PRICE DETERMINATION IN THE U.S. SHRIMP MARKET

download PRICE DETERMINATION IN THE U.S. SHRIMP MARKET

of 10

Transcript of PRICE DETERMINATION IN THE U.S. SHRIMP MARKET

  • 8/12/2019 PRICE DETERMINATION IN THE U.S. SHRIMP MARKET

    1/10

    SOUTHERN JOURNAL OF AGRICULTURAL ECONOMICS DECEMBER, 1987

    PRICE DETERMINATION IN THE U.S. SHRIMP MARKETCharles M Adams Fred J. Prochaska and Thomas H. Spreen

    Abstract cultured product, disproportionate increasesThe monthly and quarterly price determina- in costs of production (i.e., fuel, financing, andtion processes for 31-40 and 21-25 size classes marine insurance), and fluctuating domesticof raw-headless shrimp were examined to de- economic conditions.termine price leadership between market The domestic production sector is presentlylevels. Causal relationships were assessed characterized as overcapitalized and fully ex-using Haugh-Pierce, Sims, and Granger meth- ploited. This condition has led to increasedods. Price models at the retail, wholesale, and competition for limited domestic stocks andexvessel market levels were estimated. declining catch per unit of effort. In addition,Economic factors analyzed were income, the apparent concentrated nature of the

    prices of competing products, landings and im- shrimp wholesaling-processing sector (lessports of raw headless shrimp, total retail sup- than 20 firms control approximately 90 per-ply, beginning stocks, and marketing costs. cent of total domestic output) has been sug-Monthly prices generally exhibited gested to have encouraged monopsonisticunidirectional causality from exvessel to retail pricing (wholesaling and processing activitiesprice. Quarterly prices were determined in- are often both carried out by a given firm).terdependently among market levels. Price The production sector of the industry hasresponses between market levels were found repeatedly requested restrictive measures onoes etr w ennnand imports toe symmetric with beginning stocks,tuation and,ings, and imports of own-size shrimp the most thereby, relieve their current cost-priceimportant determinants of price. squeeze. Others have suggested new market-ing organizations and increased promotionalKey words: shrimp, prices, causality. programs to bolster prices and/or toredistribute alleged excess profits which are

    7r conjectured to exist at some market levels.The U.S. shrimp industry is the most Previous research on such marketing issuesvaluable component of the nation's commer- has focused on either one size class or a singlecial fishing industry when measured in terms market level (Thompson and Roberts; Doll;of dockside value. Landings for 1984, of which Hopkins). Other research has addressed a91 percent originated from the southern coastal specific component of the industry, such as im-regions from Texas to North Carolina, were ports (Prochaska and Keithly). No researchvalued at $488.4 million (U.S. Dept. of Com- has been conducted to determine price rela-merce [b]). The shrimp industry has recently tionships between adjacent market levels forexhibited considerable instability and price various size classes of shrimp. These relation-volatility throughout its market system. In ships are of key importance given that dif-general, shrimp prices have been falling since ferent size classes impact different segments1982, with divergent trends between larger of the retail market. In addition, previousand smaller size classes of shrimp and be- research has failed to address the dynamictween market levels. Several factors are nature of price transmission between adjacentsuspected to have contributed to this state of market levels. Examining the causal directionflux, such as limited domestic shrimp supplies, of price formation and the nature of priceincreasing dependency on tariff-free imports linkage between market levels will provide in-of wild catch and increasing amounts of mari- sight into the degree of competitiveness which

    Charles M.Adams is an Assistant Professor, Fred J. Prochaska (deceased) was a Professor, and Thomas H. Spreen is a Professor,Food and Resource Economics Department, University of Florida. Dr. Prochaska died in September 1986, but made a significant con-tribution to this article before his death.The research reported in this article was supported by the Florida Sea Grant College. The authors wish to thank an anonymousreviewer and the editorial board for helpful comments.Florida Agricultural Experiment Station Journal Series No. 8430.Copyright 1987, Southern Agricultural Economics Association.103

  • 8/12/2019 PRICE DETERMINATION IN THE U.S. SHRIMP MARKET

    2/10

  • 8/12/2019 PRICE DETERMINATION IN THE U.S. SHRIMP MARKET

    3/10

    dockside and is specified as a function of the methods essentially relax the constraint im-quantities offered to first handlers (domestic posed by the Granger requirement that alllandings of the specific size class and other available information be used in predictingsizes) and a cost index of marketing inputs X t by only taking into account Yt and the pastutilized by the first handlers. In addition to history of Xt.the predetermined variables discussed above, Haugh-Pierce method contrasts withfindings regarding the direction of causality other methods in that techniques of determin-are used to indicate whether each price ex- i resdl ross correlations are employedpression should be a function of current and infer causality between two time series.lagged exogenous price, lagged endogenous ore iortantly resulting causal in-price, or both. Given that shrimp supplies are re s an residul correlations canferences and residual cross correlations canconsidered to be exogenous, supply expres- then be used in a two-step dynamic regressionsions for each market level and size class are edue arrie at a sggeprocedure to arrive at a suggested specifica-not considered. tion of the lead/lag relationship which existsCAUSALITY AND SYMMETRY TESTING between the two time series (Haugh and Box).Assume initially that two time series X t andIn the presence of highly competitivemarkets, auctions, and the increased use of Yt (i.e., prices for adjacent market levels) canmarkets, auctions, and the incereased use of bcomputerized marketing techniques, rapid ad- be represented byjustment of prices to changes in supply anddemand may be evident. However, in less (5) B) X t = ut, andcompetitive and less organized markets (suchas those for many seafood products), the no- (6) e(B) Yt = vtion of short-run disequilibrium and thepossibility of slower price adjustment war- where(B) and e(B) are invertiblerants investigation of the inherent dynamic polynomial filters in the lag operator B, andproperties of price transmission and causal the residuals ut and vt are white noise proc-direction as information flows between equi- esses. The filters are univariate time serieslibrium points among adjacent market levels models identified and estimated through thein a lead/lag fashion. Though economic theory Box-Jenkins approach. Haugh suggests that,suggests the structural specifications of the due to the absence of autocorrelation amongmodel, a priori information is not sufficently the residuals, cross correlations between utdetailed to suggest the exact specifications of and vt can be used to infer causality betweenleads, lags, and other dynamic components of X and Y. Pierce provides alternative condi-price transmission. These relationships should tions for residual cross correlation significancebe asssessed to provide additional information at lag k which are used to make inferencesfor model specification. regarding the specific nature of the causalrelationship between X and Y (i.e., unidirec-Identifying Causal Relationships tional, instantaneous, feedback, or in-There have been numerous studies in- dependence). Given an implied causal relation-vestigating the direction of price causality in ship between X and Y, a dynamic shock modelagricultural markets (Bessler and Brandt; can be given that connects the orthogonalBessler and Schrader; Miller; Spreen and residuals ut and vt. Assuming unidirectionalShonkwiler). However, no studies have been causality from X to Y, the dynamic shockpublished which test the direction of causality model isbetween prices representing vertical market (7) vt = V(B) ut + 6(B) at,levels in the U.S. seafood market. Causality where a t is an error process and V(B) and 6(B)between two theoretically related time series are polynomials in the lag operator B. Eachis defined in the Granger sense as Yt is caus- parameter in V(B) is the bivariate regressioning Xt if we are better able to predict X t using coefficent relating vt to ut k . Given that theall available information, than if the informa- order and parameters of the polynomial V(B)tion apart from Yt had been used (Granger, are known, the original filter expressions arep. 428). Three empirical approaches which substituted in the dynamic shock model givinghave been used extensively in the literature toidentify the causal relationship between two (8) e (B) Yt = V(B)k(B) Xt+ 6(B) at.time series are the Granger, Sims, and Haugh-Pierce methods (Haugh; Pierce; Sims). These Isolating Yt and completing the necessary

    105

  • 8/12/2019 PRICE DETERMINATION IN THE U.S. SHRIMP MARKET

    4/10

    simplification yields a distributed lag, or store prices for raw-headless shrimp in thetransfer function, which expresses Yt as a Baltimore, Maryland, metropolitan area. Thisfunction of current and/or lagged X t given as price reflects at-home consumption of shrimp.(9) t = O(B)Xt + X B) at. Institutional prices, which would reflect away-w ~(9)Y A + \ ^from-home consumption of shrimp, are notThe polynomials (B) and X B) suggest a available. Wholesale price is the ex-warehouselead/lag structure between adjacent market price in the New York metropolitan area aslevels which is revealed and supported by the reported for the New York Fulton fish mar-data. Once the transfer function relating ket. Exvessel price is a weighted average forprices X and Y for each market level interface all species of shrimp by size class landed in thehas been identified, the lead/lag structures Gulf and South Atlantic. Price, inventory,(e.g., current and/or lagged prices) are included landings, supply, and import data were obtainedin a more complete explanatory model of the from published and unpublished Nationalmarket. Marine Fisheries services sources (U.S.Testing the Symmetric Nature Department of Commerce [c] and [d]).of Price Transmission Although the price data do not reflect a na-The speed and extent with which price tional or regional average, they are used by in-changes are passed to adjacent market levels dustry in establishing prices for local produc-may not be equivalent for price increases or tion and marketing for respective marketdecreases. Thus, a market may be characterized levels.by a lack of symmetry in vertical price Cost index data for seafood processing andtransmission. Recent trends in shrimp prices wholesaling were not available on a consistenthave exhibited such divergence or con- time series basis. Therefore, cost index datavergence between prices at adjacent market for the processing, wholesaling, and retailinglevels, particularly as prices move through of general agricultural food products were ob-peaks or troughs. At the retail/wholesaler- tained from the U.S. Department of Agricul-processor interface, this asymmetry may be a ture. This cost index for agricultural foodfunction of: (1) the cost of changing prices on products was assumed to be a proxy for thecurrent inventories, (2) the need to move costs associated with seafood processing and

    perishable product types quickly, or (3) simply marketing. Income and consumer price indexthe reluctance by retailers to relinquish a data were obtained from published Bureau ofprice peak once it is established. In addition, Economic Analysis and Bureau of Laborthe desire to maintain most efficient use of Statistics reports, respectively (U.S. Depart-capacity may result in retail price rigidity as ment of Commerce [a] and U.S. Department ofwholesale prices vary. If monopsonistic pric- Labor).ing tendencies exist among lower market The data collected from these secondarylevels, wholesale price increases, for example, sources are on a monthly basis. Quarterly datamay not be passed down to first handlers or used in the analysis are constructed from theproducers with the speed and degree of price monthly data as unweighted three-monthdecreases. If this were the case, one market averages (price, income, and index data) andlevel may be able to control the price spread unweighted three-month totals (supply, lan-through influencing price at an adjacent dings, and import data). Price data by sizemarket level. The existence of this phenome- class are available for the period 1968 to 1981.non in the U.S. shrimp market is at least im- The remaining quantity, cost, and income dataplied by recent legislation calling for aid in represent only the period 1972 to 1981.establishing cooperatives and market orders Therefore, 168 monthly observations arein the producer sector. available for an analysis of causal directionThis study uses a modified version of the among prices at alternative market levels.Wolframm model, as suggested by Gollnick, to However, estimation of price models isexamine the symmetric nature of price restricted to 120 observations due to limita-response between market levels (Wolframm; tions on landings and import data by sizeYoung). This form of the Wolframm model has class.been used in previous studies of pricebehavior in more traditional agricultural EMPIRICAL FINDINGS AND DISCUSSIONmarkets (Van Dijk; Ward). Causal Relationships

    DATA The Haugh-Pierce test for causality isRetail price represents grocery and food employed to examine whitened monthly and10 6

  • 8/12/2019 PRICE DETERMINATION IN THE U.S. SHRIMP MARKET

    5/10

    quarterly price changes for 21-25 (larger) and class. Price transmission between adjacent31-40 (smaller) count raw-headless shrimp for market levels for the larger shrimp generallyexvessel, wholesaler-processor, and retail exhibits a longer lag structure (lagged tw omarket levels. Though not presented here, periods) than that for the smaller shrimpcausal relationships found using the Granger (lagged one period). In addition, the price ad-and Sims tests were in general agreement justment between the exvessel and wholesaler-with the Haugh-Pierce findings. processor levels requires one additional timeThe causality tests provided in Table 1 in- period for the larger shrimp, while pricedicate that upward unidirectional causality ex- movement between the retail and wholesaler-ists between the three market levels on a processor levels requires one additional timemonthly basis such that exvessel price causes period for the smaller shrimp. The slower ad-wholesaler-processor price and wholesaler- justment in prices suggests the larger shrimpprocessor price causes retail price. An unex- are being held in inventory longer, with thepected exception to this generalization is smaller, more versatile shrimp being pushedfound between the exvessel and wholesaler- to the retail market in a shorter period ofprocessor prices for the larger shrimp, where time, possibly through different market out-no unidirectional causality occurs. Adjacent lets. These findings suggest that the marketsmarket levels are instantaneously related on a for the two size classes of shrimp function dif-

    monthly basis. The test applied to quarterly ferently over time. The transfer functions,data for both size classes provides no evidence however, only suggest the nature of the lagof unidirectional causality between the price structure. The extent by which these lag rela-series representing any two adjacent market tionships are found to be significant in thelevels. However, instantaneous causality ex- estimated price models is shown in the nextists between adjacent market levels on a section.quarterly basis. These findings suggest that Tthe price determination process is, in general, Symmetry estsrecursive from exvessel to retail market Given the causal relationships suggested bylevels on a monthly basis and simultaneous on the Haugh-Pierce tests, an analysis of thea quarterly basis. The monthly price deter- symmetric nature of price responses betweenmination process may be dominated at the ex- adjacent market levels was performed only onvessel level through exogenous variations in monthly data. Symmetric price movements weresupply, with insufficient time for retail factors found to characterize price changes for bothto play an important part in determining size classes of shrimp. Dependent price responseprices. Thus, consumer market signals do not was found not to be related to direction ofappear to have a dominant impact on exvessel causal price change. This finding suggestsprice on a short-term month-to-month basis. that no one market level is able to effectivelyHowever, a three-month period allows suffi- control the price spread between adjacentcient time for feedback of market signals to oc- market levels represented by the data.cur among retail, wholesaler-processor, andexvessel market levels, resulting in a simul- Price Modelstaneous price determination process. Price dependent equations for the threeIdentification of the transfer functions for market levels are estimated for both sizemonthly and quarterly data suggests lag classes. Only models estimated using quarterlystructures of differing lengths for each size data are presented. The causality findingsTABLE 1. SUMMARY OF MONTHLY AND QUARTERLY HAUGH-PIERCE CAUSALITY TESTS USING EXVESSEL (E), WHOLESALE (W), AND

    RETAIL (R) PRICE DATA BY SIZE CLASS, 1968-1981Testa

    Null Hypothesisb Monthly Quarterly31-40 21-25 31-40 21-25E > W 118.65* 137.87* 47.66* 49.21*E ----- > W 21.16* 13.61 3.87 4.31W / E 6.40 6.40 3.40 2.16W < / R 45.03* 58.25* 32.42* 20.35*W / ) R 30.18* 44.02* 10.09 3.33R / W 9.32 13.10 3.63 4.07

    aTable entries are Chi-square values with 6 and 12 degrees of freedom for quarterly and monthly tests, respectively. Asteriskedvalues were significant at least at the 90 percent level, indicating a rejection of the null hypothesis.bNo instantaneous or unidirectional causality indicated by / ) which reads does not cause.

    107

  • 8/12/2019 PRICE DETERMINATION IN THE U.S. SHRIMP MARKET

    6/10

    suggest simultaneous price determination the various lagged prices suggested throughamong market levels on a quarterly basis. For identification of the dynamic shock models andthis reason, and because the error terms of transfer functions, most are insignificant andthe quarterly models are contemporaneously are not included in the final models. Laggedcross correlated, the models are estimated endogenous prices are included, however, tousing three stage least squares (3SLS) pro- correct for serial correlation. Retail prices forcedures. The final form of the estimated coeffi- both size classes appear to require at least onecients is derived utilizing procedures outlined period to fully adjust. In addition, the pricesin Goldberger. Given that identification of the for the larger shrimp are characterized by sig-transfer functions suggests lag structures to nificant lagged adjustment at both the retailbe present in quarterly price adjustment, the and wholesaler-processor level. Stronger rela-final form represents the long-run relationship tionships are found between exvessel andbetween each endogenous variable and the ex- wholesaler-processor prices than betweenogenous variables of the model. retail and wholesaler-processor prices.Price interrelationships between market In general, the estimated price models cor-levels are estimated for each size class. Struc- respond to a priori expectations. For thetural estimates are presented in Table 2. Of larger size shrimp, retail prices are inverselyTABLE 2. ESTIMATED QUARTERLY RELATIONSHIPSa AMONG EXVESSEL (E), WHOLESALE (W), AND RETAIL (R) PRICES FOR 21-25 AND

    31-40 COUNT RAW-HEADLESS SHRIMP, 1972-198121 25 Count Shrimp 31 40 Count Shrimp

    ExplanatoryVariables Rt Wt t Rt Wt tRt .189 - .057~~~~~~~~t ~~(.198) b (.075)Wt .481 .858 .708 .932(.088) (.028) .146) (.039)Et .839 .978(.102) .091)Rt 1 .701 . 181 .557 . 017(.073) (.090) .081) (.043)Wt-1 .176(.054)Income c . 0001 . 0011(.0005) (.0004)Total .0052 .0045Supplyd (.0054) (.0057)CPIMe .0034 .0045(.0040) (.0042)Stocksf -. 0023 -. 0014(.0016) (.0014)Imports:9 Own -. 0079 -. 0113 .0551) (.0326)Other .0003 .00003(.0019) (.0013)Landings:h Own -. 0598 -. 0084(.0244) (.0086)

    Other - .0014 - .0005.0011) (.0008)Costi .0017 -. 0002 .0006 -. 0006(.0009) (.0006) (.0076) (.0006)

    aprice effects are 3SLS estimates.bThe values in parentheses are the estimated standard errors of the parameter estimates.CNominal (1972) disposable income in billion dollar units.dEstimated as total disappearance from wholesale market of all sizes of raw-headless shrimp.eDeseasonalized consumer price index for red meat and poultry products (1972 = 100).fBeginning inventories of raw-headless fresh and frozen shrimp in million pound units.g Own imports are 21-25 or 31-40 count imports. Other imports refer to all other size classes of raw-headless shrimp im-ports in million pound units.hOwn landings are 21-25 or 31-40 count shrimp. Other landings are all other size classes of Gulf and South Atlantic shrimplandings in million pound units.iTotal food marketing cost index (1967 = 100).

    108

  • 8/12/2019 PRICE DETERMINATION IN THE U.S. SHRIMP MARKET

    7/10

    related to total supply. For 31-40 shrimp, ucts points out the difference between short-however, the opposite relationship was found. run and long-run effects. In the structuralThe estimated coefficient associated with con- models, the estimated coefficient of marketingsumer income was negative and too small to costs was positive for wholesale prices andestablish income as a major factor determin- negative for exvessel prices for both sizeing quarterly price changes. This result is con- classes. These results are consistent with thesistent with previous studies which used notion that increases in marketing costs placemonthly and quarterly data for a given level of upward pressure on wholesale prices butthe shrimp market, while the income effect is reduce the level wholesalers are willing to payusually stronger on an annual basis (Doll; for their raw product. The final form flex-Hopkins; Thompson and Roberts). The esti- ibilities, however, are positive for both sizemated positive coefficient associated with the classes and all three market levels. This resultprice index for other meat products suggests occurs because increases in marketing coststhat red meat and poultry serve as substitutes initially cause increases in wholesale prices,for both size classes of shrimp. The parameter and since wholesale and exvessel prices areestimates associated with beginning stocks, closely linked, eventually exvessel prices alsolandings, and imports in general had the ex- increase. Increases in marketing costs have apected negative relationship with price. larger effect on larger size prices. This may be

    From computation of the final form, the explained by higher costs associated with aestimated long-run impact multipliers ex- larger, more expensive product which is morepressed as price flexibilities are reported in likely to be stored in frozen form for a longerTable 3. As was found in the structural period oftime.estimates, the coefficients associated with in- SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONScome and total supply have either wrong or in- SUMMAY Dconsistent signs across size classes. The The primary purpose of this study was tosubstitution effect between other meat prod- evaluate the dynamic nature of price deter-ucts and shrimp appears to be greater for the mination and to assess the differential impactssmaller size class of shrimp. Smaller size various price determining factors have onshrimp prices appear to be more sensitive to alternative market levels of the U.S. shrimpchanges in landings, imports, and beginning industry. Different market levels, as well asstocks than larger size shrimp prices. different size count shrimp markets, wereThe effect of marketing costs of inter- analyzed. Partial or independent effects ofmediate goods and services for all food prod- causal variables such as imports, landings,TABLE 3. PRICE FLEXIBILITIES a FOR SPECIFIED PREDETERMINED VARIABLES AT EXVESSEL (E), WHOLESALE (W), AND RETAIL (R)

    MARKET LEVELS FOR 21-25 AND 31-40 COUNT RAW-HEADLESS SHRIMP, i972-198121 25 Count Shrimp 31 40 Count Shrimp

    Predeterminedvariables R W R WIncomeb - .2833 - .1829 - .2028 -. 1345 - .0130 - .0131Total SupplyC .7549 .4860 .5397 -. 3196 -. 0345 -. 0349CPIMd 1.5657 1.0079 1.1198 .4367 .0484 .0483Stockse - 1.2827 -1.1436 -1.2703 -. 4474 -. 3918 -. 3949Imports: fOwn -. 1966 -. 1754 -. 1947 .0227 .0199 .0201Other - .3041 - .2703 - .0301 .0576 .0499 .0509Landings:9Own - .2519 - .2245 - .2561 - .1974 -. 1729 -. 1963Other - .2622 - .2339 - .2667 -. 1466 -. 1284 - .1458Costh .2440 .2129 .1903 1.0481 .9194 .9131

    aValues are flexibilities derived at the means from quarterly final form estimates.bNominal (1972) disposable income in billion dollar units.cEstimated as total disappearance from wholesale market of all sizes of raw-headless shrimp in million pound units.dDeseasonalized consumer price index for red meat and poultry products (1972 = 100).eBeginning inventories of raw-headless fresh and frozen shrimp in million pound units.f Own imports are 21-25 or 31-40 count imports. Other imports refer to all other size classes of raw-headless shrimp im-ports in million pound units.9 Own landings are 21-25 or 31-40 count shrimp. Other landings are all other size classes of Gulf and South Atlanticshrimp landings in million pound units.hTotal food marketing cost index (1967 = 100).

    109

  • 8/12/2019 PRICE DETERMINATION IN THE U.S. SHRIMP MARKET

    8/10

    beginning inventories, income, marketing The estimated price relationships suggestcost, and prices of competing meat products all market levels will be impacted by changeswere developed. This information is vital for in imports and/or policy measures. Impactsaccurately predicting the consequences of the are nearly equal at the wholesale and exvesselspecific policy questions and also is necessary level but are considerably greater at the retailfor a complete understanding of the economic level. Impacts at the retail and wholesaler-relationships which exist within the U.S. processor market levels will likely take longershrimp marketing system. to be fully realized than at the producer level.No single level in the marketing system ap- On a size class basis, the prices for smallpears to have sufficient market power to ac- shrimp appear to adjust more rapidly toquire an unequal share of the benefits or avoid change in market conditions.an unequal share of the costs of increased or Although the direction of price impacts isreduced trade. On a monthly basis, it may ap- generally the same for the two size shrimppear that the exvessel market level leads classes analyzed, there are some differences inother levels in determining prices. However, terms of the magnitude of the effects. Thethis probably is due to factors other than market for smaller shrimp appears to be muchmarket power, such as wide month-to-month more affected by changes in domestic landingsvariations in landings, marketing response and imports. Prices for larger shrimp, on thetime, and time required for market informa- other hand, are more sensitive to the totaltion to fully permeate the system. The latter costs of marketing.criterion was suggested by the upward recur- The findings of this analysis may be used insive nature of monthly price changes com- further research to address two topics of in-pared to the simultaneous nature of quarterly creasing concern in the domestic shrimp mar-price movements. Although prices are simul- ket: increasing levels of imported culturedtaneously determined on a quarterly basis, shrimp and the popularity of closure policiesprice increases from restrictive trade policies for domestic shrimp stock management. Cul-will be passed on to higher market levels with tured shrimp are arriving predominantly inproportionally larger price increases. In addi- the 31-40 size class, with less seasonality thantion, price responses were found to be sym- wild-caught supplies. Closure policies, whichmetric. Thus, no evidence was found to sup- are used to protect smaller shrimp in shallowport the presence of monopsonistic pricing in Gulf waters, tend to result in an abundance ofthe market. The weaker linkage found between shrimp in the 31-40 size class. Theseretail and wholesale-processor prices than for developments are noteworthy consideringthe wholesaler-processor and exvessel prices that this study has suggested that the marketsuggests policy measures administered at the for smaller shrimp is already subject to largerretail level (i.e., market promotional pro- price responses than the larger count shrimpgrams) may have less of an impact on the total market for comparable changes in certainsystem than will policy measures adminis- causal factors in the domestic market. Thistered at the lower market levels, such as im- model can be used to assess the impacts ofplementation of cooperatives or market such structural change in the market.orders. REFERENCES

    Adams, C. M. Price Dynamics in the U.S. Shrimp Market. Unpublished Ph.D. dissertation.Food and Resource Economics Department. University of Florida, Gainesville, Florida,1984.Bessler, D. A., and J. A. Brandt. Causality Tests in Livestock Markets. Amer. J. Agr. Econ.64 (1982):140-44.Bessler, D. A., and L. F. Schrader. Relationship Between Two Price Quotes for Eggs. Amer.J. Agr. Econ. 62(1980):766-71.Box, G. E. P., and G. M. Jenkins. Time SeriesAnalysis-Forecastingand Control. San Francisco:Holden-Day, 1976.Doll, J. P. An Econometric Analysis of Shrimp Ex-vessel Prices, 1950-1968. Amer J. Agr.Econ. 54(1972):431-40.Goldberger, A. S. Econometric Theory. New York: John Wiley and Sons, 1964.Gollnick, H. Zur Statistischen Schatzung und Profung Irreversibler Nachfragefunktionen.Agronwirtschaft 21(1972):227-31.

    110

  • 8/12/2019 PRICE DETERMINATION IN THE U.S. SHRIMP MARKET

    9/10

    Granger, C. W. J. Investigating Casual Relations by Econometric Models and Cross SpectralMethods. Econometrica 37, 3(1969):424-38.Grant, W. E., and W. L. Griffin. A Bioeconomic Model of the Gulf of Mexico Shrimp Fishery.Trans. Amer. FisheriesSociety 108(1979):1-13.Haugh, L. D. The Identification of Time Series Interrelationships with Special Reference toDynamic Regression. Ph.D. dissertation, University of Wisconsin-Madison, 1972.Haugh, L. D., and G. E. P. Box. Identification of Dynamic Regression (Distributed Lag)Models Connecting Two Time Series. J. Amer. Stat. Assoc. 72(1977):121-30.Hopkins, J. C. An Econometric Analysis of the U.S. Shrimp Industry. Master's thesis, De-partment of Agricultural Economics, Texas A&M University, 1980.Keithly, W. R. Socioeconomic Determinants of At-Home Seafood Consumption: A Limited De-pendent Variable Analysis of Existing and Latent Consumers. Ph.D. dissertation, Foodand Resource Economics Department, University of Florida, 1985.Miller, S. E. Lead-Lag Relationships Between Pork Prices at the Retail, Wholesale, and FarmLevels. So. J. Agr. Econ. 12,1(1980):73-76.Pierce, D. A. Relationships-and the Lack Thereof-Between Economic Time Series, withSpecial Reference to Money and Interest Rates. J. Amer. Stat. Assoc. 72(1977):11-22.Prochaska, F. J., and W. R. Keithly. Market Impacts of U.S. Shrimp Imports. Workshop onShrimp and PrawnMarkets. International Institute of Fisheries Economics and Trade.Oregon State University, Corvalis, Oregon, 1985.Sims, C. A. Money, Income, and Causality. Amer. Econ. Rev. 62(1972):540-42.Spreen, T. H., and J. S. Shonkwiler. Causal Relationships in the Fed Cattle Market. So. J.Agr. Econ. 13,1(1981):145-53.Thompson, M. E., and K. J. Roberts. An Econometric Analysis of the U.S. Shrimp Market.Center for Wetland Resources, Louisiana State University, Baton Rouge, Louisiana, 1983.U.S. Department of Agriculture. AgriculturalOutlook. Various issues, 1975-1981.U.S. Department of Commerce(a), Bureau of Economic Analysis. Business Statistics: 1982.23rd Edition, 1983.U.S Department of Commerce(b), National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration, NationalMarine Fisheries Service. Fisheriesof the United States. Various issues, 1980-83.U.S. Department of Commerce(c), National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration, NationalMarine Fisheries Service. Shellfish Market Review-Annual Summary. Various issues,1968-1982.U.S. Department of Commerce(d), National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration andNational Marine Fisheries Service. Unpublished data files.U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. CPIDetailedReport. December 1972through December 1981.Van Dijk, G. Price Formation and Margin Behavior of Meat in the Netherlands and the Fed-eral Republic of Germany. Department of Agricultural Economics, Agricultural Univer-sity of Wageningen, the Netherlands, 1978.Ward, R. W. Asymmetry in Retail, Wholesale, and Shipping Point Pricing for Fresh Vegeta-bles. Amer. J. Agr. Econ. 64(1982):205-12.Wolfamm, R. Positivistic Measures of Aggregate Supply Elasticities: Some New Approaches-Some Critical Notes. Amer. J. Agr. Econ. 53(1971):356-59.Young, T. Modelling Asymmetric Consumer Responses with an Example. J. Agr. Econ. 31,2(1980):175-86.

    111

  • 8/12/2019 PRICE DETERMINATION IN THE U.S. SHRIMP MARKET

    10/10

    112