Psurplus Handout

6
 Producer’s Surplus Philip A. Viton October 24, 2011 Philip A. Viton  ()  CRP 763 — Producer’s Surplus  Oct obe r 24, 201 1 1 / 22 Introduction We have seen how to evaluate consumer’s wtp for a market-induced price change: we measure this (with appropriate cautions, primarily that we treat it as an approximation) by the change in consumer’s surplus, the area under the demand function between the two price horizontals. We now address to the remaining question in market-induced (price) changes: how to evaluate the bene…ts to  producers  or  …rms . Fortunately this is easy, and has none of the complications of consumer’s surplus. The obviously correct measure of bene…ts to …rms is  pro…ts . If a project changes the level of the …rm’s pro…ts, we measure the impact by the change in its pro…ts. Philip A. Viton  ()  CRP 763 — Producer’s Surplus  Oct obe r 24, 201 1 2 / 22 Pro…ts Consider a …rm selling  x 1  units of output at price  p 1 . Its Total Revenues (TR) are  p 1   x 1 . Write its Total Costs as  TC . Then pro…ts are Total Revenues minus Total Costs or: Π =  TR  TC . Philip A. Viton  ()  CRP 763 — Producer’s Surplus  Oct ober 24, 201 1 3 / 22 Total Costs: Fixed and Variable Typically a …rm will have both …xed and variable costs. So write total costs as: TC  = TFC  + TVC Then we have: Π =  TR   (TFC  + TVC ) Philip A. Viton  ()  CRP 763 — Producer’s Surplus  Oct obe r 24, 201 1 4 / 22

description

Psurplus Handout

Transcript of Psurplus Handout

  • Producers Surplus

    Philip A. Viton

    October 24, 2011

    Philip A. Viton ()CRP 763 Producers Surplus October 24, 2011 1 / 22

    Introduction

    We have seen how to evaluate consumers wtp for a market-inducedprice change: we measure this (with appropriate cautions, primarilythat we treat it as an approximation) by the change in consumerssurplus, the area under the demand function between the two pricehorizontals.

    We now address to the remaining question in market-induced (price)changes: how to evaluate the benets to producers or rms.

    Fortunately this is easy, and has none of the complications ofconsumers surplus.

    The obviously correct measure of benets to rms is prots.

    If a project changes the level of the rms prots, we measure theimpact by the change in its prots.

    Philip A. Viton ()CRP 763 Producers Surplus October 24, 2011 2 / 22

    Prots

    Consider a rm selling x1 units of output at price p1.

    Its Total Revenues (TR) are p1 x1.Write its Total Costs as TC .

    Then prots are Total Revenues minus Total Costs or:

    = TR TC .

    Philip A. Viton ()CRP 763 Producers Surplus October 24, 2011 3 / 22

    Total Costs: Fixed and Variable

    Typically a rm will have both xed and variable costs.

    So write total costs as:

    TC = TFC + TVC

    Then we have: = TR (TFC + TVC )

    Philip A. Viton ()CRP 763 Producers Surplus October 24, 2011 4 / 22

  • Change in Prots

    Suppose a project changes revenues from TRa to TRb and costs fromTC a to TC b

    Using our decomposition of costs, we have

    = b a= (TRb TC b) (TRa TC a)= (TRb (TFC + TVC b)) (TRa (TFC + TVC a))= (TRb TVC b) (TRa TVC a)

    since by denition xed costs are unchanged by the project.The quantity

    PS = TR TVCis called the rms Producer Surplus.So we see that the change in the rms prots () is the same asthe change in producers surplus:

    = PSb PSa = PSPhilip A. Viton ()CRP 763 Producers Surplus October 24, 2011 5 / 22

    Producers Surplus I

    It is important to understand that while the change in prots equalsthe change in producers surplus, prots and producers surplusthemselves are not the same.

    They dier by the quantity of xed costs:

    = TR (TVC + TFC )= TR TVC TFC= PS TFC

    But since we will always be looking at the change in producerssurplus, this wont matter.

    Finally, remember that unlike the case of consumers surplus,producers surplus isnt an approximation to anything.

    Philip A. Viton ()CRP 763 Producers Surplus October 24, 2011 6 / 22

    Producers Surplus II

    Using the change in producers surplus has two advantages over thechange in prots:

    1. It does not require us to understand xed costs; and empirically xedcosts (ie the value of the constant or intercept in a regressionequation) is often imprecisely estimated.

    2. If we know something about the rms marginal cost schedule, it iseasy to calculate total variable costs: they are simply the area underthe marginal cost curve from x1 = 0 (zero output) to xa1 (observedoutput).

    Philip A. Viton ()CRP 763 Producers Surplus October 24, 2011 7 / 22

    Total Variable Costs

    x1

    $

    p1a

    x1a

    MC

    0

    The gure shows a rmsupward-sloping marginal costcurve ( = supply function)

    If it is a prot-maximizingprice-taker, then, if it facesmarket price pa1 its output willbe xa1Total revenue is pa1 xa1(hatched)

    Total variable costs are the areaunder MC from x1 = 0 tox1 = xa1 ( dark shade)

    So producers surplus is the areaabove MC but below the pricehorizontal (light shade)

    Philip A. Viton ()CRP 763 Producers Surplus October 24, 2011 8 / 22

  • Project

    x1

    $

    p1b

    x1b

    MC

    0

    Suppose the rm is a price-takerin the output market, and thatour project has the eect ofraising the rms market priceto pb1 . The rm responds byraising its output to xb1 .

    The new total revenue is thehatched area, total variablecosts are darkly shaded andproducers surplus is lightlyshaded.

    Philip A. Viton ()CRP 763 Producers Surplus October 24, 2011 9 / 22

    Change in Producers Surplus

    x1

    $

    p1a

    x1a

    p1b

    x1b

    MC

    0

    Comparing the previouspictures, we can see that thechange in producers surplus isthe area to the left of themarginal cost curve and betweenthe two price horizontals.

    Note that this is valid only for acompetitive rm that sees itsmarket price change with noshift in its cost curves.

    Philip A. Viton ()CRP 763 Producers Surplus October 24, 2011 10 / 22

    Multiproduct Producers Surplus

    When a rm produces several products and the project changes theirprices, we naturally measure the full impact as the change inproducers surplus in each of the product markets. So:

    PS = PS1 + PS2 + . . .

    (just as we did for consumers surplus).

    It can be shown that PS is not path-dependent: that is, for amultiproduct rm you will get the same answer in whatever order youdo the calculation (unlike consumers surplus).

    Philip A. Viton ()CRP 763 Producers Surplus October 24, 2011 11 / 22

    Market Impacts Full Analysis

    We are now in a position to evaluate the full impact of a policy thatchanges a market price from its pre-project level pa to its post project levelpb

    For the impact on consumers we use the change in consumerssurplus:

    CS = CS(pb) CS(pa)For the impact on rms we use the change in producers surplus(aggregating over rms, if necessary):

    PS = PS(pb) PS(pa)And then the full impact is:

    W = CS + PS

    Philip A. Viton ()CRP 763 Producers Surplus October 24, 2011 12 / 22

  • Example Monopolization

    We have seen that monopolization has two impacts: it reduced thequantity produced and increases the price consumers pay for theproduct.

    Intuitively, this is a bad thing ; but you might wonder if it really is:what if the price increase leads to an increase in rm prots mightnot this outweigh the loss to consumers?

    By using our new tools, we can see that this is not so.

    Philip A. Viton ()CRP 763 Producers Surplus October 24, 2011 13 / 22

    Monopolization Setup

    S MC=S

    DMR

    $

    xxaxb

    papb

    The gure shows the basicposition: under competition,demand = supply, where supplyis the sum of the rmsmarginalcosts ; the result is price pa andoutput xa.

    Under monopolization,prot-maximizing output isgoverned by the condition MC= MR, leading to output xb .The monopolist prices to sell alloutput, resulting in a price pb .

    Philip A. Viton ()CRP 763 Producers Surplus October 24, 2011 14 / 22

    Computational Aside I

    Suppose you want to calculate the pre-project equilibrium (pa, xa).Conceptually, you want to equate supply (= MC) and demand.

    However, note that the marginal cost function is MC (x) : that is, ittakes a quantity and delivers its marginal cost, in dollars.

    While the demand function is x(p) : that is, it takes a price anddelivers the demand (quantity) at that price.

    So you cant just equate x(p) and MC (x) : that would bemeaningless.

    Instead, you must rst invert (solve) either the demand function orthe marginal cost function, so they both deliver the same thing(output or money). Then you can equate the two equations.

    Philip A. Viton ()CRP 763 Producers Surplus October 24, 2011 15 / 22

    Computational Aside II

    For example, suppose in the linear case you have:

    Marginal cost: c = 0 + 1x (1 > 0)Demand: x = 0 + 1p (1 < 0)The in order to nd the equilibrium you can invert the demandfunction, giving p = (x 0)/1 and then equate supply anddemand:

    (x 0)/1 = 0 + 1xwhich is an equation in quantity only.Alternatively, you can just feed in the price (cost) equation into thedemand function:

    x = 0 + 1p

    = 0 + 1(0 + 1x

    which is also an equation in x only; and solve.

    Philip A. Viton ()CRP 763 Producers Surplus October 24, 2011 16 / 22

  • Monopolization Impact on Consumers

    S MC=S

    DMR

    $

    xxaxb

    papb

    As usual, the impact onconsumers is CS = signedarea under the demand functionbetween the two pricehorizontals.

    This is the shaded area, and it isimportant to note that it is anegative quantity.

    Philip A. Viton ()CRP 763 Producers Surplus October 24, 2011 17 / 22

    Producers Surplus under Competition

    S MC=S

    DMR

    $

    xxaxb

    papb

    Pre-project producers surplusPSa is TR ( = pa xa) TVC(= area under MC from x = 0to x = xa).

    In the gure, this is shaded.

    Philip A. Viton ()CRP 763 Producers Surplus October 24, 2011 18 / 22

    Producers Surplus under Monopoly

    S MC=S

    DMR

    $

    xxaxb

    papb

    Similarly, relative to themonopoly equilibrium (xb , pb)post-project producers surplusPSb is the shaded area.

    Philip A. Viton ()CRP 763 Producers Surplus October 24, 2011 19 / 22

    Change in Producers Surplus

    S MC=S

    DMR

    $

    xxaxb

    papb

    +-

    Comparing the two previousgures, PS is the shaded areaNote that this has two parts: arectangle, representing wherePSb is more than PSa andhence has a positive sign ; and alittle triangle representing partof PSa not covered by PSb : sothis bit has a negative sign.

    Obviously the net eect ispositive : as wed expect,monopoly increases rm prots.

    Philip A. Viton ()CRP 763 Producers Surplus October 24, 2011 20 / 22

  • Net Impact

    S MC=S

    DMR

    $

    xxaxb

    papb

    For the overall net impact, wecompare PS to CS . We seethat CS more than covers thearea of the rectangle part ofPS . The left-over area is partof CS and hence is negative.There is also the little triangleof PS , which is also negative.So all net impacts work out to adeterminately negative area,shown in the gure as theshaded area.

    Philip A. Viton ()CRP 763 Producers Surplus October 24, 2011 21 / 22

    Conclusion

    We conclude that going from a situation of competition to one ofmonopoly has an unambiguously negative impact.

    In the literature, this is referred to as the Deadweight Loss tomonopolization.

    Philip A. Viton ()CRP 763 Producers Surplus October 24, 2011 22 / 22