Rescission and Repricing of Executive Stock Options

21
Rescission and Repricing of Executive Stock Options Jerry T. Yang Eller College of Business and Public Administration University of Arizona Willard T. Carleton Eller College of Business and Public Administration University of Arizona First draft: October 2001 Current draft: March 2002

description

Rescission and Repricing of Executive Stock Options. Jerry T. Yang Eller College of Business and Public Administration University of Arizona  Willard T. Carleton Eller College of Business and Public Administration University of Arizona. First draft:October 2001 - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Transcript of Rescission and Repricing of Executive Stock Options

Page 1: Rescission and Repricing of Executive Stock Options

Rescission and Repricing of Executive Stock Options

Jerry T. Yang Eller College of Business and Public Administration

University of Arizona 

 Willard T. CarletonEller College of Business and Public Administration

University of Arizona

First draft: October 2001Current draft: March 2002

Page 2: Rescission and Repricing of Executive Stock Options

Repricing options is a process of canceling existing outstanding

options and reissuing new options at a lower strike price.

 

[Traditional repricings simply lower the exercise prices of existing options.]

Page 3: Rescission and Repricing of Executive Stock Options

Rescission 

is a business practice in which employees are allowed to cancel already-exercised options

when share prices fell.

[Essentially, this practice allows companies to buy back the shares resulting from previous option exercises at original strike prices which are higher than current market values. Replacement options are usually issued following the cancellation. This tax-motivated strategy is designed to rescue employees who would not have sufficient proceeds from selling the stock to pay the tax occurring after option exercise, because of subsequent stock price declines.]

Page 4: Rescission and Repricing of Executive Stock Options

Generally, we ask: To reprice (rescind) or not to reprice (rescind)? Do accounting (variable) charges matter?

Page 5: Rescission and Repricing of Executive Stock Options

7. Model - Figure 1t = 0 t = 1 t = 2 Share Value Agent's payoffs

Figure 1. A two-period binomial model and distribution of terminal cash flows.

I[ a]

H[ ah ]

L [ al ]

HH = (1+u)2 fhh whh

HL = 1 - u2 fhl whl

LH = 1 - u2 flh wlh

LL = (1-u)2 fll wll

P(ah)

1-P(ah)

P(ai)

1-P(ai)

P(a)

1-P(a)

Page 6: Rescission and Repricing of Executive Stock Options

1.Risk neutral for both agent and principal2.All payoffs are assumed to be received at the

terminal date t = 23.No layoff and bankruptcy will occur

throughout these two periods.4.All discount rates are zero to simplify the

notation.5.Our model in essence is a one-period model

with an interim period in which possible occurrence of repricing or rescission is anticipated by both parties.

• The agent is compensated with stock options only.

Assumptions

Page 7: Rescission and Repricing of Executive Stock Options

Assumptions6. Homogeneous expectation:

p(H) = qm + (1-q)a = 1-p(L), where H = 1+u, L = 1-ua [0,1] is taken by the agent.m [0,1]: the influence of external factorsq [0,1]: the influence of agent's action on p(H)

To keep our focus on the issues motivating this paper, we assume that m and q are common knowledge between the principal and the agent.

• Only the tax benefit (or liability) resulting from the new accounting rulings has an economic impact on firm value.

• Exogenous probability () of underwater options being repriced at node L (but both the principal and the agent have the same expectation about .)

• All options are granted at the money.

Page 8: Rescission and Repricing of Executive Stock Options

Model -Table 1The principal's expected share values at the terminal date.

LL + c[ (1-L) +

(LL-L) ]LLLL + c[ (1-L) +

(LL-L) ]

LLfll

LHLHflh

HL + c (1-HL) HL + c (1-

HL)

HLHLfhl

fhh

Repricing + Rescission

RescissionRepricingDo NothingScenarios

• BR ( = c[ (1-L) + (LH-L) ] ) is the tax benefit resulting from

the accounting charges associated with repricing, where c is the

corporate tax rate. * Repricing occurs at node L; reset the exercise price to L for all

options.

1

cHH

1

cHH

1

cHH

1

cHH

1

cHH

1

BLLH R

Page 9: Rescission and Repricing of Executive Stock Options

Model - Table 2The agent's terminal payoffs if initial call options on firm's terminal value are granted.

0000wll

( flh - L) 0

( flh - L) 0wlh

0000whl

( fhh - 1) ( fhh - 1) ( fhh - 1) ( fhh - 1)* whh

Repricing + Rescission

Rescission Repricing Do Nothing Scenarios

** Note that personal taxes are ignored and the options are granted at-the-money (hence the exercise price is unity).

** Repricing occurs at node L; reset the exercise price to L for all options.

Page 10: Rescission and Repricing of Executive Stock Options

Table 3The agent's terminal payoffs

if initial call options are exercised at node H

00wll

00wlh

0fhl - 1) - Twhl

fhh - 1) - Tfhh - 1) - Twhh

Rescission2 Do Nothing1 Scenarios

* Personal taxes are considered.* T = c(H-1) is the tax liability (benefit) for the agent (principal).

* fhh = fhl =

1

THH

1

THL

Page 11: Rescission and Repricing of Executive Stock Options

* Personal taxes are considered.* T = c(H-1) is the tax liability (benefit) for the agent (principal).

* fhh = fhl =

Table 4The principal's net terminal payoffs

if initial call options are exercised at node H.

LLLLLL

LHLHLH

HL + c(1- HL) 3 fhl >HL

fhh fhh HH

Rescission2 Do Nothing1 Scenarios

1

THH

1

THL

Page 12: Rescission and Repricing of Executive Stock Options

Model - Equilibrium under Do-nothingUnder the do-nothing strategy, the agent's best responses A() = {a, ah , al } are

al = 0, (3.8)

ah () = min{1, (1-q)( fhh -1)/k },

a () = min{1, (1- q) Uh () / k }

where fhh = (c: corporate tax rate)

Uh () = [ p(ah ()) ][ (fhh -1) ] - (1/2) k [a h ()]2

Then the principal's expected initial payoff given W and A() is

V(, Vh ,Vl ) = p(a) Vh + [1- p(a)] Vl

The principal's objective is to choose an initial grant, *, to maximize his/her expected initial payoff, given the agent's compensation profile W and expected actions A() = {a , ah , al }.

1

HH c

Page 13: Rescission and Repricing of Executive Stock Options

7. Model - Figure 1t = 0 t = 1 t = 2 Share Value Agent's payoffs

Figure 1. A two-period binomial model and distribution of terminal cash flows.

I[ a]

H[ ah ]

L [ al ]

HH = (1+u)2 fhh whh

HL = 1 - u2 fhl whl

LH = 1 - u2 flh wlh

LL = (1-u)2 fll wll

P(ah)

1-P(ah)

P(ai)

1-P(ai)

P(a)

1-P(a)

Page 14: Rescission and Repricing of Executive Stock Options

<1>Shareholders concern about:[1] why not penalize employees for poor

performance or why they even reward employees' poor performance by repricing underwater options.

[2]"If the company doesn't fare well, it completely undermines the purpose of an option plan to simply change the rules," said Eric Roiter, general counsel for Fidelity Management & Research Co.

Page 15: Rescission and Repricing of Executive Stock Options

<2>Employers or top executives concern about:

[1] finding an effective way to attract and retain top talent.

[2] boosting employees' morale.

[3] protecting self interests

Page 16: Rescission and Repricing of Executive Stock Options

<3>Employees concern about:[1] having no money to pay tax bills and margin

loans when the stock price plummeted.

[2] "sell to cover"?

[3] finding another job which pays "real" money.

[4] At 40% of companies that issues stock options in 1999, those options were underwater in January 2001, according to TIAA-CREF

Page 17: Rescission and Repricing of Executive Stock Options

Reasons for Using Executive Stock Options

[1] Align executives' interest with shareholders'. (However, with convex payoff structures, options have no value unless they are in-the-money.)

[2] Attract and/or retain key employees (especially for cash-starved companies)

[3] The only form of compensation that does not result in financial expense for the company. (Companies do not have to deduct the cost of options from their income, as they must for wages paid in cash.)

[4] Tax deduction

Page 18: Rescission and Repricing of Executive Stock Options

Contributions Lay foundation of evaluating repricing

alternatives Shed light on optimality of repricing

whileconsidering dilution effects and tax effects.

Examine the optimality of rescission.

Page 19: Rescission and Repricing of Executive Stock Options

Conclusion Repricing is indifferent, on average, from

no-repricing in terms of the principal's expected initial payoffs.(see table)

Repricing loses its ex-ante dominance over do-nothing strategy as claimed by AJS after we incorporate dilution effects and the tax effects of new accounting rules associated with repricing.

Page 20: Rescission and Repricing of Executive Stock Options

Conclusion The principal is, on average, better off in terms

of expected initial payoffs under rescission than under a do-nothing policy.(see table 7)

Under rescission, we see little change on the principal`s initial incentive contract decision, a higher a*, and a slightly lower a*h (negative feedback effect).

Page 21: Rescission and Repricing of Executive Stock Options

Conclusion Under some conditions, ESOs do indeed

encourage agent`s risk-taking actions, even from an ex-ante viewpoint.

Estimate a wide range of agency costs.(see table 5)