Shengyu Zhang The Chinese University of Hong Kong.

35
Shengyu Zhang The Chinese University of Hong Kong

Transcript of Shengyu Zhang The Chinese University of Hong Kong.

Shengyu Zhang

The Chinese University of Hong Kong

Content

Classical game theory. Quantum games: models. Quantum strategic games: relation to

classical equilibria. Quantum advantage against classical players Quantum advantage with quantum players.

Quantum information processing Understanding the power of quantum

Computation: quantum algorithms/complexity Communication: quantum info. theory Cryptography: quantum cryptography, quantum

algorithm breaking classical cryptosystems.

Another field: game theory

Game: Two basic forms

strategic (normal) form extensive form

Game: Two basic forms

strategic (normal) form

players: , …, has a set of

strategies has a utility

function ℝ

Equilibrium

Equilibrium: each player has adopted an optimal strategy, provided that others keep their strategies unchanged

Classical strategic games

is an equilibrium if ,

Nash equilibrium: is product distribution. Correlated equilibrium: is general distribution.

𝑠1′

𝑠2′

𝑝

output utility

𝑢1(𝑠1′ ,𝑠2

′ )

𝑢2(𝑠1′ ,𝑠2

′ )

𝑠1

𝑠2

potentialaction

“quantum games”

Non-local games

EWL-quantization of strategic games*1

Others Meyer’s Penny Matching*2 Gutoski-Watrous framework for refereed game*3

*1. Eisert, Wilkens, Lewenstein, Phys. Rev. Lett., 1999.*2. Meyer, Phys. Rev. Lett., 1999.*3. Gutoski and Watrous, STOC, 2007.

EWL model

𝐽

⋮⋮ ⋮

𝒔𝟏

𝒔𝒏

|0

|0

What’s this classically?

𝒖𝟏(𝒔)

𝒖𝒏(𝒔)

States of concern

output utilitypotential

action

EWL model

Classically we don’t undo the sampling (or do any re-sampling) after players’ actions. If a joint operation is allowed, then a simple swapping solves

Prisoner’s Dilemma classically!

𝐽

⋮⋮ ⋮

|0

|0

𝒔𝟏

𝒔𝒏

𝒖𝟏(𝒔)

𝒖𝒏(𝒔)

output utilitypotential

action

EWL model

𝐽

⋮⋮ ⋮

|0

|0

and consider the state at this point

𝒔𝟏

𝒔𝒏

𝒖𝟏(𝒔)

𝒖𝒏(𝒔)

output utilitypotential

action

Quantum strategic games

⋮ ⋮ρ

and consider the state at this point

A simpler model, corresponding to classical

games more precisely.

CPTP

𝒔𝟏

𝒔𝒏

𝒖𝟏(𝒔)

𝒖𝒏(𝒔)

output utilitypotential

action

*1. Zhang, ITCS, 2012.

Other than the model

Main differences than previous work in quantum strategic games:

We consider general games of growing sizes. Previous: specific games, usually 2*2 or 3*3

We study quantitative questions. Previous work: advantages exist? Ours: How much can it be?

Central question: How much “advantage” can playing quantum provide?

Measure 1: Increase of payoff Measure 2: Hardness of generation

First measure: increase of payoff We will define natural correspondences

between classical distributions and quantum states.

And examine how well the equilibrium property is preserved.

Quantum equilibrium

classical quantum

Φ1

Φn

⋮ ⋮

s1

sn

⋮ρ

u1(s)

un(s)

C1

Cn

s1’

sn’⋮p → s

u1(s’)

un(s’)

classical equilibrium:

No player wants to do anything to the assigned strategy si, if others do nothing on their parts- p = p1…pn: Nash equilibrium- general p: correlated equilibrium

quantum equilibrium:

No player wants to do anything to the assigned strategy ρ|Hi, if others do nothing on their parts- ρ = ρ1… ρn: quantum Nash equilibrium- general ρ: quantum correlated equilibrium

Correspondence of classical and quantum states

classical quantum

p: p(s) = ρss

(measure in comp. basis)

ρ

p: distri. on S

ρp = ∑s p(s) |ss| (classical mixture)

|ψp = ∑s√p(s) |s (quantum superposition)

ρ s.t. p(s) = ρss (general class)

Φ1

Φn

⋮ ⋮s1

sn

⋮ρC1

Cn

⋮s1’

sn’⋮p→s

Preservation of equilibrium?

classical quantum

p: p(s) = ρss ρ

p

ρp = ∑s p(s) |ss|

|ψp = ∑s√p(s) |s

ρ s.t. p(s) = ρss

Obs: ρ is a quantum Nash/correlated equilibrium p is a (classical) Nash/correlated equilibrium

p NE CE

ρp

|ψp

gen. ρ

Question: Maximum additive and multiplicative increase of payoff (in a [0,1]-normalized game, |Si| = n)?

Maximum additive increase

classical quantum

p: p(s) = ρss ρ

p

ρp = ∑s p(s) |ss|

|ψp = ∑s√p(s) |s

ρ s.t. p(s) = ρss

p NE CE

ρp 0 0

|ψp 0 1-Õ(1/log n)

gen. ρ 1-1/n 1-1/n

max payoff increase, additive

Question: Maximum additive and multiplicative increase of payoff (in a [0,1]-normalized game, |Si| = n)?

Maximum multiplicative increase

classical quantum

p: p(s) = ρss ρ

p

ρp = ∑s p(s) |ss|

|ψp = ∑s√p(s) |s

ρ s.t. p(s) = ρss

p NE CE

ρp 1 1

|ψp 1 Ω(n0.585…)

gen. ρ n n

Question: Maximum additive and multiplicative increase of payoff (in a [0,1]-normalized game, |Si| = n)?

max payoff increase, multipliative

Next

Classical game theory. Quantum games: models. Quantum strategic games: relation to

classical equilibria. Quantum advantage against classical players Quantum advantage with quantum players.

Meyer’s game: classical

Actions : to flip or not to flip

Alice’s Goal: 0. Bob’s Goal: 1. A Nash equilibrium: flip with half prob.

Then each wins with half prob.

0 0/1?

Meyer’s game: quantum

Bob remains classical: is either or identity. Alice is quantum: can be any 1-qubit

operation. Alice’s Goal: . Bob’s Goal: . Now Alice can win for sure by applying a

Hadamard gate. . .

|0 ⟩ or ?

Meyer’s game: fairness issue

Despite the quantum advantage, there is clear a fairness issue. Alice has two actions. And the actions are in a fixed order of .

Question: Can quantum advantage still exist in a more fair setting?

For fairness: each player makes just one action, simultaneously. This is nothing but strategic games!

|0 ⟩ or ?

Quantization*1 of strategic game: Penny Matching

is an equilibrium if both players are classical, Each wins with half prob.

If Alice turns to quantum: turns into . Then she wins for sure! Message: quantum player has a huge advantage when playing

against a classical player.

|𝑎 ⟩

|𝑏 ⟩

goal:

goal:

|𝜑 ⟩

*1. Zu, Wang, Chang, Wei, Zhang, Duan, NJP, 2012.

¿¿¿

potential action classical outcome utility

Quantization of strategic game: Penny Matching

State is symmetric, so it doesn’t matter who takes which qubit.

We can also let the classical player Bob to choose the target goal. If Bob wants , then Alice applies .

¿|0 ⟩ ¿¿

|𝑎 ⟩

|𝑏 ⟩

goal:

goal:

|𝜑 ⟩¿¿¿

potential action classical outcome utility

Quantum advantage in strategic games

is an equilibrium if both players are classical, each winning with prob. = ½

If Alice uses quantum, increases her winning prob. to ¾. Question*2: Is discord necessary?

Yes, if each player’s part (of the shared state) is a qubit, No, if each player’s part (of the shared state) has dimension 3 or more.

Entangled. Necessary?

No! No entanglement. But has discord.

*2. Wei, Zhang, manuscript, 2014.

|𝑎 ⟩

|𝑏 ⟩

goal:

goal:

|𝜑 ⟩¿¿¿

potential action classical outcome utility

Games between quantum players After these examples, Bob realizes that he

should use quantum computers as well. Question: Any advantage when both players are

quantum? Previous correspondence results imply a

negative answer for complete information games.

But quantum advantage exists for Bayesian games!

Quantum Bayesian games

Each player has a private input/type . is known to Player only. The joint input is drawn from some distribution .

Each player can potentially apply some operation . A measurement in the computational basis gives output for

Player , who receives utility .

|𝑦1 ⟩

|𝑦2 ⟩

|𝜑 ⟩(𝑥1 , 𝑥2)←𝑃

𝑢1(𝑥1 , 𝑥2, 𝑦1 , 𝑦2)

𝑢2(𝑥1 ,𝑥2, 𝑦 1, 𝑦 2)

potential actionclassical outcome utility

Quantum Bayesian games

Classical state distribution . Classical strategy . Classical payoff

is equilibrium if no player can gain a higher payoff by changing her strategy unilaterally.

|𝑦1 ⟩

|𝑦2 ⟩

|𝜑 ⟩(𝑥1 , 𝑥2)←𝑃

𝑢1(𝑥1 , 𝑥2, 𝑦1 , 𝑦2)

𝑢2(𝑥1 ,𝑥2, 𝑦 1, 𝑦 2)

potential actionclassical outcome utility

Quantum Bayesian games

Quantum strategy , . Quantum payoff

is equilibrium if no player can gain a higher payoff by changing her strategy unilaterally.

|𝑦1 ⟩

|𝑦2 ⟩

|𝜑 ⟩(𝑥1 , 𝑥2)←𝑃

𝑢1(𝑥1 , 𝑥2, 𝑦1 , 𝑦2)

𝑢2(𝑥1 ,𝑥2, 𝑦 1, 𝑦 2)

potential actionclassical outcome utility

Quantum Bayesian games

*1. Pappa, Kumar, Lawson, Santha, Zhang, Diamanti, Kerenidis, PRL, 2015.

A game*1 combining Battle of the Sexes and CHSH.

The players need to coordinate like in CHSH, except when , in which case they need to anti-coordinate.

In Table I, they have conflicting interest.

|𝑦1 ⟩

|𝑦2 ⟩

|𝜑 ⟩(𝑥1 , 𝑥2)←𝑃

𝑢1(𝑥1 , 𝑥2, 𝑦1 , 𝑦2)

𝑢2(𝑥1 ,𝑥2, 𝑦 1, 𝑦 2)

potential actionclassical outcome utility

Quantum Bayesian games

*1. Pappa, Kumar, Lawson, Santha, Zhang, Diamanti, Kerenidis, PRL, 2015.

is uniform. Classical:

And a fair equilibrium with

Quantum: a fair equilibrium with

|𝑦1 ⟩

|𝑦2 ⟩

|𝜑 ⟩(𝑥1 , 𝑥2)←𝑃

𝑢1(𝑥1 , 𝑥2, 𝑦1 , 𝑦2)

𝑢2(𝑥1 ,𝑥2, 𝑦 1, 𝑦 2)

potential actionclassical outcome utility

Viewed as non-locality

Traditional quantum non-local games exhibit quantum advantages when the two players have the common goal. CHSH, GHZ, Magic Square Game, Hidden Matching

Game, Brunner-Linden game. Now the two players have conflicting interests. Quantum advantages still exist. Message: If both players play quantum strategies in

an equilibrium, they can also have advantage over both being classical.

Summary

Quantum strategic games: be careful with the model.

Quantum vs. classical: quantum has advantage.

Quantum vs. quantum: both have advantages compared to both being classical.

(Experiments for the above two results.) The field of quantum game theory: call for

more systematic studies in proper models.