THAMMASAT REVIEW OF ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL POLICY › paper › vol4-2 › 01_TRESP Vol.4... ·...

117
Faculty of Economics, Thammasat University THAMMASAT REVIEW OF ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL POLICY Credit Guarantee Optimization of State-owned Enterprises Chayanisa Chaisuekul Investigating relationship between Government Spending and Economic Growth: Public Spending and long-run GDP level Kritchasorn Jarupasin Linkage of Technological Innovation toward ICT base and Economic Output in CLMV Region Theara Chhorn Volume 4, Number 2, July - December 2018 ISSN 2465-390X (Print) ISSN 2465-4167 (Online)

Transcript of THAMMASAT REVIEW OF ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL POLICY › paper › vol4-2 › 01_TRESP Vol.4... ·...

  • Faculty of Economics, Thammasat University

    THAMMASAT REVIEW OF

    ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL POLICY

    Credit Guarantee Optimization of State-owned Enterprises

    Chayanisa Chaisuekul

    Investigating relationship between Government Spending

    and Economic Growth: Public Spending and long-run GDP

    level

    Kritchasorn Jarupasin

    Linkage of Technological Innovation toward ICT base and

    Economic Output in CLMV Region

    Theara Chhorn

    Volume 4, Number 2, July - December 2018

    ISSN 2465-390X (Print)

    ISSN 2465-4167 (Online)

  • THAMMASAT REVIEW OF

    ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL POLICY Volume 4, Number 2, July – December 2018

    ISSN 2465-390X (Print)

    ISSN 2465-4167 (Online)

  • Thammasat Review of Economic and Social Policy

    Thammasat Review of Economic and Social Policy (TRESP) is a

    double-blind peer reviewed biannual international journal published in

    June and December. The journal is managed by the Research Committee

    under the supervision of the Academic Affairs Division of the Faculty of

    Economics, Thammasat University. Our editorial board and review panel

    comprise of academicians and practitioners across various areas of

    economic and social policies. The goal of the journal is to provide up-to-

    date practical and policy-oriented analysis and assessment of economic and

    social issues, with particular focus on Asia and the Pacific region.

    However, research findings from other parts of the world that are relevant

    to the theme of the journal may be considered.

    Aims & Scopes

    Our journal is dedicated to serve as a platform for debate and

    critical discussion pertaining to the current issues of public policy. The

    outcome of such research is expected to yield concrete policy implications.

    Some of the targeted issues include urban and regional socio-economic

    disparities, ageing society, healthcare, education and welfare policies,

    environmental and natural resources, local communities, labor migration,

    productivity, economic and political integration, political economy,

    macroeconomic instability, trade and investment, fiscal imbalances,

    decentralization, gender issues, behavioral economics and regulations; and

    law and economics. The journal makes its best effort to cater a wide range

    of audience, including policymakers, practitioners in the public and

    business sectors, researchers as well as graduate students.

    Articles should identify any particular issue concisely, address the

    problems of the research explicitly and supply sufficient empirical data or

    strong evidence and substantial argument to support the discussion of

    policy initiatives asserted by the author(s). Theoretical and applied papers

    are equally welcome provided their contributions are policy-relevant.

    Authors are responsible for the published articles. The views and

    opinions expressed in the articles do not necessarily reflect those of the

    Editors and the Editorial Board.

  • Advisory Board

    Dean, Faculty of Economics, Thammasat University, Thailand

    Ian Coxhead, University of Wisconsin-Madison, United State

    Tran Van Hoa, Centre for Strategic Economic Studies, Victoria University, Australia

    Suthipun Jitpimolmard, Khon Kaen University and Thailand Research Fund, Thailand

    Medhi Krongkaew, National Institute of Development Administration, Thailand

    Duangmanee Laovakul, Thammasat University, Thailand

    Arayah Preechametta, Thammasat University, Thailand

    Sakon Varanyuwatana, King Prajadhipok's Institute, Thailand

    Editor-in-Chief

    Euamporn Phijaisanit, Thammasat University, Thailand

    Associate Editor

    Pornthep Benyaapikul, Thammasat University, Thailand

    Editorial Board

    Kirida Bhaophichitr, Thailand Development Research Institute, Thailand

    Brahma Chellaney, Center for Policy Research, New Delhi, India

    Aekapol Chongvilaivan, Asian Development Bank, Manila, Philippines

    Emma Jackson, Bank of England, UK

    Armin Kammel, Lauder Business School, Vienna, Austria

    Somprawin Manprasert, Bank of Ayudhya, Thailand

    Gareth D. Myles, School of Economics, University of Adelaide, Australia

    Voraprapa Nakavachara, Chulalongkorn University, Thailand

    Songtham Pinto, Bank of Thailand, Thailand

    Pathomdanai Ponjan, Fiscal Policy Office, Ministry of Finance, Thailand

    Watcharapong Ratisukpimol, Chulalongkorn University, Thailand

    Sasatra Sudsawasd, National Institute of Development Administration, Thailand

    Maria-Angeles Tobarra-Gomez, University of Castilla-La Mancha, Spain

    Soraphol Tulayasathien, Fiscal Policy Office, Ministry of Finance, Thailand

    Editorial Assistants

    Darawan Raksuntikul

    Sorravich Kingsuwankul

    Panit Buranawijarn

    Editorial and Managerial Contact

    c/o Mrs. Darawan Raksuntikul

    Thammasat Review of Economic and Social Policy (TRESP)

    Faculty of Economics, Thammasat University

    2 Prachan Road, Bangkok 10200, Thailand

    Tel. +66 2 696 5979

    Fax. +66 2 696 5987

    E-mail: [email protected]

    Url: http://www.tresp.econ.tu.ac.th

  • Thammasat Review of Economic and Social Policy

    Volume 4, Number 2, July-December 2018

    Editorial Introduction 1

    ARTICLES

    Credit Guarantee Optimization of State-owned Enterprises 6

    Chayanisa Chaisuekul

    Investigating relationship between Government Spending and

    Economic Growth: Public Spending and long-run GDP level

    Kritchasorn Jarupasin 28

    Linkage of Technological Innovation toward ICT base and

    Economic Output in CLMV Region 76

    Theara Chhorn

  • Thammasat Review of Economic and Social Policy

    Volume 4, Number 2, July – December 2018

    1

    Editorial Introduction

    In this issue, Chayanisa Chaisuekul from Fiscal Policy

    Research Institute, Thailand, conducted an investigative

    research on government credit guarantee, which can be

    considered one of the fiscal instruments for public support on

    infrastructure and public goods investment. Her article,

    “Credit Guarantee Optimization of State-owned Entreprises”,

    studies the risk profile of government credit guarantees in

    Thailand which are overseen by the Public Debt Management

    Office (PDMO) of the Ministry of Finance. Government credit

    guarantees are particularly effective in cases where the

    government is the best stakeholder to anticipate, control, and

    minimize risk. They are best viewed as endogeneous risks

    since the risks can potentially be influenced by government

    policy.

    The state-owned enterprises (SOEs) examined in this

    study are categorized into financial institutions and non-

    financial institutions. The paper studies the relationship

    between default events and credit rating of these two types of

    SOEs over the period 2009-2014. In the case of financial

    institutions, a separate definition for a ‘default event’ was

    utilized (focusing instead on the rollover and restructuring of

    debt) as no financial institution SOEs failed to pay scheduled

    debt service in that time period. Intuitively, this may be due to

    the fact that a financial institution defaulting on a payment has

    the potential to be much more disruptive than a non-financial

    institution from the government perspective. The probability of default for financial and non-financial SOEs was estimated

    using the hybrid forward model.

    Government credit guarantees can entail both benefits and risks for the government. In Thailand, the role of the

    PDMO is to manage the fiscal risk stemming from government

    guarantees. The optimal credit guarantee values were

  • Thammasat Review of Economic and Social Policy

    Volume 4, Number 2, July – December 2018

    2

    calculated using linear programming models of two types:

    maximizing net benefits, and minimizing net expected loss.

    The paper found that the two methods yield similar results.

    The probability of default for both types of SOEs closely

    follows rank-order in terms of credit rating. However, in

    contrast to the literature, it was found that in the time period

    studied, the probability of default for financial institution

    SOEs was higher than that of non-financial institutions, for a

    given credit rating. This is perhaps due to the turbulent time

    period which was studied where the government of Thailand

    embarked on many new initiatives which were not all

    successful. Further studies may consider longer time periods

    to further clarify the picture.

    The second article of this issue is “Investigating

    relationship between Government Spending and Economic

    Growth: Public Spending and long-run GDP level” by

    Kritchasorn Jarupasin from Office of the National Economic

    and Social Development Board (NESDB). This article

    analyses the impacts of fiscal policy using a Solow-type model

    with transitional dynamics, allowing for persisting effects of

    fiscal policy à la Gemmell, Kneller and Sanz (2016). Previous

    studies have looked at, through various methods and with

    various dependent and fiscal variables, the effects of fiscal

    policy changes on economic growth. While findings reveal

    evidence for both significant and non-significant effects on

    short-run and long-run growth, the literature indicates that

    careful design is required to isolate effects and derive results.

    The article displays the effects of fiscal policy changes

    in 38 countries, with 17 developing countries and 21 high-

    income OECD countries. The data indicates that, on average,

    high-income countries spend more (as a percentage of Gross

    Domestic Product, GDP) on healthcare and social welfare,

    while developing countries spend more on general public

    services. Unweighted averages suggested that, as a percentage

  • Thammasat Review of Economic and Social Policy

    Volume 4, Number 2, July – December 2018

    3

    of GDP, developing and high-income countries spend similar

    amounts on education. Pooled mean group (PMG) estimator

    with an autoregressive distributed lag (ARDL(1,1)) structure

    was employed to analyse short-run dynamics and long-run

    equilibrium relationships between fiscal change and growth.

    There is evidence that an increase in the share of a particular

    type of spending could improve the level of per capita GDP in

    the long run for developing countries in the sample, for

    example, in healthcare and in general public services. For

    high-income countries, the model suggests additional

    spending on education could boost long-term GDP levels.

    However, how this additional spending is financed also has

    implications for growth; the data suggests that in the high-

    income country group, excise taxes play a large role in

    determining the effectiveness of spending increases.

    Overall, one important key point from the study

    implies that increasing revenue through distortionary taxes

    should be avoided, since it reduces economic growth rate.

    Moreover, the growth impacts of fiscal changes vary by

    different implicit financing elements. In developing countries,

    the focus should be on increasing the share of spending on

    general public services and healthcare.

    The third article, “Linkage of Technological

    Innovation toward ICT base and Economic Output in CLMV

    Region,” by Theara Chhorn, Chiang Mai University, considers

    the relationship between information and communication

    technology (ICT) development in Cambodia, Lao PDR,

    Myanmar and Vietnam, and economic growth and

    development, with a view towards providing policy

    recommendations.

    Technological innovation and progress through

    improvements in ICT has driven economic growth and

    reduced poverty across the world. In the vein of similar studies

    in the literature on technological progress and growth, ICT is

  • Thammasat Review of Economic and Social Policy

    Volume 4, Number 2, July – December 2018

    4

    assumed to augment labour and capital productivity.

    Estimation methods used include the fixed-effects and

    random-effects model, the maximum-likelihood random

    effects model, and feasible generalised least squares

    estimation. The different approaches are used to obtain more

    efficient and consistent estimates, as well as minimize the

    effects of heteroskedasticity and serial autocorrelation.

    Estimation of the impact of technological progress is

    proxied in two ways in the study: (i) number of internet server

    connections, and; (ii) imports of computers and other ICT-

    related goods. The literature suggests that estimation of both

    factors should be positively correlated with economic growth.

    The study finds that, for the period 1995-2016, internet server

    connections have a positive and significant relationship with

    per capita GDP growth. However, there is opposite

    relationship between imports of computers and ICT products,

    i.e. increased imports lead to lower per capita GDP growth.

    The study supports the notion that greater access to

    technology has the potential to improve economic growth and

    development. Policymakers should thus harness this

    relationship to bolster domestic development, as well as take

    steps to attract increased investment in technology. Further

    research should, however, be conducted to identify why

    greater imports of computer and ICT products are negatively

    related to economic development in the CLMV region.

    Thammasat Review of Economic and Social Policy

    (TRESP) is a young biannual double-blind peer reviewed

    international journal published in June and December. Its first

    publication was in December 2015. The Faculty of

    Economics, Thammasat University and the Editorial Team of

    TRESP seek to provide an effective platform for reflecting

    practical and policy-oriented perspectives that links the

    academic and policymaking community. Having devoted to

    our ‘knowledge-for-all’ philosophy so as to drive our society

  • Thammasat Review of Economic and Social Policy

    Volume 4, Number 2, July – December 2018

    5

    forward, the Faculty decided that TRESP published in an open

    access model. Authors are responsible for the published

    articles. The views and opinions expressed in the articles do

    not necessarily reflect those of the Editors and the Editorial

    Board. For further information and updates on this journal, or to submit an article, please visit our website at

    www.tresp.econ.tu.ac.th.

    Euamporn Phijaisanit

    Editor-in-Chief

  • Thammasat Review of Economic and Social Policy

    Volume 4, Number 2, July – December 2018

    6

    Credit Guarantee Optimization of State-owned

    Enterprises

    Chayanisa Chaisuekul

    Senior Researcher

    Fiscal Policy Research Institute

    [email protected]

  • Thammasat Review of Economic and Social Policy

    Volume 4, Number 2, July – December 2018

    7

    ABSTRACT

    The objective of this paper is to estimate the credit risk of state-

    owned enterprises (SOEs) in the form of probability of default

    (PD) and then use it to analyze credit guarantee optimization.

    Estimation of the probability of default by the Hybrid Model

    found that the estimated PD for both financial and non-

    financial SOEs are ranked by credit rating grade (the rank

    ordering property), except for the 3rd rating grade PD of non-

    financial SOEs. Analysis of the optimal credit guarantee for

    each SOE by Linear Programming model found that the results

    of maximizing the net benefit and the results of minimizing the

    net expected loss from credit guarantee are similar. Moreover,

    the value of expected loss implies that the magnitude of credit

    risk must be mitigated and managed with appropriate tools by

    the Ministry of Finance.

    Keywords: Government credit guarantee, Credit risk, State-

    owned enterprises

    JEL Classification: C61, H63

  • Thammasat Review of Economic and Social Policy

    Volume 4, Number 2, July – December 2018

    8

    Introduction

    1.1. Government credit guarantees

    Government credit guarantees are a fiscal instrument of

    government financial support for infrastructure and public

    goods investment in cases where the government is the best

    organization to anticipate risk, control risk exposure, and

    minimize the cost of risk (IMF, 2005).

    In Thailand, the Public Debt Management Office

    (PDMO) of the Ministry of Finance has guaranteed credit

    (loan and bond) to some state-owned enterprises (SOEs) since

    20051. Its goals are to give SOEs access to finance at a lower

    financial cost (loan interest rate) and to get a greater amount

    of credit from financial institutions with a favorable borrowing

    term because they can benefit from the government's high

    credit standing. In addition, the government’s support for

    SOEs also support economic growth and social development,

    such as infrastructure development projects2 and supporting

    farmers.3

    1.2. Fiscal risk from government credit guarantee

    Government credit guarantees create a contingent liability

    or government obligation for the Ministry of Finance. The

    Ministry of Finance must repay the outstanding guaranteed

    loans of state-owned enterprises if those state-owned

    enterprises default on the loans. It is the uncertainty as to whether the government will have to pay, and if so the timing

    1 Under the Thailand's Public Debt Management Act of 2005 (B.E. 2548) 2 E.g. High-speed train project by the State Railway of Thailand (SRT) 3 E.g. Rice pledging scheme and agricultural credit for rural development

    project by Bank for Agriculture and Agricultural Cooperatives (BAAC)

  • Thammasat Review of Economic and Social Policy

    Volume 4, Number 2, July – December 2018

    9

    and amount of spending that is complicated for estimation of

    fiscal risk management (IMF, 2005).

    The fiscal risk from government credit guarantees are

    classified as endogenous risks that are generated from

    government activities or where the probability of the event can

    be influenced by government actions (IMF, 2016).

    Table 1. Government Credit Guarantee Fee Rate

    Credit

    rating

    grade

    Guarantee Fee Rate

    (Percentage of outstanding guaranteed loan)

    5 years

    but 10 years

    of loan

    period

    Government

    agency - 0.01 0.05 0.10 0.15

    SOE

    1 0.01 0.05 0.10 0.15

    2 0.05 0.10 0.15 0.20

    3 0.10 0.15 0.20 0.25

    4 0.15 0.20 0.25 0.30

    5 0.20 0.25 0.30 0.35

    6 0.25 0.30 0.35 0.40

    7 0.30 0.35 0.40 0.45

    8 0.35 0.40 0.45 0.50

    Source: The Guarantee Fee Rate and Condition Ministerial

    Regulation of 2008 (B.E. 2551)

    Currently, the Ministry of Finance of Thailand partially

    manages this fiscal risk by charging a fee for credit guarantees

    from state-owned enterprises. The fee pricing is around 0.01-

    0.5 %, depending on the credit rating grade4 and the loan

    4 The credit rating grade has 8 levels from grade 1 (the lowest risk) to

    grade 8 (the highest risk) that is evaluated by the PDMO every fiscal year.

  • Thammasat Review of Economic and Social Policy

    Volume 4, Number 2, July – December 2018

    10

    period, which reflects the level of credit risk of each state-

    owned enterprise. Nevertheless, the Ministry of Finance can

    use the SOEs credit rating grade to evaluate fiscal risk

    exposure from credit guarantee each fiscal year to take

    advantage of the value of such contingent liabilities and to

    determine the optimal value of credit guarantee for each SOE

    which the Ministry of Finance has the highest net benefit from

    credit guarantees, and the least risk from credit guarantees for

    the SOE in each fiscal year.

    Credit Risk of State-owned Enterprises

    2.1. Credit risk from government credit guarantee

    A financial instrument that is similar to government credit

    guarantees are bank loans. The credit risk of bank loans

    consists of three components, Exposure at default (EAD), Loss

    given default (LGD), and Probability of default (PD). Then,

    the magnitude of credit risk from credit guarantees is a

    multiplied result of EAD, LGD, and PD (Naksakul, 2006;

    Public Debt Management Office, 2014).

    In the case of government credit guarantees, EADs are the

    risk of disbursement that can be estimated from the value of

    guaranteed loans outstanding, while LGDs are risk in

    collateral value that can be estimated from a proportion of loss

    value after recovery from collateral that is equal to one since

    no collateral is required in this case. So, the variable that must

    be estimated is the probability of default or default risk.

    2.2. Simulated default for state-owned enterprises

    Default events are important data for estimating the

    probability of default. Standard & Poor’s Global Rating (2017)

  • Thammasat Review of Economic and Social Policy

    Volume 4, Number 2, July – December 2018

    11

    and the Bank of Thailand (2016) define "default event" in the

    general case as the event in which "the debtor or the counter-

    party cannot pay back the loan principal or interest on the due

    date contained in the original terms of a debt issue". However,

    in practice, when referring to sovereign debt, including

    government, state-owned enterprises, and other government

    agency debt, both in the form of loan and bond, default events

    never occur when considering the definition of default in the

    general case. Especially in the case of Thailand if the state-

    owned enterprise fails to pay the loan principal or interest on

    the due date, the Ministry of Finance will give assistance such

    as finding a new source of funds to repay original debts,

    according to financial market conditions and financial status

    of state-owned enterprises at that time.

    Because of the special characteristics of SOE debt, it is

    necessary to define a new default event as applied to SOEs to

    calculated their PD. Default events for state-owned enterprises

    are defined in this article according to Public Debt

    Management Office (2014) which defined SOEs default

    events as “when their liabilities greater than their assets in a

    year, when they have EBITDA5 negative for three consecutive

    years, when they received a credit rating grade as 8 in a year,

    or when they received a credit rating grade as 7 for three

    consecutive years.” Those conditions of the Public Debt

    Management Office (2014) apply only to the non-financial

    state-owned enterprise 6 ; none of the financial state-owned

    enterprise have performance that meet these conditions.

    5 EBITDA is Earnings before Interest, Taxes, Depreciation and

    Amortization that calculated in the following manner: EBITDA =

    Operating Profit + Depreciation Expense + Amortization Expense. 6 The total number of state-owned enterprises that are given credit rating

    by the Public Debt Management Office in each fiscal year is 20 SOEs,

    including 16 non-financial institutions and 4 financial institutions.

  • Thammasat Review of Economic and Social Policy

    Volume 4, Number 2, July – December 2018

    12

    Therefore, the Public Debt Management Office (2014) can

    estimate default probabilities only for non-financial SOEs.

    To resolve that limitation to estimate all types of SOE’s

    default probabilities, consider the characteristics of sovereign

    debt. The Standard & Poor’s Global Rating (2017) defines a

    default for sovereign debt as “when they fail to pay scheduled

    debt service on the due date or tenders an exchange offer of

    new debt with less favorable terms than the original issue, or

    when their notes or bonds are converted into a new currency

    of less than the equivalent face value.” The default definition

    of Standard & Poor’s Global Rating (2017) focuses on the

    characteristic of the loan agreement, not the SOE’s

    performance like the default definition of the Public Debt

    Management Office (2014). Thus, focusing on the

    characteristics of a loan agreement is more appropriate to

    define SOE’s default event.

    Therefore, to properly define default events for Thailand’s

    SOEs, consider S&P Global Rating’s default condition with a

    framework for public debt management of the Ministry of

    Finance of Thailand, in the case of state-owned enterprises. A

    framework for public debt management found that the type of

    SOE’s debt management, which meets the S&P Global

    Rating’s default condition, is debt management with rollover

    method7. Thus, this article defined a new definition of default

    for SOE (Simulated default) as "when the SOE either issues

    new bonds to repay original bond with less-favorable terms

    than the original bond or negotiates with the bank creditors a

    rescheduling of principal or interest at less-favorable terms

    than in the original loan."

    However, with limited access to SOE insights data, i.e.,

    we did not have more details about the payment terms of the

    pair of loan, which rollover or issue new bonds to repay

    7 The SOE issue new bonds to repay original bond

  • Thammasat Review of Economic and Social Policy

    Volume 4, Number 2, July – December 2018

    13

    original bonds. So, this article will use default condition as

    “when the SOE manages its debt with rollover” to be a proxy

    for our default condition as defined above.

    Debt data on SOEs during the fiscal years 2009-2014 were

    used in this study; it was found that this period has data on 110

    SOEs where their credit was rated by Thailand's public debt

    management office. Among them, it was found that there were

    4,087 contracts for loans and bonds that were outstanding, and

    restructured debt as rollover totaled 355 contracts that

    presented in Table 2.8

    Table 2. Number of SOE’s loan and bond that restructure

    debt as rollover during the years 2009-2014

    Fiscal

    year

    The number of

    state-owned

    enterprises that

    PDMO's credit

    rated

    The number of

    loan and bond

    outstanding

    The number of loan

    and bond that

    restructure debt as

    a rollover

    - Enterprises contracts contracts

    2009 19 658 47

    2010 17 705 54

    2011 16 672 5

    2012 18 683 95

    2013 20 690 85

    2014 20 679 69

    Total 110 4,087 355

    8 In practice, the public debt management office did not collect data about

    payment structure between pairs of loan or bond that restructure debt as

    rollover and their original issue, so this study uses the loan and bond that

    restructure debt as rollover every case as a simulated default event instead

    of the new definition of default for SOE which mentioned above. As a

    result, this estimation will give a conservative probability of default.

  • Thammasat Review of Economic and Social Policy

    Volume 4, Number 2, July – December 2018

    14

    Note: This data, includes both non-financial institutions and

    financial institutions, and their debt, including all currencies.

    2.3. Probability of default for state-owned enterprises

    The nature of SOE debt is low default portfolios, which

    limits default events and thus general estimation models

    cannot estimate PD in the case of no default events occurring

    and may yield an underestimation of credit risk. So, the

    estimation of probability of default for SOE in this study will

    use the model that is appropriate for SOE debt characteristics,

    which is the Hybrid model of Roengpitya (2012). The Hybrid

    model was based on two existing estimation approaches,

    including the most prudent estimation of Pluto and Tasche

    (2006) and the maximum likelihood of Forrest (2005). In this

    study, we use the Hybrid model with forward method to

    estimate PD and assume that there is no asset correlation

    between SOEs. The PD estimates are split between SOEs that

    are non-financial institutions and SOEs that are financial institutions.

    First of all, let the general likelihood function of N rating

    grade be defined as ℒ(𝑝1,…,𝑝𝑁) = ∏ ℒ(𝑝𝑖)𝑁𝑖=1 , where 𝑝1,…,𝑝𝑁

    are the PD estimates for each rating grade. Let 𝑖 =1 be the lowest risk grade and 𝑖 = 𝑁 be the highest risk grade. In the non-financial institutions case, 𝑖 =1, 2, 3, … , 7 9 , while financial institutions rank from, 𝑖 =3, 4, 5, 6.10 Then, using the concept of the most prudent to collapse the rating grade –

    assuming that the N rating grade satisfy the rank order

    9 Total of PDMO's credit rating grade is eight grades, but this estimation

    ignores grade 8 because this grade never rated to any state-owned

    enterprise. 10 During the fiscal year 2009-2014, state-owned financial institutions

    received a PDMO's credit rating in grade 3-6 out of the total grade (8

    grades).

  • Thammasat Review of Economic and Social Policy

    Volume 4, Number 2, July – December 2018

    15

    requirement, then we must have 𝑝1 ≤ 𝑝2 ≤ 𝑝3 ≤ ⋯ ≤ 𝑝𝑁 . And to find the upper bound of 𝑝1, the most prudent implies that the condition is 𝑝1 = 𝑝2 = 𝑝3 = ⋯ = 𝑝𝑁 = 𝑝 –in the general likelihood function, and we get the new likelihood

    function:

    ℒ(�⃗�𝑖) = 𝑝∑ 𝑘𝑗

    𝑁𝑗=𝑖 (1 − 𝑝)∑ (𝑛𝑗−𝑘𝑗)

    𝑁𝑗=𝑖 (1)

    Next, let ℒ̅ = 𝑒(−0.5⋅𝜒2(∝,𝑁))

    ∙ ℒ(𝑀𝐿𝐸) where

    ℒ(𝑀𝐿𝐸) = ∏ ℒ(𝑝𝑀𝐿𝐸𝑖 )𝑁𝑖=1 is the maximum likelihood value

    that is evaluated at the estimated PD from the maximum

    likelihood method and set confident level is 0.95 and degree

    of freedom is N.11 The hybrid forward method begins with

    solving for the best grade PD first so 𝑝1 solves

    (𝑝1)∑ 𝑘𝑗

    𝑁𝑗=1 (1 − 𝑝1)

    ∑ (𝑛𝑗−𝑘𝑗)𝑁𝑗=1 = ℒ̅ (2)

    The PD estimates for other rating grades will be solved

    through the following iterative process. The estimated PD for

    grade 𝑖 = 2, …, N is 𝑝𝑖 that solves

    𝓛(�⃗�𝑖) = (𝑝𝑖)∑ 𝑘𝑗

    𝑁𝑗=𝑖 (1 − 𝑝𝑖)

    ∑ (𝑛𝑗−𝑘𝑗)𝑁𝑗=𝑖 =

    ℒ̅

    ∏ ℒ(𝑝𝑀𝐿𝐸𝑙 )𝑖−1𝑙=1

    (3)

    This model can estimate the probability of default for both

    financial and non-financial institution presented in Table 3 and

    Table 4. This study can resolve previous limitations in studies

    that only estimated PD for non-financial institutions because

    of the new definition of simulated default for state-owned

    11 The degree of freedom in case of non-financial institution and financial

    institution is 7 and 4 respectively, according to the results of the credit

    rating grade of the Public Debt Management Office in the past fiscal year

    2009-2014.

  • Thammasat Review of Economic and Social Policy

    Volume 4, Number 2, July – December 2018

    16

    enterprise and new model that is more appropriate with low

    default portfolio than the earlier model.

    Table 3. The estimated PD for Non-financial state-owned

    enterprises (Percentage)

    Model Hybrid forward MLE The most

    prudent

    Rating grade (i) 𝒑𝒊𝑵𝑩 𝒑𝑴𝑳𝑬

    𝒊 𝒑𝑴𝑷𝒊

    1 1.8202 2.0548 8.3220

    2 2.1529 1.2987 8.6504

    3 2.0951 3.8462 9.0805

    4 10.4135 7.0485 10.7972

    5 14.6874 12.6984 11.9110

    6 15.2261 10.6816 11.7999

    7 22.8343 14.8876 14.8876

    In addition, this study found that the estimated PD for both

    financial and non-financial are ranked by credit rating grade

    (the rank ordering property), except the 3rd rating grade PD of

    non-financial. However, the Hybrid forward PD (𝑝𝑖𝑁𝐵) has

    failed to rank order condition less than the maximum

    likelihood PD (𝑝𝑀𝐿𝐸𝑖 ).

    In case of financial institutions, estimation of PD found

    that all the Hybrid forward PD are ranked by credit rating

    grade and the Hybrid forward model can estimate PD in rating

    grade 6. The maximum likelihood model and the most prudent

    model cannot estimate this because there is no default event

    occurring at this rating grade. This is to be expected as it is

    characteristic of Low default portfolios, hence the Hybrid

  • Thammasat Review of Economic and Social Policy

    Volume 4, Number 2, July – December 2018

    17

    forward model can solve this characteristic of Low default

    portfolios.

    Table 4. The estimated PD for Financial state-owned

    enterprises (Percentage)

    Model Hybrid

    forward MLE

    The most

    prudent

    Rating grade (i) 𝒑𝒊𝑩 𝒑𝑴𝑳𝑬

    𝒊 𝒑𝑴𝑷𝒊

    3 12.0480 5.3571 12.0301

    4 12.5684 7.4510 12.5337

    5 19.9955 15.3846 15.1951

    6 54.5415 n.a. n.a.

    Note: During the fiscal year 2009-2014, state-owned financial

    institutions received a PDMO's credit rating in grade 3-6 out of the

    total grade (8 grades).

    It should be noted that when we compare the estimated

    PD for financial and non-financial SOEs at the same credit

    rating grade, it was found that the financial institutions were

    more likely to default on debt than the non-financial

    institutions (see Figure 1), in spite of the fact that financial

    institutions should have a lower default. That result may be

    due to the data used during 2009 and 2014 which experienced

    many changes in government policies and interventions, such

    as intervention in the Bank for Agriculture and Agricultural

    Cooperatives and Government Housing Bank. Even these

    policies have ended, the liabilities and obligations from

    implementing these policies remain with these banks since the

    majority of loans and bonds that rollover debts restructure are

    from these banks and these debts was from government

    projects.

  • Thammasat Review of Economic and Social Policy

    Volume 4, Number 2, July – December 2018

    18

    Figure 1. The estimated PD of financial and non-financial

    state-owned enterprise

    Thus, these estimated PD reflect the magnitude of the

    credit risk of each state-owned enterprise which are important

    data to risk management process of the Ministry of Finance in

    the next section.

    Credit Guarantee Optimization

    3.1. The objectives of government credit guarantees and risk

    exposure

    Government credit guarantees to state-owned enterprises

    create both benefits and fiscal risk for the Ministry of Finance.

    Government credit guarantees were used as a fiscal tool for

    financially supporting SOE investment in the production of

    public goods and services and infrastructure investment.

    1.82 2.15 2.1010.41

    14.69

    15.23

    22.83

    12.05 12.5720.00

    54.54

    1 2 3 4 5 6 7

    rating grade

    non-bank bank

  • Thammasat Review of Economic and Social Policy

    Volume 4, Number 2, July – December 2018

    19

    Meanwhile, this government transaction creates a fiscal risk

    and obligation to the Ministry of Finance as the guarantor.

    The Public Debt Management Office (PDMO), the main

    player in public debt management, should manage the fiscal

    risk from government guarantees. Risk management may be

    within the design of the guarantee system, including the

    optimal credit guarantees, which the PDMO stands to have a

    maximum benefit from while fulfilling the goals of the

    government credit guarantee, while also experiencing

    minimum fiscal risk, under the relevant legal framework.

    Based on portfolio selection theory, the expected utility of

    the investor is a function that depends on the expected return

    and risk of investing. However, the PDMO is a government

    agency that is not intended for profit, but it has the primary

    purpose of managing public debt of the country. So, the net

    benefit from credit guarantees of PDMO depends on achieving

    the goals of government credit guarantees to SOEs against the

    fiscal risk of this operation, which can be characterized as

    𝑛𝑒𝑡 𝑏𝑒𝑛𝑒𝑓𝑖𝑡 = 𝑎𝑐ℎ𝑖𝑒𝑣𝑖𝑛𝑔 𝑡ℎ𝑒 𝑜𝑏𝑗𝑒𝑐𝑡𝑖𝑣𝑒𝑠 − 𝑓𝑖𝑠𝑐𝑎𝑙 𝑟𝑖𝑠𝑘(4)

    Consider the goals of government credit guarantees in

    Thailand: one is to provide SOEs with access to finance at a

    lower financial cost (loan interest rate) and another one is to

    support those that have high credit risk to get access to finance

    because they can benefit from the government’s high credit

    standing. The fiscal risk from government credit guarantees is

    the credit risk of SOEs that can be estimated in the form of the

    value of the net expected loss from credit guarantees. Thus, the

    net benefit from credit guarantees of PDMO is as the following

    equation:

  • Thammasat Review of Economic and Social Policy

    Volume 4, Number 2, July – December 2018

    20

    𝐵(𝑋𝑗) = {[∑ (𝑅𝑗𝑁𝐺 − 𝑅𝑗

    𝐺)𝑋𝑗20𝑗=1 ] + ∑ 𝑋𝑗

    20𝑗=1 } − {∑ 𝑃𝐷𝑗𝑋𝑗

    20𝑗=1 −

    ∑ 𝑟𝑗20𝑗=1 𝑋𝑗}(5)

    Where 𝑋𝑗 is guaranteed loan of state-owned enterprise 𝑗;

    𝑗 =1, 2, 3,…, 20. Achieving the goals of government credit guarantees to SOEs is (i) to provide state-owned enterprises

    with access to finance at a lower financial cost that is evaluated

    by the spread of interest rate between non-government

    guaranteed loan and government guaranteed loan (𝑅𝑗𝑁𝐺 − 𝑅𝑗

    𝐺)

    and (ii) to support those that have high credit risk to get access

    to finance that is evaluated by the amount of guaranteed loan

    of each state-owned enterprise (∑ 𝑋𝑗20𝑗=1 ). The net expected

    loss from credit guarantees is the value of expected loss after

    recovery by the total value of guarantee fee. The expected loss

    from credit guarantees is the sum of multiple of the probability

    of default (𝑃𝐷𝑗 )12 by guaranteed loan (𝑋𝑗 ) of state-owned

    enterprise 𝑗 . Income from government guarantee fees is a multiple of the fee rate (𝑟𝑗)

    13 by guaranteed loan (𝑋𝑗) of the

    state-owned enterprise 𝑗.

    3.2. Laws and regulations

    Considering the optimal guaranteed loan of each state-

    owned enterprise (𝑋𝑗∗), the value of guaranteed loan at which

    the Public Debt Management Office receives a maximum the

    net benefit from credit guarantees is subject to the relevant

    laws and regulations. The relevant laws and regulations are as

    follows:

    12 Use the estimated PD from the previous section. 13 The fee rate is set by the Guarantee Fee Rate and Condition Ministerial

    Regulation of 2008 (B.E. 2551), that fee rate varies by the credit rating

    grade and loan period for each state-owned enterprise.

  • Thammasat Review of Economic and Social Policy

    Volume 4, Number 2, July – December 2018

    21

    (i) A quasi-budget constraint: in each fiscal year the Ministry of Finance can guarantee no more than 20% of

    the annual budget that is in force at that time14. This can

    be expressed as ∑ 𝑋𝑗 ≤ 0.2𝐴20𝑗=1 where 𝐴 is the annual

    budget that is in force at fiscal year 2014.

    (ii) Fiscal Sustainability Framework: in each fiscal year the government can generate public debt outstanding no

    more than 60% of GDP. This can be expressed as

    ∑ 𝑋𝑗 + 𝐵 ≤ 0.6 𝐺𝐷𝑃20𝑗=1 where 𝐵 public debt is

    outstanding at the end of fiscal year 2013 and the

    forecast of other public debt in fiscal year 2014.

    (iii) Exchange rate risk requirement: in each fiscal year, the proportion of foreign debt to export income must not be

    more than 9%15. This can be expressed as ∑ 𝑋𝑗𝑓 +20𝑗=1

    𝐶 ≤ 0.09 𝐸𝑋𝑃 where 𝑋𝑗𝑓

    is the value of guaranteed

    loan in foreign currency of state-owned enterprise 𝑗 and 𝐶 is another foreign currency debt outstanding of the government at the end of the fiscal year 2013.

    (iv) Leverage ratio: the Ministry of Finance can provide credit guarantees to each state-owned enterprise an

    amount (𝑋𝑗) that, after summing with that SOE's other

    debt (𝐷𝑗), does not exceed three times the capital of the

    SOE (𝐸𝑗). In the case where the SOE is a Public Limited

    Company (𝑗 = 9) the amount must not exceed six times the capital of the SOE, and similarly for SOEs which are

    14 Section 28 of Public Debt Management Act of 2005 (B.E. 2548) 15 The Regulation of the Ministry of Finance on Public Debt Management

    of 2006 (B.E. 2549)

  • Thammasat Review of Economic and Social Policy

    Volume 4, Number 2, July – December 2018

    22

    financial institutions ( 𝑗 = 17, 18, 19, 20). This can be expressed as 𝐷𝑗 + 𝑋𝑗 ≤ 3𝐸𝑗 ; 𝑗 = 9 and 𝐷𝑗 + 𝑋𝑗 ≤ 6𝐸𝑗 ;

    and 𝑗 = 17, 18, 19, 20 respectively.

    Furthermore, the optimal guaranteed loan also considers

    the demand for loan of each state-owned enterprise in a fiscal

    year that can be expressed as 𝑋𝑗 ≤ 𝐿𝑑𝑗 where 𝐿𝑑𝑗 is the

    demand for loan of state-owned enterprise 𝑗 in fiscal year 2014.

    3.3. Optimization for government credit guarantees

    The study of the optimization of credit guarantees of state-

    owned enterprise using linear programming models is divided

    into two groups: maximizing the net benefit from credit

    guarantee, and minimizing the net expected loss from credit

    guarantee. This optimization found that (i) subject to all the

    relevant laws and regulations, and demand for fund of each

    state-owned enterprise in that time, the results from

    maximizing the net benefit and the results from minimizing

    the net expected loss from credit guarantee are similar in terms

    of optimal guaranteed loan distribution, the value of the net

    benefit, and the value of the net expected loss from credit

    guarantees (models 1.1 and 2.1). In addition, (ii) adding the total value of guaranteed loan, which happened in fiscal year

    2014 as constraints of the optimization, it was found that high

    risk enterprises have been reduced to a guaranteed amount, if

    considered with a focus on the net benefit of PDMO, while

    some enterprises are not guaranteed, if considered with a focus

    on the net expected loss value (models 1.2 and 2.2).

  • Thammasat Review of Economic and Social Policy

    Volume 4, Number 2, July – December 2018

    23

    Table 5. The optimal values from credit guarantee

    optimization

    Model Model 1.1 Model 1.2 Model 2.1 Model 2.2

    Method Maximize Maximize Minimize Minimize

    Objective

    function

    Net

    Benefit

    Net

    Benefit

    Net

    Expected

    loss

    Net

    Expected

    loss

    Constraints ≤ ≤ = =

    1. Budget

    constraints I √ √ √ √

    2. Budget

    constraints

    II

    √ √ √ √

    3. Exchange rate

    risk

    constraints

    √ √ √ √

    4. Leverage

    constraints √ √ √ √

    5. Demand for

    loan √ √ √ √

    6. Total of credit

    guarantee - √ - √

    Optimal values (Million Baht)

    Guaranteed

    loan

    SOE1 =

    751.45

    SOE1 =

    751.45

    SOE1 =

    751.45

    SOE1 =

    751.45

    SOE5 =

    8,810.00

    SOE5 =

    8,810.00

    SOE5 =

    8,810.00

    SOE5 =

    8,810.00

    SOE7 =

    30,033.13

    SOE7 =

    15,790.15

    SOE7 =

    30,033.13

    SOE7 =

    30,033.13

    SOE8 =

    20,539.94

    SOE8 =

    20,539.94

    SOE8 =

    20,539.94

    SOE8 =

    20,539.94

    SOE10 =

    3,000.00

    SOE10 =

    3,000.00

    SOE10 =

    3,000.00

    SOE10 =

    3,000.00

    SOE11 =

    10,532.99

    SOE11 =

    10,532.99

    SOE11 =

    10,532.99

    SOE11 =

    290.00

  • Thammasat Review of Economic and Social Policy

    Volume 4, Number 2, July – December 2018

    24

    Table 5. (Continued) Model Model 1.1 Model 1.2 Model 2.1 Model 2.2 Optimal values (Million Baht)

    Guaranteed

    loan

    SOE13 =

    3,000.00 SOE13 =

    3,000.00 SOE13 =

    3,000.00 -

    SOE16 =

    1,000.00 SOE16 =

    1,000.00 SOE16 =

    1,000.00 -

    SOE17 =

    285,360.90 SOE17 =285,360.90

    SOE17 =285,360.90

    SOE17 =285,360.90

    Total of credit

    guarantee 363,028.41 348,785.42 363,028.41 348,785.42

    Net benefit 320,228.76 309,046.31 320,228.76 306,578.97 Net expected

    loss 45,765.10 42,576.90 45,765.10 45,115.41

    Conclusion and Implication

    Estimation of default probability with the Hybrid Model

    found that the estimated PD for both financial and non-

    financial SOE is ranked by credit rating grade (the rank

    ordering property), except the 3rd rating grade PD of non-

    financial SOE. It should be noted that financial SOEs have a

    higher estimated PD than non-financial SOEs at the same

    rating grade despite the fact that financial institutions should

    perhaps have a lower default risk than non-financial

    institutions. However, data limitations must be acknowledged

    as the estimation of PD in this study used data over a period of

    six years, even if it is under the requirements specific for PD

    Estimation of the Bank of Thailand (2012) that require use of

    data of at least five years. In the future, a longer time series

    data of SOE debts may be used, and thus the estimated PD may

    be more consistent with financial theory, including satisfying

    the rank order condition and the financial institution PD less

    than the non-financial institution PD.

    Moreover, estimated PD in this article represents the size

    of the credit risk of each SOE's credit rating grade that

  • Thammasat Review of Economic and Social Policy

    Volume 4, Number 2, July – December 2018

    25

    increases by each rating grade exponentially, while the

    guarantee fee rate increases by each rating grade linearly. This

    is so despite the fact that, in financial theory, the guarantor

    should charge a guarantee fee equal to the default probability

    of each borrower to mitigate their risk exposure. This implies

    that the Public Debt Management Office just manages partial

    risk from a guarantee. However, in the case of SOEs, the

    Public Debt Management Office cannot charge a guarantee fee

    more than as prescribed in the Guarantee Fee Rate and

    Condition Ministerial Regulation of 2008 (B.E. 2551) and

    increasing the fee contradicts the goal of credit guarantee to

    SOE, which helps SOE to reach the financial source with a

    lower cost.

    Nevertheless, the Public Debt Management Office can use

    this estimated default probability to recognize size of credit

    risk from their credit guarantees to better manage risk, for

    example counter-guarantees funds. Moreover, estimated

    default probability can be used to enhance the efficiency of

    guarantee allocations by using PD as a criterion in the decision

    about the optimal value of guaranteed loans for each state-

    owned enterprise.

  • Thammasat Review of Economic and Social Policy

    Volume 4, Number 2, July – December 2018

    26

    References

    Bank of Thailand. (2012). Notification of the Bank of Thailand

    Re: Rule of Credit Risk Internal Ratings-Based

    Approach by Internal Ratings-Based Approach.

    Bangkok: Bank of Thailand.

    Bank of Thailand. (2016). Notification of the Bank of Thailand

    Re: Rules for Credit Ratings and Reserves Requirement

    of Financial Institutions. Bangkok: Bank of Thailand.

    Forrest, A. (2005). Likelihood Approaches to Low Default

    Portfolios. Discussion paper, Dunfermline Building

    Society, September 2005.

    International Monetary Fund. (2005). Government Guarantees

    and Fiscal Risk. Prepared by the Fiscal Affairs

    Department (In consultation with other departments).

    Approved by Ter-Minassian, Teresa.

    International Monetary Fund. (2016). Analyzing and

    managing fiscal risks-Best Practices.

    Naksakul, P. (2006). Credit Risk Models in Relation to Capital

    Reserve Framework of Financial Institutions. Bangkok:

    Bank of Thailand.

    Pluto, K., & Tasche, D. (2006). Estimating Probabilities of

    Default for Low Default Portfolios. In B. Engelmann &

    R. Rauhmeier (Eds.), The Basel II Risk Parameters:

    Estimation, Validation, and Stress Testing (pp. 79–103).

    Berlin, Heidelberg: Springer Berlin Heidelberg.

    https://doi.org/10.1007/3-540-33087-9_5

    Public Debt Management Office. (2014). Improvement of Credit Rating model for State-owned Enterprises.

    Bangkok. Ministry of Finance, Thailand.

  • Thammasat Review of Economic and Social Policy

    Volume 4, Number 2, July – December 2018

    27

    Roengpitya, R. (2012). Proposal of New Hybrid PD

    Estimation Models for The Low Default Portfolio

    (LDPs), Empirical Comparisons and Policy

    Implications. Discussion paper. Bangkok: Bank of

    Thailand.

    Standard & Poor's Global Rating. (2017). Default, Transition,

    and Recovery: 2016 Annual Sovereign Default Study

    and Rating Transitions

  • Thammasat Review of Economic and Social Policy

    Volume 4, Number 2, July – December 2018

    28

    Investigating relationship between Government

    Spending and Economic Growth: Public

    Spending and long-run GDP level

    Kritchasorn Jarupasin*

    Plan and Policy Analyst

    Office of the National Economic and Social Development

    Board

    Office of the Prime Minister

    Thailand

    [email protected]

    * The contents of this article do not reflect the author’s affiliation. This

    article is a part of the author’s doctoral thesis submitted to the University

    of Exeter. The author thanks Professor Gareth D. Myles, Professor Ben

    Zissimos, Professor Norman Gemmell and Dr. Xiaohui Zhang for their

    kind advice and support during his doctoral study. Sincere gratitude must

    also be extended to the Royal Thai Government for the research grant. All

    remaining errors rest with the author.

  • Thammasat Review of Economic and Social Policy

    Volume 4, Number 2, July – December 2018

    29

    ABSTRACT

    This study investigates the relationship between public

    spending and long-run GDP per capita. While most fiscal-

    growth studies put emphasis on the relationship in the public-

    policy endogenous growth model, this analysis allows for

    Solow-type transitional dynamics where the effects of fiscal

    policy can be persistent. Moreover, the long-run and short-run

    effects of fiscal changes are identified separately in this

    analysis using the groups of countries comprising 38 countries

    (17 developing countries and 21 high-income OECD

    countries). Our results show that an increase in total spending

    which is financed by non-distortionary taxes only enhances the

    level of GDP per capita in high-income OECD countries. With

    a given level of total spending, increases in the shares of

    healthcare and general public services spending can improve

    the levels of GDP per capita in developing countries. On the

    other hand, increasing the share of education spending in a

    high-income OECD country is conducive to increasing the

    level of GDP per capita

    Keywords: Fiscal policy, Economic growth, Public

    expenditure, Government

    JEL Classification: E62, H50, O23, O47

  • Thammasat Review of Economic and Social Policy

    Volume 4, Number 2, July – December 2018

    30

    1. Introduction

    The fiscal-growth studies in a number of studies focus on

    the public-policy endogenous growth model. In those studies,

    permanent growth effects of fiscal changes are analysed

    without transitional dynamics. The analysis of fiscal policy

    impacts in this study allows for Solow-type transitional

    dynamics, but the effects of fiscal policy may be persistent

    according to the framework proposed by Gemmell, Kneller

    and Sanz (2016).

    Gemmell et al.’s (2016) study was motivated by the recent

    fiscal stimulus enacted after 2009 in order to counteract the

    global financial crisis. Governments’ spending choices in

    these short-term packages are partially influenced by their

    ambitions to comply with long-term growth objectives. With

    this policy design, there are two different questions to be

    addressed: how forceful is the evidence that long-run income

    levels or growth rates react to changes in public spending, and

    if they do, which expenditure types produce most considerable

    impacts? In the following section, we attempt to respond to

    these questions similar to Gemmell et al. (2016) by looking at

    both developing countries and high-income OECD countries.

    2. Literature review

    In terms of the period of study, recent studies on fiscal

    policy and long-run size of economy (either level of GDP or

    rate of growth) include recent data, especially the Acosta-

    Ormaechea and Morozumi’s (2013) study which uses data

    from 1970 to 2010. Other studies (Afonso & Jalles, 2014;

    Arnold et al., 2011; Gemmell, Kneller & Sanz, 2011; Gemmell

    et al., 2016; Xing, 2012) also cover periods from the 1970s

    until 2010. Ojede and Yamarik (2012) focus on an earlier

    period; 1967 to 2008.

  • Thammasat Review of Economic and Social Policy

    Volume 4, Number 2, July – December 2018

    31

    In terms of the sets of fiscal variables used, these studies

    either put emphasis on tax policy (Arnold et al., 2011; Ojede

    & Yamarik, 2012; Xing, 2012), public spending (Gemmell et

    al., 2016), or both types of variables at once (Afonso & Jalles,

    2014; Gemmell et al., 2011). In addition, Afonso and Jalles

    (2014) look at both functional and economic classes of fiscal

    variables according to the Government Finance Statistics

    (GFS) definitions provided by the International Monetary

    Fund (IMF).

    As well as being categorised by their focus (on revenue

    and/or expenditure), the effects of fiscal changes can be

    classified by their impact on the size of economy (short-run or

    long-run impact). Some of these studies focus only on

    permanent growth effects (Acosta-Ormaechea & Morozumi,

    2013; Afonso & Jalles, 2014), while others distinguish

    between the long-run and short-run impacts of changes in

    fiscal variables (Arnold et al., 2011; Gemmell et al., 2011;

    Gemmell et al., 2016; Ojede & Yamarik, 2012; Xing, 2012).

    Our study pays specific attention to the latter set of studies.

    While many studies that differentiate between the long-

    run and short-run effects of fiscal change capture the size of an

    economy by using the growth rate of GDP or the growth rate

    of GDP per capita, Arnold et al. (2011), Xing (2012) and

    Gemmell et al. (2016) use the level of per capita GDP.

    Gemmell et al. (2016) claim that using this specification is

    advantageous since it allows the degree of persistence in GDP

    growth responses to be identified by the data, rather than by

    using a functional form incorporating permanent effects. For

    this reason, our study will focus on the impact on level of GDP

    per capita.

    The three studies (Arnold et al., 2011; Gemmell et al.,

    2016; Xing, 2012) referred to above use cross-country data,

    whereas Ojede and Yamarik (2012) evaluate the growth

    effects of tax policy at state level. Instead of investigating the

  • Thammasat Review of Economic and Social Policy

    Volume 4, Number 2, July – December 2018

    32

    growth effects of fiscal policy, Lamartina and Zaghini (2011)

    test the validity of Wagner’s law in high-income OECD

    countries.

    Although there are differences in the model specifications

    for investigating change in fiscal composition and their effects

    on either the level of GDP or economic growth, the findings

    are, to a certain degree, harmoniously aligned. We go on to

    discuss previous findings, econometric methods, variables

    included in the model, the role played by budget constraint,

    and other econometric issues in these studies. 2.1. Previous findings

    This strand of literature, like the permanent growth effects

    of fiscal change studies in endogenous growth model, mainly

    considers high-income countries and, more specifically, high-

    income OECD countries (Arnold et al., 2011; Gemmell et al.,

    2011; Gemmell et al., 2016; Xing, 2012). Other studies, e.g.

    Acosta-Ormaechea and Morozumi (2013) and Afonso and

    Jalles (2014), consider a wider set of countries.

    Some studies find the reallocation of fiscal composition to

    be robustly related to long-run growth or GDP level, while

    others do not. In order to understand this incongruity clearly,

    we need to take several aspects of the preceding results into

    consideration. Firstly, there are two different types of fiscal

    variables being considered, namely public expenditure and

    public revenue. Secondly, we need to consider the way in

    which an increase in public expenditure is financed. We

    previously refer to this as an implicit financing element. For

    example, Gemmell et al. (2016) find that an increase in total

    spending enhances GDP per capita level in the long run when

    financed by non-distortionary taxes. Thirdly, fiscal variable

    classifications can be interpreted differently when we analyse

    the impacts of changes in these variables on GDP or growth of

  • Thammasat Review of Economic and Social Policy

    Volume 4, Number 2, July – December 2018

    33

    GDP. This depends on the aspect of fiscal change we need to

    evaluate in order to assess its impact. The following

    paragraphs summarise the key findings of the papers

    mentioned earlier.

    Arnold et al. (2011) find that shifting taxes on income

    towards consumption and immovable property enhances long-

    run GDP per capita. In particular, increasing revenue by

    raising current taxes on immovable property and consumption

    is least harmful to growth. Arnold et al.’s (2011) findings are

    supported by Xing (2012), suggesting that shifting tax revenue

    away from corporate income, personal income, and

    consumption taxes, and towards property taxes is associated

    with a higher level of income per capita in the long run. When

    investigating state-level data, Ojede and Yamarik (2012)

    obtained different results from Arnold et al. (2011) and Xing

    (2012). They found that increases in sales and property taxes

    reduce long-run real income growth.

    Gemmell et al. (2011) observe that the growth effects of

    fiscal policy in the short run appear to persist. Although some

    fiscal variables only have transitory effects, others might have

    persistent growth effects. However, the positive growth effects

    associated with productive spending are often counteracted by

    the negative effects of tax changes.

    Gemmell et al. (2016) raise awareness of the significance

    of financing methods for increasing any type of public

    expenditure when determining long-run GDP level. By using

    pooled mean group estimators (PMG) with contemporaneous

    correlation, they find robust long-run positive effects on GDP

    per capita levels for reallocating total spending towards

    transportation and communication, and education spending.

    In contrast, Afonso and Jalles (2014) find that an increase

    in government revenue has no significant impact on growth.

    Moreover, the coefficients of government expenditures appear

    to have highly significant negative signs.

  • Thammasat Review of Economic and Social Policy

    Volume 4, Number 2, July – December 2018

    34

    Acosta-Ormaechea and Morozumi (2013) find that an

    increase in education spending offset by a fall in social

    spending seems to be robustly related to higher growth rates.

    These results also hold true at the general government level.

    Their results also show that education spending promotes

    growth as well as public capital does in the long run.

    2.2. Improvement of econometric methods

    Recent developments in data collection have improved

    the availability of data, so it has become possible to investigate

    the compositional change of public spending and its impact on

    long-run GDP per capita level or growth.

    From above reason, the updated data can be used under

    the assumptions of short-run heterogeneity and long-run

    homogeneity. This econometric method proposed by Pesaran

    Shin, and Smith (1999) is pooled mean group estimators

    (PMG). It is a compromise between the fixed effects model

    and the mean group estimator (MG). While intercept, short-

    run coefficients and error variances are allowed to differ across

    groups, the long-run coefficients are equal. This method has

    been analysed by Arnold et al. (2011), Gemmell et al. (2011),

    Ojede and Yamarik (2012), Xing (2012), and Gemmell et al.

    (2016).

    2.3. Variables included in recent studies

    Dependent variable

    The choice of dependent variable is distinctly separable

    between growth of GDP and level of GDP. While most studies

    use the growth rate of either GDP or GDP per capita, Arnold

    et al. (2011) use a change in log of GDP per capita and a

    change in log of total factor productivity (TFP) of a given firm.

    Similarly, Xing (2012) also uses a change in log of real GDP

  • Thammasat Review of Economic and Social Policy

    Volume 4, Number 2, July – December 2018

    35

    per capita as a dependent variable. While Gemmell et al.

    (2011) use a change in the growth rate of GDP in one of their

    studies, the level of GDP per capita is employed by Gemmell

    et al. (2016). The dependent variable in Ojede and Yamarik

    (2012) is the change in growth rate of real income.

    It is important to note that all of these studies (Arnold et

    al., 2011; Gemmell et al., 2011; Gemmell et al., 2016; Ojede

    & Yamarik, 2012; Xing, 2012) estimate the results with an

    error correction model. When interpreting the results, we need

    to refer back to the equations in terms of the autoregressive

    distributed lag model: i.e. the long-run level of GDP per capita

    impact from fiscal change is analysed in Xing (2012), rather

    than the growth effect (change in log of real GDP per capita).

    Afonso and Jalles (2014) use the real growth rate of GDP

    per capita, and Acosta-Ormaechea and Morozumi (2013)

    select the growth of output per capita.

    Fiscal variables

    Different classes of expenditure and revenue can be

    considered. Two broad categories of each type of fiscal

    variables are included, following the example of Kneller,

    Bleaney and Gemmell (1999) and based on the framework

    proposed by Barro (1990); namely productive expenditure,

    unproductive expenditure, distortionary taxes and non-

    distortionary taxes. We will now describe some of the fiscal

    variables included in recent studies.

    Arnold et al. (2011) focus on tax structures which can be

    classified mainly into income taxes, consumption taxes and

    property taxes. Ojede and Yamarik (2012) and Xing (2012)

    also emphasise on the composition of tax revenues.

    Gemmell et al. (2011) use broad categories of revenue and

    expenditure: productive expenditure, non-productive

    expenditure, distortionary taxes and non-distortionary taxes.

  • Thammasat Review of Economic and Social Policy

    Volume 4, Number 2, July – December 2018

    36

    Gemmell et al. (2016) utilise broad categories of revenue

    similar to those used by Gemmell et al. (2011) and functional

    classifications of public expenditure, namely transportation

    and communication, education, health and housing etc.

    Afonso and Jalles (2014) focus on both aggregate levels

    and GFS (Government Finance Statistics) classifications of

    fiscal variables. This includes functional and economic

    classifications of both government expenditure and revenue.

    Acosta-Ormaechea and Morozumi (2013) also look at both

    economic and functional classifications of public expenditure.

    Economic classifications include the compensation of

    employees, other expenses and the net acquisition of non-

    financial assets. Functional classifications include defence,

    transportation and communication, health, education, and

    social protection expenditures.

    Non-fiscal control variables

    A number of factors can be used as non-fiscal control

    variables. The criteria used to decide which variable should be

    chosen are highly dependent on the type of question or

    particular model being investigated. Since using pooled mean

    group estimators limits the number of control variables due to

    a decrease in the degree of freedom, this strand of literature

    often only includes a few non-fiscal control variables in

    analyses.

    Arnold et al. (2011) and Xing (2012) include investment

    rate, human capital and population growth. Gemmell et al.

    (2011, 2016) use investment rate and employment growth.

    Like Gemmell et al. (2011, 2016), Ojede and Yamarik (2012)

    include growth in private employment and private investment

    share in their set of non-fiscal control variables.

    While Afonso and Jalles (2014) use population growth,

    investment, education and trade openness, Acosta-Ormaechea

  • Thammasat Review of Economic and Social Policy

    Volume 4, Number 2, July – December 2018

    37

    and Morozumi (2013) include initial GDP per capita and initial

    human capital in their set of non-fiscal control variables.

    2.4. The role of government budget constraint

    Government budget constraint needs to be considered in

    order to avoid the production of invalid results due to biases

    occurring as a result of not including both revenue and

    spending variables in the same equation. Recent studies take

    government budget constraint into account while avoiding

    perfect multicollinearity in accordance with the specification

    in Kneller et al. (1999). As a result, the important role played

    by the implicit financing element is highly relevant in this

    analysis.

    2.5. Other econometric issues

    There are also other econometric issues which should be

    addressed, such as endogeneity and a robustness check.

    Firstly, Afonso and Jalles (2014) investigate the

    robustness of their results by adding variables (labour force

    participation and unemployment rates) into their baseline

    regression. Similarly, Acosta-Ormaechea and Morozumi

    (2013) add inflation, openness, population growth and terms

    of trade growth into their original set of control variables.

    Different specifications, including lagged fiscal variables and

    the different developmental levels of countries in the sample,

    might also be considered.

    Secondly, using pooled mean group estimators to analyse

    the error-correction model requires some tests as prerequisites.

    Gemmell et al. (2016) tested the order of integration and

    cointegration, autoregressive distributed (ARDL) lag

    structure, and weak exogeneity. They found that their

    variables are best treated as non-stationary. Imposing two-lags

    of ARDL tends to strengthen the case for significant causal

  • Thammasat Review of Economic and Social Policy

    Volume 4, Number 2, July – December 2018

    38

    effects from a number of public spending categories on the

    level of long-run GDP per capita. Their estimated results offer

    relatively strong support for the theory that expenditure share

    variables can be considered to be weakly exogenous, allowing

    interpretation of the estimated long-run expenditure

    parameters as capturing causal effects on GDP. The issues

    tested in Gemmell et al. (2016) will be further investigated in

    Section 4 of our study. Public expenditure composition is

    analysed in the next section.

    3. Public expenditure composition of countries in our

    sample

    In this section, we analyse the data on public expenditure

    composition for 38 selected countries in our sample according

    to the availability of control variables, which is mainly

    affected by labour growth. The set of countries in Table 1 is

    divided into two main groups: 17 developing countries and 21

    high-income OECD countries.

    As shown in Figure 1, total public spending in the group

    of countries in our sample has slightly increased in the past

    four decades. This can be seen from the increase in unweighted

    10-year average total spending to GDP from 23.42% in 1972-

    1981 to 25.44% in 2002-2011 for developing countries. For

    high-income OECD countries, the level of total public

    spending to GDP increased from 32.55% in 1972-1981 to

    35.19% in 2002-2011. Public spending in high-income OECD

    countries increased significantly during the 1970s and 1980s

    but subsided in later periods. On the other hand, the proportion

    of government spending to GDP in developing countries

    increased consistently during 1992-2001 and 2002-2011.

  • Thammasat Review of Economic and Social Policy

    Volume 4, Number 2, July – December 2018

    39

    Table 1. List of countries in our study by group

    Developing countries High-income OECD countries

    Bolivia Morocco Austria* Korea, Rep.

    Brazil South Africa Canada* Luxembourg*

    Cameroon Thailand Chile Netherlands*

    Costa Rica Tunisia Denmark* New Zealand*

    Dominican Republic Turkey Finland* Norway*

    Egypt, Arab Rep. Nepal France* Portugal

    India Hungary Spain*

    Indonesia Iceland* Sweden*

    Iran, Islamic Rep. Ireland UK*

    Malaysia Israel United States*

    Mauritius Italy

    Note: Our 14 OECD countries included in Gemmell et al.’s (2016) group of 17

    OECD countries

    3.1. The composition of public spending

    Table 2 presents the average amount of particular types of

    public spending by groups of countries as percentages of GDP.

    In percentage terms, government spending in our sample of

    high-income OECD countries is obviously higher than in our

    sample of developing countries. The same also applies to

    many other types of spending, although not to spending on

    general public services. The level of spending on education as

    a share of GDP is relatively similar across different groups of

    countries in the sample, with an average of around 3.38% of

    GDP.

  • Thammasat Review of Economic and Social Policy

    Volume 4, Number 2, July – December 2018

    40

    Figure 1. Unweighted 10-year averages of total public

    spending as percentages of GDP for groups of countries in

    our sample (1972-2011)

    Table 2. Unweighted averages of public spending by type as

    percentages of GDP for groups of countries in our sample

    (1972-2012)

    Developing

    countries

    High-income

    OECD countries

    Total spending 23.96 35.74

    General public services 3.80 2.73

    Defence 2.07 2.41

    Transportation and communication 1.42 1.64

    Education 3.38 3.39

    Healthcare 1.45 3.62

    Social welfare 3.13 12.59

    0

    5

    10

    15

    20

    25

    30

    35

    40

    1972-1981 1982-1991 1992-2001 2002-2011

    Developing OECD

  • Thammasat Review of Economic and Social Policy

    Volume 4, Number 2, July – December 2018

    41

    The composition of public spending in different groups of

    countries varies depending on the policies and problems that

    particular governments encounter. The unweighted averages

    of public spending by type as percentages of total spending

    from 1972 to 2012 for developing countries and high-income

    OECD countries are shown in Table 3. In developing

    countries, general public services (16.2%), education (14.1%)

    and social welfare (11.9%) spending are crucial elements of

    government budgets. In contrast, high-income OECD

    countries spend a large proportion of public expenditure on

    social welfare (34.7%), healthcare (10.1%) and education

    (9.7%). Social welfare spending accounts for more than a third

    of total public spending in high-income OECD countries.

    Table 3. Unweighted averages of public spending by type as

    percentages of total spending for groups of countries in our

    sample (1972-2012)

    Developing

    countries

    High-income

    OECD countries

    General public services 16.20 7.65

    Defence 8.69 7.30

    Transportation and communication 6.51 4.71

    Education 14.10 9.67

    Healthcare 6.23 10.05

    Social welfare 11.93 34.72

    The public spending composition of developing countries

    is presented in Figure 2 using unweighted 10-year averages for

    the period from 1972 to 2011. It is clear that social welfare

    spending as a proportion of total public spending has increased

    significantly over time. In contrast, spending on defence, and

  • Thammasat Review of Economic and Social Policy

    Volume 4, Number 2, July – December 2018

    42

    transportation and communication has decreased significantly

    relative to other types of public spending.

    The proportions of most spending types, including general

    public services, education and social welfare spending, in

    relation to total spending in high-income OECD countries

    have not changed dramatically in the past forty years as can be

    seen in Figure 3. Healthcare spending has increased more

    noticeably over time than other types of expenditure, whereas

    spending on defence has been decreasing.

    Figure 2. Unweighted 10-year averages of spending by type

    as percentages of total spending for developing countries in

    our sample (1972-2011)

    0%

    10%

    20%

    30%

    40%

    50%

    60%

    70%

    80%

    90%

    100%

    1972-19811982-19911992-20012002-2011

    General public services

    Defence

    Transportation and

    communication

    Education

    Healthcare

    Social welfare

  • Thammasat Review of Economic and Social Policy

    Volume 4, Number 2, July – December 2018

    43

    Figure 3. Unweighted 10-year averages of spending by type

    as percentages of total spending for high-income OECD

    countries in our sample (1972-2011)

    The following subsection explains the estimation method

    used to analyse long-run relationship between fiscal variables

    and GDP per capita.

    4. Public spending and long-run GDP per capita

    investigating heterogenous panel data: estimation method

    In this section, we discuss the econometric methods used

    to study the relationship between public spending and long-

    run levels of GDP per capita in our sample’s groups of

    countries. Later (in Section 5), we present the estimates

    separately, according to the country groupings, i.e. developing

    countries and high-income OECD countries. This section

    includes the discussion of pooled mean group estimator

    (PMG), and tests for cointegration and ARDL lag structure.

    0%

    10%

    20%

    30%

    40%

    50%

    60%

    70%

    80%

    90%

    100%

    1972-19811982-19911992-20012002-2011

    General public services

    Defence

    Transportation and

    communication

    Education

    Healthcare

    Social welfare

  • Thammasat Review of Economic and Social Policy

    Volume 4, Number 2, July – December 2018

    44

    4.1. Pooled mean group (PMG) estimator

    The endogenous growth model in Devarajan, Swaroop

    and Zou (1996) captures the permanent growth effects from

    fiscal changes without transitional dynamics (Gemmell et al.,

    2016). Allowing for Solow-type transitional dynamics while

    the effects of fiscal change may be persistent requires a more

    flexible functional form than that of Devarajan et al. (1996).

    Using an autoregressive distributed lag (ARDL) model

    parameterised in error correction form in Gemmell et al.

    (2016) allows both the short-run dynamic and the long-run

    equilibrium relationships between GDP and fiscal variables to

    be identified separately. The ARDL(p,q) specification is:

    𝑦𝑖,𝑡 = ∑ 𝛼𝑖,𝑗𝑦𝑖,𝑡−𝑗 + ∑ 𝛽𝑖,𝑗𝑋𝑖,𝑡−𝑗 + 𝜇𝑖 + 𝜀𝑖,𝑡𝑞𝑗=0

    𝑝𝑗=1 (1)

    where Xi,t-j includes all explanatory variables. Equation (1) can

    be expressed in error correction form:

    𝑔𝑖,𝑡 = ∆𝑦𝑖,𝑡 = ∅𝑖(𝑦𝑖,𝑡−1 − 𝛽𝑖𝑋𝑖,𝑡) + ∑ 𝛼𝑖,𝑗∗ ∆𝑦𝑖,𝑡−𝑗

    𝑝−1𝑗=1

    + ∑ 𝛽𝑖,𝑗∗𝑞−1

    𝑗=0 ∆𝑋𝑖,𝑡−𝑗 + 𝜇𝑖 + 𝜀𝑖,𝑡 (2)

    where ∅i captures the error correcting speed of adjustment and βi captures the long-run equilibrium relationship between y

    and X with short-run effects measured by β*i,j. The estimates

    of long-run coefficient βi are not affected by the choice

    between Xi,t and Xi,t-1 in determining the long-run relationship.

    While Arnold et al. (2011), Ojede and Yamarik (2012), and

    Xing (2012) use Xi,t, Gemmell et al. (2011, 2016) prefer Xi,t-1.

    We use Xi,t in our study, since it provides better computational

    convenience in our statistical package than using Xi,t-1.

    Blackburne and Frank (2007) suggest several approaches

    which can be taken in order to estimate Equation (2). Firstly,

  • Thammasat Review of Economic and Social Policy

    Volume 4, Number 2, July – December 2018

    45

    a fixed effect (FE) estimation approach could be used when

    data from each group is pooled and only the intercepts are

    allowed to differ across groups. Pesaran and Smith (1995)

    show that these regressions are likely to be biased if the

    assumption of homogeneity of the short-run parameter

    estimates across countries is rejected. Secondly, the model

    might be fitted separately for each group and the arithmetic

    average of coefficients could be calculated by using mean

    group estimators (MG). The MG estimators allow both short

    and long-run parameter heterogeneity. Thirdly, Pesaran et al.

    (1999) proposed a PMG estimation that combines both

    methods of pooling (FE) and averaging (MG). The intercept,

    short-run coefficients and error variances are allowed to differ

    across groups, but the long-run coefficients are constrained to

    be equal across groups. Furthermore, Pesaran et al. (1999)

    have also demonstrated that allowing for short-run parameter

    heterogeneity results in more reliable estimates of the long-run

    responses.

    We present the results of PMG estimates, as the Hausman

    test prefers PMG to MG.1 The implication of the results from

    the Hausman test is that the assumption of homogenous long-

    run parameter estimates across countries is valid. The PMG

    method selected is then comparable to Gemmell et al.’s (2016)

    study.

    Our study investigates the long-run relationship between

    public spending and the GDP per capita level of the 38

    countries (see Table 1) which are classified as developing

    countries (17 countries) and high-income OECD countries (21

    countries). These groups of countries were selected based on

    the availability of control and fiscal variables. The groups of

    developing countries and high-income OECD countries in our

    1 We do not show the results of the Hausman test in this paper; however,

    they could be provided by request.

  • Thammasat Review of Economic and Social Policy

    Volume 4, Number 2, July – December 2018

    46

    sample have been analysed separately, in a similar way to

    Gemmell et al. (2016), by looking at the effects of total public

    expenditure and public expenditure composition. The study

    period is 1972-2012.

    Our dependent variable gi,t is the change in log of GDP

    per capita. Although the growth rate of per capita GDP is the

    dependent variable, as shown in Equation (2), the regression

    measures the impacts of fiscal and other variables on long-run

    per capita GDP level. Equation (2) is only a re-

    parameterisation of Equation (1). As discussed earlier,

    Gemmell et al. (2016) argue that using level specification

    allows the identification of the degree of persistence in GDP

    growth responses.

    The non-fiscal control variables included in this study are

    labour force growth (LG) and investment ratio to GDP (K).

    Labour force growth before 1990 is assumed to be constant

    (from the average of available data) in a number of countries

    in the sample where accurate data is not readily available.

    When taking government budget constraint into account, our

    fiscal control variables include the ratio of total expenditure to

    GDP, distortionary taxes to GDP, non-distortionary taxes to

    GDP and budget surplus to GDP. In the cases where we

    consider public spending composition, the expenditure share

    of a particular type of public spending in relation to total public

    spending is added individually. The list of variables included

    in this study is shown in Table 4.

  • Thammasat Review of Economic and Social Policy

    Volume 4, Number 2, July – December 2018

    47

    Table 4. List of variables for this study Variables Description of the variables

    y

    K

    LG

    tot_gdp

    distax_gdp

    tgs_gdp

    SURBP

    TOT

    gps_tot

    def_tot

    trc_tot

    edu_tot

    hea_tot

    soc_tot

    Log of GDP per capita (2005 USD)

    Gross capital formation (% of GDP)

    Labour force growth (%)

    Total public spending (% of GDP)

    Distortionary taxation (% of GDP)

    Non-distortionary taxation (% of GDP)

    Budget balance (% of GDP)

    Total public spending in local currency unit

    Spending on general public services (% of

    TOT)

    Spending on defence (% of TOT)

    Spending on transportation and

    communication (% of TOT)

    Spending on education (% of TOT)

    Spending on health (% of TOT)

    Spending on social welfare (% of TOT)

    The first part of the analysis of each group of countries in

    our sample looks at the total public expenditure effect with

    four different implicit financing elements: budget deficit;

    distortionary taxes; non-distortionary taxes; and a mix of both

    distortionary and non-distortionary taxes. In the second part of

    the analysis, we use budget deficit as an implicit financing

    element, focussing on the impact of shifting expenditure

    towards a particular type of public spending composition on

    the long-run GDP per capita level. There are two groups of

    countries consider