Technology-push,Demand-pull,andStrategic R&D...

26
INFORMS Annual Meeting Nashville, TN November , Technology-push, Demand-pull, and Strategic R&D Investment Benjamin D. Leibowicz Assistant Professor Graduate Program in Operations Research and Industrial Engineering Department of Mechanical Engineering The University of Texas at Austin

Transcript of Technology-push,Demand-pull,andStrategic R&D...

  • INFORMS Annual MeetingNashville, TNNovember 13, 2016

    Technology-push, Demand-pull, and StrategicR&D Investment

    Benjamin D. LeibowiczAssistant ProfessorGraduate Program in Operations Research and Industrial EngineeringDepartment of Mechanical EngineeringThe University of Texas at Austin

  • OutlineBackground

    Model

    Numerical SimulationsMotivations for Stimulating InnovationMarket Failure Sensitivity Analysis

    Conclusions

  • OutlineBackground

    Model

    Numerical SimulationsMotivations for Stimulating InnovationMarket Failure Sensitivity Analysis

    Conclusions

  • Two Types of Technology PolicyI Technology-push

    – Reduce the private cost of engaging in innovation– ExamplesI Public R&DI Government funding for private R&DI Support for higher education to enlarge pool of innovators

    I Demand-pull– Create or expand markets to increase the payoff tosuccessful innovation– Examples

    I Subsidies for consumer purchasesI Direct government procurementI Stronger intellectual property protection

  • Retrospective AnalysesI Empirical and case study literatures indicate that eachpolicy type is generally ineffective if used alone.I Technology-push

    – Mod program for wind turbines, U.S., 1970sI Loiter and Norberg-Bohm (1999)

    – GAVE program for biofuels, Netherlands, 1998–2002I Suurs and Hekkert (2009)

    I Demand-pull– Tax credits for wind installations, California, 1980s

    I Nemet (2009)– Tax credits for solar installations, California, 1970s–present

    I Taylor (2008); Wiser et al. (2007)

  • Portfolio ApproachI Technology-push and demand-pull policies arecomplementary, and the ideal technology policy portfolioshould include policies of both types (Gallagher et al., 2012).I The relative importance of technology-push anddemand-pull varies across applications (Pavitt 1984).

    In this study, a bilevel optimization model is developed todetermine the optimal balance of technology-push anddemand-pull policies for a given technology policyapplication.

  • OutlineBackground

    Model

    Numerical SimulationsMotivations for Stimulating InnovationMarket Failure Sensitivity Analysis

    Conclusions

  • Key Model Features 1I Unique features

    – Includes a policymaker and firms as separatedecision-making agents– Represents both technology-push and demand-pull– Represents both process and product R&D– Captures uncertainty in R&D outcomesI Three market failures

    – Incomplete appropriability of innovation– Imperfect competition– Negative production externality

    1 Contrast these to how energy technology R&D is incorporated into IAMs (Bosetti et al., 2009).

  • Strategic Innovation in an Oligopoly

  • The Model

  • OutlineBackground

    Model

    Numerical SimulationsMotivations for Stimulating InnovationMarket Failure Sensitivity Analysis

    Conclusions

  • OutlineBackground

    Model

    Numerical SimulationsMotivations for Stimulating InnovationMarket Failure Sensitivity Analysis

    Conclusions

  • Three Different Motivations for Stimulating InnovationI Case 1: Combat negative externality

    – The new good is a close and expensive substitute for theexsiting good, but the latter has a negative productionexternality (e.g. nuclear fission to fusion).I Case 2: Reduce cost

    – The new good is a close substitute for the existing good, butcan ultimately be produced at lower cost (e.g. crystallinesilicon to organic PV).I Case 3: Create demand

    – Developing the new good is expensive, but it has a largepotential demand that is not being met by the existing good(e.g. new energy-consuming end-use appliance).

  • Case 1: Combat Negative Externality

  • Case 2: Reduce Cost

  • Case 3: Create Demand

  • OutlineBackground

    Model

    Numerical SimulationsMotivations for Stimulating InnovationMarket Failure Sensitivity Analysis

    Conclusions

  • Product R&D

  • Expected Profit

  • Expected Welfare

  • Optimal Technology-push Policy

  • OutlineBackground

    Model

    Numerical SimulationsMotivations for Stimulating InnovationMarket Failure Sensitivity Analysis

    Conclusions

  • ConclusionsI Process and product R&D are substitutes.I If innovation serves to combat a negative externality,technology policy should emphasize technology-push, butit is difficult to enhance welfare through technology policy.I Firms perform less product R&D under stronger spillovers,but expected welfare is higher.I Each firm performs less product R&D under greatercompetition, but total industry R&D rises.I Expected welfare decreases with competition in theno-policy case, but increases with competition if optimaltechnology policies are imposed.

  • AcknowledgmentsI Previous institutions where this work took place

    – International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis– Stanford UniversityI Individuals who offered guidance

    – Lawrence Goulder– Arnulf Grubler– Charles Kolstad– Volker Krey– James Sweeney– John WeyantI Funding source

    – DOE Office of Science PIAMDDI grant

  • Thank You for Listening!

  • ReferencesBosetti, V., Carraro, C., Massetti, E., Sgobbi, A., Tavoni, M. (2009). Optimal energy investment and R&D strategies tostabilize atmospheric greenhouse gas concentrations. Resource and Energy Economics 31, 123-137.D’Aspremont, C. and Jacquemin, A. (1988). Cooperative and Noncooperative R&D in Duopoly with Spillovers.

    American Economic Review 78, 1133-1137.Dasgupta, P. and Stiglitz, J. (1980). Industrial Structure and the Nature of Innovative Activity The Economic Journal 90,266-293.Gallagher, K.S., Grubler, A., Kuhl, L., Nemet, G., Wilson, C. (2012). The Energy Technology Innovation System. Annual

    Review of Environment and Resources 37, 137-162.Levin, R.C. and Reiss, P.C. (1990). Cost-Reducing and Demand-Creating R&D with Spillovers. RAND Journal of

    Economics 19, 538-556.Lin, P. and Saggi, K. (2002). Product differentiation, process R&D, and the nature of market competition. European

    Economic Review 46, 201-211.Loiter, J.M. and Norberg-Bohm, V. (1999). Technology policy and renewable energy: public roles in the developmentof new energy technologies. Energy Policy 27, 85-97.Nemet, G.F. (2009). Interim monitoring of cost dynamics for publicly supported energy technologies. Energy Policy37, 825-835.Pavitt, K. (1984). Sectoral patterns of technological change: Towards a taxonomy and a theory. Research Policy 13,343-373.Suurs, R.A.A. and Hekkert, M.P. (2009). Competition between first and second generation technologies: Lessons fromthe formation of a biofuels innovation systems in the Netherlands. Energy 34, 669-679.Suzumura, K. (1992). Cooperative and Noncooperative R&D in an Oligopoly with Spillovers. American Economic Review82, 1307-1320.Wiser, R., Bolinger, M., Cappers, P., Margolis, R. (2007). Analyzing Historical Cost Trends in California’s Market forCustomer-Sited Photovoltaics. Progress in Photovoltaics: Research and Applications 15, 69-85.

    BackgroundModelNumerical SimulationsMotivations for Stimulating InnovationMarket Failure Sensitivity Analysis

    Conclusions