PRINCIPLES OF MACROECONOMICS - University of …lwoods/ecp6705/ECP6705sum07.doc · Web...

54
ECONOMICS OF BUSINESS DECISIONS Term: Summer 2007 – Cross Term Course Number: ECP 6705-799 Meeting Times Monday & Wednesday – 4:20 – 6:00 P.M. and Location: Required Text: Buckley, James A., Clifford W. Smith, Jr. and Jerold L. Zimmerman. 2007. Managerial Economics and Organizational Architecture, 4 th Ed., Boston, MA: McGraw-Hill, Irwin. Course Prerequisites Introduction to Economics, two course sequence or equivalent or ECO and Description: 5115. Contrary to popular myths, Economics of Business Decisions, is NOT a watered-down Intermediate Microeconomics Theory course. Rather, it is has a Managerial Economics focus. This does not imply that ‘theorydoes not matter; it means the focus is on the individual decision-making units – households, firms and the public sector, with the firm and its interactions with both its internal and external environments. Perhaps a single best expression of this approach may be found in Chapter 1 “Introduction: Firms and Managing Them,” to Zoltan J. Acs and Daniel A. Gerlowski’s pioneering text: Managerial Economics and Organization. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice Hall, 1996. They have written: firm: A conscious, willful effort to organize economic activity that consists of a collection of contracts when more than one party is involved…. A firm is not a person or any other living thing; it is merely a legal entity, recognized by law, which is permitted to enter into binding contracts with other persons and firms (2)

Transcript of PRINCIPLES OF MACROECONOMICS - University of …lwoods/ecp6705/ECP6705sum07.doc · Web...

Page 1: PRINCIPLES OF MACROECONOMICS - University of …lwoods/ecp6705/ECP6705sum07.doc · Web viewManagerial Economics and Organizational Architecture, 4th Ed., Boston, MA: McGraw-Hill,

ECONOMICS OF BUSINESS DECISIONS

Term: Summer 2007 – Cross Term

Course Number: ECP 6705-799

Meeting Times Monday & Wednesday – 4:20 – 6:00 P.M. and Location:

Required Text: Buckley, James A., Clifford W. Smith, Jr. and Jerold L. Zimmerman. 2007. Managerial Economics and Organizational Architecture, 4th Ed., Boston, MA: McGraw-Hill, Irwin.

Course Prerequisites Introduction to Economics, two course sequence or equivalent or ECO and Description: 5115.

Contrary to popular myths, Economics of Business Decisions, is NOT a watered-down Intermediate Microeconomics Theory course. Rather, it is has a Managerial Economics focus. This does not imply that ‘theory’ does not matter; it means the focus is on the individual decision-making units – households, firms and the public sector, with the firm and its interactions with both its internal and external environments. Perhaps a single best expression of this approach may be found in Chapter 1 “Introduction: Firms and Managing Them,” to Zoltan J. Acs and Daniel A. Gerlowski’s pioneering text: Managerial Economics and Organization. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice Hall, 1996. They have written:

firm: A conscious, willful effort to organize economic activity that consists of a collection of contracts when more than one partyis involved…. A firm is not a person or any other living thing;it is merely a legal entity, recognized by law, which is permitted to enter into binding contracts with other persons and firms (2)

Notice that in the ‘Preface’ to Brickley, Smith and Zimmerman, five factors have been identified as comprising “The Conceptual Framework” that focuses ‘special’ attention “… to organizational issues.” (v) They have noted that this helps understand:

▪ How the business environment (technology, regulation, and competition in input and output markets) drives the firm’s choice of strategy.

▪ How strategy and the business environment affect the firm’s choice of organizational design – what we call organizational architecture.

Page 2: PRINCIPLES OF MACROECONOMICS - University of …lwoods/ecp6705/ECP6705sum07.doc · Web viewManagerial Economics and Organizational Architecture, 4th Ed., Boston, MA: McGraw-Hill,

▪ How the firm’s organizational architecture is like DNA; the firm’s ultimate success or failure can be traced back to its organizational architecture, which will affect how people in the organization will behave in terms of creating or destroying firm value.

▪ How corporate policies such as strategy, financing, accounting,marketing, information systems, operations, competition, and human resources are interrelated and thus why it is criticallyimportant that they have coordinated.

▪ How the three key features of organizational architecture – the assignment of decision-making authority, the reward system, andthe performance-evaluation system – can be structured to allowmanagers to achieve their desired results. (v-vi, emphasis in original)

Interestingly, Acs and Gerlowski continue their analysis by explaining the terms used in this apparently simple definition of ‘a firm’ –

It is quite important to recognize the implied functionality of firms; they organize economic activity. For this reason, a more general

term has evolved in business for firms: organizations. (2, emphasis in original)

…. Each of these activities is organized or arranged in a particular way that depends on a number of forces both inside and outside the firm.

Traditional economic analysis focuses to a great degree on profit maximization as the primary force driving firms in their actions. We [Acs and Gerlowski] will adopt the much broader concept of efficiency. A particular way of organizing economic activity is said to be efficient if it is impossible, given available resources, to implement an alternative arrangement under which all parties involved are at least as well off. [2, emphasis is original]

It might be noted that the foundations of this approach were established long ago, but ignored by most economists in a most irresponsible manner. To check on this, read about Ronald Coase at: www.dsallasfed.org/research/ei. Pay particular attention to his article: “The Nature of the Firm,” (Economica, 1937) and his view that ‘activities may be accomplished ‘within’ the firm or be ‘out-sourced’, with the decision-criterion: the minimization of ‘transaction costs.’ Coase was heavily influenced by his colleague at the University of Chicago, Frank Knight and his Dissertation turned into book: Risk, Uncertainty and Profit. In a later article, “The Problem of Social Costs,” (1960. Journal of Law and Economics), Coase more fully developed his ideas on ‘transaction costs’, calling into question the ‘conventional wisdom’ of economic policy …. that

Page 3: PRINCIPLES OF MACROECONOMICS - University of …lwoods/ecp6705/ECP6705sum07.doc · Web viewManagerial Economics and Organizational Architecture, 4th Ed., Boston, MA: McGraw-Hill,

government regulations served to ‘correct’ market-failures and promote economic efficiency. This silliness may be traced back to A. C. Pigou’s notorious book: The Economics of Welfare (1920). Robert Formaini has commented on Coase:

… methodologically demonstrates that regulatory interventions can under certain conditions lead to less economically efficient outcomes than markets alone would create. [“Ronald Coase – The Nature of

Firms and Their Costs,” Economic Insights, 8 (3).]

A second significant contemporary economist that you should review is James M. Buchanan, who also acknowledged the costly role ‘government failure’ in its pretenses of correcting the alleged failures of free-markets a la A. C. Pigou. Buchanan notes that he has been heavily influenced by Frank Knight and Frederick Hayek. The silliness of the pretense that government can correct market failure devolves from the conviction that ‘bureaucrats’ are superhuman entities, capable of setting aside their own ‘self-interest’ and acting ONLY to serve the interests of the public!, e.g., they are “… a disinterested agency that could correct for market failures.” Unfortunately, the pretense of sainthood is overshadowed by the existence of ‘rent-seeking’ and ‘wealth-trading’ inherent in the legislative processes. For more on Buchanan, see: Robert Formaini. “James M. Buchanan – The Creation of Public Choice Theory,” Economic Insights, 8 (2); @ www.dallasfed.org/research/ei.

A basic understanding of major precepts of both micro- and macro-economics is assumed – the essential nature of economics as practical exercises in making difficult decisions necessitated by explicit recognition that ALL resources (land, labor, capital and entrepreneurial talent) are scarce. Rational decisions under conditions of resource scarcity require that the factors of production (or, resources or inputs) be directed to their ‘highest and best uses.’ This has been summed-up by James D. Gwartney and Richard L. Stroup as “There Ain’t No Such Things As A Free Lunch,” or TANSTAAFL. Such a definition indicates that deviations from such a pattern of resource allocation involves waste or inefficiencies – that less is made available than would be the case.

No mode of social organization (capitalism or socialism, not even communism or simple subsistence economies) is exempt from this so-called iron ‘law of scarcity.’ Though some decision-makers forget this, or choose to ignore it, or, arrogantly, in

Page 4: PRINCIPLES OF MACROECONOMICS - University of …lwoods/ecp6705/ECP6705sum07.doc · Web viewManagerial Economics and Organizational Architecture, 4th Ed., Boston, MA: McGraw-Hill,

their superior wisdom, presume that they are able to suspend the laws of human nature. Such behaviors are a suspension of the ‘Baconian’ Scientific Method’ and has been chronicled by Michael Crichton, M.D. in his disturbing speech (available on his website – www.crichton-official.com/speeches/index.htmh): 2003. “Aliens Cause Global Warming,” California Institute of Technology, January 17.

The ‘theories’ and ‘laws’ of economics are subject to empirical verification through the assiduous application of the ‘Baconian’ scientific method. This means a theory or law that fails to ‘predict’ outcomes with a high level of precision at a high degree of accuracy must be rejected – neither science nor economics is a democracy. When you hear “most scientists or economists agree,” you know that, as Sherlock Holmes would, “Something is afoot.” There are no partial truths, the theory/law is either correct or it is incorrect!

Among the issues to be investigated include such problems as (i) the nature of organizational structures for decision making; (ii) prices and supply/demand relationships; (iii) production theory, including cost analysis; (iv) the nature and comparison of the relative merits (efficiency, as opposed to equity) of various market structures); (v) the role of information, risk and uncertainty in decision making and the need for probability models, rather than ‘deterministic’ approaches; (vi) consideration of the distorting effects of governmental intervention into free markets; and, finally, (vii) an evaluation of ‘time’ and the business horizon – the short-run and the long-run.

Instructor: Louis A. Woods

Office Hours: Monday and Wednesday @ – 1:00 to 2:30; and by appointment.

Phone: [904] 620-2641

E-mail: [email protected]

Assigned Outside The following readings constitute a portion of this courses required Readings: readings and materials drawn from them will appear on quiz materials:

Oliver E. Williamson. 1981. “The Modern Corporation, Origins, Evolution, Attributes,” Journal of Economic Literature, 19(December), 1537-65.

Ronald H. Coase. 1937. “The Nature of the Firm,” Economica, 4, 386-405.

While not exactly a CliffNotes version, see: Robert L. Formaini and Thomas F. Siems. Ronald Coase – The Nature of Firms and Their Costs,” Economic Insights, 8 (3); available @: www.dallasfed.org/research/ei/ei0303.html.

Outside Readings: In addition to the assigned reading material in the text, each student is

Page 5: PRINCIPLES OF MACROECONOMICS - University of …lwoods/ecp6705/ECP6705sum07.doc · Web viewManagerial Economics and Organizational Architecture, 4th Ed., Boston, MA: McGraw-Hill,

expected to read a total of ten (10) articles (not editorials or book reviews) from scholarly journals over the term. Time, Businessweek, Fortune, The Wall Street Journal, etc. are all popular periodicals and DO NOT qualify as scholarly journals. Several examples of scholarly journals are: Journal of Business, Harvard Business Journal, Journal of Marketing, Journal of Accountancy, Land Economics. Each of the articles should be reviewed, summarized or outlined as a written report on 5" x 8" note-cards. Reviews must be headed with the appropriate bibliographic heading on the top line:

Author. Year. “Title,” Journal, Vol. ?? , No. ? (Month), pages; --

for example:

Hermann Hauser. 2000. “Entrepreneurship in Europe,” Business Strategy Review, 11, 1 (Spring). 1-9.

These reports are to be turned in on a weekly basis, beginning the week of May 23rd.

Textbook: Brickley, Smith and Zimmerman, Managerial Economics and Organizational Architecture, 4th Ed.

May 14 - Basic Concepts June 6 Chapters 1 – 3, pp. 2-91;

Managerial Economics, Chapters 4-7, pp. 96 – 210.

May 28 University Holiday – MEMORIAL DAY

June 6 FIRST QUIZ

June 11 - Managerial Economics – continued: July 9 Chapters 8 – 10; pp. 213-301;

Designing Organizational Architecture, Chapters 11 – 15, pp. 304 – 440.

July 4 University Holiday – INDEPENDENCE DAY

July 9 SECOND QUIZ

July 11- Designing Organizational Architecture – continued: Aug. 6 Chapters 16 – 17, pp. 444 -505

Application of Organizational Architecture, Chapters 18 -23, pp. 518-698.

Page 6: PRINCIPLES OF MACROECONOMICS - University of …lwoods/ecp6705/ECP6705sum07.doc · Web viewManagerial Economics and Organizational Architecture, 4th Ed., Boston, MA: McGraw-Hill,

Aug. 6 THIRD QUIZ.

Short, Informative The following brief columns have been carefully selected to address key Suggested topics that comprise Economics of Business Decisions and are currently Readings: issues being raised in public discussions. Unfortunately nearly all of this

discussion has created a lot of smoke and very little light. This is true, since, as Gwartney and Stroup have pointed out in their Introduction (v),“…we are a nation of economic illiterates.” Two of my favorite and most reliable economists are Thomas Sowell and Walter E. Williams, so I have included a number of their most significant brief commentaries:

William L. Anderson. 2004. “The Economics of Outsourcing,” April 21; @ www.mises.org/fullarticle.asp?control=1488&id=68.

Doug Bandow. 2005. “Sugar Subsidies: How Sweet It Is,” February 7; @www.townhall.com/columnists/dougbandow/printdb20050207.shtml.

Randall G. Holcombe. 1998. “Economic Freedom and Economic Growth,”

The Freeman: Ideas on Liberty (February); available @: www.fee.org/vnews.php?nid=3955.

Charles Krauthammer. 2006. “Say It With Me: Supply and Demand,” April 28; @ www.washingtonpost.com/wp-dyn/content/article/2006/04/27/AR2006042701693_pf.html.

John Stossel. 2005. “Half-Baked Science,” August 31; @ www.townhall.com/columnists/JohnStossel/printjs20050831.shtml.

*Thomas Sowell. 2006. “Oily Politicians,” April 27; @ www.townhall.com

www.townhall.com/opinion/contributors/thomassowell.html. __________. 2006. “Oily Politicians: Part II,” April 28; @

www.townhall.com/opinions/contributors/thomassowell.html.

*__________. 2003. “Free-Lunch Medicine,” November 13; @ www.townhall.com/opinion/contributors/thomassowellprintts20031113.html.

*__________. 2003. “Free-Lunch Medicine, II,” November 14; @www.townhall.com/columnists/thomassowell/printts20031114.shtms.

*__________. 2003. “Free-Lunch Medicine, III,” November 15; @ www.townhall.col/columnists/thomassoweel/printts20031115.

shtml. *__________. 2003. “Letters About Medical Care,” November 18; @

www.townhall.com/columnists/thomassowell/printts20031118.Shtml.

Walter E. Williams. 2000. “Political Exploitation of Ignorance,” March 1;@ www.townhall.com/columnists/walterwilliams/ww000301.shtml.

Page 7: PRINCIPLES OF MACROECONOMICS - University of …lwoods/ecp6705/ECP6705sum07.doc · Web viewManagerial Economics and Organizational Architecture, 4th Ed., Boston, MA: McGraw-Hill,

*__________. 2004. “Price Gouging,” March 24; @ www.townhall.com/columnists/walterwilliams/printww20040324.shtml.

*__________. 2005. “Gasoline Prices,” August 31; @ www.townhall.com/

columnists/walterwilliams/printww20050831.shtml. *__________. 2003. “Drug Industry Destruction,” July 30; @

www.townhall.com/columnists/walterwilliams/printww20030730.shtml.

*__________. 2000. “Social Security Lies,” May 14; @ www.townhall. com/columnists/walterwillia,s/ww000525.shtml.

Additional Each student is expected to be well informed on current social and Requirements: economic issues – both domestic and international -- by reading a reliable

newspaper or internet source, including the editorial pages (such as the Wall Street Journal or Investor’s Business Daily; and/or by viewing a reliable television news source (if that’s even possible) on a daily basis.

Initial Comments: Introduction/background/housekeeping

Comments on the Baconian method, its abandonment in both the natural and the social sciences, and intellectual honesty or opinion; fact or fantasy? An economic answer: Confusion over John Neville Keynes’ distinctions: ’positive economics’, ‘normative economics,’ and ‘economics as an art.’

In a recent Investor’s Business Daily editorial, Paul Craig Roberts presented ‘seven big economic ideas’ and three related issues. Finally, in an editorial written by Walter E. Williams, entitled “Economics 101’, he identified the ‘key characteristic of economics’. In order to set the tone for this course, I can think of no better place to begin than in Williams’ editorial, “Economics 101”:

More than anything else, economics is a way of thinking. At the heart of economics are several simple and easily observable characteristics of humans and the world in which we live. The first is that people prefer more of those things that give them satisfaction and fewer of those things that give them dissatisfaction. Second, when the cost of something goes down, people tend to take or do more of it, and when the cost of something increases, people tend to take or do less of it. Finally, having more of one thing requires less of something else. Or, as my colleague Professor Milton Friedman puts it, “There’s no free lunch.” [“Economics 101,” available at: www.townhall.com/columnists/walterwilliams/ww000607, emphasis added]

It would be wise to read Williams’ entire editorial to discover how he applies these basic principles to ‘public policy issues’. For more about Milton Friedman go to www.dallasfed.org and ‘click’ on ‘Publications

Page 8: PRINCIPLES OF MACROECONOMICS - University of …lwoods/ecp6705/ECP6705sum07.doc · Web viewManagerial Economics and Organizational Architecture, 4th Ed., Boston, MA: McGraw-Hill,

and Resources’ (top banner); then to ‘E’ (extreme upper right); and then on ‘Economic Insights’. Now, page down to “Milton Friedman – Economist as Public Intellectual,” Economic Insights, Vol. 7, No. 2; or you may simply go to: www.dallasfed.org/research/ei/ei0202.

Paul Craig Roberts in his editorial has identified the seven big economic ideas of the 20th Century (having had the most socio-political influence). He lists:

(i) communism (socialism);(ii) Keynesianism and spending or demand-side economics;(iii) Hayek’s identification of “the market system as an

information network”;(iv) monetarism à la Friedman’s notion “demand is a

monetary phenomenon”;(v) supply-side economics;(vi) Coase and transaction cost analysis (“laws and property

rights” affect economic outcomes, i.e., so-called ‘market failures’; and

(vii) Buchanan and ‘public choice’ economics (“policy-makers use public policy to advance their ownself-interests”).

Note that there are explanatory materials devoted to Frederick Hayek, James

M. Buchanan and Ronald Coase available on the Dallas Federal Reserve website:

“Hayek – Social Theorist of the Century,” @ www.dallasfed.org/research/ei/ei9901;

“James M Buchanan – The Creation of Public Choice Theory,” @ www.dallasfed.org/research/ei/ei0302; and

“Ronald Coase – The Nature of Firms and Their Costs,” @ www.dallasfed.org/researh/ei/ei03.03.

Additionally, an historical evaluation and comparison of John Maynard Keynes and Frederick Hayek and their influence of politics and economics during the 20th and early 21st centuries may be found on the PBS website relating to one of their programs, “The Commanding Heights,” (a nine hour special devoted to ‘the battle of economic ideas’ during the 20th Century) especially:

‘Episode One: The Battle of Ideas’ @ www.pbs.org/wgbh/commandingheights/ lo/story/index.

The series and a companion book by the same title (1998. The Commanding Heights: The Battle for the World Economy) was written by Daniel Yergin and Joseph Stanislaw. Dan Yergin is one of the world’s leading experts on petroleum and the economics of its exploitation.

Roberts begins his editorial by stating: “The two most influential – communism

Page 9: PRINCIPLES OF MACROECONOMICS - University of …lwoods/ecp6705/ECP6705sum07.doc · Web viewManagerial Economics and Organizational Architecture, 4th Ed., Boston, MA: McGraw-Hill,

and Keynesian economics – proved themselves to be false, but the shadows they cast kept the five valid ideas in the shade.” (Emphasis added) He proceeds by examining the ‘seven big ideas’, and concludes by observing:

Government growth is the 20th century reflected two big ideas that proved to be wrong. If the five valid economic ideas prove to be as influential, the future will bring a contraction of government and an expansion of individual freedom.

Grading: Three, equally weighted quizzes will comprise 86% of the final grade. The remaining 14% of the final grade will be determined by the outside

readings and summaries. The following aggregate grading scale will be used:

350 to 323 (100% to 93%) ............... A322 to 298 (92% to 86%) ................. B297 to 270 (85% to 77%) ................. C269 to 242 (76% to 70%) ................. D

Less than 242 (69%) ..................... F

Library Scholarly journals may be located in the periodical section of the library Assignments: (The Third Level).

Written The individual article summaries will comprise one of the written Communication communication requirements in this course. Please note that the cards= Requirements: format, particularly the Bibliographic material, should conform to those

found in the Chicago Manual of Style.

Oral Class participation constitutes the demonstration of oral Communication communication skills. At all times, class discussion and class Requirements: participation is strongly encouraged.

Computer Use of the Internet for data searches, articles from scholarly journals Applications: and data manipulation are encouraged. The need for students to access the

instructor=s home page to download syllabi, class materials, and project

instructions serves as an additional set of computer applications.

International Mankiw devotes several chapter to international issues. Lectures and Coverage: handouts are used to augment the international component of this course.

Environmental Externalities/market failures, as well as government policies, are used Issues Covered: to examine environmental issues. In addition, the regulatory response and

burden on private markets are discussed. The role of private property in a

free-market economy and its implications for economic efficiency vis-a-vis the public provision of goods and services are examined in the so-called

Page 10: PRINCIPLES OF MACROECONOMICS - University of …lwoods/ecp6705/ECP6705sum07.doc · Web viewManagerial Economics and Organizational Architecture, 4th Ed., Boston, MA: McGraw-Hill,

>tragedy of the commons=.

Ethical Issues Ethical issues related to illegal or immoral activity within the economy will Covered: be discussed where and as appropriate. This is particularly appropriate,

given recent scandals—Enron, Global Crossing, etc. and elected governmental officials. Since the course addresses aggregates, aggregate behavior of producers, consumers, regulators will be considered.

Academic Integrity: Each student is expected to do his/her own work on assigned activities and on all quizzes. An understanding of what constitutes plagiarism and abuse of copyright >fair use= laws is expected of each student.

Students With Students with a disability, as defined under the Americans with Disabilities: Disabilities Act (ADA), who may require special classroom

accommodations, should inform the instructor of any special needs during the first week of class. Students should also contact the Office of Disabled Services Programs (620-2769) immediately.

Gregg Mankiw has proposed the following ‘Key Element in contrast with the’ Ten Key Concepts’ founding Gwartney, Stroup and Lee [GS&L}:

‘Ten Key Elements of Economics’

Principle #1. People Face Tradeoffs – [Incentives Matter] – The ultimate source of the need for tradeoffs is

the ‘scarcity of (natural) resources’, sometimes this is known as the ‘Law of Scarcity’. This is reflected in what Milton Friedman has characterized as “There ain’t no such thing as a free lunch (TANSTAAFL).” This true since to devote scarce resources to one use, necessarily means that there are fewer resources available to allocate to other, alternative uses. These ideas are best seen in the ‘production possibilities curve’. This principle applies to individuals (households), as well as to society as a whole. In making a decision whether or not to expend some portion of a household’s (or a nation’s) scarce resources (income) [or GDP] on a particular good/service (public policy), tradeoffs should be taken into consideration, e.g., the benefits derived and the costs imposed by increasing taxes on households in order to provide subsidies to farmers (from hops to tobacco, from wheat, cotton and corn to sugar and ethanol). Resource scarcities serve as a constraint on economic production in the short-run, but over the longer run the constraint is relaxed as prices rise. Price increases stimulate new discoveries and older, leaner sources are made more profitable [old copper deposits and oil wells have been made more profitable by higher prices, while small or distant, previously uneconomic deposits, are made profitable]. Additionally, as population grows the potential labor force is expanded; new technologies are developed [olive/animal fat lamps, candles, whale oil lamps, kerosene lamps, electric lights] encouraged by rising prices; and substitutes are found and developed [fiber glass as a substitute for steel in auto bodies and fiber optic cable replaces copper wire in telecommunications]. This

Page 11: PRINCIPLES OF MACROECONOMICS - University of …lwoods/ecp6705/ECP6705sum07.doc · Web viewManagerial Economics and Organizational Architecture, 4th Ed., Boston, MA: McGraw-Hill,

process may be seen in Schumpeter’s ‘perennial gale of creative destruction’ driven by the entrepreneur, his/her quest for profit by innovating. [See: W. Michael Cox. “Schumpeter – In His Own Words,” Economic Insights, Vol. 6, No. 3; or online @ www.dallasfed.org/research/ei/ei0103]

The ‘free lunch mythology’ is clearly addressed by Walter E. Williams in an editorial he wrote in 2001, “There’s No Free Lunch,” @ www.townhall.com/columnists/walter williams/ww20011003. In it Williams introduces several ideas of the 19 th Century French economist, Frédéric Bastiat (1801-1850). [See: Robert L. Formaini, “Frédéric Bastiat – World Class Economic Educator,” Economic Insights, Vol. 3, No. 1; or online @ www.dallasfed.org/research/ei/ei9801] Williams quotes from one of Bastiat’s pamphlets, “What is Seen and What is Not Seen,” which illuminates the issues discussed by Gwartney and Stroup as their Principle #2: The Cost of Something Is What You [Have To] Give Up to Get It (Emphasis added). – This principle is known as an ‘Opportunity Cost’, or, perhaps more descriptively, an ‘Alternative Cost.’ A decision-maker (household, business man, government bureaucrat), to avoid the waste of scarce resources, should evaluate or weigh the ‘benefits’ derived from the purchase or use of one item (a sirloin steak) in comparison with the ‘potential benefits’ that must be foregone (Kentucky Fried Chicken – an alternative to the steak) in order to have the sirloin steak. In this context, the value of the fried chicken (what must be given up in order to get the sirloin steak) is known as its alternative or opportunity cost. Normally, if the benefits derived from the steak exceed the benefits of the fried chicken (the steak’s alternative cost), a rational consumer will purchase the steak. Another example involves a quasi-scientific attempt to justify a ‘progressive’ tax policy (Robin Hood – take from the rich, give to the poor). It is argued that the rich value their last dollar less (expressed as ‘marginal utility’) than the poor value their last dollar (expressed as ‘marginal utility’), so to improve ‘social welfare’ (‘maximize society’s total utility or want satisfaction), it makes sense to transfer income from the wealthy to the poor! The only problem is that this argument is ‘built on sand’, since it assumes that there exists, empirically, measurable units known as ‘utils’. (This assumption is really scientific, just like measuring the flow of electricity through a copper wire!)

Clearly, all decision-making involves a comparison of the expected benefits and the expected costs associated with any transaction, including the use of tax revenues (more highway mileage or more Medicaid). Reflecting on Bastiat’s example of the ‘broken window fallacy’, it is clear that the opportunity cost associated with repairing the broken window is the foregone suit and the income for the tailor. The production possibilities curve provides a graphic representation of the trade-offs and their opportunity costs. One of the problems with the ‘Robin Hood tax policy’ is that it only considers that which Bastiat described as the attribute of a ‘bad economist’ – ‘that which is seen’, totally ignoring what a ‘good economist’ must consider – ‘both that which is seen and that which is unseen.’ Remember the quotation on page 3, above:

There is only one difference between a bad economist and a good one: The badeconomist confines himself to the visible effects, the good economist takes intoaccount both the effect that can be seen and those effects that must be foreseen.

Also, consider: Gwartney and Stroup’s last principle, drawn from Henry Hazlitt’s, Economics in One Lesson -- 10. Ignoring Secondary Effects and Long-term Consequences is the Most Common Source of Error in Economics. There Gwartney, Stroup and Lee are quoted as having

Page 12: PRINCIPLES OF MACROECONOMICS - University of …lwoods/ecp6705/ECP6705sum07.doc · Web viewManagerial Economics and Organizational Architecture, 4th Ed., Boston, MA: McGraw-Hill,

written: “Hazlitt’s one lesson was, that when analyzing an economic proposal, one:

must trace not merely the immediate results but the results in the long run, not merely the primary consequences but the secondary consequences, and not merely the effects on some special group but the effects on everyone.(27, emphasis in the original)

It would be helpful to read: Robert L. Formaini. “Henry Hazlitt – Journalist Advocate of Free Enterprise,” Economic Insights, Vol. 6, No. 1; available @ www.dallasfed.org/research /ei/ei0101.

Comparison of the benefits and the costs are essential if the decision maker wishes to avoid waste (inefficient choices). This principle applies to individuals, households, larger groups, as well as government bureaucrats. All too often, bureaucrats believe that they have superior wisdom and, therefore have the right to impose their decisions on others. In order to accomplish their ‘rights’ to governance, bureaucrats and bureaucracies create a justifying mythology. Typically, this mythology is advanced and perpetuated by the self-anointed ‘intelligencia’ [интеллигéнция] … the taste makers, the cultural pace setters. For examples of the myths that have been created, see: Walter E. Williams. 2005. “Greedy or Ignorant,” available @ www.townhall.com/columnists/walter williams/ww20050112. The myths must be scrapped before the true relationships-- the real costs and the real benefits may be revealed.

Principle #2: The Cost of Something Is What You [Have To] Give Up to Get It (Emphasis added). [There

Ain’t No Such Thing As A Free Lunch] – This principle is known as an ‘Opportunity Cost’, or, perhaps more descriptively, an ‘Alternative Cost.’ A decision-maker (household, business man, government bureaucrat), to avoid the waste of scarce resources, should evaluate or weigh the ‘benefits’ derived from the purchase or use of one item (a sirloin steak) in comparison with the ‘potential benefits’ that must be foregone (Kentucky Fried Chicken – an alternative to the steak) in order to have the sirloin steak. In this context, the value of the fried chicken (what must be given up in order to get the sirloin steak) is known as its alternative or opportunity cost. Normally, if the benefits derived from the steak exceed the benefits of the fried chicken (the steak’s alternative cost), a rational consumer will purchase the steak. Another example involves a quasi-scientific attempt to justify a ‘progressive’ tax policy (Robin Hood – take from the rich, give to the poor). It is argued that the rich value their last dollar less (expressed as ‘marginal utility’) than the poor value their last dollar (expressed as ‘marginal utility’), so to improve ‘social welfare’ (‘maximize society’s total utility or want satisfaction), it makes sense to transfer income from the wealthy to the poor! The only problem is that this argument is ‘built on sand’, since it assumes that there exists, empirically, measurable units known as ‘utils’. (This assumption is really scientific, just like measuring the flow of electricity through a copper wire!)

Clearly, all decision-making involves a comparison of the expected benefits and the expected costs associated with any transaction, including the use of tax revenues (more highway mileage or more Medicaid). Reflecting on Bastiat’s example of the ‘broken window fallacy’, it is clear that the opportunity cost associated with repairing the broken window is the foregone suit and the income for the tailor. The production possibilities curve provides a graphic representation of the trade-offs and their opportunity costs. One of the problems with the ‘Robin Hood tax policy’

Page 13: PRINCIPLES OF MACROECONOMICS - University of …lwoods/ecp6705/ECP6705sum07.doc · Web viewManagerial Economics and Organizational Architecture, 4th Ed., Boston, MA: McGraw-Hill,

is that it only considers that which Bastiat described as the attribute of a ‘bad economist’ – ‘that which is seen’, totally ignoring what a ‘good economist’ must consider – ‘both that which is seen and that which is unseen.’

There is only one difference between a bad economist and a good one: The badeconomist confines himself to the visible effects, the good economist takes intoaccount both the effect that can be seen and those effects that must be foreseen.

Also, consider: Gwartney and Stroup’s last principle, drawn from Henry Hazlitt’s, Economics in One Lesson -- 10. Ignoring Secondary Effects and Long-term Consequences is the Most Common Source of Error in Economics. There Gwartney, Stroup and Lee are quoted as having written: “Hazlitt’s one lesson was, that when analyzing an economic proposal, one:

must trace not merely the immediate results but the results in the long run, not merely the primary consequences but the secondary consequences, and not merely the effects on some special group but the effects on everyone.(27, emphasis in the original)

It would be helpful to read: Robert L. Formaini. “Henry Hazlitt – Journalist Advocate of Free Enterprise,” Economic Insights, Vol. 6, No. 1; available @ www.dallasfed.org/research/ ei/ei0101.

Comparison of the benefits and the costs are essential if the decision maker wishes to avoid waste (inefficient choices). This principle applies to individuals, households, larger groups, as well as government bureaucrats. All too often, bureaucrats believe that they have superior wisdom and, therefore have the right to impose their decisions on others. In order to accomplish their ‘rights’ to governance, bureaucrats and bureaucracies create a justifying mythology. Typically, this mythology is advanced and perpetuated by the self-anointed ‘intelligencia’ [интеллигéнция] … the taste makers, the cultural pace setters. For examples of the myths that have been created, see: Walter E. Williams. 2005. “Greedy or Ignorant,” available @ www.townhall.com/columnists/walter williams/ww20050112. The myths must be scrapped before the true relationships-- the real costs and the real benefits may be revealed.

Principle #3: Rational People Think at the Margin – This represents the basis of what is known as marginal

analysis, the weighing of the relative merits (benefits vs. costs) of the last unit(s) of a given transaction, e.g., one more hour at a weekend party, compared with one more hour studying for the economics test scheduled for Tuesday [benefits = momentary fun vs. cost = lower grade). For an alternative view see Gwartney and Stroup, page 46:

If an investment program is going to enhance the wealth of a nation, the value ofthe additional output derived from the investment must exceed the cost of the investment….

If my weekly allowance is $100 and I want to buy some DVDs ($ 25 each) and go out with the love of my life this week end. I can: (i) ignore ‘the love of my life” and buy four DVDs; (ii) buy three DVDs and take the ‘love of my life’ out for dinner at McDonald’s; (iii) buy two DVDs and take the ‘love of my life’ to an afternoon Matinee and dinner at Burger King; (iv) buy one

Page 14: PRINCIPLES OF MACROECONOMICS - University of …lwoods/ecp6705/ECP6705sum07.doc · Web viewManagerial Economics and Organizational Architecture, 4th Ed., Boston, MA: McGraw-Hill,

DVD and take the ‘love of my life’ to dinner at Wendy’s; (v) take the ‘love of my life’ to dinner at Chris’ Steakhouse and walk in the moonlight along the Riverwalk. Each alternative involve a tradeoff or the sacrifice of something desirable to the individual. The critical point is: in order to get something of value, one must give-up, or sacrifice, something else of value.

Principle # 4: People Respond to Incentives (or Disincentives) [Emphasis added] – [Transaction Costs Are

An Obstacle to Exchange; Reducing This Obstacle Will Help Promote Economic Progress] – Keep in mind Gwartney Stroup and Lee’s first element of economics “Incentives Matter.” They specifically note that incentives affect human behaviors, e.g., if you want more of a certain behavior, provide incentives (tax breaks), but if you want less of a behavior, impose disincentives (taxes). Please pay particular attention to the responses of buyers and sellers to the higher gasoline prices of the 1970s (the so-called ‘energy crises’ of 1973/4). [For an analysis of the current ‘oil crisis’, see: Thomas Sowell, “An Oil ‘Crisis?” @ www.townhall.com/columnists/thomassowell/printts 20050823; and Thomas Sowell, “An Oil ‘Crisis’? Part II, @ www.townhall.com/ columnists/thomassowell/ printts20050824.] Sowell points to the obvious reasons for the high prices: excess demand or inadequate supply. No mystery there. What should government’s response be? According to Sowell the best response would be to do nothing! He notes that unfortunately there are Congressional elections coming up in 1906 and Presidential elections in ’08. The ‘solutions’ likely to emerge are: “price controls, arbitrary new higher gas mileage standards for vehicles, ‘alternative energy sources’”…all of which have substantial costs, e.g., price controls = SHORTAGES; higher gas standards = higher priced cars or lighter (unsafe vehicles); and alternative sources = more expensive energy (largely funded through government subsidies [consider ‘ethanol’]. For more on the effects of government subsidies, see: Alan Greenspan’s comments in his article “Antitrust,” discussed in Principle 7, below. Alan Reynolds, in a brief article, cut to the heart of the current energy situation [“Oil Prices: Cause and Effect,” available @ www.townhall.com/columnists/ alanreynolds20050623. He explains oil prices simply in terms of, surprise, surprise: Supply and Demand – pointing out that only 45% of each barrel of oil is converted into gasoline! Notice that in1997/98 the price of a barrel of oil was cut in half (a disincentive for oil exploration). Also note that between:

…1978 and 2004 oil consumption rose 28.6 percent in the world but only 8.9 per-cent in the United States. That difference was exemplified by a 344 percentincrease in South Korea’s oil demand.

… 60 percent of incremental oil demand [is] not coming from China and the United States.

Especially interesting, or should I say alarming, are Reynolds’ conclusions concerning potential proposed actions by members of Congress:

Meanwhile, some clueless senators are oddly eager to push the Chinese currency up, which would make oil cheaper for Chinese industry and more expensive at home. The White House seems oddly eager to enact more tax-financed subsidies for those who buy Japanese hybrid cars, German diesels and ethanol made from corn or sugar. It is difficult to imagine a more irrelevant ‘energy policy.’ (emphasis added)

Page 15: PRINCIPLES OF MACROECONOMICS - University of …lwoods/ecp6705/ECP6705sum07.doc · Web viewManagerial Economics and Organizational Architecture, 4th Ed., Boston, MA: McGraw-Hill,

The only policy that might actually shrink the ‘fear premium’ in oil (estimated at $10 to $ 20) is to use the strategic petroleum reserve strategically – to quell panic during hurricanes, strikes, wars and the like. But the United States has instead imported oil to add to the reserve whenever oil prices were unnaturally high (1981 to 1985 and now) and sold when the price was low (1997).

When it comes to causes and effects of high oil prices, nobody in Washington shows much interest in logic or facts. It might be sad if it wasn’t so pathologically pathetic.

Sowell identifies ‘organized nature cults’, read: environmental groups (a special interest group), that impede drilling (increasing the domestic supply and lower prices). He debunks the idea that we are running-out of petroleum (or any other minerals, for that matter) … See the bet between Julian Simon (an economist) and Paul Ehrlich (a botanist), a paper “Julian Simon’s Bet with Paul Ehrlich,” is available @ www.overpopulation.com/faq/People/julian_simon.html. [This particular paper is a must read for those who have been duped into believing extreme environmental rhetoric. After losing the bet Ehrlich reverted to his old ways “…ignoring his failed predictions in general” and declaring that the bet “didn’t mean anything.” (Now that’s adhering to the scientific method!)] Higher prices means that oil producers will seek out and attempt to discover and produce more! Remember: INCENTIVES MATTER and higher prices are incentives for oil producers.

Incentives (money, power, prestige, approval, love) normally lead to more of a given behavior, while negative incentives (disincentives) typically discourage given behaviors. Greg Mankiw in his Introduction to Economics textbook, rightly emphasizes the critical role that price plays in the ‘free’ market in allocating (channel or direct) resources to their ‘highest and best (most valued) uses’. This is an issue of economic efficiency and deviations from the allocation of scarce resources to their highest and most valued uses represent economic waste and a reduction is social welfare. For an example, see: Thomas Sowell. 2001. “The Mail Monopoly,” available @ www.townhall. com/columnists/thomassowell/printts20010705. Sowell discusses how the Postal Service is a protected entity and does not have to worry about competition, and therefore does not have to cater to its customers. His point is:

When the post office’s copier takes business away from a local copier shop, italso takes taxes away from the local government. More important, the economy’s resources do not flow to the most efficient user but to the operation with the most privileges.

Monopoly means inefficiency and a money-losing monopoly means even more inefficiency.

It is rare that a change in one economic variable does not affect the behaviors of market participants. Mankiw uses an example of an increase in the price of apples resulting in an increase in purchases of other alternative fruit (pears) to make this point. Also, note Mankiw’s example of seat belts….people feel safer….so they speed more, resulting in even more accidents, but fewer deaths. More accidents are the ‘unintended consequences’ of government imposed mandatory seat belt laws.

Principle # 5: Trade Can Make Everyone Better Off – [Increases in Real Income Are Dependent Upon

Page 16: PRINCIPLES OF MACROECONOMICS - University of …lwoods/ecp6705/ECP6705sum07.doc · Web viewManagerial Economics and Organizational Architecture, 4th Ed., Boston, MA: McGraw-Hill,

Increases in Real Output] – It makes sense to substitute the broader term, ‘exchange’ for ‘trade’ in Mankiw’s statement. Such a substitution permits a fuller understanding of the concept by introducing the ideas of two ‘Classical economists’: Adam Smith and David Ricardo. When considering Adam Smith’s contributions it is essential to note two major ideas: (i) the ‘division of labor’ and (ii) the ‘invisible hand’ that is the free market. First, consider the ‘origin of the ‘division of labor’:

This division of work is not however the effect of any human policy, but is the necessary consequence of a natural disposition altogether particular to man, viz

[Latin, videlicet – that is to say, namely] the disposition to truck, barter, and exchange; and as this disposition is peculiar to man, so is the consequences of it, the division of work betwixt different persons acting in concert….Man continually standing in need of the assistance of others, must fall upon some means to procure their help. This he does not merely by coaxing and courting; he does not expect it unless he can turn it to your advantage or make it appear to be so. Mere love is not sufficient for it, till he applies in some way to your self-love. A bargain does this in the easiest manner. When you apply to a brewer or butcher for beer or beef, you do not explain to him your interest to allow you to have them for a certain price. You do not address his humanity, but his selflove…. This disposition to truck, barter, and exchange does not only give occasion to the diversity of employment, but also makes it useful. [Smith, Lectures on Jurisprudence, 347-8, as quoted by Robert L. Formaini in “Adam Smith – Capitalism’s Prophet,” Economic Insights, Vol. 7, No. 1; available @www.dallasfed.org/research/ei/ei0201. Emphasis added.

Smith’s famous remark about the ‘invisible hand’ guiding the market may also be usefully considered here:

…By pursuing his own interest he frequently promotes that of society moreeffectually than when he really intends to promote it. I have never known

much good done by those who affected to trade for the public good. It is an affectation, indeed, not very common among merchants, and very few wordsneed be employed in dissuading them from it. (1981. The Wealth of Nations, I, 456, emphasis added)

For more, see: Robert L. Formaini. “Adam Smith – Capitalism’s Prophet,” Economic Insights, Vol. 7, No. 1; available @ www.dallasfed.org/ research/ei/ei 0201. The voluntary (free) exchange between individuals and between nations makes at least one party better off, without making the other party any worse off, or the voluntary exchange would not take place. Ricardo argues that individuals and nations should focus their productive efforts (land, labor, capital and entrepreneurial talents) on doing the things they do best (in which they have a ‘comparative advantage’.) For more, see: Robert L. Formaini. “David Ricardo – Theory of Free International Trade,” Economic Insights, Vol. 9, No. 2; available @ www.dallasfed.org/research/ei/ei04012. If the exchanges are truly voluntary, the mere existence of exchange indicates that the individual parties and, by extension, society is better off. Additional insights are to be found in Dwight R. Lee. “Economic Protectionism,” Economic Insights, Vol. 6, No. 2; @ www. dallasfed.org/research/ei/ei04012. This paper is a must read for anyone who want to understand the basic principles of economics and wants to be inoculated against the pathogenic views of politicians and mainstream journalists. Perhaps one of the most telling ideas is the conflict between production and consumption, between the interests of producers and the interests of

Page 17: PRINCIPLES OF MACROECONOMICS - University of …lwoods/ecp6705/ECP6705sum07.doc · Web viewManagerial Economics and Organizational Architecture, 4th Ed., Boston, MA: McGraw-Hill,

consumers. Lee writes:

To some degree, a strong emphasis on productions is justified….Few things are more destructive than concentrating on grandiose redistribution [Robin Hood economics] schemes with no thought to their negative effect on incentives to produce [“that which is seen and that which is unseen”]. The supply-side move-ment focuses attention on the distorting impact of high marginal tax rates have on production decisions. Lower marginal tax rates reduce the difference between what consumers pay and what producers receive and make producers more respon-sive to consumer demands.

Unfortunately, political decisions aimed at promoting production typically make producers less responsive to consumers. Instead of seeing production as the means of serving consumer interests, producers’ interests are treated as ends in them-selves. The result is a reduction in the value of what is produced, which is, since we are all consumers, a sure prescription for making most people worse off. [emphasis added]

Principle # 6: Markets Are Usually a Good Way to Organize Economic Activity – [The Four Sources of Income Growth Are: (a) Improvements in Worker Skills; (b) Capital Formation; (c) Technological Advancements; and (d) Better Economic Organization] – This calls attention to the three main ways that societies have organized themselves to produce goods and services efficiently. First, is ‘subsistence economies’ – usually characteristic of pre-industrial societies, where one eats what one produces and there is little division of labor, save along gender lines. In such societies, per capita output is low as is the standards of living. The benefits and costs of such social arrangements have been discussed in James M. Buchanan’s small book: Market as a Guarantor of Liberty, The Shaftesbury Papers. Hants, England: Edward Elgar, 1993. The second form is capitalism, a system in which private property, well enforced property rights and specialization of task are well-developed. Under such a social system surplus production accompanies the division of labor permitting a higher level of per capita output and level of earnings, as well as a higher standard of living. [The role of specialization of task and increased levels of worker productivity is to be seen in Adam Smith’s justifiably famous ‘pin factory’ example, according to Rima, Adam Smith:

…calculates that division of labor makes it possible for ten workers to produce 48,000 pins per day, so that each worker produces the equivalent of 4,800. Without division of labor, a worker might not even make one pinin a day, and certainly not 20. (I.H. Rima. 1971. Development of Economic Analysis. Haywood, IL: Richard D. Irwin, Inc, 68.)]

The third mode of economic organization is communism (or socialism). Under such a system private property rights do not exist, or are strictly limited to personal effects. The factors of production are all directly under the control of the government and are allocated to the uses decided upon by government decision-makers (or bureaucrats), including production and consumption. The ‘collectivization of the factors of production’ by the state eliminates the incentives for individuals to produce and to excel.

The issue of modern capitalism and its benefits have been addressed in a series of articles (extracted from a book, Investor’s Business Daily Guide to the Markets) published several years ago – “The Hallmarks of Modern Capitalism,” “America, And the Entrepreneur, Ascendant,” and “Capitalism’s ‘Miracle Period’ After WW II.”) The author(s) point out the obvious:

Page 18: PRINCIPLES OF MACROECONOMICS - University of …lwoods/ecp6705/ECP6705sum07.doc · Web viewManagerial Economics and Organizational Architecture, 4th Ed., Boston, MA: McGraw-Hill,

If capitalism has many forms, what makes the modern variety different?

For one thing, property rights are now a bedrock of our existence. In no other system are the rights of the individual so carefully guarded.

Such a system presumes the individual will use his role as property owner tobeneficial ends, [remember Adam Smith’s comments on ‘self-interest’ and a ‘public good’?] that in pursuing his own self-interest through profit, the greater interest of society will be served. [emphasis added]

Contrary to what critics of capitalism say, the placement of property in private hands requires the owner to be a good steward, not a despoiler.

It’s no coincidence, for example, that the worst ecological crisis wrought during the industrial age came in the former nations of the East Bloc and in the Third World, where property rights are weakest. [emphasis added]

Markets, ultimately, are a kind of democracy. One person sells, another buys at a mutually agreed-upon price. Markets rarely discriminate – efficient markets never do – except on price. When two parties strike a deal, it tangibly demon-strates that both are better off, or neither would have wasted the time or effort. [emphasis added]

Somewhat later, the author(s) add:

In today’s world, the most ‘advanced’ capitalist nations are also the wealthiest….

These countries have had the most success not only in creating wealth, but also in getting that wealth into the most hands…. [emphasis added]

More importantly, they quote Angus Maddison’s book, Dynamic Forces in Capitalist Development:

Since 1820, the total product of the advanced capitalist group [Britain, the United States, Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Italy, Japan, the Netherlands, Norway, Sweden and Switzer-land] has increased 70-fold, population nearly 5-fold, and per capita product 14-fold. Annual working hours have been cut in half and life expectancy has doubled.

These 17 decades constitute the capitalist epoch, for the pace of advance in peacetime has virtually always been a huge multiple of that in earlier centuries….

The output of the average worker today increases more during the short span of a career than during the entire 1,000 years of the Middle Ages.

The basic reason for this productivity miracle is investment…. [emphasis in original]

Investments are made for improving one’s lot-in-life (betterment, self-interest) which may be accomplished through the quest for profits. Many of those who invested in the growth of this country (the Goulds, Vanderbilts, Rockefellers, Morgans, and Carnegies) and increased the nation’s physical capital, infrastructure and output have been vilified as ‘Robber Barons,’

Page 19: PRINCIPLES OF MACROECONOMICS - University of …lwoods/ecp6705/ECP6705sum07.doc · Web viewManagerial Economics and Organizational Architecture, 4th Ed., Boston, MA: McGraw-Hill,

implying that they succeeded by stealing wealth, not creating it. In fact, they were responsible for building the nation’s industrial infrastructure, partly with foreign money (investment). For an informative perspective on this issue, see ‘The Maestro’, Alan Greenspan (1961), “Antitrust,” paper given at the Antitrust Seminar of the National Association of Business Economics, September [the paper has been printed in Ayn Rand’s Capitalism: The Unknown Ideal (1967), 63-71]. Greenspan’s ‘key comments’ follow:

The world of antitrust is reminiscent of Alice’s Wonderland: everything seemingly is, yet apparently isn’t, simultaneously. It is a world in which competition is laudedas the basic axiom and guiding principle, yet ‘too much’ competition is condemned as ‘cutthroat.’ It is a world in which actions designed to limit competition are branded ascriminal when taken by businessmen, yet praised as ‘enlightened’ when initiated by the government. (63)

To understand these comments, it must be remembered that “All production is for consumption,” as Ludwig von Mises was so fond of reminding us! His simple comment is a reminder that the satisfaction of the consumer’s is THE heart of economic activity, that the consumer comes first, not the producer – all of this was well-known to ‘classical’ and ‘neo-classical economists,’ but was ignored in a most irresponsible way during the Keynesian era. Greenspan proceeds to assess the origin of antitrust laws and policies:

Americans have always feared the concentration of arbitrary power in the hands of politicians. Prior to the Civil War, few attributed such power to businessmen. It wasrecognized that government officials had the legal power to compel obedience by the use of physical force – and that the businessman had no such power. A business-man needed customers. He had to appeal to their self interest. (Emphasis added)

This appraisal of the issue changed radiply in the immediate aftermath of the Civil War, particularly with the coming of the railroad age. …to the farmers of the West, the railroads seemed to hold the arbitrary power previously ascribed solely to the government The railroads seemed unhampered by the laws of competition. Theyseemed able to charge rates calculated to keep farmers in seed grain – no higher,no lower. The farmers’ protest took the form of the National Grange movement, theorganization responsible for the passing of the Interstate Commerce Act of 1887. (63-4)

The industrial giants, such as Rockefeller’s Standard Oil Trust, which were rising during this period, were also alleged to be immune from competition, from the laws of supply and demand. The public reaction against the trusts culminated in the Sherman Antitrust Act of 1890. (64, emphasis added)

This should sound familiar – the same nonsense is heard or read daily in regard to gasoline prices – and the pandering politicians’ demand for ‘wind-fall profits’ taxes and ‘price-controls’. Even a simpleton can recognize that the government has a ‘monopoly’ on the use of coercion on its citizens … no businessperson has such power to ‘force’ consumers to buy from him/her. Greenspan continues to unravel the origins of Alice’s (or, is it really, Orwell’s) world:

It was claimed then – as it is still claimed today – that business, if left free, wouldnecessarily develop into an institution vested with arbitrary power. Is this assertion valid? …. Or did the government remain the source of such power, with business merely providing a new avenue through which it could be exercised? (64, emphasis

Page 20: PRINCIPLES OF MACROECONOMICS - University of …lwoods/ecp6705/ECP6705sum07.doc · Web viewManagerial Economics and Organizational Architecture, 4th Ed., Boston, MA: McGraw-Hill,

added)

The railroads developed in the East, prior to the Civil War, in stiff competition with one another as well as with the older forms of transportation – barges, riverboats, and wagons. By the 1860’s there arose a political clamor demanding that railroads move west and tie California to the nation: national prestige was held to be at stake. But thetraffic volume outside the of the populous East was insufficient to draw commercialtransportation westward. The potential profit did not warrant the heavy investment intransportation facilities. In the name of ‘public policy’ it was, therefore, decided to subsidize the railroads in their move to the West. (64, emphasis added)

This should all sound vaguely familiar, especially in connection with the issue of ‘alternative’ and ‘biofuels’ today – especially for ethanol. Adding a $ 15.00 quart of ethanol to $ 3.00 a gallon of gasoline only makes sense when the government mandates it and provides tax incentives (higher taxes for tax payers) to pay for it! Then too, Archer Daniels Midland (ADM) [a company that was the subject of the largest price-fixing investigation ever, over lysine] has the lion’s share of the market and corn farmers in the mid-West appreciate the increase in market demand for their grain! All the while peasants in Mexico riot over higher prices for tortillas, and Americans pay higher and higher prices for animal products, including meat, cheese, milk and eggs!

ADM, the self-styled “Supermarket to the World” is a sponsor “The Jim Lehrer Hour” on PBS (a government sponsored network supported by coerced taxes extracted from all citizens’ income). There have been no specials on PBS investigating ADM, nor reporting on the economic consequences of its past and current business practices. The following sources should be consulted to verify my assertions:

Common Cause. 1995. “The Ethanol Switch – A Story of Corporate Welfare,” www.ccsi.com~comcause/news/corwel.html#THE%20ETHANOL%20SWITCH.

John M. Connor of Agricultural Economics at Purdue University has written:“Both Archer Daniels Midland structure and corporate practices favored the implementation of the largest price-fixing conspiracy seen in modern times.” In: Archer Daniels Midland: Price Fixer to the World. http://ideas.repec.org/p/wop

Wikipedia has the following entry on ADM and its price-fixing scheme for lysine and citric acid under the subheading: “Critiques of ADM Practices”:

ADM is also the recipient of federal agribusiness subsidies. According to Libertarian think tank the Cato Institute, “ADM has cost the American economy billions of dollars since 1980 and has indirectly cost the Americans tens of billions of dollars in higher prices and higher taxes over the same period. At least 43 percent of ADM’s annual profits are from products heavily subsidized of protected by the American government. Moreover, every $ 1 of profits earned (?) by ADM’s corn sweetner operation costs consumers $ 10, and every $ 1 of profit earned (?) by its ethanol operation costs taxpayers $30.” @ http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Archer_Daniels_Midland (Emphasis added)

1996 – largest price-fixing investigation; 1999 -- three to official, including Michael Andreas, Executive Vice President, were sentenced to prison;2003 –sued for patent infringements, June 09;

Page 21: PRINCIPLES OF MACROECONOMICS - University of …lwoods/ecp6705/ECP6705sum07.doc · Web viewManagerial Economics and Organizational Architecture, 4th Ed., Boston, MA: McGraw-Hill,

2005 – ADM settles class action antitrust lawsuit for $ 400 million (see: ADM’s

2005 Annual Report (note 15, p. 52)

HOW SWEET IT IS!

Now, back to Alan Greenspan’s commentary on ‘Antitrust,’

Between 1863 and 1867, close to one hundred million acres of public lands were granted to the railroads. Since these grants were made to individual roads, no competing railroad could vie for traffic in the same area in the West [creation of a monopoly]. Meanwhile, the alternative forms of competition (wagons, riverboats, etc.) could not afford to challenge the railroads in the West. Thus, with the aid of the federal government, a segment of the railroad industry was able to ‘break free’from the competitive bounds which had prevailed in the East.

As might be expected, the subsidies attracted the kind of promoters who always exist on the fringe of the business community and who are constantly seeking an ‘easy deal.’ Many of the new western railroads were shabbily built: they were notconstructed to carry traffic, but to acquire land. (64)

The western railroads were true monopolies in the textbook sense of the word. They could and did behave with an aura of arbitrary power. But the power was not derived from a free market. It stemmed from government subsidies and government restrictions. (65)

When, ultimately, western traffic increased to levels which could support other profit-making transportation carriers, the railroads’ monopolistic power was undercut….

In the meantime, however, an ominous turning point had taken place in our economichistory: the Interstate Commerce Act of 1887.

That Act was not necessitated by the ‘evils’ of the free market. Like subsequent legislation controlling business, the Act was an attempt to remedy the economic distortions which prior government interventions had created, but which were blamed on the free market. (65, emphasis added)

There you have it – once the camel’s (government’s) nose is under the tent, you have a guest in your accommodations for life. Extend the example: Social Security, CAFÉ Standards, trade restrictions, acreage/poundage allotments – and you’ll find similar results (distortions) from government intervention in the markets.

The second installment of the IBD’s series (“America, And The Entrepreneur, Ascendant”) reports:

From 1890 to 1913, America’s capital stock grew at an average rate of 5.4% a year – about 60% higher than the average for other major capitalist countries.

Relatively less was invested in the following decades….

The United States also seemed to be the home of an unusual number of geniuses – people like Thomas Edison and Alexander Graham Bell, who found ready markets in the U.S. for their ideas.

Page 22: PRINCIPLES OF MACROECONOMICS - University of …lwoods/ecp6705/ECP6705sum07.doc · Web viewManagerial Economics and Organizational Architecture, 4th Ed., Boston, MA: McGraw-Hill,

The vast economies of scale that America’s markets provided were not lost on U.S. corporations

The primary reason for U.S. dominance, however, can be summed up in one, Ironically foreign, word: entrepreneur. Derived from the French for ‘undertake,’ it refers to the individual who drives the economy by organizing and managing business ventures, and assumes risks for the sake of profit. [emphasis added]

Remember the first key element formulated by Gwartney and Stroup: “Incentives Matter”? Well, profits is not a dirty word, in fact, profits provide incentives for entrepreneurs to ‘drive the economy’ and to ‘bear risk’!

It was not a French, but an Austrian economist who first gave the entrepreneur his due. Previous commentators on capitalism had focused on the accumulation of capital, laissez-faire trade policies or technological change as the reasons for capitalism’s success.

Joseph Schumpeter was different. He saw capitalism as a dynamic system beset by periodic crises he termed ‘waves of creative destruction.’ A crisis, he believed, led to new opportunities as much as it destroyed something old…. [emphasis added]

The entrepreneur, he asserted, is the rarest of commodities: an able risk taker.

For a more comprehensive view of Schumpeter and his contributions to economics, see: W. Michael Cox. Schumpeter – In His Own Words,” Economic Insights, Vol. 6, No. 3; available @ www.dallasfed.org/ research/ei/ei0103.

Principle # 7: Governments Can Sometimes [?] Improve Market Outcomes [emphasis added] – [Income is

Compensation Derived From the Provision of Services to Others. People Earn Income by Helping Others] – Provides economic justifications for the public provision of certain ‘essential’ goods and services (police). The primary explanation is that at times ‘markets fail’ [Adam Smith’s ‘invisible hand’ doesn’t seem to work in certain situations] due to the nature of the production processes (need for very large-scale production units to attain both economic and technological efficiencies); so-called ‘externalities’ (pollution, health risks); or ‘fairness’ in the distribution of either income or wealth (the fruits of the production process).

A good place to find some answers to the issue of so-called ‘market failure’ is in the works of James M. Buchanan … it would be helpful to read: Robert L. Formaini. “James M. Buchanan – The Creation of Public Choice Theory,” Economic Insights, Vol. 8, No. 2; available @ www.dallasfed. orf/research/ei/ei0302. Formaini has noted:

At first glance, public choice theory seems to be nothing more than common sense: Governments are collections of individuals whose interaction is determined by the same self-interest that motivates people in the private sector….

…As many economists came to doubt the efficiency of large, state-funded programs, they saw public choice theory as a way to examine what has come to be known

Page 23: PRINCIPLES OF MACROECONOMICS - University of …lwoods/ecp6705/ECP6705sum07.doc · Web viewManagerial Economics and Organizational Architecture, 4th Ed., Boston, MA: McGraw-Hill,

as government failure. For decades following Arthur Cecil Pigou’s famous bookThe Economics of Welfare, economists saw government as a disinterested agency that could correct for market failure. Buchanan and other public choice theorists altered the debate by proposing that government may not really correct problems in the marketplace because of the wealth trading, or rent seeking, that occurs during the legislative process.

Interestingly, Pigou’s ideas figure strongly in the formulation of Ronald Coase’s ‘transaction cost’ approach to economic analysis. [See: Robert L. Formaini and Thomas F. Siems. “Ronald Coase – The Nature of Firms and Their Costs,” Economic Insights, Vol. 8, No. 3; available at: www.dallasfed.org/research/ei/ei0303.html.] Coase’s arguments against the ‘Pigouvian’ position are best developed in: Ronald H. Coase. 1960. “The Problem of Social Cost,” Journal of Law and Economics; earlier intimations are to be found in his 1937 article, “The Nature of the Firm,” Economica, Vol. 4 (November), 386-405.

It is well to re-consider the observations of Alan Greenspan in the paper he presented at the National Association of Business Economists in 1961. His discussion provides insights into the consequences of governmental policies (“things unseen” to use Bastiat’s terms). The implications of the contrast between the entrepreneur and the bureaucrat is unnerving – bureaucrats are portrayed in popular and most academic circles as omniscient, dedicated public servants, while businessmen (with their own money at risk) are not only short-sighted, but greedy (self-interested) and tend to behave illegally, if not carefully overseen by government regulators! But, please keep James M. Buchanan’s ideas in mind: bureaucrats behave in their own self-interest and frequently respond to the ‘rent-seeking’ behaviors of special interest (aka ‘political pressure’) groups, often placing these interests above the interests of the rest of society. Greenspan then reviews the origins of the Interstate Commerce Act (1887) and the Sherman Act (1890).

All of this should encourage skepticism regarding Mankiw’s idea that: Markets Are Usually a Good Way to Organize Economic Activity [Principle # 6]. Perhaps ‘free-markets’ are a better way of getting things done, since they harness, explicitly and legally, individual self-interest in serving the needs and wants of others through the provision of positive incentives (rents, wages and salaries, interest and dividends, AND profits.

For a brief comparison of the issue of provision of goods and services by the ‘free market’ and by the ‘government,’ see: Hugh Macaulay. 1999. “Can Government Deliver the Goods?” The Freeman: Ideas in Liberty (January); available @: www.fee.org/vnews.php?nid=4220.

Principle # 8: A Country’s Standard of Living Depends on Its Ability to Produce Goods and Services– [Profits Direct Businesses Toward Activities That Increase Wealth] – Identifies the nexus between/among ‘production,’ ‘wealth creation,’ and a region’s ‘standard of living.’ Perhaps one of the most illuminating sources for a deeper understanding of these issues, particularly in Africa and South Asia, as well as other regions of developed countries, may be found in the writings of Sir Peter Bauer (1915-2002), especially a brief article in a hard to find German economics journal: “The Vicious Circle of Poverty.” Much of the material from the article may be found in chapters with the same title in several of his books. On his death in 2002, Thomas Sowell wrote a tribute to Bauer, it is worth a quick read, just to discover his key ideas

Page 24: PRINCIPLES OF MACROECONOMICS - University of …lwoods/ecp6705/ECP6705sum07.doc · Web viewManagerial Economics and Organizational Architecture, 4th Ed., Boston, MA: McGraw-Hill,

[www.townhall.com/columnists/thomassowell/20020510] Other tributes to Sir Peter are: Paul Craig Roberts, “Peter Bauer: A Dissenter on Development,” www.vdare.com/roberts/bauer; Peter Brimelow, “In Memoriam: Peter, Lord Bauer,” www.dare.com/pb/bauer_memorium; and Razeen Sally, “Aid, Trade, Development: The Bauer Legacy,” www.lse.ac.uk/collections/globalDimensions/ research/aid....

Several of Sowell’s comments regarding Sir Peter Bauer and these issue are:

The dominant orthodoxy in developmental economics was that Third World countries were trapped in a vicious cycle of poverty that could be broken only by massive foreign aid from the more prosperous industrial nations of the world… [emphasis added]

Peter Bauer never bought any part of this vision. He had too much respect for people in the Third World, where he had lived for years, to think of them as helpless. ‘Before 1886,’ he pointed out, ‘there was not one cocoa tree in British West Africa. By the 1930s there were millions of acres under cocoa there, all owned and operated by Africans.’

Developmental economics’ hostility to the market and ‘contempt for ordinarypeople’ were to Bauer ‘only two sides of the same coin.’ [emphasis added]

If poverty was a trap from which there was no escape, Bauer declared, we would all still be living in the Stone Age, since all countries were once as poor as Third World nations are today.

Peter Bauer considered it arbitrary and self-serving to call international transfers of money [wealth] to Third World governments ‘foreign aid.’ Whether it was aid or a hindrance was an empirical question. Sometimes it could turn out to be simply ‘transferring money from poor people in rich countries to rich people in poor countries.’[emphasis added]

Bauer likewise rejected ‘overpopulation’ as a cause of Third World poverty, eventhough that was also one of the key dogmas of developmental economics. [emphasis added]

Finally,

The later research of Hernando de Soto, published in his book ‘The Mystery of Capital,’ added still more evidence that supported Peter Bauer’s thesis that Third World people were capable of creating wealth, even if their governments followed economically counterproductive policies that held them back.

For decades on end, Peter Bauer stood virtually alone in opposing the prevailing dogmas of developmental economics.

Perhaps a most telling observation about Sir Peter Bauer has been made by Paul Craig Roberts. He has written:

One of the chilling facts about the 20th century West is how poorly champions of individual liberty have fared in free societies. They seldom receive state honors. Rarely are they celebrated in academia or the media.

Page 25: PRINCIPLES OF MACROECONOMICS - University of …lwoods/ecp6705/ECP6705sum07.doc · Web viewManagerial Economics and Organizational Architecture, 4th Ed., Boston, MA: McGraw-Hill,

One of the 20th century’s great economists, Ludwig von Mises, a refugee from Hitler, could not get a university appointment in America. Mises said that government was the problem, not the solution, and outraged progressives, who were committed to the welfare state, ostracized him. F.A. Hayek was disparagedfor many years for his warnings against big government, as was Milton Friedman.

There have been no prizes for those whose work advanced liberty. Neither are there Ford, Rockefeller, or Carnegie Foundation grants nor Mac Arthur Foundation ‘genius’ grants. Progressive prejudice has been such that no onewho advances liberty could possibly be seen as a genius. The liberal-socialist establishment has worked to shut such people up.

For decades Lord Bauer stood alone in opposition to the view that only planning and foreign aid could produce economic development in poor third world countries.

He watched marketing boards destroy a flourishing peasant agriculture keyed toexports, forcing the peasants back into subsistence farming….

Bauer’s dissent on development was based on his realization of the importance of traders in moving an economy from subsistence to exchange. This critical activity of traders was curtailed by the regulations imposed by development planning.

Ironically, according to Bauer’s research:

With planning and aid came poverty and war. Foreign aid, Bauer noted, made control of the government a life-and-death matter, causing genocidal warfare between tribes…. [emphasis added]

Even more telling are the observations of Peter Brimelow:

…, Bauer had two problems as an economist. Firstly, in the mysterious way that these things happen, he chose to get interested in free market economics at a time when it was utterly and completely out of fashion – …portrait of Cambridge (U.K.) in the early 1950s, with economics discourse controlled by the self-styled ‘secret seminar’ orchestrated by left-wing Keynesians led by Richard Kahn and Joan Robinson….

Bauer’s second problem – in some ways even more serious, it may have cost him the Nobel Prize – was that he preferred words to numbers andarguments to equations….

Most economists since Adam Smith and David Ricardo have understood the connection between production, exchange, wealth creation and rising standards of living (individual and national) are attained by serving the needs of others, while pursuing your own self-interest. Please remember Adam Smith’s comment on the pursuit of self-interest:

By pursuing his own interest he frequently promotes that of the society more effectually than when he really intends to promote it. I have never known much good done by those who affected to trade for the public good……

Few have put it better, none more succinctly.

Page 26: PRINCIPLES OF MACROECONOMICS - University of …lwoods/ecp6705/ECP6705sum07.doc · Web viewManagerial Economics and Organizational Architecture, 4th Ed., Boston, MA: McGraw-Hill,

Principle # 9: Prices Rise When the Government Prints Too Much Money – [The ‘Invisible Hand’ Principle -- Market Prices Bring Personal Self-Interest and General Welfare Into Harmony] – Such actions by thegovernment are meant to have a(n) ameliorative effect(s) on certain economic variables, but all too often, there are ‘unintended consequences’ (read ‘inflation’). Inflation has been described as ‘Too many dollars chasing to few goods,” resulting rising price levels. To understand one of the effects of ‘too much money’, ‘inflation’, and ‘contemporary issues’, see: Walter E. Williams. 2005. “Gasoline Prices,” @ www.townhall.com/columnists/ walter williams/ww20050831. Most economists recognize the harmful effects of inflation, many recall the ‘good-ol’-days’ of the late 1970’s (President Jimmy Carter) and the days of the first Reagan administration when inflation rates were high …. To verify this statement, go to:

www.bls.gov↓

in the left hand corner, click on: “Inflation $ Consumer Spending”

↓ CPI and Inflation Calculator

↓ “Tables Created by BLS”

↓ [First Table] “Table Containing History of CPI”

In this table, look at the last column on the right, per cent change year on year and read down to the period 1970 to 1990. Note that in 1971 the annual CPI rate (inflation rate) was 3.3%. After 1973 [the first, so-called ‘energy crisis’ began in October of that year], the rate rose to 12.3% in 1974 and remained higher than the average for the previous decade. The second, so-called ‘energy crisis’ began in 1979 [remember the seizure of the U.S. Embassy in Tehran and Iranian Hostage Crisis under Jimmie Carter, which lasted for 444 days? (November 4, 1979 – January 20, 1981)] when the CPI reached 13.3% and in 1980 was still high at 12.5%, only falling to 8.9% in 1981. (Could it have been the election of Ronald Reagan as President that ‘encouraged’ the Iranians to free the hostages ONLY a few minutes BEFORE he was sworn in as President?) It then fell to 3.8% in 1982, and has continued to be low to the present day.

Despite the acknowledgement by Milton Friedman, that “always and everywhere,” ‘inflation is a monetary phenomenon,’ myths about inflation abound. In an essay, “Ten Great Economic Myths,” in Murry N. Rotherbard’s book, Making Economic Myths,” Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute, 1995, 18-29. Rothbard’s first myth is:

Myth 1: Deficits are the cause of inflation; deficits have nothing to do with inflation.

In recent decades we always have had federal deficits. The invariable response of the party out of power, whichever it may be, is to denounce those deficits as being the cause of perpetual inflation. And the invariable response of whatever party is in power has been to claim that deficits have nothing to do with inflation. Both opposing statements are myths.

Page 27: PRINCIPLES OF MACROECONOMICS - University of …lwoods/ecp6705/ECP6705sum07.doc · Web viewManagerial Economics and Organizational Architecture, 4th Ed., Boston, MA: McGraw-Hill,

Deficits mean that the federal government is spending more than it is taking in in taxes. Those deficits can be financed in two ways. If they are financed by sellingTreasury bonds to the public, then the deficits are not inflationary. No new money is created; people and institutions simply draw down their bank deposits to pay for the bonds, and the Treasury spends that money. Money has simply been transferredfrom the public to the Treasury, and then the money is spent on other members ofthe public.

On the other hand, the deficit may be financed by selling bonds to the banking system If that occurs, the banks create new money by creating new bank depositsand using them to buy the bonds. The new money, in the form of bank deposits,is then spent by the Treasury , and thereby enters permanently into the spendingstream of the economy raising prices and causing inflation. By a complex process the Federal Reserve enables the banks to create the new money by generating bankreserves….In short, the government and the banking system it controls in effect ‘print’ new money to pay for the federal deficit. (19, emphasis in the original)

Thus, deficits are inflationary to the extent that they are financed by the banking system; they are not inflationary to the extent they are underwritten by the public.

General price changes are determined by two factors: the supply of, and the demand for, money. (19-20)

Some economists have argued that ‘inflation’ is a form of ‘tax’ on peoples’ wealth (savings and investments), eroding the value of their assets over time. This is a cruel joke to play on people ‘saving for their retirement’. A wonderful example of this view may be found in a brief article by Llewelln H. Rockwell, Jr., 2005. “Bush’s Ten Worst Economic Errors,” The Free Market, Vol. 23, No. 6 (June), 3-6. In this article, Rockwell considers the single worst economic mistake that President Bush has made to date, has been his appointment of Ben S. Bernanke as the head of the Council of Economic Advisors (notice that Bernake is now the Head of the Federal Reserve), replacing Greg Mankiw. Rockwell wrote:

Number One: The Appointment of Ben S. Bernanke, formerly of the Fed, to be chairman of the Council of Economic Advisors. Please listen to his words from a speech given in the context of trying to settle down people’s fears of the economic future.

‘The US government has a technology, called a printing press (or, today itselectronic equivalent), that allows it to produce as many US dollars as it wishes at essentially no cost. By increasing the number of US dollars in circulation, oreven by credibly threatening to do so, the US government can also reduce the value of goods and services, which is equivalent to raising the prices in dollars of those goods and services. We conclude that, under a paper-money system, adetermined government can always generate higher spending and hence positive inflation.”

Having caught his breathe, Rockwell continues, sarcastically:

Well, these comments certainly do calm fears that deflation is in our future. But what he seems incredibly sanguine about is the effects of inflation. Already,inflation amounts to a daily robbery of the American consumer. Even in thesesupposedly low inflation times, price indexes have doubled since 1980. Whatthis means is that one dollar in 1980 purchases only 50 cents worth of goods and

Page 28: PRINCIPLES OF MACROECONOMICS - University of …lwoods/ecp6705/ECP6705sum07.doc · Web viewManagerial Economics and Organizational Architecture, 4th Ed., Boston, MA: McGraw-Hill,

services today. There are no long lines at gas stations and we aren’t panicked for our future, but we are still being robbed, only more slowly and more subtly thanin the past.

The Bernanke appointment is … the most egregious decision that the Bush adminis-tration has made.

An inflationist Keynesian and an aggressive advocate of printing-press economics, Bernanke is the sort of crank who becomes famous in history for having destroyed whole countries. He is utterly and completely dedicated to the idea that paper money will save the world, with no downside. I shudder for our future if he becomes head ofthe Fed. Yet this appointment is probably a pathway to Greenspan’s job, as it was for Greenspan himself. (6, emphasis in the original)

Principle # 10: Society Faces a Short-Run Tradeoff between Inflation and Unemployment – [Too Often Long-Term Consequences or Secondary Effects of an Action are Ignored] -- It’s important to note upfront that government has a monopoly on ‘money creation’, but has no power to create jobs, that is a function of the ‘private sector’. While some economists believe in this relationship, known as the so-called ‘Phillips curve,’ many economists have called it into question. Murray Rothbard, for example, considers it to be one of the “Ten Great Economic Myths,” having written:

Myth 6: There is a tradeoff between unemployment and inflation.

Every time someone calls for the government to abandon its inflationary policies,establishment economists and politicians warn that the result can only be severeunemployment. We are trapped, therefore, into playing off inflation against highunemployment, and become persuaded that we must therefore accept some of both.

The doctrine is the fallback position for Keynesians. Originally, the Keynesians promised us that by manipulating and fine-tuning deficits and government spending,they could and would bring us permanent prosperity and full employment without inflation. Then, when inflation became chronic and ever-greater, they changed their tune to warn of the alleged tradeoff, so as to weaken any possible pressure upon the government to stop its inflationary creation of new money. (24)

The tradeoff doctrine is based on the alleged ‘Phillips curve,’ a curve invented many years ago by the British economist A.W. Phillips. Phillips correlated [In statistics it has been long know that correlation is not causation.] wage rate increases with unemployment, and claimed that the two move inversely: the higher the increases in wage rates, the lower the unemployment. On its face, this is a peculiar doctrine, since it flies in the face of logical, commonsense theory.Theory tells us that the higher the wage rates, the greater the unemployment, and vice versa. If everyone went to their employer tomorrow and insisted on double or triple the wage rate, many of us would be promptly out of a job. Yet this bizarre finding was accepted as gospel by the Keynesian economicestablishment. (24-5, emphasis in original, material in brackets added)

By now, it should be clear that this statistical finding violates the facts as well as logical theory. For during the 1959s, inflation was only about one to two percent per year, and unemployment hovered around three or four percent, whereas later unemployment ranged between eight and 11%, and inflation between five and 13%. In the last two or three decades, in short, both inflation and unemploymenthave increased sharply and severely. If anything, we have had a reverse Phillips

Page 29: PRINCIPLES OF MACROECONOMICS - University of …lwoods/ecp6705/ECP6705sum07.doc · Web viewManagerial Economics and Organizational Architecture, 4th Ed., Boston, MA: McGraw-Hill,

curve. There has been anything but an inflation-unemployment tradeoff.

But ideologues seldom give way to the facts, even as they continuously claim to ‘test’ their theories by Facts. To save the concept, they have simply concluded that the Phillips curve still remains as an inflation-unemployment tradeoff, except that the curve has unaccountably ‘shifted’ to a new set of alleged tradeoffs. On this sort of mind-set, of course, no one could ever refute any theory. In fact, current inflation, even if it reduces unemployment in the short-run byinducing prices to spurt ahead of wage rates (thereby reducing real wage rates), will only create more unemployment in the long run. Eventually, wage rates catchup with inflation, and inflation brings recession and unemployment inevitably inits wake. After more than two decades of inflation, we are now living in that “long run.”

There are several major points to consider in Murray Rothbard’s discussion of the Keynesian adherence to the so-called Phillips curve: (i) an unwillingness on the part of Phillips curve advocates to adhere to the standards of the Baconian Scientific Method [subject their theory to the rigors of empirical testing]; and (ii) once the theory has been demonstrated to be defective to reject it and seek a new theory. [Remember the points made by Michael Crichton in his Michelin Speech, “Aliens Cause Global Warming”?]

The French economist, Frédéric Bastiat, wrote as a precaution:

There is only one difference between a bad economist and a good one: The badeconomist confines himself to the visible effects, the good economist takes intoaccount both the effect that can be seen and those effects that must be foreseen.

Walter Williams uses the writings of Bastiat to refute the silly notions regarding the potential economic outcomes (benefits) of 9/11 – job creation associated with public and private expenditures ‘rebuilding’ the damage. He employs Bastiat’s well-known, but often forgotten, idea of the ‘broken window fallacy’ [a child throws a rock through a shopkeepers window, which then has to be replaced, creating work and income for the glazer (that which is seen)]. But this is not the whole of it, since it fails to take into account what the shopkeeper might have done with this money, it alternative use (that which is unseen), say the purchase of a new jacket.] There is in fact a reorientation of spending and income earning away from the tailor and to the glazer. Williams concludes: “Property destruction always lowers the wealth of a nation.”

For other examples of the ‘free lunch’ mythology (ignoring the ‘Law of Scarcity), the significance of government intervention (“I’m from the government and I’m here to help you”) and their applications to contemporary issues, see the following:

Thomas Sowell. 2001. “Electricity Shocks California,” @ www.townhall. com/ columnists/thomassowell/printts20010111.

Thomas Sowell. 2001. “Property Rites,” @ www.townhall.com/columnists/ thomassowell/prints20010809.

Thomas Sowell. 2002. “An Ancient Fallacy,” @ www.townhall.com/columnists/ thomassowell/printts20020527.

Walter E. Williams. 2004. “Minimum Gasoline Prices,” @ www.townhall.com/

Page 30: PRINCIPLES OF MACROECONOMICS - University of …lwoods/ecp6705/ECP6705sum07.doc · Web viewManagerial Economics and Organizational Architecture, 4th Ed., Boston, MA: McGraw-Hill,

columnists/walterwilliams/printww20040331.

Sowell, in “Electricity Shocks in California,” points out the role of government, through the use of price controls, in creating shortages and then seeking to shift the blame onto the private sector. Notice what Sowell writes,

In the never-never land of California ideology, it is considered terrible if the publicshould have to pay the full cost of what it wants.

In California, prices higher than you like are attributed to ‘greed’ or ‘price gouging’ and the answer is either more government regulation or having the government take over the utility company completely and run it….

But just as there is no free lunch, there is no free electricity. And the idea that the government can run businesses at lower costs flies in the face of worldwide evidence that whatever enterprise politicians and bureaucrats run has higher costs.

Far from lowering the cost of producing electricity, government at all levels has for many years and in many ways been needlessly increasing that cost. (emphasis added)

He concludes with:

But if we are too squeamish to build a dam and inconvenience some fish or reptiles, too aesthetically delicate to permit drilling for oil out in the boondocks and tooparanoid to allow nuclear power plants to be built, then we should not be surprised if there is not enough electricity to supply our homes and support a growing economy.

Mankiw in his ‘Introductory’ text, provides an interesting example of a social tradeoff that needs careful consideration: a tradeoff between efficiency and equity. Notice Mankiw’s definition of terms: efficiency – the property of getting the most it can from its scarce resources;” and, “equity – the property of distributing economic property fairly among members of society.” Please note the inherent disconnect between the two terms: ‘efficiency’ is a ‘technological concept’, while, ‘equity’ refers to some ‘moral standard’. ‘Efficiency’ may be measured as an increase in some quantitative variable (output, costs, price) which serve to raise social welfare (product), while ‘equity’ is a qualitative term, (defined as “something that is fair or just”), a term that has as many meanings as there are people observing a process – what’s fair to me, may be unfair to others (reducing their well-being). Perhaps, as important in understanding these distinctions, is the decomposition of economics and economic analysis first made by John Neville Keynes, father of John Maynard Keynes, in his book, The Nature and Scope of Political Economy. Keynes argued that an individual’s approach to economic analysis may take one of three approaches: (i) positive analysis; (ii) normative analysis; or (iii) the art of practicing economic analysis. Positive economics involves the study of economic phenomena as they are (an empirical approach), while normative economics considers economic phenomena as they ought to be (implying some ethical judgment, without specifically identifying whose ethical values are being used as the standard). Further clarification may be found differentiating the tasks of the economist as: (i) ‘scientist’ (implying positive analysis); and (ii) ‘policy formulator’ or political adviser (employing normative judgments).

The issue of economist as ‘scientist’ necessitates consideration of the Baconian ‘Scientific

Page 31: PRINCIPLES OF MACROECONOMICS - University of …lwoods/ecp6705/ECP6705sum07.doc · Web viewManagerial Economics and Organizational Architecture, 4th Ed., Boston, MA: McGraw-Hill,

Method’ and its application to the advancement of knowledge. For an example of the misuse and abuse of the ‘Scientific Method’ in an attempt to advance a particular political viewpoint, see: Michael Crichton, “Caltech Michelin Lecture,” January 11, 2003; available at: www.crichton-official.com/ speeches/index. All of the other papers on the website are worth reading. Deliberate misuse of the scientific method is a form of intellectual dishonesty and fraud and is often employed to advance or justify normative goals.

Page 32: PRINCIPLES OF MACROECONOMICS - University of …lwoods/ecp6705/ECP6705sum07.doc · Web viewManagerial Economics and Organizational Architecture, 4th Ed., Boston, MA: McGraw-Hill,
Page 33: PRINCIPLES OF MACROECONOMICS - University of …lwoods/ecp6705/ECP6705sum07.doc · Web viewManagerial Economics and Organizational Architecture, 4th Ed., Boston, MA: McGraw-Hill,