Sterilization_ Monetary Policy_ and Global Financila Integration_2

download Sterilization_ Monetary Policy_ and Global Financila Integration_2

of 26

Transcript of Sterilization_ Monetary Policy_ and Global Financila Integration_2

  • 8/6/2019 Sterilization_ Monetary Policy_ and Global Financila Integration_2

    1/26

    Sterilization, Monetary Policy, and GlobalFinancial Integrationroie_848 777..801

    Joshua Aizenman and Reuven Glick*

    Abstract

    This paper investigates the changing pattern and efficacy of sterilization within emerging market countries asthey liberalize markets and integrate with the world economy. We estimate the marginal propensity tosterilize foreign asset accumulation associated with net balance of payments inflows, across countries, andover time.We find that the extent of sterilization of foreign reserve inflows has risen in recent years to varyingdegrees in Asia as well as in Latin America, consistent with greater concerns about the potential inflationaryimpact of reserve inflows.We also find that sterilization depends on the composition of balance of paymentsinflows.

    1. Introduction

    In the late 1980s and early 1990s, emerging market countries embraced growing finan-cial liberalization and openness. However, by also trying to maintain some degree ofboth exchange rate stability and monetary independence, many of these countriesexperienced severe financial crises. In the aftermath of these crises, many emergingmarkets have adopted a policy configuration involving greater, though still managed,exchange rate flexibility, together with ongoing financial integration and some degreeof domestic monetary independence. Hoarding of international reserves has become akey ingredient enhancing the stability of this new pattern. Concerns about the cost ofmaintaining monetary stability with this new policy mix suggest the need to supporthoarding international reserves with more aggressive sterilization. Apprehensionsabout the opportunity costs of accumulating reserves and the fiscal and distortionaryfinancial costs of sterilization,in turn, have raised questions about the long-run viabilityof this new policy mix, particularly the efficacy of sterilization.

    Recent literature has analyzed various aspects of recent developments, such as thenature and extent of greater exchange rate flexibility, monetary autonomy, and financialintegration by emerging market countries (e.g. Fischer, 2001; Aizenman and Lee, 2008).In this paper we focus on concerns about the extent of sterilization by estimating themarginal propensity to sterilize foreign asset accumulation over time for selectedcountries in Asia and Latin America.

    * Aizenman: Department of Economics, University of California at Santa Cruz, E2, Santa Cruz, CA 95064,USA. Tel: (1) 831-459-4791; E-mail: [email protected]. Glick: Economic Research Department, FederalReserve Bank of San Francisco, 101 Market Street, San Francisco, CA 96105, USA. Tel: (415) 974-3184; Fax:(415) 974-2168; E-mail: [email protected] would like to thank Michael Hutchison, Menzie Chinn,ananonymous referee, participants at the Review of International Economics/Santa Cruz Center for Interna-tional Economics Conference on Global Liquidity (University of California at Santa Cruz, 1112 April

    2008), as well as participants at the First Annual Management Institute Research Conference on CapitalFlows and Asset Prices: The International Dimension of Risk (National University of Singapore, 67 July2007) for useful comments.We also thank Michael Simmons and Andrew Cohn for research assistance.The

    i d b l d h f h F d l R B k f S F i h B d f

    Review of International Economics, 17(4), 777801, 2009DOI:10.1111/j.1467-9396.2009.00848.x

  • 8/6/2019 Sterilization_ Monetary Policy_ and Global Financila Integration_2

    2/26

    Our results confirm that the greater accumulation of foreign reserves in recent yearshas been associated with a greater intensity of sterilization by developing countries inAsia as well as in Latin America. In particular, we show that there has been a significantincrease in the coefficient of sterilization in recent years. Thus the policies of hoardinginternational reserves and sterilizing the potential inflationary impact have comple-mented each other during recent years. In addition, we find that sterilization of foreign

    direct investment (FDI) inflows typically is less than that for current account surplusesand for non-FDI inflows, suggesting that misgivings about monetary instability dependon the composition of balance of payments inflows.

    We also discuss the benefits and costs of sterilization. For many countries the costs ofsterilization appear to be less than the perceived benefits associated with monetarystability and reserve accumulation. However, we present evidence suggesting that therelative benefits to China and other countries have fallen in recent quarters. Thisimplies limits to the sustainability of the new policy configuration in the near term.

    Finally, we outline a model (presented in the Appendix) explaining how the ability tosterilize depends on imperfect substitutability of assets in a world where the costs of

    trading assets varies systematically across agents (due to possible scale effects) andacross asset classes (due to varying liquidity and risk characteristics). We show thatpolicies fostering greater domestic financial repression reduce the costs of sterilization,suggesting that the extent to which a country may sterilize depends on the degree towhich it is willing to tolerate financial repression and other economic distortions.

    2. Changing Trilemma Configuration

    A major lesson of the past decade or so has been the downside risk of combininginternational financial integration with soft exchange rate pegs. Each of the major

    international financial market-related crises since 1994Mexico in 1994, Thailand,Indonesia, and Korea in 1997, Russia and Brazil in 1998, and Argentina and Turkey in2000has in some way involved a fixed or pegged exchange rate regime. At the sametime, countries that did not have pegged ratesamong them, Israel, Mexico, and SouthAfrica in 1998avoided crises of the type that afflicted emerging market countries withpegged rates.1 As a result, more emerging market countries have adopted a policy mixof managed exchange rates, while still trying to maintain some degree of domesticmonetary control together with growing financial integration. They have accomplishedthis with a policy combination of massive reserve hoarding and sterilization.

    A useful perspective for understanding the changing configuration of monetary

    policy by developing countries is provided by applying the framework of the impossibletrinity dilemmathe Trilemma.TheTrilemma states that a country simultaneously maychoose any two, but not all, of the following three goals: monetary independence,exchange rate stability, and financial integration (see Obstfeld et al., 2005, for furtherdiscussion and references dealing with the Trilemma).

    With closed capital markets, a country can have monetary policy control and a fixedexchange rate, but not financial integration. This was the preferred policy choice ofmost developing countries in the mid to late 1980s, as they maintained a combinationof exchange rate stability and monetary independence, with relatively closed capitalaccounts.

    In the late 1980s and early 1990s countries such as Mexico, Korea, and several otherAsian economies, embraced growing financial liberalization and openness. However, asthey opened more financially they found that the goals of greater financial integration

    778 Joshua Aizenman and Reuven Glick

  • 8/6/2019 Sterilization_ Monetary Policy_ and Global Financila Integration_2

    3/26

    The inconsistent policy goals resulted in severe financial crises, in Mexico during199495 and in East Asia during 199798.2 These crises confirmed the tradeoffs asso-ciated with the Trilemma: a country opting for greater financial integration must give upexchange rate stability if it wishes to preserve a degree of monetary independence.Failure to do so induced crises, after which Mexico, Korea, and other countries optedfor a new policy configuration. The emerging Trilemma configuration seems to involve

    greater financial integration and greater managed exchange rate flexibility, tradingoff exchange rate stability with capital mobility while maintaining some degree ofmonetary independence.3 In the early 1990s, Argentina adopted another Trilemmaconfiguration involving exchange rate fixity, supported by a version of a currencyboard, and complete financial integration. Argentina also experienced a crisis in theearly 2000s when ceding monetary policy independence became no longer viable.

    Post-crisis, more emerging markets have opted for a policy configuration involvingmore exchange rate flexibility, domestic monetary independence, and growing financialintegration. But they are still engaging in a great degree of exchange rate management.So, in the face of pressures for their currencies to appreciate, they have been accumu-

    lating reserves and sterilizing. China vividly displays this policy mix, allowing greater defacto financial integration, and in mid-2005 adopting managed exchange rate flexibility,while also accumulating and sterilizing massive amounts of foreign reserve inflows.

    Econometric analysis suggests structural shifts in the pattern of reserve hoarding bydeveloping countries (see Aizenman and Marion, 2003; Aizenman and Lee, 2008;Cheung and Ito, 2008). One shift occurred in the early 1990s, as reflected in risingforeign reserve/GDP ratios, a trend that intensified shortly after the East Asian crisis of199798, but subsided by 2000. A second structural shift seems to have taken place inthe early 2000s, driven largely by the unprecedented increase in hoarding of foreignreserves by China.

    This massive foreign reserve accumulation may be attributed to several factors. First,some countries have acquired reserves to satisfy precautionary demand needs.Reserves provide self-insurance against sudden stops of foreign capital inflows, therebyoffsetting the downside risk of greater financial integration. Secondly, reserves may beused to cushion the effects of terms-of-trade shocks on a countrys real exchange rateand its exports, smoothing the adjustment of the current account. In addition, theyallow countries to avoid relying on the IMF, World Bank, and other internationalfinancial organizations, etc., for implicit insurance. Lastly, reserve accumulation mayoccur as a byproduct of managing exchange rates to promote exports by undervaluingdomestic currency.4

    3. Reserve Accumulation and Sterilization Response

    Reserve accumulation has monetary implications. When a central bank purchasesforeign reserve assets, it must decide whether to fund it by increasing the reserve moneybase, which is potentially inflationary, or by reducing its net domestic assets, whichsterilizes the impact on the domestic reserve money base. Central banks may offset theeffects of reserve accumulation on the monetary base in a number of ways, includingselling market instruments, such as government bonds or central bank bills or by usingswaps or repurchase operations. With foreign exchange swaps, the central bank typ-

    ically agrees to buy foreign exchange forward, while with repurchase operations(repos) the central bank sells securities with an agreement to buy them back in thefuture When markets are thin some authorities rely on nonmarket instruments such as

    STERILIZATION, MONETARY POLICY, AND FINANCIAL INTEGRATION 779

  • 8/6/2019 Sterilization_ Monetary Policy_ and Global Financila Integration_2

    4/26

    commercial banking system to the central bank or selling foreign exchange reserves tothe government (perhaps to allow it to reduce external sovereign debt).5

    Some Plots

    Figure 1 plots four-quarter changes in central bank net foreign reserve assets (FR) andin net domestic credit assets (DC), each scaled by the reserve money stock (RM) at theend of the period four quarters earlier, for China, Korea, and Thailand.6 Net foreignreserves are defined by taking the dollar-denominated level of foreign reserves andadjusting them for exchange rate changes, to give a valuation-adjusted measure ofchanges in net foreign reserves in domestic currency.7 Net domestic credit assets (DC)are defined as the reserve monetary base (RM) minus net foreign reserves (FR).Positive values of net foreign reserve accumulation by the central bank correspond toforeign reserve inflows. Negative values of net domestic credit correspond to reductionsin domestic assets held by the monetary authorities.

    In the case of China, the extent of sterilization was relatively limited until the early2000s, as the monetary impact of reserve inflows (i.e. positive levels of DFR/RM) wasgenerally augmented by monetary stimulus from central bank acquisition of domesticassets (i.e. positive levels ofDDC/RM).8 Since mid-2002, however,as China experiencedsharply rising foreign reserve inflows, these inflows were accompanied by negativechanges in domestic asset holdings by the central bank, primarily through sales ofPeoples Bank of China bills, implying the reserve inflows were being sterilized. Theincrease in the extent of sterilization in the early 2000s implies a possible break fromChinas prior sterilization behavior.

    Korea and Thailand also have experienced significant reserve inflows in the after-math of the Asia crisis. In Korea, reserve inflows increased in 1999 and 2000, subsidedsomewhat, and then rose again in the period 200205 around the time China beganaccumulating reserves at a rising rate. Koreas monetary authorities responded to themonetary impact of these inflows by sterilization. A similar pattern of inflows andsterilization is apparent in Thailand.

    Aizenman and Glick (2008b) show results for other selected countries in Asia(Singapore, Malaysia, and India) and Latin American countries (Argentina, Brazil, andMexico).9 In the case of Argentina, modest reserve inflows emerged in 2003 in theaftermath of the countrys financial crisis of 200102; however, these inflows were notevidently sterilized until the latter half of 2004 when changes in the domestic assetholdings of the central bank turned negative. In Brazil, reserve inflows began increasingin the latter half of 2004, accompanied by sterilization. A similar pattern of reserveinflows and offsetting declines in central bank domestic assets occurred in Mexico in1996 in the aftermath of its 199495 peso crisis.

    Estimation of Sterilization Response

    We now turn to quantitatively estimating changes in the degree of sterilization. Weestimate the extent of sterilization by a simple regression of the monetary authoritieschange in net domestic assets on the change in net foreign assets held on its balance

    sheet, where change is measured over four quarters, and scaled by the level of thereserve money stock lagged four quarters. We also include the four-quarter growth rateof nominal GDP on the right-hand side to control for other explanatory variables Z

    780 Joshua Aizenman and Reuven Glick

  • 8/6/2019 Sterilization_ Monetary Policy_ and Global Financila Integration_2

    5/26

    DC RM FR RM Z = + +4 4 . (1)

    We estimate the sterilization coefficient,b, with OLS using 40-quarter rolling samples.11

    In these circumstances a unitary coefficient i e b = -1 on the variable DFR/RM

    China

    0.8

    0.6

    0.4

    0.2

    0

    0.2

    0.4

    0.6

    0.8

    1985 1987 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007

    FR/RM DC/RM

    Korea

    2

    1.6

    1.2

    0.8

    0.4

    0

    0.4

    0.81.2

    1.6

    2

    1985 1987 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007

    FR/RM DC/RM

    Thailand

    2

    1.6

    1.2

    0.8

    0.4

    0

    0.4

    0.8

    1.2

    1.6

    2

    1985 1987 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007

    FR/RM DC/RM

    Figure 1. Net Foreign Reserve and Net Domestic Credit Changes of Central Bank:Selected Asian Countries ( four-quarter changes relative to stock of reserve money laggedfour quarters, in percent)

    STERILIZATION, MONETARY POLICY, AND FINANCIAL INTEGRATION 781

  • 8/6/2019 Sterilization_ Monetary Policy_ and Global Financila Integration_2

    6/26

    sterilization. A value of the sterilization coefficient between these levels, -1 < b< 0,indicates partial sterilization.

    In our base specification Zis defined as the rate of nominal GDP growth. Presuminga stable demand for money, a rudimentary version of the monetary approach to thebalance of payments implies that expansion of DC by the central bank at the growthrate of GDP would meet the increase in the demand for money, without the need to

    hoard foreign reserves. Thus, full sterilization (b= -1) implies that the central bankallows domestic credit to accommodate fully higher demand for money due to GDPgrowth, but prevents any domestic credit expansion due to hoarding foreign reserves.A value of sterilization less than -1 may represent tighter monetary policy, potentiallydue to greater concerns about inflation. In this case hoarding a unit of foreign reservesreduces domestic assets held by the central bank by more than one unit, therebyreducing the monetary base. Similarly, a value of sterilization above zero may indicateexpansionary monetary policy, possibly due to concerns about a credit crunch orexposure to a systemic crisis.12

    Figure 2 plots sterilization coefficients from rolling regressions based on estimation

    of our benchmark specification. Coefficient observations correspond to the calendardate of the 40th quarter in each rolling sample.13

    In the case of China,observe that the sterilization coefficient began rising (in absolutevalue) from roughly 0.6 in 2000, a trend that accelerated in the latter half of 2002 andcontinued into 2006 when it peaked at almost 1.5, suggesting the presence of a break inbehavior.14 The plot also indicates a reversal of Chinas sterilization behavior beginningin the fourth quarter of 2006.This evident decline in Chinas degree of sterilization canbe attributed to two possibilities. First, Chinas foreign reserve accumulation in recentperiods may be overstated to the extent that the reported figures have not been adjustedto take account of swaps and shifts of foreign reserve assets to Chinas nascent sovereign

    wealth fund and state-owned banks.15 Secondly, China may indeedhave reached limits tothe extent of its ability to sterilize its massive reserve inflows.

    A break in Koreas sterilization behavior is evident after the 199798 financial crisis,with the sterilization coefficient increasing from 0.9 to more than 1.0 by 1999. Increasedsterilization, though to a lesser extent, is observable in Thailand and Malaysia, while nochange is evident in the case of Singapore. For India, a modest increase in sterilizationappears to have occurred in the mid-1990s after its financial crisis of 1991, followed bya further increase after 2002.

    For comparison we also present rolling regression results for our three LatinAmerica countries. As before, the sample ranges are limited to the period after the

    stabilization of monetary policy in 1991 in Argentina and 1994 in Brazil; in both casessome increases in sterilization are observable over the period.16 In the case of Mexico,sterilization increased modestly in 1996 and later around 2005.

    In Aizenman and Glick (2008b), we examine the sensitivity of our results to alter-native regression specifications. Specifically, we plot rolling regression coefficientsbased on (i) nonoverlapping quarterly observations of one-quarter changes, and (ii)nonoverlapping annual observations of four-quarter changes.17 Our general finding thatsterilization has increased appears reasonably robust.

    The rolling regressions suggest that sterilization increased in many countries after theAsia crisis or at the time that China began sterilizing significantly in 2002.To assess the

    extent to which countries are converging towards similar sterilization patterns, we makea cross-country comparison of sterilization behavior over time. Figure 3 reports thecoefficient of variation of the sterilization coefficients for countries in Asia and Latin

    782 Joshua Aizenman and Reuven Glick

  • 8/6/2019 Sterilization_ Monetary Policy_ and Global Financila Integration_2

    7/26

    countries: in Asia, to our original sample of China, Korea, Thailand, Malaysia,Singapore, and India,we add Indonesia, Pakistan,and the Philippines;in Latin America,to our original sample of Argentina, Brazil, and Mexico, we add Chile, Colombia, and

    Peru.18

    Observe that the coefficient of variation declined substantially in Asia over theperiod 200005, after which it began to rise somewhat. In Latin America, the coefficientof variation fell beginning in 2000 These results suggest the timing of the increase in the

    1.6

    1.4

    1.2

    1

    0.8

    0.6

    0.4

    0.2

    0

    1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006

    1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006

    1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006

    China

    1.6

    1.4

    1.2

    1

    0.8

    0.6

    0.4

    0.2

    0Korea

    1.6

    1.4

    1.2

    1

    0.8

    0.6

    0.4

    0.2

    0Thailand

    1.6

    1.4

    1.2

    1

    0.8

    0.6

    0.4

    0.2

    0Malaysia

    1.6

    1.4

    1.2

    1

    0.8

    0.6

    0.4

    0.2

    0Singapore

    1.6

    1.4

    1.2

    1

    0.8

    0.6

    0.4

    0.2

    0India

    1.6

    1.4

    1.2

    1

    0.8

    0.6

    0.4

    0.2

    0Argentina

    1.6

    1.4

    1.2

    1

    0.8

    0.6

    0.4

    0.2

    0Brazil

    1.6

    1.4

    1.2

    1

    0.8

    0.6

    0.4

    0.2

    0Mexico

    Figure 2. Sterilization Coefficients from 40-Quarter Rolling Regressions; Selected Asianand Latin American Countries

    Notes: Plots report coefficient estimates from regression of change in central bank domesticcredit on change in foreign reserves (defined as four-quarter changes relative to stock of reservemoney lagged four quarters) and nominal GDP growth (with one standard error bands). Coef-ficient observations correspond to calendar date of 40th quarter of rolling sample period.

    STERILIZATION, MONETARY POLICY, AND FINANCIAL INTEGRATION 783

  • 8/6/2019 Sterilization_ Monetary Policy_ and Global Financila Integration_2

    8/26

    Formal regressions assessing the significance of breaks in sterilization behavior arereported in Table 1. There we estimate equation (1) for the full sample period by alsoincluding a term interacting DFR/RMwith a dummy variable DumBreak, defined witha value of unity for all periods beginning with each countrys designated break date.We

    identified break dates for each country by the first observation after the 199798 Asiacrisis (after the 199495 peso crisis in the case of Mexico) in which reserve inflows werepositive and net domestic assets were reduced for at least two quarters in a row.19 Avariant regression, reported in column (3), controls separately for sterilization behaviorduring a countrys most recent period of significant foreign reserve outflows, denotedby DumCrisis. We report both HuberWhite standard errors (in parentheses) andNeweyWest standard errors (in square brackets). The NeweyWest errors adjust forserial correlation up to eight quarters, a possible concern because of our use of over-lapping quarterly observations of four-quarter changes.20 The break date and crisisperiods for each country are reported at the bottom of Table 1. Our methodology

    identifies a break date of 2002Q2 for China, 1998Q4 for Korea,Thailand, Malaysia, andSingapore, and 2000Q4 for India.The break dates for Argentina, Brazil, and Mexico are2004Q3, 2003Q3, and 1996Q4, respectively.21

    Observe that the coefficients on the net foreign reserve inflow variable and on theinteractive term are always negative for all countries, implying the inflows were ster-ilized by reduction of central bank domestic assets and that this sterilizationincreased (i.e. the change in domestic asset holdings is more negative) after the breakdate. The coefficient on the interaction term is significant at 10% (using a two-tailedtest) in all cases (except Malaysia). This supports the observation drawn from therolling regression plots that sterilization behavior has intensified in recent years for

    emerging countries in Asia as well as in Latin America. Also note that the coefficienton nominal GDP growth is positive, implying that the central bank suppliesliquidity to the economy by increasing its claims in response to greater economic

    0

    0.1

    0.2

    0.3

    0.4

    1996Q1 1997Q1 1998Q1 1999Q1 2001Q12000Q1 2002Q1 2003Q1 2004Q1 2005Q1 2006Q1 2007Q1

    Asia & LA Asia LA

    Figure 3. Coefficient of Variation of Sterilization Coefficients

    Notes: Calculations based on coefficient estimates from regression of central bank net domesticcredit on foreign reserve change and nominal GDP growth for countries in Asia (China,Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, Pakistan, the Philippines, Singapore, Thailand) and Latin America(Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Mexico, Peru). Coefficient observations correspond to cal-endar date of 40th quarter of rolling sample period.

    784 Joshua Aizenman and Reuven Glick

  • 8/6/2019 Sterilization_ Monetary Policy_ and Global Financila Integration_2

    9/26

    ble1.H

    asSterilizationIncreasedinM

    agnitudeOverTime?

    DCRM

    FRRM

    FRRM

    DumBreak

    FRRM

    DumCri

    =

    +

    +

    (

    )

    (

    )+

    (

    )

    4

    0

    4

    1

    4

    2

    /

    ssis

    GNP

    (

    )

    +

    (

    )

    3ln

    nelA.SelectedAsianCountries

    planato

    ryvariable

    China

    Korea

    Thaila

    nd

    (1)

    (2)

    (3)

    (1)

    (2)

    (

    3)

    (1)

    (2)

    (3)

    R/RM

    -0.782

    -0.768

    -0.827

    -0

    .770

    -0.833

    -0.744

    -0.931

    -1.039

    -0.929

    (0.148)***

    (0.096)***

    (0.166)***

    (0

    .039)***

    (0.046)***

    (0.038)***

    (0.032)***

    (0.034)***

    (0.046)***

    [0.214]***

    [0.141]***

    [0.244]***

    [0

    .048]***

    [0.066]***

    [0.036]***

    [0.039]***

    [0.034]***

    [0.055]***

    FR/RM)(DumBreak)

    -0.345

    -0.301

    -0.256

    -0

    .252

    -0.132

    -0.193

    -0.099

    -0.034

    -0.044

    (0.132)**

    (0.102)***

    (0.146)*

    (0

    .042)***

    (0.057)**

    (0.047)***

    (0.032)***

    (0.044)

    (0.043)

    [0.171]**

    [0.152]*

    [0.221]

    [0

    .059]***

    [0.078]*

    [0.043]***

    [0.047]**

    [0.059]

    [0.068]

    FR/RM)(DumCrisis)

    0.176

    -0.219

    -0.127

    (0.304)

    (0.064)***

    (0.053)**

    [0.340]

    [0.061]***

    [0.056]**

    n(GNP

    )

    0.889

    0.918

    1.058

    1.198

    1.200

    0.820

    (0.088)***

    (0.103)***

    (0.324)***

    (0.326)***

    (0.262)***

    (0.282)***

    [0.149]***

    [0.160]***

    [0.299]***

    [0.392]***

    [0.271]***

    [0.344]**

    b0=-

    1

    2.183

    5.837**

    1.083

    34

    .299***

    13.181***

    44.776***

    4.639**

    1.319

    2.431

    b0+b

    1=

    -1

    2.194

    1.046

    1.223

    0

    .550

    1.226

    3.892

    0.839

    0.024

    0.659

    justed

    R-squared

    0.674

    0.837

    0.835

    0

    .952

    0.957

    0.960

    0.971

    0.978

    0.979

    eakdate

    2002Q2

    1998Q4

    1998Q

    4

    sisperiod

    19

    92Q31993Q3

    1997Q11998Q3

    1997Q11

    998Q3

    mpleperiod

    19

    86Q22007Q2

    1985Q12007Q2

    1985Q12

    007Q2

    servations

    85

    90

    90

    STERILIZATION, MONETARY POLICY, AND FINANCIAL INTEGRATION 785

  • 8/6/2019 Sterilization_ Monetary Policy_ and Global Financila Integration_2

    10/26

    ble1.C

    ontinued

    nelB.SelectedAsianCountries

    planato

    ryvariable

    Malaysia

    Singapore

    India

    (1)

    (2)

    (3)

    (1)

    (2)

    (

    3)

    (1)

    (2)

    (3)

    R/RM

    -0.858

    -0.880

    -0.874

    -0

    .935

    -0.984

    -0.993

    -0.822

    -0.805

    -0.770

    (0.140)***

    (0.137)***

    (0.152)***

    (0

    .018)***

    (0.019)***

    (0.024)***

    (0.108)***

    (0.090)***

    (0.099)***

    [0.195]***

    [0.177]***

    [0.198]***

    [0

    .016]***

    [0.013]***

    [0.017]***

    [0.189]***

    [0.126]***

    [0.130]***

    FR/RM)(DumBreak)

    -0.193

    -0.191

    -0.196

    -0

    .044

    -0.018

    -0.014

    -0.208

    -0.144

    -0.169

    (0.141)

    (0.142)

    (0.153)

    (0

    .011)***

    (0.011)

    (0.013)

    (0.108)*

    (0.087)*

    (0.092)*

    [0.195]

    [0.180]

    [0.196]

    [0

    .016]***

    [0.016]

    [0.016]

    [0.192]

    [0.125]

    [0.124]

    FR/RM)(DumCrisis)

    -0.077

    0.052

    -0.363

    (0.299)

    (0.083)

    (0.181)**

    [0.295]

    [0.044]

    [0.222]

    n(GNP

    )

    1.732

    1.748

    0.567

    0.584

    0.924

    0.919

    (0.416)***

    (0.442)***

    (0.120)***

    (0.129)***

    (0.152)***

    (0.147)***

    [0.713]**

    [0.761]**

    [0.181]***

    [0.182]***

    [0.241]***

    [0.226]***

    b0=-

    1

    1.036

    0.761

    0.689

    12

    .596***

    0.767

    0.083

    2.722

    4.744**

    5.386***

    b0+b

    1=

    -1

    3.791*

    8.940***

    9.081***

    1

    .888

    0.006

    0.182

    0.837

    2.606*

    3.231*

    justed

    R-squared

    0.829

    0.851

    0.849

    0

    .983

    0.986

    0.986

    0.849

    0.892

    0.893

    eakdate

    1998Q4

    1998Q4

    2000Q

    4

    sisperiod

    19

    97Q31998Q3

    1997Q41998Q3

    1990Q41

    991Q4

    mpleperiod

    19

    85Q12007Q2

    1985Q12007Q2

    1985Q12

    006Q4

    servations

    90

    90

    88

    786 Joshua Aizenman and Reuven Glick

  • 8/6/2019 Sterilization_ Monetary Policy_ and Global Financila Integration_2

    11/26

    nelC.SelectedLatinAmericanCountries

    planato

    ryvariable

    Argentina

    Brazil

    Mexico

    (1)

    (2)

    (3)

    (1)

    (2)

    (3)

    (1)

    (2)

    (3)

    R/RM

    -0.989

    -1.006

    -0.783

    -0.861

    -0.938

    -0.569

    -0.959

    -0.975

    -0.934

    (0.033)***

    (0.030)***

    (0.089)***

    (0.136)***

    (0.135)***

    (0.186)***

    (0.027)***

    (0.018)***

    (0.036)***

    [0.034]***

    [0.020]***

    [0.079]***

    [0.185]***

    [0.185]***

    [0.244]**

    [0.030]***

    [0.023]***

    [0.042]***

    FR/RM

    )(DumBreak)

    -0.019

    -0.257

    -0.282

    -0.419

    -0.284

    -0.539

    -0.233

    -0.077

    -0.103

    (0.102)

    (0.123)**

    (0.107)**

    (0.183)**

    (0.180)

    (0.217)**

    (0.056)***

    (0.038)**

    (0.043)**

    [0.193]

    [0.182]

    [0.179]

    [0.218]*

    [0.241]

    [0.285]*

    [0.105]**

    [0.052]

    [0.060]*

    FR/RM

    )(DumCrisis)

    -0.262

    -0.828

    -0.071

    (0.102)**

    (0.246)***

    (0.040)*

    [0.085]***

    [0.297]***

    [0.046]

    n(GNP

    )

    1.272

    0.936

    0.138

    0.131

    0.394

    0.399

    (0.352)***

    (0.310)***

    (0.021)***

    (0.025)***

    (0.057)***

    (0.061)***

    [0.428]***

    [0.322]***

    [0.024]***

    [0.027]***

    [0.068]***

    [0.069]***

    b0=-

    1

    0.103

    0.047

    5.756**

    1.045

    0.213

    5.402**

    2.360

    1.826

    3.450*

    b0+b

    1=

    -1

    0.175

    5.820**

    0.653

    4.957**

    3.386

    0.956

    17.411***

    2.518

    1.097

    justed

    R-squared

    0.949

    0.968

    0.972

    0.591

    0.640

    0.683

    0.958

    0.979

    0.980

    eakdate

    2004Q3

    2003Q3

    1996Q

    4

    sisperiod

    20

    00Q42003Q1

    1998Q31999Q4

    1994Q21

    995Q4

    mpleperiod

    19

    92Q12007Q2

    1995Q22007Q2

    1985Q12

    007Q2

    servations

    62

    49

    90

    es:The

    tablereportscoefficientsofregres

    singcentralbanknetdomesticcreditonnetforeignreserves,measuredasfour-quarterchanges,scaledb

    ythelaggedreserve

    neystock(RM).D

    ln(GNP)isthefour-qu

    arterpercentchangeinnominalG

    DP,DumBreakisadummyvaria

    bledenotingbreakpointinsterilizationbehavior,and

    mCrisis

    isadummyvariabledenotingthemostrecentperiodofsignificantre

    serveoutflows.HuberWhitestand

    arderrorsinparentheses;NeweyWeststandarderrors

    ustedfo

    rserialcorrelationuptoeightquartersinsquarebrackets.F-statistic

    fornullhypothesistests.Significanceat1%,5%,10%

    indicatedby***,**,*,respectively,

    ngtwo-tailedtest.Constantnotreported.

    STERILIZATION, MONETARY POLICY, AND FINANCIAL INTEGRATION 787

  • 8/6/2019 Sterilization_ Monetary Policy_ and Global Financila Integration_2

    12/26

    To address concern about the effects of serial correlation induced by our use ofoverlapping four-quarter changes, in Aizenman and Glick (2008b, Table 1b) we reportresults based on nonoverlapping annual observations of four-quarter changes. Becauseof the severe reduction in degrees of freedom by using nonoverlapping data and apossible loss of power in detecting breaks, we report significance levels for the inter-action terms based on two-tailed tests of the null that sterilization behavior (as before)

    as well one-tailed tests of the null that sterilization behavior has increased (i.e. thecoefficient is more negative) after the break. Reassuringly, our results are essentiallyunchanged. All countries show evidence of increased sterilization over time, generallywith statistical significance.

    Sterilization and Inflation

    Table 2 separates out the effects of inflation from real GDP changes on the centralbanks management of its domestic asset holdings. It also examines the extent to whichthe response to inflation has changed over time and whether any change in this

    response has affected the sterilization of foreign reserve inflows.Observe in columns (1) and (2) that the coefficients on inflation and real GDP

    growth are generally positive and significant, consistent with the positive sign onnominal GDP observed earlier (the exceptions are the negative coefficients on realGDP for Korea and Thailand, though they are not significant). Note also that themagnitude of the coefficient of net foreign assets interacted with our break dummiesare smaller (in absolute value) and in some cases less significant than those reported inTable 1. Column (3) includes an interaction variable involving the inflation rate withthe break date dummies. For several countriesnotably Korea, Thailand, Malaysia,Singapore, Argentina, and Brazilthe coefficient on this variable is negative, suggest-

    ing an increase in anti-inflation monetary management by the central bank in recentyears (though the coefficient is not significant for Korea and Singapore). Note also thatwe still find an increase in the sterilization response in most countries, as indicated bya negative coefficient on the interactive variable with foreign reserve inflows (theexceptions are Malaysia, Argentina, and Brazil).23 Thus, our result that developingcountries have increased their degree of sterilization in recent years appears to berobust to allowing for any direct response to inflation pressures.

    Sterilization and the Composition of Balance of Payments Inflows

    Does the sterilization response to reserve inflows vary according to the source ofinflows? That is, does the extent to which the central bank manages its domestic assetholdings depend on whether reserve inflows are associated with cold money flowslike FDI, or hot money inflows associated with other components of the balance ofpayments? Table 3 reports the results of estimating the sterilization response of thecentral bank to whether reserve inflows come from current account surpluses, foreigndirect investment inflows, or non-FDI capital inflows.24 We also investigate whetherthese responses have varied at the same time as the break dates in sterilization behav-ior identified earlier. Consistent with our prior regression analysis, we measurevariables in four-quarter change terms, scaled by the lagged reserve money stock.25

    As shown in column (2) of Table 3, the sterilization response to foreign directinvestment is lower (in absolute magnitude, i.e. |b1| < |b0|, |b1| < |b2|) in several countries,including China Korea Thailand Malaysia and Singapore as well as Brazil and

    788 Joshua Aizenman and Reuven Glick

  • 8/6/2019 Sterilization_ Monetary Policy_ and Global Financila Integration_2

    13/26

    ble2.D

    oesSterilizationDependonIn

    flation?

    DCRM

    FRRM

    FRRM

    DumBreak

    INFL

    =

    +

    +

    (

    )

    (

    )+

    +

    4

    0

    4

    1

    4

    2

    3

    ln(

    )

    lnn

    ln

    INFLD

    umBreak

    RGNP

    (

    )

    (

    )

    +

    (

    )

    4

    nelA.SelectedAsianCountries

    planato

    ryvariable

    China

    Korea

    Thaila

    nd

    (1)

    (2)

    (3)

    (1)

    (2)

    (3)

    (1)

    (2)

    (3)

    R/RM

    -0.786

    -0.778

    -0.778

    -

    0.767

    -0.758

    -0.760

    -0.925

    -0.930

    -0.936

    (0.130)***

    (0.122)***

    (0.123)***

    (0.035)***

    (0.038)***

    (0.039)***

    (0.031)***

    (0.030)***

    (0.029)***

    [0.114]***

    [0.116]***

    [0.117]***

    [0.038]***

    [0.039]***

    [0.040]***

    [0.019]***

    [0.019]***

    [0.019]***

    FR/RM)(DumBreak)

    -0.176

    -0.191

    -0.214

    -

    0.216

    -0.223

    -0.215

    -0.069

    -0.066

    -0.030

    (0.126)

    (0.117)

    (0.123)*

    (0.045)***

    (0.046)***

    (0.052)***

    (0.042)

    (0.042)

    (0.044)

    [0.115]

    [0.119]

    [0.143]

    [0.045]***

    [0.046]***

    [0.053]***

    [0.038]*

    [0.038]*

    [0.038]

    n(INFL

    )

    0.816

    0.795

    0.791

    1.790

    1.631

    1.644

    1.051

    1.145

    1.176

    (0.117)***

    (0.108)***

    (0.109)***

    (0.705)**

    (0.717)**

    (0.711)**

    (0.644)

    (0.684)*

    (0.719)

    [0.107]***

    [0.116]***

    [0.118]***

    [0.678]***

    [0.698]**

    [0.703]**

    [0.454]**

    [0.465]**

    [0.446]***

    n(INFL

    )(DumBreak)

    0.350

    -0.324

    -1.687

    (0.597)

    (1.057)

    (0.604)***

    [1.150]

    [1.116]

    [0.577]***

    n(RGN

    P)

    0.180

    0.181

    -0.813

    -0.741

    -0.385

    -0.240

    (0.453)

    (0.455)

    (0.685)

    (0.711)

    (0.380)

    (0.389)

    [0.383]

    [0.385]

    [0.837]

    [0.878]

    [0.403]

    [0.389]

    b0=-

    1

    2.710*

    3.314*

    3.274*

    45.496***

    39.800***

    38.146***

    5.946**

    5.345**

    4.712**

    b0+b

    1=

    -1

    0.264

    0.188

    0.009

    0.241

    0.295

    0.433

    0.019

    0.011

    0.898

    justed

    R-squared

    0.804

    0.802

    0.799

    0.955

    0.955

    0.954

    0.972

    0.972

    0.975

    eakdate

    2002Q2

    1998Q4

    1998Q

    4

    mpleperiod

    1987Q12007Q2

    1985Q12007Q2

    1985Q12

    007Q2

    servations

    82

    90

    90

    STERILIZATION, MONETARY POLICY, AND FINANCIAL INTEGRATION 789

  • 8/6/2019 Sterilization_ Monetary Policy_ and Global Financila Integration_2

    14/26

    ble2.C

    ontinued

    nelB.OtherSelectedAsianCountries

    planato

    ryvariable

    Malaysia

    Singapore

    India

    (1)

    (2)

    (3)

    (1)

    (2)

    (3)

    (1)

    (2)

    (3)

    R/RM

    -0.861

    -0.930

    -0.961

    -

    0.959

    -0.977

    -0.978

    -0.816

    -0.751

    -0.733

    (0.135)***

    (0.141)***

    (0.137)***

    (0.019)***

    (0.020)***

    (0.018)***

    (0.102)***

    (0.086)***

    (0.087)***

    [0.082]***

    [0.084]***

    [0.080]***

    [0.018]***

    [0.019]***

    [0.020]***

    [0.080]***

    [0.071]***

    [0.071]***

    FR/RM)(DumBreak)

    -0.183

    -0.082

    0.039

    -

    0.025

    -0.022

    -0.021

    -0.152

    -0.200

    -0.314

    (0.134)

    (0.147)

    (0.138)

    (0.014)*

    (0.013)*

    (0.019)

    (0.098)

    (0.081)**

    (0.098)***

    [0.091]**

    [0.097]

    [0.099]

    [0.019]

    [0.018]

    [0.023]

    [0.088]*

    [0.078]**

    [0.101]***

    n(INFL

    )

    2.719

    4.623

    5.152

    1.274

    0.534

    0.562

    0.462

    0.422

    0.486

    (2.438)

    (1.795)**

    (1.690)***

    (0.620)**

    (0.673)

    (0.497)

    (0.214)**

    (0.169)**

    (0.171)***

    [1.875]

    [1.975]**

    [1.875]***

    [0.606]**

    [0.640]

    [0.739]

    [0.220]**

    [0.194]**

    [0.195]**

    n(INFL

    )(DumBreak)

    -7.550

    -0.104

    0.854

    (2.551)***

    (1.995)

    (0.445)*

    [2.280]***

    [1.313]

    [0.492]*

    n(RGN

    P)

    2.395

    1.783

    0.691

    0.688

    0.596

    0.629

    (1.029)**

    (1.168)

    (0.225)***

    (0.229)***

    (0.098)***

    (0.108)***

    [0.961]**

    [0.928]*

    [0.246]***

    [0.250]***

    [0.119]***

    [0.119]***

    b0=-

    1

    1.049

    0.244

    0.083

    4.518**

    1.281

    1.476

    3.266

    8.403***

    9.423***

    b0+b

    1=

    -1

    3.406*

    0.175

    5.859**

    1.256

    0.001

    0.003

    0.545

    1.397

    0.696

    justed

    R-squared

    0.831

    0.840

    0.857

    0.984

    0.985

    0.985

    0.855

    0.888

    0.890

    eakdate

    1998Q4

    1998Q4

    2000Q

    4

    mpleperiod

    1985Q12007Q2

    1985Q12007Q2

    1985Q12

    006Q4

    servations

    90

    90

    88

    790 Joshua Aizenman and Reuven Glick

  • 8/6/2019 Sterilization_ Monetary Policy_ and Global Financila Integration_2

    15/26

    nelC.SelectedLatinAmericanCountries

    planato

    ryvariable

    Argentina

    Brazil

    Mexico

    (1)

    (2)

    (3)

    (1)

    (2)

    (3)

    (1)

    (2)

    (3)

    R/RM

    -0.956

    -1.032

    -1.040

    -0.932

    -0.690

    -0.736

    -0.975

    -0.975

    -0.976

    (0.040)***

    (0.054)***

    (0.055)***

    (0.164)***

    (0.165)***

    (0.171)***

    (0.019)***

    (0.019)***

    (0.019)***

    [0.026]***

    [0.042]***

    [0.041]***

    [0.167]***

    [0.167]***

    [0.164]***

    [0.017]***

    [0.017]***

    [0.016]***

    FR/RM)(DumBreak)

    -0.145

    -0.262

    0.837

    -0.285

    -0.130

    0.044

    -0.067

    -0.059

    -0.174

    (0.097)

    (0.113)**

    (0.345)**

    (0.246)

    (0.216)

    (0.227)

    (0.040)*

    (0.050)

    (0.063)***

    [0.125]

    [0.131]*

    [0.679]

    [0.281]

    [0.258]

    [0.268]

    [0.048]

    [0.050]

    [0.064]***

    n(INFL

    )

    1.713

    1.377

    1.352

    0.603

    1.077

    1.017

    0.561

    0.566

    0.582

    (0.275)***

    (0.334)***

    (0.338)***

    (0.875)

    (0.904)

    (-0.838)

    (0.079)***

    (0.081)***

    (0.081)***

    [0.329]***

    [0.350]***

    [0.345]***

    [0.524]

    [0.494]**

    [0.481]**

    [0.055]***

    [0.056]***

    [0.054]***

    n(INFL

    )(DumBreak)

    -7.488

    -2.448

    0.862

    (2.415)***

    (0.937)**

    (0.399)**

    [4.540]

    [1.309]*

    [0.313]***

    n(RGN

    P)

    2.184

    2.434

    -13.796

    -11.265

    0.208

    0.456

    (1.031)**

    (1.052)**

    (3.838)***

    (4.258)**

    (0.488)

    (0.448)

    [0.958]**

    [0.956]**

    [4.124]***

    [4.233]**

    [0.368]

    [0.365]

    b0=-

    1

    1.201

    0.343

    0.534

    0.172

    3.525

    2.398

    1.677

    1.785

    1.594

    b0+b

    1=

    -1

    1.366

    5.071**

    5.570**

    2.152

    1.857

    4.740*

    1.471

    0.567

    6.293**

    justed

    R-squared

    0.965

    0.967

    0.968

    0.593

    0.669

    0.686

    0.981

    0.980

    0.982

    eakdate

    2004Q3

    2003Q3

    1996Q4

    mpleperiod

    19

    92Q12007Q2

    1995Q22007Q2

    1985Q12

    007Q2

    servations

    62

    49

    90

    es:The

    tablereportscoefficientsofregressingcentralbanknetdomesticcreditonforeignreserves,measureda

    sfour-quarterchanges,scaledbyla

    ggedreservemoney

    ck(RM).D

    ln(INFL)isthefour-quarterpercentchangeintheCPI,D

    ln(RGN

    P)isthefour-quarterchangeinrealGDP,andDumBreakisadumm

    yvariabledenoting

    akpointinsterilizationbehavior.Constantnotreported.HuberWhitestanda

    rderrorsinparentheses;NeweyW

    eststandarderrorsadjustedforserialcorrelationupto

    htquartersinsquarebrackets.Significance

    at1%,5%,10%

    indicatedby***,**,*,respectively.

    STERILIZATION, MONETARY POLICY, AND FINANCIAL INTEGRATION 791

  • 8/6/2019 Sterilization_ Monetary Policy_ and Global Financila Integration_2

    16/26

    ble3.D

    oesSterilizationDependontheCompositionofBalanceofPaymentsInflows?

    DCRM

    CA

    RM

    NFDI

    RM

    nonNFDI

    RM

    k

    k

    k

    k

    k

    =

    =

    =

    +

    +

    +

    4

    0

    4

    14

    1

    4

    14

    2

    -

    =

    =

    +

    (

    )

    +

    (

    )

    (

    )

    +

    4

    14

    3

    0

    4

    14

    1

    k

    k

    k

    k

    GNP

    CA

    RM

    DumBreak

    NFDI

    ln

    RRM

    DumBreak

    nonNFDI

    RM

    DumBreak

    k

    k

    k

    =

    =

    (

    )

    (

    )

    +

    (

    )

    (

    )

    4

    14

    2

    4

    1

    4

    -

    nelA.SelectedAsianCountries

    planator

    yvariable

    China

    Korea

    Thailand

    (1)

    (2)

    (3)

    (1)

    (2)

    (3)

    (1)

    (2)

    (3)

    A-k/RM

    -1.728

    -1.416

    -0.798

    -0.881

    -0.867

    -0

    .887

    -1.482

    -1.434

    -1.011

    (0.160)***

    (0.106)***

    (0.194)***

    (0.058)***

    (0.067)***

    (0

    .112)***

    (0.186)***

    (0.204)***

    (0.309)***

    [0.312]***

    [0.174]***

    [0.274]***

    [0.063]***

    [0.083]***

    [0

    .122]***

    [0.328]***

    [0.344]***

    [0.525]*

    FDI-k/R

    M

    -0.173

    -1.098

    -0.924

    -0.806

    -0.759

    -1

    .052

    -0.963

    -0.938

    -0.744

    (0.207)

    (0.251)***

    (0.246)***

    (0.326)**

    (0.333)**

    (0

    .561)*

    (0.221)***

    (0.216)***

    (0.266)***

    [0.424]

    [0.512]**

    [0.415]**

    [0.409]*

    [0.411]*

    [0

    .715]

    [0.376]**

    [0.349]***

    [0.458]

    on-NFDL

    -k/RM

    -0.572

    -1.606

    -0.931

    -1.052

    -1.037

    -1

    .087

    -1.260

    -1.188

    -0.937

    (0.228)**

    (0.207)***

    (0.321)***

    (0.074)***

    (0.088)***

    (0

    .144)***

    (0.121)***

    (0.150)***

    (0.220)***

    [0.464]

    [0.350]***

    [0.598]

    [0.112]***

    [0.139]***

    [0

    .214]***

    [0.200]***

    [0.225]***

    [0.346]***

    n(GNP)

    1.241

    1.121

    0.510

    0

    .693

    -0.860

    -2.340

    (0.155)***

    (0.184)***

    (0.607)

    (0

    .617)

    (0.683)

    (0.998)**

    [0.272]***

    [0.290]***

    [0.868]

    [0

    .888]

    [1.050]

    [1.585]

    CA

    -k/RM

    )(DumBreak)

    -0.438

    0

    .004

    -1.216

    (0.239)*

    (0

    .106)

    (0.472)**

    [0.276]

    [0

    .112]

    [0.764]

    FD

    I-k/RM)(DumBreak)

    -0.859

    0

    .335

    -0.359

    (0.319)***

    (0

    .734)

    (0.269)

    [0.324]***

    [0

    .916]

    [0.435]

    on-FDI

    -k/RM)(DumBreak)

    -0.329

    0

    .185

    -0.655

    (0.487)

    (0

    .162)

    (0.302)**

    [0.611]

    [0

    .232]

    [0.445]

    |b1|

    0.043

    0.087

    >

    2.918**

    2.614*

    1.035

    1

    1

    0

    0

    +

    0

    .134

    10.471***

    |b1|

    >

    >

    >

    1

    1

    0

    0

    +

    >

    >

    1

    1

    2

    2

    +

    >

    11.547***

    9.627***

    27

    .678***

    0.098

    1.445

    1.572

    1

    1

    0

    0

    +

    >

    >

    |b1|

    >

    >

    2.078*

    1.905*

    1

    .123

    >

    >

    0.608

    1

    1

    2

    2

    +

    >

    >

    ustedR

    -squared

    0.508

    0.508

    0.530

    0.670

    0.663

    0

    .724

    0.685

    0.687

    0.699

    akdate

    2004Q3

    2003Q3

    1996

    Q4

    mpleperiod

    1992Q12007Q1

    1995Q22006Q4

    1985Q1

    2007Q2

    servatio

    ns

    61

    47

    90

    es:Thetablereportscoefficientsofregressingc

    entralbanknetdomesticcreditonfour-quartercumulativecurrentaccountsu

    rplus(CA),netforeigndirectinvestme

    ntinflows(NFDI),and

    -NFDIc

    apitalinflows(non-NFDI)expressedin

    localcurrencyterms,allscaledbythelaggedreservemoneystock(RM).D

    ln(GNP)isthefour-quarterpercentchang

    einnominalGDP,and

    mBreakisadummyvariabledenotingbreakpoin

    tinsterilizationbehavior.HuberWhitestandarderrorsinparentheses;NeweyWeststandarderrorsadjustedforserialcorrelationuptoeight

    rtersins

    quarebrackets.F-statisticfornullinequ

    alityhypotheses,withone-tailsignifican

    cetestresults;resultsnotreportedwhenthe(absolutevalueofthe)coefficientonFDIinflowsexceeds

    oncurrentaccountsurplusornon-FDIinflows,

    asindicatedby>.Constantnotreported.Significanceat1%,5%,10%

    indicatedby***,**,*,respectively.

    794 Joshua Aizenman and Reuven Glick

  • 8/6/2019 Sterilization_ Monetary Policy_ and Global Financila Integration_2

    19/26

    differences are significant in China (relative to non-FDI inflows), Thailand (relative tothe current account surplus), Malaysia, Singapore (relative to the current account), andBrazil. Column (3) of Table 3 interacts the individual balance of payments componentswith our break date dummies to detect whether there is more or less sensitivity to thesecomponents in recent years. Consistent with our findings in Table 1, we find greatersensitivity (i.e. more negative coefficient values) in the cases of China, Thailand, Malay-

    sia (though not to the current account balance in Malaysia), and India (though not inresponse to FDI flows, where the response fell significantly).

    Summarizing our empirical evidence on sterilization: The extent of sterilization offoreign reserve inflows has risen in recent years to varying degrees in Asia as well as inLatin America. This is consistent with greater concerns about the potential inflationaryimpact of reserve inflows. Sterilization depends on the composition of balance ofpayments inflows, i.e. for some countries the response to foreign direct investmentinflows is less than that to the current account surplus or non-FDI inflows. This isconsistent with the view that these countries are less concerned about the monetaryimpact of direct investment flows.

    4. Costs, Benefits, and Sustainability of Sterilization Policy

    Growing financial integration is an unavoidable outcome of deeper trade integrationby developing countries. A byproduct of growing financial integration is greater expo-sure to financial instability. Concerns about financial and monetary instability haveincreased the complementarity between the extent of reserve hoarding and steriliza-tion:The extent to which individual countries may continue to accumulate reserves andsterilize and the stability of this policy mix depends on the associated benefits and costs.

    While providing useful services, international reserve management is subject toserious limitations. First, there are direct opportunity costs of reserves associated withthe marginal productivity of public capital and/or the cost of external borrowing.Secondly, sterilization has fiscal costs associated with the difference between, on theone hand, the return paid on central bank liabilities issued to sterilize domestic liquidity(or the opportunity cost from foregone returns on domestic assets, such as governmentbonds, sold to the private sector) and, on the other hand, the return earned on foreignreserve assets.

    Figure 4a plots a proxy for the fiscal costs of sterilization in the case of China, givenby the difference between the one-year Peoples Bank of China and US Treasury bill

    rates (the spread is the vertical difference between the two plotted lines).26

    Observethat the interest rate spread was positive, but shrinking in 2003 and 2004, and actuallyturned negative in 2005, implying China then was earning money on balance from itssterilization operations.The narrowing of this differential in recent quarters (it actuallyturned positive again in December 2007), however, implies that Chinas sterilizationcosts have been rising. Figure 4b plots the change in interest rate spreads for five Asiancountries between June 2004 and May 2007, showing that sterilization costs increasedin all these countries.

    Sterilization and hoarding international reserves also involve macro and micro moralhazard costs. The macro moral hazard arises when reserve hoarding encourages

    opportunistic spending in regimes characterized by political instability and limitedmonitoring (see Aizenman and Marion, 2004, who show that countries characterized bygreater political instability and polarization opt to hold fewer international reserves)

    STERILIZATION, MONETARY POLICY, AND FINANCIAL INTEGRATION 795

  • 8/6/2019 Sterilization_ Monetary Policy_ and Global Financila Integration_2

    20/26

    Yeyati, 2008, who calls for liquid reserve requirements on banks as well as an ex-antesuspension-of-convertibility clause). Lastly, reserve accumulation and sterilization canencourage financial sector distortions. For example, greater use of nonmarket instru-ments (e.g. reserve requirements, direct credit controls) can hinder the development ofthe corporate bond market and alter the behavior of banks.Also it may hinder financialdevelopment by segmenting the public debt market through the issuance of centralbank liabilities instead of Treasury securities.27

    This discussion suggests that the extent to which a country may continue to sterilizedepends also on the degree to which it is willing to tolerate financial repression andother distortions to its economy. In the Appendix we outline a model explaining how

    the ability to sterilize depends on imperfect substitutability of assets in a world wherethe costs of trading assets varies systematically across agents (due to possible scaleeffects) and across asset classes (due to varying liquidity and risk characteristics)

    0

    1

    2

    3

    4

    5

    6

    Aug-02

    Dec-02

    Apr-03

    Aug-03

    Dec-03

    Apr-04

    Aug-04

    Dec-04

    Apr-05

    Aug-05

    Dec-05

    Apr-06

    Aug-06

    Dec-06

    Apr-07

    Aug-07

    Dec-07

    China1 Year US1 Year

    Figure 4a. China Central Bank and US Treasury One-Year Interest Rates (in percent)

    3

    2

    1

    0

    1

    2

    3

    70-yaM40-nuJ

    China Korea Malaysia Thailand Singapore

    Figure 4b. Bond Spreads over US Treasury One-Year Interest Rates (in percent)

    796 Joshua Aizenman and Reuven Glick

  • 8/6/2019 Sterilization_ Monetary Policy_ and Global Financila Integration_2

    21/26

    repression also reduce the costs of sterilization. This suggests that countries able andwilling to engage in greater financial sterilization will be able to sustain the policyconfiguration of reserve hoarding and sterilizing for a longer period of time. 28

    The stability of the current policy mix is further complicated by the extent to whicheach countrys costbenefit calculation depends on the actions of other countries.Countries following export-oriented growth strategies may choose to engage in com-

    petitive reserve accumulation to improve and maintain their competitiveness inexporting to industrial countries. Thus, for example, as long as China and its East Asianneighbors are trying to maintain competitiveness in exporting to the United States,those countries with lower costs of sterilization, due for example to greater willingnessto distort their financial systems, might end up hoarding increasingly large amounts ofinternational reserves, winning the hoarding game at least in the short run. Arguably,this interpretation explains Chinas unprecedented increase in foreign reserves from2002, now amounting to almost 50% of GDP and well above the levels of other EastAsia countries (see Aizenman and Lee, 2008). Yet, this outcome may be fragile if itinduces a country to accumulate to levels where the costs of sterilization exceed the

    benefit. These observations are consistent with the World Economic Outlook (2007),finding that resisting nominal exchange rate appreciation through sterilized interven-tion is likely to be ineffective when the influx of capital is persistent and large. Indeed,Chinas recently rising costs of sterilization may account for its recent decline insterilization and increasing inflation.

    Our finding of significant changes in the degree of sterilization by many emergingmarket countries is consistent with a new Trilemma configuration, in which emergingmarket countries engage in foreign reserve accumulation while at the same timeseeking to preserve some degree of monetary autonomy. Fuller investigation of thechanging nature and degree of exchange rate flexibility, financial integration, and

    monetary autonomy among emerging market countries is left for further research.

    Appendix

    This appendix analyzes the costs of sterilization by formulating a model of the deter-minants of the substitutability between domestic and foreign bonds as characterized bythe marginal increase in the interest rate differential associated with reducing the shareof foreign bonds in private portfolios.

    We consider a country where agents face financial repression and uncertainty about

    domestic price inflation, currency depreciation, and the tax rate on returns. The realyields to domestic residents to holding domestic and foreign bonds (B, B*) are

    r i= , (A1)

    r i e t * * *= + , (A2)

    where i, i* denote nominal interest returns, p is the domestic inflation rate, e is thedepreciation rate of domestic currency, and t* is the tax on returns to holding foreignassets, reflecting the realized costs of financial repression;p, e, and t* are all stochastic.The tax rate t* reflects the de facto degree of financial repression, which may include

    regulations inhibiting or penalizing the holding of foreign assets.We assume agents are risk averse, with mean variance preferences:

    STERILIZATION, MONETARY POLICY, AND FINANCIAL INTEGRATION 797

  • 8/6/2019 Sterilization_ Monetary Policy_ and Global Financila Integration_2

    22/26

    The expected real yield differential can be solved as

    E * E*

    *r rB

    Wr r[ ] [ ] = ( ) 2 , (A4)

    where

    =

    = = +

    r r r r r

    r r

    r r r r r r r

    U W

    U

    2

    2

    2

    1

    2 2 22 2, ,; ;* *

    ** * * rr*.

    Hence, sterilized intervention that reduces the share of foreign assets in the privateportfolio, B*/W, increases the expected interest rate differential, E[r] - E[r*], by thedegree of risk aversion times the variance of the real interest rate differential, r r *

    2 .The variables p, e, and t* are all stochastic. Specifically, we denote by ak k, the

    constant and the shock associated with variables k, k = p, e, t*, as

    = + = + = +a e a t ae e t t ; ; .* *

    We further assume (i) expected domestic inflation and the depreciation rate are cor-related, (ii) shocks are zero mean and may be correlated, and (iii) there are two typesof agents (i = l, h), with differential costs of holding foreign assets reflecting potentiallydifferent degrees of risk aversion, with the favored type i = lhaving a low t*, implying

    = + = + = +( ) = >a e e a t c a i l h c ce e i t t h l ; ; , , , ,* * *

    where E[ep] = E[ee] = E[et*] = 0.Noting that r- r* = i - i* + t* - e, it follows that

    r r t e t e t e i ic ct t e t e = + = ( ) +* * * * * * *2 2 2 2 2

    2 2, , e2

    . (A5)

    Consequently,

    d

    dcc

    r r

    i

    i t t e t e

    = ( )

    ** * *

    222 , . (A6)

    We presume that the correlation between depreciation and the financial repression taxis positive, i.e. t e*, > 0 (see Giovannini and De Melo, 1993).

    Expression (A6) implies that a higher correlation between the exchange rate depre-

    ciation rate and financial repression tax reduces the cost of sterilization. This effect islarger the greater is the extent of financial repression (i.e. the higher is c, and the greateris the share of agents facing higher c). In the limiting case when the correlationapproaches 1, it follows that et* @ kee, where k is a constant, and

    r r it e e

    c k ( )* *2

    1

    2 21,

    . (A7)

    Consequently, the ability to sterilize depends on imperfect substitutability of assets ina world where the cost of trading assets varies systematically across agents (due topossible scale effects) and across asset classes (due to varying liquidity and risk char-

    acteristics). Policies fostering greater domestic financial repression also reduce thecosts of sterilization. This suggests that countries able and willing to engage in greaterfinancial sterilization will be able to sustain the policy configuration of reserve hoarding

    798 Joshua Aizenman and Reuven Glick

  • 8/6/2019 Sterilization_ Monetary Policy_ and Global Financila Integration_2

    23/26

    References

    Aizenman, Joshua and Reuven Glick, Pegged Exchange Rate Regimes: A Trap? Journal ofMoney, Credit and Banking 40 (2008a):81735.

    ,Sterilization, Monetary Policy, and Global Financial Integration, NBER working paper13902 (revised August) (2008b).

    Aizenman, Joshua and Jae-woo Lee,Financial versus Monetary MercantilismLong-Run Viewof Large International Reserves Hoarding, The World Economy 31 (2008):593611.

    Aizenman Joshua and Nancy Marion,The High Demand for International Reserves in the FarEast: Whats Going On? Journal of the Japanese and International Economies 17 (2003):370400.

    , International Reserves Holdings with Sovereign Risk and Costly Tax Collection,Economic Journal 114 (2004):56991.

    Cheung, Yin-Wong and Hiro Ito, Hoarding of International Reserves: A Comparison of theAsian and Latin American Experiences, in R. S. Rajan, S. Thangavelu, and R. A. Parinduri(eds), Monetary, Exchange Rate, and Financial Issues and Policies in Asia , Singapore: WorldScientific Press (2008):77116.

    Cochrane, John, Production-Based Asset Pricing and the Link between Stock Returns and

    Economic Fluctuation, Journal of Finance 46 (1991):20937.Edwards, Sebastian and Eduardo Levy-Yeyati, Flexible Exchange Rates as Shock Absorbers,

    European Economic Review 49 (2005):2079105.Eichengreen, Barry, Kicking the Habit: Moving from Pegged Rates to Greater Exchange Rate

    Flexibility, Economic Journal 109 (1999):114.Fischer, Stanley, Exchange Rate Regimes: Is the Bipolar View Correct? Journal of Economic

    Perspectives 15 (2001):324.Frankel, Jeffrey, No Single Currency Regime is Right for all Countries or at all Times, NBER

    working paper 7338, September (1999).Giovannini, Alberto and Martha De Melo, Government Revenue from Financial Repression,

    American Economic Review 83 (1993):95363.

    Glick, Reuven and Michael M. Hutchison, Foreign Reserve and Money Dynamics with AssetPortfolio Adjustment: International Evidence, Journal of International Financial Markets,Institutions, and Money 10 (2000):22947.

    Levy-Yeyati, Eduardo, Liquidity Insurance in a Financially Dollarized Economy, in SebastianEdwards and Mrcio Gomes Pinto (eds), Financial Markets Volatility and Performance inEmerging Markets, Chicago: University of Chicago Press (2008):185211.

    Mohanty, M. S. and Philip Turner, Foreign Exchange Reserve Accumulation in Emerging Mar-kets: What are the Domestic Implications? BIS Quarterly Review, September (2006):3952.

    Obstfeld, Maury and Kenneth Rogoff, The Mirage of Fixed Exchange Rates, Journal ofEconomic Perspectives 9 (1995):7396.

    Obstfeld, Maury, Jay Shambaugh, and Alan M. Taylor, The Trilemma in History: Tradeoffs

    among Exchange Rates, Monetary Policies, and Capital Mobility, Review of Economics andStatistics 3 (2005):42338.

    Ouyang, Alice, Ramkishen Rajan, and Thomas Willett, China as a Reserve Sink: The Evidencefrom Offset and Sterilization Coefficients, Hong Kong Institute for Monetary Researchworking paper 2007-10, October (2007).

    World Economic Outlook,Managing Large Capital Inflows, Ch. 3 in World Economic Outlook,Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund, October (2007).

    Notes

    1. This message has been communicated in well-known papers by Obstfeld and Rogoff (1995)and Fischer (2001). Related papers have raised the possibility that a pegged exchange rate cancreate a trap in an era of greater financial integration whereby the regime initially confers

    STERILIZATION, MONETARY POLICY, AND FINANCIAL INTEGRATION 799

  • 8/6/2019 Sterilization_ Monetary Policy_ and Global Financila Integration_2

    24/26

    enough adverse real shock that creates large welfare losses to the economy (see Eichengreen,1999; Frankel, 1999; Edwards and Levy-Yeyati, 2005; Aizenman and Glick, 2008a).2. The list of countries with similar experiences is much longer (e.g., Russia, Brazil, and others).Our reference here to Mexico and East Asia is mostly due to the timing of their crises, each beingthe first in its respective region to experience a sudden stop episode, triggered by the sharpreversal of short-term financial flows (hot money).

    3. Note that exchange rate stability may remain a desirable policy goal. A heavily managed floatallows countries to stabilize their exchange rate, while retaining the option of exchange rateadjustment in the presence of large shocks without undergoing a balance of payments crisis.Similarly, countries may opt for a stable exchange rate, though at the cost of less monetaryindependence (see the experiences of Estonia, Hong Kong, and other countries). Hence, in linewith the Trilemma, the trend towards greater financial integration by developing countriesimplies that they must trade off the benefits of financial integration against the costs of reducedmonetary autonomy and/or more flexible exchange rates.4. For these reasons, even countries that maintained fixed exchange rates, such as Chinauntil mid-2005, opted to support their pegs by accumulating sizable amounts of foreignreserves.

    5. Monetary authorities also may seek to sterilize the effects of reserve inflows, not just on thereserve money base, but also on the broader money supply by, for example, increasing compul-sory reserve requirements on bank deposits. China, for example, has raised reserve requirementssignificantly in recent years.6. Using four-quarter changes helps to smooth the data by eliminating much of the quarter-to-quarter noise.7. Specifically, we define DFRt = (SLC/$)t(FR$t - FR$t-1) - (FLt - FLt-1), where FR$ denotesforeign reserves in dollars (IMF line 11d), SLC/$ is the local currency price of the dollar, FLdenotes financial liabilities of the central bank (IMF line 16c), and D is the change operator.Accordingly, we define DDC= DRM- DFR.8. The exception is the period 1993 when China sterilized the effects of foreign reserve outflows

    by expanding the reserve money stock by increasing domestic asset holdings.9. The sample period for Argentina and Brazil begins four quarters after the implementation oftheir monetary reforms1992Q1 for Argentina and 1995Q2 for Brazil.10. We imputed quarterly GDP growth for some countries in our sample from a moving averageof the prior-year, current, and following-year observations.11. We begin with the sample period 1984Q21994Q1, roll to 1984Q31994Q2, etc., ending with1997Q32007Q2, depending on data availability.12. Note that the sterilization coefficient is only one parameter determining the stance ofmonetary policy. Fuller understanding of monetary policy requires information about changes inprivate and public banks reserve requirements, discount window operations, etc.13. The figures report one standard error bands, using NeweyWest errors adjusted for serialcorrelation of up to three quarters.14. Central bank balance sheet data for China are available only from 1985Q3, implying that thefirst four-quarter change observation begins in 1986Q2, and the first 40-quarter rolling sampleperiod is 1986Q21996Q1.15. Chinas sovereign wealth fund, the China Investment Corporation, was not formally estab-lished until the latter half of 2007 with an initial capitalization of $200 billion out of Chinas totalreserve holdings then of more than $1.3 trillion. But there are indications of central bank assetshifts to its predecessor institution, Huijins Investment, and to some Chinese commercial banksbefore then. Netting these amounts against reported foreign reserve holdings would reduce themagnitude of foreign reserve inflows and raise the implied level of central bank domestic assets,resulting in a lower estimated degree of sterilization.16. For Argentina, monetary policy was initially stabilized with the adoption of its currencyboard in 1991Q1, implying that the first four-quarter change observation begins in 1992Q1, andthe first 40-quarter rolling sample period is 1992Q12001Q4. For Brazil, the first 40-quarter

    800 Joshua Aizenman and Reuven Glick

  • 8/6/2019 Sterilization_ Monetary Policy_ and Global Financila Integration_2

    25/26

    17. In the first specification we also include a lagged dependent variable as well as threequarterly dummies as explanatory variables. See Mohanty and Turner (2006) who employ asimilar specification; also see Glick and Hutchison (2000) who use an unconstrained vectorerror-correction approach to estimate sterilization dynamics.18. We include Argentina and Brazil in the sample only 10 years after the implementation oftheir monetary reforms, 2002Q1 for Argentina and 2005Q2 for Brazil.

    19. We are aware of potential biases inherent in using prior knowledge to pick break dates. Forthis reason we deliberately avoided choosing break dates based on the inflection points of ourrolling regression plots.We do not feel that our general conclusions would be affected by use ofmore sophisticated time-series approaches to identifying breaks.20. Assuming a possible moving-average error length of twice the number of overlappingquarters accounts for possible serial correlation not just from the overlap, but from other sourcesas well (e.g. see Cochrane, 1991).21. It should be noted that we do not take account of possible simultaneity bias because netforeign reserve changes may respond to domestic monetary policy, particularly when the centralbank intervenes and affects the exchange rate. However, prior work seeking to control for thepossible endogeneity of the explanatory variables in sterilization regressions through instrumen-

    tal estimation has not found much effect on coefficient magnitudes and their standard errors ascompared to OLS (e.g. Ouyang et al., 2007).22. The inclusion of nominal GDP renders the break term insignificant in the cases of Thailandand Singapore.23. The increase in sterilization was significant for both Argentina and Brazil in Table 1, wherewe controlled for other determinants of domestic monetary policy with nominal GDP, but did notallow for any break in the response to this variable. Evidently, allowing a break in the responseto inflation, as in column (3) in Table 2, soaks up the effect of a break in sterilization behavior.The result in Table 2 for Argentina is particularly problematic as the coefficient on the interactiveterm with reserve inflows is significant and positive; in this case the coefficient on the interactiveinflation term is unusually large (in absolute value) as well as significant.

    24. If the central bank is insensitive to any concerns about the relative magnitudes of differentcomponents of the balance of payments one would expect that the relevant regression coeffi-cients would be insignificant. The discussion about the risks of growing exposure to hot moneysuggests that the central bank may indeed adjust its policies to reflect greater concern about hotmoney rather than about FDI flows.25. The quarterly data on dollar-denominated balance of payments flows are converted intolocal currency terms using the average local currency price of the dollar for each quarter.26. Note that this proxy ignores the adverse valuation effects from continued appreciation of theyuan and other Asian currencies.27. Sterilization operations in this form also have costs. For example, reserve requirements actlike a tax on banks which reduces financial intermediation and imposes a form of repression onthe financial system.28. Our discussion points out that the costs of sterilization are the sum of direct opportunitycosts and indirect costs associated with financial repression in the form of capital controls andhigher reserve requirements imposed on the banking system. As the focus of our paper is on thepositive aspects of recent sterilization trends, we do not attempt to estimate the overall costs ofsterilization. Nevertheless, our discussion is consistent with changes in the direct opportunitycosts of holding reserves affecting the patterns of sterilization. Further investigation of theseissues is left for future research.

    STERILIZATION, MONETARY POLICY, AND FINANCIAL INTEGRATION 801

  • 8/6/2019 Sterilization_ Monetary Policy_ and Global Financila Integration_2

    26/26