.

Enables us to carry out counterfactual experiments:

The role of labor market experience.

The relative importance of fiscal change.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 31 / 46

Page 98: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

�antitative Analysis

Calibration II

The added value of the quantitative analysis.

Makes explicit the causal connection between the war and the rise infertility.

Assesses the implications of the theory for changes in female laborsupply (which are not constrained by the calibration).

Assesses the implications of the theory for the timing of the rise and fallin fertility.

Enables us to carry out counterfactual experiments:

The role of labor market experience.

The relative importance of fiscal change.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 31 / 46

Page 99: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

�antitative Analysis

Calibration II

The added value of the quantitative analysis.

Makes explicit the causal connection between the war and the rise infertility.

Assesses the implications of the theory for changes in female laborsupply (which are not constrained by the calibration).

Assesses the implications of the theory for the timing of the rise and fallin fertility.

Enables us to carry out counterfactual experiments:

The role of labor market experience.

The relative importance of fiscal change.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 31 / 46

Page 100: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

�antitative Analysis results

Cohort Fertility Rate

1910 1920 1930 1940 1950

2

2.5

3

Co

mp

lete

d F

erti

lity

Rat

e

Year of Birth

Model

Data

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 32 / 46

Page 101: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

�antitative Analysis results

Total Fertility Rate

1940 1950 1960 1970

2

2.5

3

3.5

To

tal

Fer

tili

ty R

ate

Year

Model

Data

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 33 / 46

Page 102: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

�antitative Analysis results

Average Age at First Birth

1940 1950 1960 1970−2

−1.5

−1

−0.5

0

0.5

1

Av

erag

e A

ge

at F

irst

Bir

th R

elat

ive

to 1

940

Year

Model

Data

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 34 / 46

Page 103: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

�antitative Analysis results

Labor Force Participation of Young Women

1940 1950 1960 1970−0.15

−0.1

−0.05

0

0.05

LF

P 2

0−32

Rel

ativ

e to

194

0

Year

Model

Data

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 35 / 46

Page 104: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

�antitative Analysis results

Labor Force Participation – Goldin 1991 vs. our Model

Goldin (1991) documents that WWII entrants made up 25.6 percent of

the female labor force in 1951.

In our simulation, WWII entrants make up 22.8 percent of the female

labor force in 1951.

Goldin (1991) also documents that more than half of wartime entrants

le� the labor force before 1951.

This is also true in our simulation.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 36 / 46

Page 105: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

�antitative Analysis results

Labor Force Participation – Goldin 1991 vs. our Model

Goldin (1991) documents that WWII entrants made up 25.6 percent of

the female labor force in 1951.

In our simulation, WWII entrants make up 22.8 percent of the female

labor force in 1951.

Goldin (1991) also documents that more than half of wartime entrants

le� the labor force before 1951.

This is also true in our simulation.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 36 / 46

Page 106: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

�antitative Analysis results

Labor Force Participation – Goldin 1991 vs. our Model

Goldin (1991) documents that WWII entrants made up 25.6 percent of

the female labor force in 1951.

In our simulation, WWII entrants make up 22.8 percent of the female

labor force in 1951.

Goldin (1991) also documents that more than half of wartime entrants

le� the labor force before 1951.

This is also true in our simulation.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 36 / 46

Page 107: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

�antitative Analysis results

Labor Force Participation – Goldin 1991 vs. our Model

Goldin (1991) documents that WWII entrants made up 25.6 percent of

the female labor force in 1951.

In our simulation, WWII entrants make up 22.8 percent of the female

labor force in 1951.

Goldin (1991) also documents that more than half of wartime entrants

le� the labor force before 1951.

This is also true in our simulation.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 36 / 46

Page 108: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

�antitative Analysis results

Females Relative Wage

1940 1950 1960 1970−0.04

−0.03

−0.02

−0.01

0

Gen

der

Wag

e R

atio

20−

24 R

elat

ive

to 1

940

Year

Model

Data

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 37 / 46

Page 109: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

�antitative Analysis results

Cohort Fertility Rate – Matched Wages

1910 1920 1930 1940 1950

2

2.5

3

Co

mp

lete

d F

erti

lity

Rat

e

Year of Birth

Baseline

Matched Wage Gap

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 38 / 46

Page 110: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

�antitative Analysis results

Cohort Fertility Rate – With Experience

1910 1920 1930 1940 1950

2

2.5

3

Co

mp

lete

d F

erti

lity

Rat

e

Year of Birth

Baseline

No Experience Accumulation

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 39 / 46

Page 111: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

�antitative Analysis results

The Labor Supply Channel versus the Fiscal Channel

1910 1920 1930 1940 1950

2

2.5

3

Co

mp

lete

d F

erti

lity

Rat

e

Year of Birth

Baseline

No Fiscal Changes

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 40 / 46

Page 112: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

International Evidence - Baby Boom in other countries

The Baby Boom in Other Countries

Most industrialized countries experienced a post-war baby boom.

Size and duration of boom varies substantially.

Compare two groups:

Countries with similar war experience to U.S.:Canada, Australia, New Zealand.

Neutral countries:Sweden, Switzerland, Portugal, Spain, Ireland.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 41 / 46

Page 113: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

International Evidence - Baby Boom in other countries

The Baby Boom in Other Countries

Most industrialized countries experienced a post-war baby boom.

Size and duration of boom varies substantially.

Compare two groups:

Countries with similar war experience to U.S.:Canada, Australia, New Zealand.

Neutral countries:Sweden, Switzerland, Portugal, Spain, Ireland.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 41 / 46

Page 114: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

International Evidence - Baby Boom in other countries

The Baby Boom in Other Countries

Most industrialized countries experienced a post-war baby boom.

Size and duration of boom varies substantially.

Compare two groups:

Countries with similar war experience to U.S.:Canada, Australia, New Zealand.

Neutral countries:Sweden, Switzerland, Portugal, Spain, Ireland.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 41 / 46

Page 115: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

International Evidence - Baby Boom in other countries

The Baby Boom in Other Countries

Most industrialized countries experienced a post-war baby boom.

Size and duration of boom varies substantially.

Compare two groups:

Countries with similar war experience to U.S.:Canada, Australia, New Zealand.

Neutral countries:Sweden, Switzerland, Portugal, Spain, Ireland.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 41 / 46

Page 116: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

International Evidence - Baby Boom in other countries

The Baby Boom in Other Countries

Most industrialized countries experienced a post-war baby boom.

Size and duration of boom varies substantially.

Compare two groups:

Countries with similar war experience to U.S.:Canada, Australia, New Zealand.

Neutral countries:Sweden, Switzerland, Portugal, Spain, Ireland.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 41 / 46

Page 117: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

International Evidence - Baby Boom in other countries

The Baby Boom in Countries Similar to U.S.

1.50

2.00

2.50

3.00

3.50

4.00

1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960

CompletedFertility

Rate

Year of Birth

United States

Australia

New Zealand

Canada

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 42 / 46

Page 118: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

International Evidence - Baby Boom in other countries

The Baby Boom in the Neutral Countries

1.50

2.00

2.50

3.00

3.50

4.00

1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960

CompletedFertility

Rate

Year of Birth

United States

Sweden

Switzerland

Spain

Portugal

Ireland

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 43 / 46

Page 119: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Summary

Summary

If labor supply is persistent, one-time demand shock can lead to

long-lived, asymmetric e�ects on younger and older workers.

World War II was a huge demand shock for female labor.

�alitatively, cohort-specific participation rates, wages, fertility, and

the timing of births behave as in data a�er such a shock.

�antitative exercise suggests that our mechanism can account for a

major part of the baby boom and baby bust.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 44 / 46

Page 120: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Summary

Summary

If labor supply is persistent, one-time demand shock can lead to

long-lived, asymmetric e�ects on younger and older workers.

World War II was a huge demand shock for female labor.

�alitatively, cohort-specific participation rates, wages, fertility, and

the timing of births behave as in data a�er such a shock.

�antitative exercise suggests that our mechanism can account for a

major part of the baby boom and baby bust.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 44 / 46

Page 121: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Summary

Summary

If labor supply is persistent, one-time demand shock can lead to

long-lived, asymmetric e�ects on younger and older workers.

World War II was a huge demand shock for female labor.

�alitatively, cohort-specific participation rates, wages, fertility, and

the timing of births behave as in data a�er such a shock.

�antitative exercise suggests that our mechanism can account for a

major part of the baby boom and baby bust.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 44 / 46

Page 122: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Summary

Summary

If labor supply is persistent, one-time demand shock can lead to

long-lived, asymmetric e�ects on younger and older workers.

World War II was a huge demand shock for female labor.

�alitatively, cohort-specific participation rates, wages, fertility, and

the timing of births behave as in data a�er such a shock.

�antitative exercise suggests that our mechanism can account for a

major part of the baby boom and baby bust.

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 44 / 46

Page 123: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Thank you!

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 45 / 46

Page 124: The Baby Boom and World War II: A Macroeconomic Analysis · technology revolution.” (But see Bailey and Collins (2011)) Albanesi and Olive˛i (2014), “the maternal health revolution.”

Why WWII?

Male Military Personnel on Active Duty as % of Male Population aged 15-64

0%

5%

10%

15%

20%

25%

30%

1900 1905 1910 1915 1920 1925 1930 1935 1940 1945 1950 1955 1960 1965 1970

Moshe Hazan (TAU and CEPR) Doepke, Hazan, Maoz February 2015 46 / 46