PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky...

52
PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with Variable Markups "Field Paper Requirement for International Economics Field" MUSA ORAK 1 Department of Economics, UCLA July 31, 2012 ABSTRACT In this paper, we study the real exchange rate (RER) dynamics in a multisector, sticky price model with local currency pricing, heterogeneity in frequency of price ad- justment and variable markups. More specically, we focus on producing the RER persistence seen in data for levels of nominal aggregate demand persistence matching the "nominal" exchange rate dynamics, unlike earlier studies that rely on high de- grees of aggregate demand persistence. We nd that heterogeneity in price stickiness alone amplies the aggregate RER persistence considerably and brings it to the levels consistent with data. Despite this improvement, the model with constant markups still relies heavily on existence of high degrees of aggregate persistence. Introducing variable markups improves the aggregate RER persistence further and closes some of the gap between theory and data. Hence, the model with variable markups is superior to the constant markup model in explaining RER dynamics since it relies less on high degrees of nominal aggregate demand persistence. Yet, somewhat high (even though lower than before) degree of aggregate persistence is still needed to explain RER dy- namics seen in data. Thus, consistent with the literature, we reach to the conclusion that the contribution of variable markups remains relatively modest and other sources of real rigidities should be sought. 1 e-mail: [email protected] 1

Transcript of PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky...

Page 1: PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with Variable Markups "Field Paper Requirement for International Economics

PPP Puzzle in aHeterogenous Sticky Price Model

with Variable Markups

"Field Paper Requirement for International Economics Field"

MUSA ORAK1

Department of Economics, UCLA

July 31, 2012

ABSTRACT

In this paper, we study the real exchange rate (RER) dynamics in a multisector,sticky price model with local currency pricing, heterogeneity in frequency of price ad-justment and variable markups. More speci�cally, we focus on producing the RERpersistence seen in data for levels of nominal aggregate demand persistence matchingthe "nominal" exchange rate dynamics, unlike earlier studies that rely on high de-grees of aggregate demand persistence. We �nd that heterogeneity in price stickinessalone ampli�es the aggregate RER persistence considerably and brings it to the levelsconsistent with data. Despite this improvement, the model with constant markupsstill relies heavily on existence of high degrees of aggregate persistence. Introducingvariable markups improves the aggregate RER persistence further and closes some ofthe gap between theory and data. Hence, the model with variable markups is superiorto the constant markup model in explaining RER dynamics since it relies less on highdegrees of nominal aggregate demand persistence. Yet, somewhat high (even thoughlower than before) degree of aggregate persistence is still needed to explain RER dy-namics seen in data. Thus, consistent with the literature, we reach to the conclusionthat the contribution of variable markups remains relatively modest and other sourcesof real rigidities should be sought.

1 e-mail: [email protected]

1

Page 2: PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with Variable Markups "Field Paper Requirement for International Economics

1 INTRODUCTION

Even though the term itself is relatively new, Purchasing Power Parity (PPP)has been studied long through the economic history. In its most simple andrigid form, PPP states that the nominal exchange rate between currencies oftwo countries should be equal to their aggregate price level ratios. Hence, PPPpredicts that one unit of currency will have the same purchasing power in bothcountries. As a consequence, the real exchange rate (RER) between two coun-tries should be constant at 1.2 A less rigid form of PPP, on the other hand,asserts that RER should be constant, but not necessarily at 1. Neither of theseversions of PPP are consistent with empirical �ndings. In one of the earlierstudies, Mussa (1986) shows that both the nominal and real exchange rates arehighly volatile compared to the relative price level and highly persistent. Rogo¤(1996) provides a literature review on empirical studies and comes up with theconclusion that the half life of deviations from PPP ranges from 3 years to 5years. This discrepancy between the theory and data is termed as PPP puzzlein the literature.

A large bulk of the literature on exchange rate determination is devoted toreconciling the theory with the well-documented volatility and persistence ofthe RER as seen in data.3 The volatility side of the PPP puzzle is relativelyeasier to solve since models with monetary shocks and plausible degree of nom-inal rigidities are known to close the gap between data and theory in terms ofgenerating high RER volatility. However, these models fail to replicate the largepersistence seen in data unless the degree of nominal rigidities are unrealisticallyhigh.

In a recent study, Carvalho and Nechio (2011) introduce heterogeneity infrequency of price adjustment matching US data, and pricing to market intoan otherwise standard multisector, two-country, sticky price model. They showthat the heterogeneous multisector model generates both more volatile and per-sistent aggregate RER dynamics in response to nominal shocks compared to aone sector counterfactual model. Indeed, their heterogeneous multisector modelproduces a half life of 39 months, which falls within the range provided by Ro-go¤ (1996). However, the success of the model of Carvalho and Nechio (2011)in generating realistic measures of RER dynamics relies on having a high degreeof nominal aggregate demand persistence, which is not consistent with nom-inal exchange rate dynamics found in Imbs, Mumtaz, Ravn and Rey (2005).When nominal aggregate demand persistence is set to a level consistent withnominal exchange rate dynamics, the heterogeneous multisector model fails togenerate realistic levels of aggregate RER persistence, even though it still doesremarkably better than the counterfactual one sector economy. Carvalho and

2RER is de�ned as: eP�

P, where e is nominal exchange rate, P � and P are aggregate price

levels in foreign and home countries respectively.3See Rogo¤ (1996) and Taylor and Taylor (2004) for a review of the literature.

2

Page 3: PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with Variable Markups "Field Paper Requirement for International Economics

Nechio (2011) attribute this failure of their model to non-existence of real rigidi-ties, other than the decreasing returns to scale (DRS) production technology.To investigate the likely e¤ects of incorporating real rigidities into their model,they set elasticities of substitution across varieties and sectors at unrealisticallyhigh levels and predict that introducing real rigidities into their model wouldenable the model to explain RER dynamics even at nominal aggregate demandpersistence levels consistent with nominal exchange rate dynamics.

Our aim in this paper is to test the prediction of Carvalho and Nechio (2011)by introducing real rigidities in the form of variable markups into their baselinemodel. More speci�cally, we are aiming at generating realistic aggregate RERpersistence at a nominal aggregate demand persistence level consistent with thedynamics of nominal exchange rates, while keeping elasticities of substitutionacross varieties and sectors at their baseline calibration and markup elasticityat empirically supported levels. In our baseline model with Dixit-Stiglitz (1977)CES demand aggregation, no strategic complementarities and Calvo (1983) typeprice setting behavior, the markup over marginal cost is constant and hence theonly source of persistence is �rms� inability to change their prices wheneverthey want. Incorporating the variable markup channel of real rigidities into ourbaseline model is expected to add another source of aggregate RER persistencefollowing a shock to nominal aggregate demand. Since the endogenous markupis decreasing in the relative price of a �rm, the incentives of a �rm to resetits price would be reduced further with variable markups, unless its opponentschange their prices too.

In the literature, there are several ways to introduce variable markups intothe standard sticky price models. Some of the recent studies are exploredin the upcoming Literature Review section. Among them, three main ap-proaches stand out: (i) using translog expenditure function introduced by Feen-stra (2003), (ii) introducing strategic complementarities in price setting betweenlarge �rms into a model with CES aggregation such as in Atkeson and Burstein(2008), and (iii) using a non-CES demand for intermediate goods such as theone introduced by Kimball (1995). In this paper we follow the third approachas it �ts the best with our baseline model.

Even though we use a constant returns to scale (CRS) calibration similar tothat in Kehoe and Midrigan (2007) as the baseline, our �ndings are quite con-sistent with that of Carvalho and Nechio (2011), whose baseline calibration hasa DRS production technology. First of all, counterfactual one sector economyis unable to produce realistic levels of aggregate RER persistence even underextremely high degrees of aggregate nominal demand persistence. On the otherhand, the multisector model with heterogeneity in frequency of price adjust-ment generates realistic aggregate RER dynamics when the nominal aggregatedemand persistence is set to the level that is commonly used in literature. Com-pared to one sector counterfactual economy, the heterogeneity in frequency ofprice adjustment, coupled with pricing in local currency amplify the aggregate

3

Page 4: PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with Variable Markups "Field Paper Requirement for International Economics

RER persistence in response to a shock to aggregate nominal demand. Thisresult is true regardless of the degree of nominal aggregate demand persistence.

When we use the median of the distribution of frequency of price adjustmentrather than the weighted average, we see that one sector economy does signif-icantly better in explaining the RER dynamics. Yet, the counterfactual onesector economy falls considerably short of heterogenous multisector economy inmatching the RER persistence seen in data. Furthermore, we also created anarti�cial economy with only three sectors. This economy is calibrated by match-ing the �rst and second moments of frequency of price adjustment and averageduration of spell. This model provides a reasonably good approximation of oursixty-seven sector model and thus, saves big time in computation.

Introducing variable markup channel of real rigidities into our baseline modelincreases the aggregate RER persistence further as expected and closes some ofthe gap between the model and data. However, unless markup elasticity is setat unrealistically high levels (which corresponds to unreasonably high levels ofsuperelasticity and thus, very large curvature of demand function), the modelwith variable markups is also unable to generate reasonable RER persistencefor a level of aggregate demand persistence matching the dynamics of nominalexchange rates. Yet, despite its inability to reconcile dynamics of nominal andreal exchange rates, the model with variable markups is still better in explainingthe RER dynamics than our baseline model with CES demand since it reliesless on degree of aggregate persistence.

The ampli�cation of aggregate RER persistence stemming from the variablemarkups are even smaller under DRS calibration of Carvalho and Nechio (2011).This stems from the fact that, under DRS, there are two countere¤ects whenvariable markups are introduced. In one hand, wage e¤ect as named by Chari,Kehoe and McGrattan (2000) reduces the incentives to increase price, since mar-ginal cost is now multiplied by a smaller multiplier. On the other hand, outpute¤ect increases the marginal cost and thus �rms are more willing to increasetheir prices. Hence, when variable markups are introduced, the improvement inaggregate RER persistence is smaller under DRS case than CRS case. This willbe discussed in more detail in the upcoming sections.

Based on these, we come up with the conclusion that empirically calibratedvariable markup channel of real rigidities goes a modest way in amplifying theaggregate RER persistence and as exogenous persistence gets smaller, the ab-solute e¤ect also gets less signi�cant. In other words, despite the improvement,some degree of aggregate demand persistence is needed to generate realistic RERdynamics. Still, we can conclude that model with variable markups is better inexplaining the RER dynamics compared to the baseline model, hence it shouldbe preferred. However, we should also look for other sources of real rigidities.At this point, the �rst candidate would be introducing sector speci�c capital.However, in a recent ongoing paper, Carvalho and Nechio (2012) nest sector

4

Page 5: PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with Variable Markups "Field Paper Requirement for International Economics

speci�c capital to their model. To our surprise, they �nd that even though in-corporating capital into the baseline model increases RER persistence, makingit sector speci�c reduces it. Similarly, in an extension to their model, Kehoeand Midrigan (2007) change their basic setup and allow the intermediate �rmsto use intermediate goods as an input to their production. They also �nd thatthis form of real rigidity does not increase the RER persistence.

Because the improvement we achieved through introducing variable markupsis moderate, our �ndings seem inconsistent with the predictions of Carvalho andNechio (2011) and con�rm more the other studies such as Kehoe and Midrigan(2007), Chari, Kehoe and McGrattan (2000) and Gopinath and Itskhoki (2010a)among many others. There are mainly two reasons for the gap between our re-sults and the predictions of Carvalho and Nechio (2011). First of all, theyemploy unrealistically high levels of elasticities of substitution across varietiesand sectors. If we had also set markup elasticity to an empirically unreasonablelevel, we would obtain a much higher degree of RER persistence as well. How-ever, we kept markup elasticity (and hence superelasticity) at an empiricallydocumented level. More importantly, Carvalho and Nechio (2011) deviate fromtheir baseline calibration when they try to predict the e¤ects of real rigiditiesin their model and compare this to their baseline model. However, those twocalibrations are not comparable since this new calibration already generatessigni�cantly larger persistence at every levels of elasticities of substitution andnominal aggregate demand persistence. We could have generated similar resultsby reverting to their alternative calibration. However, this would not changeour conclusion that variable markups alone are not enough to reconcile the ag-gregate RER dynamics with nominal exchange rate dynamics, even though theymoderately bring those two closer.

The paper is organized as follows: Section 2 will provide a brief literature re-view over the papers that we bene�ted the most. The literature on real exchangerates is enormous and thus we do not claim here to cover a considerable partof it. The benchmark model and its extensions along with the solution methodand assumptions will be described in Section 3. Section 4 will present the pa-rameterization of the models, while the quantitative �ndings will be discussedin Section 5. Finally, section 6 will conclude.

2 LITERATURE REVIEW

Our paper is related to more than one literature. First of all, there is a vastliterature on determinants of exchange rates and PPP puzzle. Even though weare not exploring most of them here, a detailed review of studies on PPP can befound at Rogo¤ (1996) and Taylor and Taylor (2004). Not necessarily relatedto real exchange rates, there are also many studies nesting real rigidities into

5

Page 6: PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with Variable Markups "Field Paper Requirement for International Economics

standard sticky price models. These models are used to explain various subjectssuch as gains from trade, international relative prices, monetary non-neutralityand dynamics of exchange rates among many others. Our paper have ingredientsfrom both of these literatures. Here, we will brie�y discuss some recent papersthat are most related and were bene�cial to ours. Hence, our literature reviewis not exhaustive.

The baseline model we used in this paper is mainly based on the model ofChari, Kehoe and McGrattan (2002) except for the lack of heterogeneity in theirmodel. They come up with the conclusion that if prices are held �xed for at leastone year (in our case average duration is only 4:7 months), risk aversion is high,and preferences are separable in leisure, then real exchange rates generated bythe model are as volatile as in the data and quite persistent, but less so than inthe data. They attribute the inability of the model to replicate the US data tothe unrealistically high correlation between RERs and the ratio of consumptionacross countries. Our model share this property as well, which is inconsistentwith data. However, we try to increase the persistence of the model �rst byintroducing heterogeneity and later by incorporating the variable markups intothe baseline model of Chari, Kehoe and McGrattan (2002).

In a similar model, but with variable desired markups a la Kimball (1995),Bouakez (2005) show that variable markups exacerbate the e¤ects of nominalrigidity in terms of generating a reasonably high level of RER persistence. Hismodel, which is estimated by the maximum-likelihood method using Canadianand U.S. data, quite successfully matches the persistence found in the real ex-change rate series between Canada and US.

Kehoe and Midrigan (2007) have a similar approach to ours in the sensethat they extend the commonly used sticky price models to have heterogeneityin the degree of price stickiness. They mainly focus on RER persistence at thegood level across countries. They also conduct panel data analysis to comparethe theoretical results with data. Their �ndings are not very consistent withthe data especially when the magnitudes are concerned. In one sense, they �ndsupport for the view that the higher the price stickiness, the more persistentthe RER of a good is. However, they also �nd that the discrepancy betweenthe theory and data is very large quantitatively. Theory predicts that the RERpersistence should range from fairly transient to fairly persistent, dependingon the degree of price stickiness. Nonetheless, in data, almost all goods havepersistent RERs, which is attributed to the fact that individual RERs tendclosely track the nominal exchange rate, regardless of price stickiness. Just likewe do in this paper, they also add price complementarities (through the use ofintermediate goods as inputs in production) to their baseline model. However,they reach to the conclusion that adding real rigidities leads to only a very slightimprovement. Carvalho and Nechio (2011) explain this by the very low level ofexogenous aggregate demand persistence in Kehoe and Midrigan (2007).

6

Page 7: PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with Variable Markups "Field Paper Requirement for International Economics

Unlike our Calvo (1983) type price stickiness, Nakamura and Steinsson(2010) calibrate a multi sector menu cost model with the same data we usedin this paper. They also augment the baseline menu cost model to incorporateintermediate inputs in production. The aim of their paper is to generate a levelof monetary non-neutrality in response to nominal shocks, that is consistentwith the US data. Similar to our paper, they also �nd that the introductionof heterogeneity in frequency of price adjustment almost triples the degree ofmonetary non-neutrality. Furthermore, they also show that the introduction ofintermediate inputs raises the degree of monetary non-neutrality by another fac-tor of three, without adversely a¤ecting the model�s ability to match the largeaverage size of price changes. Another important �nding is that a one sectoreconomy that is calibrated to have frequency of price adjustment of the median(rather than mean) of the multi sector model would generate a similar level ofmonetary non-neutrality. Overall, their model shows that aggregate nominalshocks can account for around 23 percent of US business cycles, which is closeto one-third observed in data.

This paper is most related with the work of Carvalho and Nechio (2011).Using the data of Nakamura and Steinsson (2008), they aggregate 271 sectorsinto 67 sectors and calculate their frequency of price adjustment and sectoralweights. The model used in their paper is that of Chari, Kehoe and McGrattan(2002) except for the heterogeneity introduced. Comparing the RER persistenceand volatility of the multisector model with that of a counterfactual one sectoreconomy, they �nd that deviations from PPP are more volatile and persistentthan in an otherwise identical one-sector world economy with the same aver-age frequency of price changes. However, the success of their model relies ona high degree of aggregate nominal demand persistence and it fails for lowerlevel of demand persistence. The authors attribute the inability of their modelto generate high enough persistence at a level of aggregate demand persistenceconsistent with nominal exchange rate movements to the lack of real rigiditiesin their model other than DRS production function. However, in a recent andunpublished paper, Carvalho and Nechio (2012) show that real rigidities intro-duced in the form of sector speci�c capital actually reduce persistence ratherthan increasing it. Finally, Carvalho and Nechio (2011) also decompose thepersistence into two components: aggregation and heterogeneity e¤ects. Theyreconcile the con�icting views of di¤erent papers saying the heterogeneity andaggregation plays a small role (Chen and Engel, 2005 and Crucini and Shintani,2008) and the ones saying heterogeneity can explain most of the aggregate RERpersistence (Imbs, Mumtaz, Ravn and Ray, 2005). Their conclusion is thatthese papers are not really con�icting but simply focusing on di¤erent sourcesof persistence and it is the heterogeneity e¤ect that has the largest e¤ect whilethe e¤ect of aggregation is quite small.

In a closed economy set up, Eichenbaum and Fischer (2004) extends a stan-dard version of Calvo (1983) type sticky price model in two ways. First, theyintroduce variable elasticity of demand of the di¤erentiated goods by employ-

7

Page 8: PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with Variable Markups "Field Paper Requirement for International Economics

ing a Kimball (1995) type aggregator rather than CES aggregation. Secondly,they also introduce imperfect capital mobility, meaning that capital is �xed andcannot be reallocated instantly. Since their model is a closed economy one,they focus on the persistence of price rigidities, which would be related to RERrigidity in an open economy model. Similar to other studies in the literature,Eichenbaum and Fischer (2004) also �nd that standard Calvo models are not ca-pable of generating a high level of price rigidity consistent with data. However,once variable markups and immobile capital are introduced, more reasonableresults are obtained in terms of price rigidity. Their results are consistent withthat of a later study by Woodford (2005) who also investigates the frequencyof price adjustment implied by a Calvo model with variable markups and �rm-speci�c capital.

In an another closed economy environment, Klenow and Willis (2006) eval-uate the variable markup channel of real rigidities by calibrating a menu costmodel with Kimball (1995) aggregator to match the micro data from US CPIin terms of the frequency and size of price adjustment. They reach to the con-clusion that the real rigidities alone are not su¢ cient to generate realistic levelsof persistence. Once a signi�cantly large degree of real rigidities are imposedto generate considerable monetary non-neutrality, implausibly large size of idio-syncratic shocks, large movements in micro quantities and very high levels ofmenu costs are required. Gopinath and Itskhoki (2010a) provide the intuitionfor this outcome: Signi�cant real rigidities compress price dispersion so thatmuch larger idiosyncratic shocks are required to match the size of price adjust-ment. At the same time, large menu costs are required to match the averagedurations of price rigidity, given large idiosyncratic shocks.

Rather than using a Kimball (1995) aggregator, Burstein and Hellwig (2007)introduce real rigidities by increasing marginal costs at the �rms level, whichgenerates strategic complementarity in price setting. They calibrate a closedeconomy, menu cost model of price adjustment matching the degree of decreasingreturns to scale using scanner data on prices and market shares at the levelof individual varieties. They �nd that strategic complementarities play a verymoderate role in generating large aggregate real e¤ects from the nominal shocks.

Both the closed and open economy literatures on real rigidities are broughttogether in Gopinath and Itskhoki (2010a). They evaluate both Calvo and menucost models with variable markups at the wholesale level and constant markupsat the retail level and try to match the data on international prices and exchangerate shocks. They show that variable markups alone generate price sluggishnessat the aggregate level, while they fall short of matching price persistence at themicro level. As in most of the studies in the literature, the absolute e¤ects ofvariable markups are modest unless they are coupled with exogenous sourcesof persistence. In another paper, Gopinath and Itskhoki (2010b) evaluate adynamic menu cost model with Kimball (1995) demand and they �nd that thevariable markup channel can generate signi�cant variation in frequency of price

8

Page 9: PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with Variable Markups "Field Paper Requirement for International Economics

adjustment, which can be translated into heterogeneity in price adjustment andhence larger aggregate persistence.

Alternative to Kimball (1995) type of demand, Atkeson and Burstein (2008)develop a model with Cournot competition and CES demand function to gen-erate variable markups. In this model, strategic interactions among the large�rms a¤ect the level of markups through the market shares. They mainly focuson the dynamics of international pricing rather than real exchange rates. They�nd that, when their model is parameterized to match the data on internationaltrade and market structure in the US, the deviations from the relative PPP canbe reproduced. They also assess the extent to which imperfect competition withvariable markups and international trade costs play essential roles in generatingthese results and come up with the conclusion that these features are key inproducing their results.

There are several alternative methods of incorporating variable markups intootherwise standard models. Among them, some recent ones worth mentioninghere even though they are not directly related to the PPP literature. Recently,Arkolakis, Costinot, Donaldson and Rodriguez-Clare (2012) extend Arkolakis,Costinot and Rodriguez-Clare (2011) and investigate the gains from trade byintroducing variable markups to the original model with constant markups.They consider three main alternatives to their baseline CES demand function:separable but non-CES utility functions; a quadratic, but non-separable utilityfunction; and a translog expenditure function as in Feenstra (2003), Bergin andFeenstra (2009) and Feenstra and Weinstein (2010). Skipping the details, they�nd that gains from trade liberalization are weakly lower than those predictedby models with constant markups. They also show that distribution of markupsare invariant to openness to trade, even though markups vary across �rms. Inanother study that employs translog expenditures, Bilbiie, Ghironi and Melitz(2012) model endogenous entry/exit and hence product varieties to analyze themacroeconomic �uctuations. They �nd that the sluggish response of the numberof producers generates a new and potentially important endogenous propagationmechanism for business cycle models. As a matter of fact, their model is ableto replicate several features of business cycles. Finally, Gopinath and Itskhoki(2010a) introduce an alternative setup in which �nal good producers bargainwith a number of intermediate good suppliers. Their model can be consideredas a general case of Atkeson and Burstein (2008). They show that in a sta-tic bargaining model there are strategic complementarities in wholesale pricesetting, so that markups are variable and wholesale prices exhibit incompletepass-through, while �nal good producers still have constant markups.

In summary, most of the studies show that the models with variable markupsare more successful than the models with constant markups in replicating thepersistence in RER, international relative prices and other aspects of macroeco-nomic �uctuations. Nevertheless, in most of these studies, the contribution of

9

Page 10: PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with Variable Markups "Field Paper Requirement for International Economics

the variable markups still remains relatively modest. Hence, introducing vari-able markups alone does not seem su¢ cient as a source of real rigidities. Thisinvokes the incorporation of other sources of real rigidities along with variablemarkups. Furthermore, there does not exist many studies introducing hetero-geneity in variability of markups (other than broad heterogeneity of Gopinathand Itskhoki (2010a), who only di¤erentiate between wholesale and retail sec-tors) and hence this seems like a research agenda that is worth being pursuedin the future.

3 MODELS

In this section, we will �rst introduce our baseline model with Dixit-Stiglitzaggregation. The model mainly follows Chari, Kehoe and McGrattan (2002)and Carvalho and Nechio (2011). The notation is also borrowed from these twopapers. Later, we will introduce a model with variable markups using a non-CES aggregation at the intermediate good production level. To that end, wewill introduce a variant of Kimball (1995) aggregator as in Klenow and Willis(2006) into our baseline model. The ingredients of this extended model aremainly from Eichenbaum and Fisher (2004) and Smets and Wouters (2007) aswell as Gopinath and Itskhoki (2010a and 2010b).

3.1 Baseline Model: Constant Markups

The world economy consists of two symmetric countries: Home and Foreign.4

In both countries, there exists a large number of identical and in�nitely livedconsumers, who supply their labor to intermediate good producing �rms thatthey own. Using this labor as the only factor of production, the monopolis-tically competitive �rms produce a variety of the intermediate good, which isthe only traded item in the model. These �rms can price discriminate acrosscountries and set their prices in local currency in a staggered fashion. Hetero-geneity is introduced by dividing the varieties into sectors that di¤er in theirfrequency of price adjustment. Once the price is set, the forthcoming demandshould be satis�ed at that price level. There are also competitive �nal good pro-ducers in each country that purchase intermediate goods from both countriesand aggregate the varieties into a non-tradable �nal good, which is used onlyfor consumption. As it is convenient in the literature, we will follow Woodford(2003) and work with the cashless limit of a monetary economy.

4Throughout the paper, foreign variables are denoted with superscript *.

10

Page 11: PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with Variable Markups "Field Paper Requirement for International Economics

3.1.1 Households

Households supply labor to the intermediate good producing �rms that theyown and they consume the non-tradable �nal good. They also engage in tradingstate contingent bonds internationally and receive dividend payments from themonopolistically competitive intermediate good producers. Given these, therepresentative household in the home country solves the following problem:

maxCt;Lt;Bt+1

E0

1Xt=0

�t(C1��t � 11� � � L1+

1 + )

subject to the following �ow budget constraint:

PtCt + Et(Qt;t+1Bt;t+1) �WtLt +Bt +�t (1)

and the transversality condition:

lims!1

Et(Qt;t+sBt+s) = 0 (2)

where, Ct is consumption, Lt is labor supply, Pt is price of �nal good inhome country,Wt is the nominal wage rate at the market and �t is the dividendpayments received from the intermediate good producing �rms at time t. Bt+1 ,on the other hand, represents the level of state contingent claims on a portfolioof �nancial securities that the household chooses at period t to enter the nextperiod. Due to the complete markets assumption, the households can choose adi¤erent value of Bt+1 for each possible state of the world at all times. Qt;t+1is the stochastic discount factor implied by a no-arbitrage condition and it canbe considered as the current price of the bond holdings next period. Finally,considering the parameters, � is the usual discount factor, 1� is the intertemporalelasticity of substitution and 1

is the Frisch elasticity of substitution.

The First Order Conditions (FOCs) of this problem are as follows:

Ct : C��t = �tPt

Lt : L t = �tWt

Bt+1 : �tQt;t+s = �t+s�s

11

Page 12: PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with Variable Markups "Field Paper Requirement for International Economics

where �t is the Lagrangian multiplier for the �ow budget constraint. Plug-ging the FOC for Ct into the other two, we obtain:

L tC�t =

Wt

Pt(3)

Qt;t+s = �s(Ct

Ct+ s)�

PtPt+s

(4)

Here, Qt;t = 1 and Qt;t+s =t+sYr=t+1

Qr�1;r for s > 0.

The problem for the foreign consumer is the same. However, we amend thebudget constraint as follows:

P �t C�t + Et(Q

�t;t+1

B�t;t+1et

) �W �t L

�t +

B�tet+��t (5)

Here, et represents the bilateral nominal exchange rate de�ned as the homecurrency price of one unit of foreign currency. Underlying this budget constraint,there is the implicit assumption that all state contingent bonds are denominatedin home currency and hence it needs to be converted to foreign currency whenconstructing the foreign budget constraint.

FOCs for the foreign consumers�problem gives:

L� t C��t =

W �t

P �t(6)

Q�t;t+s = �s(C�t

C�t+ s)�P �tP �t+s

etet+s

(7)

Because the state contingent bonds are traded internationally and due tothe no arbitrage condition, the stochastic discount factor should be the same inboth countries. As a consequence, the right hand sides of equations (4) and (7)should equal to each other at every possible state:

(Ct

Ct+ s)�

PtPt+s

= (C�t

C�t+ s)�P �tP �t+s

etet+s

(8)

12

Page 13: PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with Variable Markups "Field Paper Requirement for International Economics

Rearranging equation (8) and de�ning qt = etP�t

Ptas the real exchange rate

(RER) between two countries, we obtain:

qt+s = qt(C�t

C�t+ s)�(

CtCt+ s

)�� (9)

Following Carvalho and Nechio (2011), we set q0 = 1 and iterate equation(9) backward, we obtain the relationship between RER and consumption levelsin both countries:

qt = (CtC�t)� (10)

Equation (10) implies that RER and consumption ratio in two countriesare perfectly correlated. Even though this is not consistent with data, it is acommon characteristics of most of the models in literature that have full risksharing through state contingent bonds.

3.1.2 Firms

There is one single �nal non-tradable consumption good, that is produced inboth countries. This good is produced by competitive �rms that aggregate Kdi¤erent intermediate goods from both countries. The sectoral division of themonopolistically competitive intermediate good producers are based on theirfrequency of price adjustment. There is a continuum of �rms in every sectorand hence none of them have a signi�cant market share. The �rms are indexedaccording to the country of origin: H and F , their sector: k 2 f1; 2; :::;Kg andfurther by the variety they produce within their sector: j 2 [0; 1]. The �rms are

distributed across sectors according to the weights fk such thatKXk=1

fk = 1 and

fk > 0.

We have three levels of aggregation for each country in the model. Firstof all, varieties in each sector that are produced at home (YH;k;j;t) and foreigncountry (YF;k;j;t) and sold at home are aggregated to obtain the sectoral levelsof home (YH;k;t) and foreign (YF;k;t) goods sold at home respectively (equations11 and 12). Secondly, home and foreign intermediate goods of each sector soldat home are aggregated to give the total output of each sector sold at home(Yk;t, equation 13). Finally, home �nal good (Yt) is the aggregation of outputof each sector sold at home (equation 14).

13

Page 14: PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with Variable Markups "Field Paper Requirement for International Economics

YH;k;t = (f(��1)=�k

1Z0

Y(��1)=�H;k;j;t dj)

�=(��1) (11)

YF;k;t = (f(��1)=�k

1Z0

Y(��1)=�F;k;j;t dj)�=(��1) (12)

Yk;t = (!1=�Y(��1)=�H;k;t + (1� !)1=�Y (��1)=�F;k;t )�=(��1) (13)

Yt = (KXk=1

f1=�k Y

(��1)=�k;t )�=(��1) (14)

Here, 1 � ! 2 [0; 1] represents the steady state share of imports used inproduction. � > 1 is the elasticity of substitution between varieties withinsectors, � � 0 is the elasticity of substitution between home and foreign goodsand �nally � � 0 is the elasticity of substitution across sectors. The foreigncounterparts of these equations are as follows:

Y �H;k;t = (f(��1)=�k

1Z0

Y�(��1)=�H;k;j;t dj)�=(��1) (15)

Y �F;k;t = (f(��1)=�k

1Z0

Y�(��1)=�F;k;j;t dj)�=(��1) (16)

Y �k;t = ((1� !)1=�Y �(��1)=�H;k;t + !1=�Y�(��1)=�F;k;t )�=(��1) (17)

Y �t = (

KXk=1

f1=�k Y

�(��1)=�k;t )�=(��1) (18)

Final Good Producers The problem of the representative home country�nal good producer is:

maxYh;k;j;t;YF;k;jt

PtYt �KXk=1

fk

1Z0

(PH;k;j;tYH;k;j;t + PF;k;j;tYF;k;j;t)dj

subject to (11), (12), (13) and (14).

14

Page 15: PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with Variable Markups "Field Paper Requirement for International Economics

Here, Pt is the domestic price of �nal good, PH;k;j;t is the price charged athome at time t by �rm j in sector k by a home �rm. PF;k;j;t is the same for aforeign �rm that sells in home country and hence in home currency.

This problem has a standard, three step Dixit-Stiglitz solution. The resultingdemand functions for variety j in sector k;sold in home country and producedby home (equation 19) and foreign (equation 20) �rms are:

YH;k;j;t = !(PH;k;j;tPH;k;t

)��(PH;k;tPk;t

)��(Pk;tPt)��Yt (19)

YF;k;j;t = (1� !)(PF;k;j;tPF;k;t

)��(PF;k;tPk;t

)��(Pk;tPt)��Yt (20)

where, PH;k;t is the index for price charged at period t in sector k for goodsproduced and sold at home, PF;k;t is the same for the goods sold in home butproduced in foreign country. Finally, Pk;t is the index for price charged forsector k goods at home.

As it is standard in the literature, this process generates the following priceequations:

PH;k;t = (

1Z0

P 1��H;k;j;tdj)1=(1��) (21)

PF;k;t = (

1Z0

P 1��F;k;j;tdj)1=(1��) (22)

Pk;t = (!P 1��H;k;t + (1� !)P1��F;k;t)

1=(1��) (23)

Pt = (KXk=1

fkP1��k;t )

1=(1��) (24)

The �nal good producers in foreign country solve a similar problem subjectto equations (15)� (18). The resulting demand functions are as follows:

Y �F;k;j;t = !(P �F;k;j;tP �F;k;t

)��(P �F;k;tP �k;t

)��(P �k;tP �t

)��Y �t (25)

Y �H;k;j;t = (1� !)(P �H;k;j;tP �H;k;t

)��(P �H;k;tP �k;t

)��(P �k;tP �t

)��Y �t (26)

15

Page 16: PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with Variable Markups "Field Paper Requirement for International Economics

De�ning P �t , P�k;t, P

�H;k;t, P

�F;k;t, P

�H;k;j;t and P

�F;k;j;t same as their counter-

parts we have the following standard price indices for the foreign country:

P �H;k;t = (

1Z0

P�(1��)H;k;j;t dj)

1=(1��) (27)

P �F;k;t = (

1Z0

P�(1��)F;k;j;t dj)

1=(1��) (28)

P �k;t = ((1� !)P �(1��)H;k;t + !P�(1��)F;k;t )1=(1��) (29)

P �t = (KXk=1

fkP�(1��)k;t )1=(1��) (30)

Price Setting by Intermediate Good Producers Nominal rigidities areintroduced into the model through Calvo (1983) type price setting behavior forthe sake of tractability. Every period, each �rm j in sector k changes its pricewith a constant probability, �k. Thus, on average the �rms in sector k changetheir prices once in every 1=�k periods. As common in the literature, �rms�ability to reset their prices is independent across �rms within a sector and time.

At this point, we make the assumption that if an intermediate �rm hasthe opportunity to reset its price, it will do so in both markets. Hence, ahome intermediate �rm j in sector k will choose two prices at the same time:XH;k;j;t and X�

H;k;j;t , which are the price charged in home country in homecurrency and price charged in foreign country in foreign currency respectively.In this framework, a home country intermediate good �rm solves the followingmaximization problem:

maxXH;k;j;t;X�

H;k;j;t;Nk;j;t

EtQt;t+s(1� �k)s�

XH;k;j;tYH;k;j;t+s+et+sX

�F;k;j;tY

�h;k;j;t+s �Wt+sLk;j;t+s

�subject to (19) and (26) and

YH;k;j;t + Y�H;k;j;t = L

�k;j;t (31)

16

Page 17: PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with Variable Markups "Field Paper Requirement for International Economics

First order conditions of this problem are:5

XH;k;j;t : EtQt;t+s(1� �k)s(((1� �)X��H;k;j;t � �

Wt+s

�L��1k;j;t+s

X���1H;k;j;t)�H;k;t+s = 0

X�H;k;j;t : EtQt;t+s(1� �k)s(((1� �)et+sX���

H;k;j;t � �Wt+s

�L��1k;j;t+s

X����1H;k;j;t )�

�H;k;t+s = 0

where,

�H;k;t+s = !(1

PH;k;t+s)��(

PH;k;t+sPk;t+s

)��(Pk;t+sPt+s

)�� = 0

��H;k;t+s = (1� !)( 1

P �H;k;t+s)��(

P �H;k;t+sP �k;t+s

)��(P �k;t+sP �t+s

)�� = 0

Rearranged, these �rst order conditions result in the following price settingequations:

XH;k;j;t =�

� � 1

1Ps=0Qt;t+s(1� �k)s�H;k;t+s Wt+s

�L��1k;j;t+s

1Ps=0Qt;t+s(1� �k)s�H;k;t+s

(32)

X�H;k;j;t =

� � 1

1Ps=0Qt;t+s(1� �k)s��H;k;t+s

Wt+s

�L��1k;j;t+s

1Ps=0Qt;t+s(1� �k)set+s�H;k;t+s

(33)

Here, Wt+s

�L��1k;j;t+s

is the marginal cost of production. Equations (32) and (33)

are the standard Calvo price setting equations showing that once a �rm hasthe opportunity to change its price, it takes all the future values of marginalcost into account. � = �

��1 > 1 is the constant markup over the marginal costand hence, as we show in Appendix A , it disappears after linearization. Thismarkup is the same for every �rm in every sector. This proves that the CESaggregation we use in the baseline model generates a constant markup.

An analogous maximization problem yields similar equations for the foreign�rms:

5Here we plugged t+s =Wt+s

Nk;j;t+s, where t+s is the Lagrangean multiplier for the con-

straint (31).

17

Page 18: PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with Variable Markups "Field Paper Requirement for International Economics

X�F;k;j;t =

� � 1

1Ps=0Qt;t+s(1� �k)s��F;k;t+s

W�t+s

�L���1k;j;t+s

1Ps=0Qt;t+s(1� �k)s��F;k;t+s

(34)

XF;k;j;t =�

� � 1

1Ps=0Qt;t+s(1� �k)s��F;k;t+s

W�t+s

�L���1k;j;t+s

1Ps=0Qt;t+s(1� �k)s

��H;k;t+set+s

(35)

where,

�F;k;t+s = (1� !)( 1

PF;k;t+s)��(

PF;k;t+sPk;t+s

)��(Pk;t+sPt+s

)�� = 0

��H;k;t+s = !(1

P �F;k;t+s)��(

P �F;k;t+sP �k;t+s

)��(P �k;t+sP �t+s

)�� = 0

and W�t

�L���1k;j;t

is the foreign marginal cost.

In a steady state equilibrium, all �rms in a sector that set a new price wouldset the same price since they will face the same information set and the jointdistribution of future variables that matter for price setting would be the samefor all �rms in sector k (Carvalho and Nechio, 2011). Therefore, we drop the jsubscript and denote the reset prices as XH;k;t, X�

H;k;t, XF;k;t and X�F;k;t. Then,

the sectoral country price indices can be re-written as:

PH;k;t = (�kX1��H;k;t + (1� �k)P

1��H;k;t�1)

1=(1��) (36)

P �H;k;t = (�kX�(1��)H;k;t + (1� �k)P �(1��)H;k;t�1)

1=(1��) (37)

P �F;k;t = (�kX�(1��)F;k;t + (1� �k)P �(1��)F;k;t�1)

1=(1��) (38)

PF;k;t = (�kX1��F;k;t + (1� �k)P

1��F;k;t�1)

1=(1��) (39)

The assumption underlying the equations (36)� (39) is that if a �rm cannotreset its price, it keeps its price at its previous level rather than some sort ofstatic or dynamic indexing, such as in Eichenbaum and Fisher (2004) and Smetsand Wouters (2007).

18

Page 19: PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with Variable Markups "Field Paper Requirement for International Economics

3.1.3 Government

The baseline model is closed with a government that implements a monetarypolicy, which ensures existence and uniqueness of a rational-expectations equi-librium. As it is standard in the monetary economics literature, the speci�cationof the monetary policy is left implicit and it is assumed that the growth rateof nominal aggregate demand in each country follows an exogenous �rst orderautoregressive process. As Carvalho and Nechio (2011) state, this speci�cation�ts the economic data very well.

Let Zt and Z�t denote the nominal aggregate demand in home and foreigncountries respectively:

Zt � PtYt (40)

Z�t � P �t Y�t (41)

The assumption we made about the growth rate of nominal aggregate de-mand can be written formally as:

�zt = �z�zt�1 + �""z;t (42)

�z�t = �z�z�t�1 + �""

�z;t (43)

where, �zt and �z�t are the growth rates of nominal aggregate demand inhome and foreign countries respectively. The autocorrelation in nominal aggre-gate demand growth, �z, is employed as the measure of aggregate persistence.Finally, "z;t and "�z;t are uncorrelated, zero mean, unit variance and indepen-dently and identically distributed shocks.

3.2 Equilibrium6

An equilibrium for this economy is a collection of allocations for home consumersCt, Lt and Bt+1; allocations for foreign consumers C�t , L

�t and B

�t+1; allocations

and prices for home intermediate good producers YH;k;j;t, Y �H;k;j;t, Lk;j;t, XH;k;j;tandX�

H;k;j;t in each sector k; allocations and prices for foreign intermediate goodproducers YF;k;j;t, Y �F;k;j;t, L

�k;j;t, X

�F;k;j;t and XF;k;j;tin each sector k; sectoral

allocations and prices for home and foreign goods YH;k;t, YF;k;t, PH;k;t and

6Equilibirum de�nition is based on Chari, Kehoe and McGrattan (2002) and Kehoe andMidrigan (2007).

19

Page 20: PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with Variable Markups "Field Paper Requirement for International Economics

PF;k;t sold in home country; sectoral allocations and prices for home and foreigngoods Y �H;k;t, Y

�F;k;t, P

�H;k;t and P

�F;k;t sold in foreign country; sectoral allocation

of prices of intermediate goods in sold home country Yk;t and Pk;t; sectoralallocation of prices of intermediate goods sold in foreign country Y �k;t and P

�k;t;

and allocations for home and foreign �nal goods producers Yt, Y �t , Pt and P�t ,

real wages Wt, W �t , and bond prices Qt;t+1 satisfying: (i) consumer allocations

satisfy the consumers�problem in both countries; (ii) the prices of intermediategoods producers solve their maximization problem in both countries; (iii) the�nal goods producers�allocations solve their problem in both countries; (iv) themarket clearing conditions hold; and (v) nominal aggregate demand satisfy theabove speci�cation.

3.3 Extended Model: Variable Markups

As shown in equations (32) � (35), the markup over marginal cost is constantand same across all �rms within a sector, as well as across di¤erent sectors.This is the standard outcome of the CES aggregation in the absence of strategiccomplementarities. Introducing variable markups into our baseline model isexpected to increase the RER persistence following a shock to nominal aggregatedemand since the endogenous markup will be lower when the relative price of a�rm is higher, hence reducing the incentive of the �rm to reset its price furtherunless its opponents change their prices too.

There are several ways to introduce variable markups to our baseline model.Among them, three main approaches stand out: (i) using translog expenditurefunction introduced by Feenstra (2003)7 , (ii) introducing strategic complemen-tarities in price setting between large �rms into a model with CES aggregationsuch as Atkeson and Burstein (2008), and (iii) using a non-CES demand forintermediate goods such as the one introduced by Kimball (1995). Here, in thispaper we will follow the third approach as it �ts the best with our baselinemodel. Our non-CES aggregation model is mainly based on Woodford (2003),Klenow and Willis (2006), Eichenbaum and Fisher (2004), Smets and Wouters(2007) and Gopinath and Itskhoki (2010a).

We will introduce a non-CES aggregation of Kimball (1995) type only at theaggregation of intermediate good varieties at every sector. In other words, theaggregation of home and foreign goods sold at home/foreign country into totaloutput of sector k sold at home/foreign country (equations 13 and 17), andaggregation of sectors into �nal good (equations 14 and 18) remain the same.

At time t, an intermediate good produced and sold at home in sector k isobtained by aggregating the varieties j 2 [0; 1] using the following technologysuggested by Kimball (1995):

7Some recent studies using translog expenditure function of Feenstra (2003) are Arkolakis,Costinot and Donaldson (2012) and Bilbiie, Ghironi and Melitz (2012).

20

Page 21: PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with Variable Markups "Field Paper Requirement for International Economics

1Z0

G(YH;k;j;tYH;k;t

)dj = 1 (44)

Technology for Y �H;k;j;t, YF;k;j;t and Y�F;k;j;t are analogous. G is assumed to

be increasing and strictly concave: G0(:) > 0, G00(:) < 0 and also G(1) = 1. TheDixit-Stiglitz (CES) in our baseline model corresponds to a special case of this:

G(YH;k;j;tYH;k;t

) = (YH;k;j;tYH;k;t

)��1� (45)

and hence, our generalized Kimball (1995) aggregation encompasses the stan-dard CES case as well.

The problem faced by the �nal good producers is the same as before, exceptfor the constraints (11) and (12), which are now replaced by equation (44) and1R0

G(YF;k;j;tYF;k;t

)dj = 1. The resulting demand functions are:

YH;k;j;t = !'(PH;k;j;tPH;k;t

DH;k;t)(PH;k;tPk;t

)��(Pk;tPt)��Yt (46)

YF;k;j;t = (1� !)'(PF;k;j;tPF;k;t

DF;k;t)(PF;k;tPk;t

)��(Pk;tPt)��Yt (47)

Analogously, the foreign �nal good producers�problem gives the followingdemand functions:

Y �F;k;j;t = !'(P �F;k;j;tP �F;k;t

D�F;k;t)(

P �F;k;tP �k;t

)��(P �k;tP �t

)��Y �t (48)

Y �H;k;j;t = (1� !)'(P �H;k;j;tP �H;k;t

D�H;k;t)(

P �H;k;tP �k;t

)��(P �k;tP �t

)��Y �t (49)

where '(:) = G0�1(:) is the inverse of the derivative of Kimball aggrega-

tor and DH;k;t =1R0

G0(YH;k;j;tYH;k;t

)YH;k;j;tYH;k;t

dj. DF;k;t, D�F;k;t and D

�H;k;t are de�ned

analogously.

21

Page 22: PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with Variable Markups "Field Paper Requirement for International Economics

Home and foreign sectoral price indices satisfy:

PH;k;tYH;k;t =

1Z0

PH;k;j;tYH;k;j;tdj (50)

since the aggregator (44) is homothetic. As usual, similar relations hold forother three related price indices.

The problem facing the intermediate good producers and our Calvo pricingset up is the same as before. However, we now use equations (46) and (49) as theconstraints of the home producers and (47) and (48) of the foreign producers.The �rst order condition of the problem of a home �rm with respect to XH;k;j;tis depicted below:

1Xs=0

Qt;t+s(1��k)sYH;k;j;t+sDH;k;t+sPH;k;t+s

[XH;k;j;t+(XH;k;j;t�Wt+s

�L��1k;j;t+s

)1

'(mt+s)

G0(xt+s)

G00(xt+s)] = 0

(51)

where, xt = '(mt) and mt =PH;k;j;tPH;k;t

DH;k;t.

Manipulating this �rst order condition, marginal cost is multiplied by theterm A = G0(xt+s)

'(mt+s)G00(xt+s)+G0(xt+s), rather than the constant multiplier �

��1under CES case. Thus, the markup over marginal cost is not a constant anymoreand it is a decreasing function of the own relative price of a good. Therefore,we will have an additional term representing variable markups and this willnot disappear after linearization. This coe¢ cient can also be written as A =

1'(mt+s)G

00(xt+s)G0(xt+s)

+1.

We adopt the Kimball aggregator speci�cation of Klenow and Willis (2006).8

This results in:

G0�1(xj) = '(xj) = [1� � ln(�xj� � 1)]

�=� (52)

where xj � DH;k;t PH;k;j;tPH;k;t:

This demand representation is governed by two parameters: � > 1 -theelasticity of substitution across varieties within a sector as before-, and �, whichis the price elasticity of elasticity of demand and termed as superelasticity. Then,elasticity and super-elasticity are given as follows:

8However, it should be noted that we do not need to exactly specify the aggregator, sincewe will solve the model upto a �rst order approximation.

22

Page 23: PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with Variable Markups "Field Paper Requirement for International Economics

e�(xj) =�

1� � ln( �xj��1 )(53)

e�(xj) =�

1� � ln( �xj��1 )(54)

Note that when � = 0, we are back at CES case. Also, under CES case,'(x) = 1 for all x. Therefore, A = 1

1+G00(1)G0(1) 1

for every relative price level (for all

x) Since e�(1) = � G0(1)1�G00(1) = � is the steady state level of elasticity of substi-

tution, we can write A = 11� 1e�(1) =

���1 , thereby generating constant markups.

However, for the general case, the coe¢ cient A changes as the relative pricechanges and hence markup is not constant at the steady state level.

3.4 Solution

We solve the model by log-linearizing it around a zero in�ation steady state. Atthis steady state equilibrium, RER is set to 1 due to the common preferencesassumption. Furthermore, the stochastic discount factor Qt;t+s is set equalto discount factor �s. The symmetry of the countries result in equal prices ofall intermediate �rms, levels of employment, and allocations of consumption,imports, and exports for both countries in the steady state.

From now on, all the lower case variables refer to log deviations from thesteady state. The complete set of linearized equations are presented in AppendixA. As an example, equation (55) gives the linearized version of the price settingequation (equation 32) for home goods that are sold at home in home currency.The other price setting equations are analogues and can be found in AppendixA.

xH;k;t = (1� �(1� �k))(pt +mct;k) + �(1� �k)EtxH;k;t+1 (55)

where, real marginal cost9 is linearized as:

mck;t = �ct + lt (56)

+1� ��

�!(yt � �(xH;k;t � pH;k;t)� �(pH;k;t � pk;t)� �(pk;t � pt))

+(1� !)(y�t � �(xH;k;t � qt � pt + p�t � p�H;k;t)� �(p�H;k;t � p�k;t)� �(p�k;t � p�t ))

�9Here, we de�ned the marginal cost at its most general form for all 0 < � � 1. Under our

baselie CRS setup, linearized real marginal cost is reduced to �ct + lt.

23

Page 24: PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with Variable Markups "Field Paper Requirement for International Economics

Note that here we plugged the real wage from the household�s maximizationproblem: wt � pt = �ct + lt.

Decreasing returns to scale assumption might potentially end up in �rmspeci�c marginal costs. However, we make a simplifying assumption that eachsector �rms that reset their prices face the same conditional distribution for allfuture variables that matter for price setting, including marginal costs. Thuswe follow Carvalho and Nechio (2011) and simplify the notation using a pricethat is common to all adjusting �rms, and also a common marginal cost.

We follow Eichenbaum and Fischer (2004) and Smets and Wouters (2007)for the linearization of the variable markup model. They show in detail thatthe additional multiplier in front of the marginal cost, A, will be reduced tothe following form once the price setting equation is log linearized around therelevant steady state:

A =1 +G00(1)=G0(1)

2 +G000(1)=G00(1)

If we de�ne elasticity of substitution as: e�(x) = � G0(x)xG00(x) and the super elas-

ticity as: e�(x) = ePe�(1) @e�(1)@ eP , where eP is the relative price of the �rm, Eichenbaumand Fischer (2004) show that A = 1

1+(��1)� , where � =e�(1)e�(1)�1 is the steady

state level of markup. Gopinath and Itskhoki (2010a) rewrite this coe¢ cient asA = 1

1+� , where � =�

��1 is the markup elasticity.

In the end, the existence of variable markups adds another multiplier in frontof the marginal cost. To be more speci�c, the price setting equation in this casecan be written as:10

xH;k;t�pH;k;t�1��(1��k)EtxH;k;t+1 = (1��(1��k))1

1 + �(pt+mct;k)+(pH;k;t�pH;k;t�1)

(57)

Under CES, � = 0 and thus, A = 11+� = 1. For the general case, on the

other hand, A < 1. This introduces additional persistence into our model. Asbefore, �rms cannot change their prices as much as they want since they haveto wait until Calvo fairy touches them. This is the source of nominal rigidity inthe model. On the other hand, they are not as willing as before to change theirprice since markup is a decreasing function of their relative price. This is the

10Here, we slightly used a di¤erent but common version of equation 32 following Gopinathand Itskhoki (2010a) for technical reasons they explain. They state that this version ensuresstationarity of the right hand side. However, both equations (32) and (58) give the sameoutcome when � = 0, and hence this a non-trivial change.

24

Page 25: PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with Variable Markups "Field Paper Requirement for International Economics

source of real rigidity in the model. The smaller A from 1 (or equivalently thelarger markup elasticity �) the higher the degree of strategic complementarityand hence persistence are.

At this point, it would be useful to examine the implications of introducingvariable markups into the model for both CRS and DRS cases in more detail.When the production technology is CRS (� = 1), equation (58) can be writtenas:

xH;k;t�pH;k;t�1��(1��k)EtxH;k;t+1 = (1��(1��k))A(pt+�ct+ lt)+(pH;k;t�pH;k;t�1)

where A = 11+� . Thus, when � > 0; increases in wage rate induce smaller

increase in the �rm�s price, compared to the constant markup case. Chari,Kehoe and McGrattan (2000) term this as wage e¤ect. Therefore, wage e¤ectby itself makes the price less sensitive to changes in demand/output.

On the other hand, when the production technology is DRS (� < 1), theexact multiplier after plugging equation (56) into equation (58) and rearranging,will be A� rather than A only, where � = 1

1+A(1��)� �

. Note that as � increases,

A gets smaller and hence � gets larger (� = 1, when � = 1). This second e¤ectis termed as output e¤ect by Chari, Kehoe and McGrattan (2000). This e¤ectalone says that increases in economy wide output increase the �rm�s marginalcost due to decreasing returns to scale. This, in turn, will increase the incentivesof the �rms to charge a higher price. Thus, when we have a higher markupelasticity, the multiplier declines more in CRS case than DRS case and hencethe e¤ect of the change in markup elasticity would be lower under DRS, sinceboth e¤ects will work in di¤erent directions.

Both Klenow and Willis (2006) and Gopinath and Itskhoki (2010b) makethe assumption that DH;k;t (and DF;k;t, D�

H;k;t and D�F;k;t) equals to its steady

state value: D = ��1� . Gopinath and Itskhoki (2010b) also provide a proof to

the lemma that the �rst order deviation of DH;k;t from D is nil. Given this,the log-linearized equation for the demand for intermediate good (YH;k;j;t ='(

PH;k;j;tPH;k;t

DH;k;t)YH;kt) is reduced to yH;k;j;t = yH;k;t � �(dH;k;t + pH;k;j;t �pH;k;t) = yH;k;t � �(pH;k;j;t � pH;k;t), which is same as the CES case. Thus,in log-linear form, the demand for intermediate varieties can be approximatedby our linear equation in the baseline model. Finally, following Gopinath andItskhoki (2010a), the price levels in sectors can be written same as before:pH;k;t = �kEjxH;k;t+(1��k)pH;k;t�1. As usual, the other sectoral price indicesare analogous.

25

Page 26: PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with Variable Markups "Field Paper Requirement for International Economics

3.5 One Sector Economy

In order to see the e¤ects of heterogeneity in terms of generating aggregateRER persistence, we create a counterfactual one sector economy like that inCarvalho and Nechio (2011) to employ as a basis of comparison. In this economy,the probability of re-setting the price, �, is set equal to the weighted average of

frequency of adjustment of all sectors in the multi-sector economy: � =KXk=1

fk�k.

We also replace the weighted average �, with the median of the distribution�Med to see if using median instead makes any di¤erence for our results.

3.6 A Three-Sector Approximating Economy

Di¤erent from Carvalho and Nechio (2011), we also create a three-sector ap-proximating economy. In this model, we have only three sectors rather than 67in baseline. Frequency of price adjustment and sectoral weights are calibratedto match the �rst and second moments of distribution of frequencies of priceadjustment and average duration of spell in the multisector model. The aimhere is to show that the results from multisector model can be approximatedreasonably well by using a three-sector approximation model, thereby enablingus to save big time in computation.

4 PARAMETERIZATION

The world consists of two economies that can be interpreted as US and the restof the world. A period of the model is one month and parameters are calibratedaccordingly. The heterogeneity is introduced by the di¤erences of sectors intheir frequency of price adjustment. We will use the frequencies and the relatedweights for 67 sectors that are aggregated by Carvalho and Nechio (2011) fromthe 272 sectors data of Nakamura and Steinsson (2008). The details of thedata and the issues related to aggregating can be found in these mentionedpapers. When the weighted average of sectoral frequency of price adjustmentis calculated, we obtain the average monthly frequency of price adjustment ofthe one sector economy: � = 0:2112. This is equivalent to saying that �rmschange their prices once in every 1=:2112 = 4:7 months. Also, the distributionof frequency of price adjustment has a median value of 0:0846.

Our baseline calibration mainly follows Kehoe and Midrigan (2007). In thisframework, we assume log utility. Hence, we set � = 1 in the baseline. However,we also consider the case � = 3 to compare the results to that of Carvalho and

26

Page 27: PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with Variable Markups "Field Paper Requirement for International Economics

Nechio (2011). We also assume unit Frisch elasticity of supply of labor: = 1.For the production side, we again take the model of Kehoe and Midrigan (2007)as baseline and set � = 1. In other words, production technology is linear inlabor and since the labor is the only factor of production, our baseline modelis CRS. We also repeat the exercises for the calibration of Carvalho and Nechio(2011), in which � = 2=3. This implies "decreasing returns to scale" productionfunction since we do not have capital or any other factor other than labor. Thisis the only source of real rigidity and strategic complementarity in the baselinemodel of Carvalho and Nechio.(2011).11

Rest of the parameters are from the calibration of Carvalho and Nechio(2011). The discount factor � is set equal to 0:9983 to match 2 percent discountrate per year. The elasticity of substitution across the varieties within a sector� is set equal to 10. This choice implies a markup rate of 11%, consistent withdata. The elasticity of substitution between home and foreign goods � is set to1:5 and the elasticity of substitution across sectors � is set to 1. Finally, shareof imports in �nal good production is set equal to 10%.

Regarding the exogenous aggregate demand persistence, we mainly focus ontwo values: �z 2 f0:35; 0:8g even though we check the persistence at every levelof �z between 0 and 0:9. Here, 0:8 is chosen as it is consistent with monthlyaggregate nominal persistence in data, which falls between 0:75 and 0:9 (Mankiwand Reis, 2002). 0:35, on the other hand, is chosen to match the properties ofthe nominal exchange rate as it in Imbs, Mumtaz, Ravn and Ray (2005). Ouraim is to generate a reasonable level of aggregate RER persistence at this levelof nominal aggregate persistence. The standard deviation of the shocks �" isset to _0:05=

p3, which roughly matches 1% at quarterly frequency as in Imbs,

Mumtaz, Ravn and Ray (2005).

3-sector model is calibrated to approximate the 67-sector model in order toexamine whether we can obtain similar results with considerably less amountof computation time. To calibrate the sectoral weights and frequencies of priceadjustment, we match the �rst and second moments of distribution of frequencyof adjustment in 67 sectors, as well as the �rst moment of the average durationof spell. The resulting parameters are depicted in the last two rows of Table 1.

11Note that when we set � = 1, = 0 and � = 1 , the model becomes strategically neutral.

27

Page 28: PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with Variable Markups "Field Paper Requirement for International Economics

Table 1. Parameters of the Baseline Model

Description ValueAll Models

Discount factor � = 0:9983Coe¢ cient of relative risk aversion � = f1; 3gElasticity of Labor Supply = 1Production technology � 2 f2=3; 1gElasticity of substitution across varieties � = 10Elasticity of substitution between home and foreign goods � = 1:5Elasticity of substitution across sectors � = 1Share of imports ! = 0:9Aggregate persistence �z2 f0:35; 0:8gStandard deviation of the shock 0:0029

1-Sector ModelAverage frequency of price adjustment �= 0:2112Median of frequency of price adjustment �Med= 0:0846

3-Sector Approximation Model

Frequencies of price adjustment � =

240:61160:12250:0323

35Sectoral weights f =

240:22350:54840:2281

35

Following Gopinath and Itskhoki (2010a and 2010b), we will analyze di¤erentlevels of markup elasticity: � 2 f0; 1; 1:5; 4; 10_g. The values of � that give thesevalues, given � = 10, are f0; 9; 13:5; 36; 90g. Here, � = 0 refers to the CEScase, while � = 1:5 (� = 13:5) is the markup elasticity estimated by Gopinathand Itskhoki (2010a) for wholesale sector. � = 1, on the other hand, matchesthe middle of the long run exchange rate pass through range in Gopinath andItskhoki (2010b). Finally, we use � = 10 to see the e¤ect of very high levels ofreal rigidities.

5 QUANTITATIVE FINDINGS

In this section, we �rst describe the measures that we will use as indicators ofaggregate RER persistence. Later, the quantitative results from the baseline1-sector, 3-sector and 67-sector models will be discussed using these measures.Finally, the results under variable markups will be presented for both the CRSand DRS cases.

28

Page 29: PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with Variable Markups "Field Paper Requirement for International Economics

5.1 Measures of Persistence

We will employ �ve di¤erent measures of persistence, all of which are directlycalculated using the Impulse Response Functions (IRFs): hL, uL, qL, CIR and�1. Among these, hL is the one that we will focus on the most, in consistencewith the literature. hL refers to the half life of the shocks. Half life is de�nedand calculated pretty standard. It measures the number of periods it takes forthe IRFs to a unit shock to dissipate by half. Upper life (uL) and quarter life(qL) are two other measures provided by Steinsson (2008). Upper life refers tothe number of periods for IRFs to fall below the initial response while quarterlife is the time it takes to drop below one fourth of it. If the IRFs are nothump-shaped and hence always declining, then the uL is said to be equal to 0.These measures are provided to give a better picture of various properties ofIRFs.

Cumulative Impulse Responses (CIR) measures the total magnitude of re-sponse, normalized by the initial response. In general, the higher the CIR, themore persistent a shock is. To calculate CIR, we divide every period�s impulseresponse by initial response and sum them up. Finally, we also calculate �1,which is the �rst order autocorrelation observed in IRFs.

5.2 Constant Markups

The results from the baseline model with CRS production technology are pre-sented in Table 1. Note that, we set �z = 0:8 as in Carvalho and Nechio (2011)in this subsection. Table 1 shows that the counterfactual 1-sector economy withfrequency of price adjustment set to weighted average is too far from generatingan empirically realistic level of RER persistence. hL in 1-sector model is only 14months, which is almost one-third of even the lowest limit of RER persistenceseen in data.12 The results are very similar to other measures of persistence aswell. When we set the frequency of price adjustment at median instead, thepersistence almost doubles, while still being considerably below the data values.On the other hand, introduction of heterogeneity improves the results consid-erably, bringing hL to a level that is within the limits found empirically. To bemore speci�c, 67-sector model generates a hL of 40 months, which falls between3� 5 years range consensus view. Furthermore, uL is 26 months, which is veryclose to data value. Nevertheless, the 67-sector does poorest in terms of gen-erating a high enough qL measure consistent with data, albeit the signi�cantimprovement compared to the counterfactual 1-sector economy. Finally, themeasures CIR and �1 also show that heterogeneity increases aggregate RERpersistence. Overall, the heterogenous multisector model increase the persis-tence of RER signi�cantly, compared to the 1-sector model (regardless of using

12See Rogo¤ (1996) and Steinsson (2008) for the measures in data.

29

Page 30: PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with Variable Markups "Field Paper Requirement for International Economics

mean or median), thereby providing a better account for RER dynamics. Asa consequence, we can say that the e¤ect of heterogeneity on explaining RERpersistence is quite large.

Table 1. RER Persistence Under Baseline Speci�cation(CRS, �z = 0:8)

Data 1-Sector 1-Sector 67-Sector(Mean) (Median)

hL 36� 60 14 28 40uL 28 9 19 26qL 76 18 35 54CIR � 20:5 49:8 69:9�1 � 0:969 0:988 0:991

The results from the calibration of Carvalho and Nechio (2011) are almostthe same (Table B.1 in Appendix B). Remember that their model has a DRSproduction technology, along with � = 3 preferences. Similar to our CRS case,1-sector model has a hL of only 14 months, while it increases to 39 months forthe multisector model with heterogeneity in frequency of price adjustment. Therest of the statistics are also very similar as well, other than a slightly higherright skewness for multisector model and hence the main message remains thesame: heterogeneity in frequency of price adjustment brings RER dynamics tolevels consistent with data, explaining most of the PPP puzzle. Hence, we cansay that our baseline calibration and that of Carvalho and Nechio (2011) doalmost equally well in explaining the aggregate RER persistence.

The �ndings in Table 1. reveals that the improvement in aggregate RERpersistence is not due to only one speci�c portion of the IRFs. This is furthercon�rmed in Figure 1.13 , where we can see that the overall response of multi-sector model is larger and more persistent at every period after a 1 standarddeviation shock to home nominal aggregate demand (which can be thought ofas a shock to monetary policy as well). Even though the initial responses aremore or less the same in both 1-sector and 67-sector economies, the response ofthe latter always remains well above that of the former.

13From now on, including Figure 1, 1-Sector always refers to the counterfactual one sectoreconomy for which the frequency of price adjustment is set at weighted average of that of 67sectors (not median).

30

Page 31: PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with Variable Markups "Field Paper Requirement for International Economics

Figure 1. Scaled IRFs of Aggregate RERto 1 Standard Deviation Shock to Nominal Aggregate Demand1415

(CRS, �z = 0:8)

0 10 20 30 40 500

1

2

3

4x 10

­3

Months

RE

R1­Sector3­Sector Approx.67­Sector

Figure 1 reveals one other crucial result. When we match the �rst and sec-ond moments of frequency of price adjustment and average duration of spell,we can approximate the 67-Sector economy reasonably well with a representa-tive 3-Sector economy. This saves big time in computation and hence increasee¢ ciency, without causing any loss in the main messages of this paper. FigureB.1 in Appendix B shows that the IRFs are almost identical for the calibrationof Carvalho and Nechio (2011).

Even though we were able to generate realistic levels of aggregate RERpersistence by introducing heterogeneity in frequency of price adjustment, thisresult relies on a high level of exogenous persistence: �z = 0:8. This level ofexogenous persistence is consistent with the evidence on the dynamic propertiesof nominal aggregate demand and it is very common in the literature. However,as Imbs, Mumtaz, Ravn and Ray (2005) show and Carvalho and Nechio (2011)replicate, this high level of exogenous persistence is not consistent with the dy-namic properties of nominal exchange rates. Indeed, if we were to calibrate �zto match the properties of nominal exchange rate, it should have been around0:35. Hence, we are producing realistic aggregate RER persistence at the ex-pense of producing counterfactual implications for the dynamic properties ofthe nominal exchange rate.

14 IRFs shows the deviations from the steady state.15 IRFs for 1-Sector model is multiplied by 1.3 to equalize the initial responses in both

1-Sector and 67-Sector economies. The initial responses are not too di¤erent but they areequalized to see the overall picture better.

31

Page 32: PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with Variable Markups "Field Paper Requirement for International Economics

At his point, a natural question emerges whether our model is capable ofproducing a realistically high degree of aggregate RER persistence when thenominal aggregate demand persistence is set to a level consistent with nominalexchange rate dynamics. To answer this question, we repeat the same exercises,this time setting �z = 0:35 (Table 2). Also, we run the model for di¤erentvalues of �z, to see the relationship between the exogenous nominal demandpersistence and RER persistence (Figure 2).

Table 2. RER Persistence Under Lower Exogenous Persistence(CRS, �z = 0:35)

Data 1-Sector 67-SectorhL 36� 60 5 12uL 28 1 3qL 76 8 23CIR � 6:2 18:7�1 � 0:872 0:948

Table 2. shows that both the 1-Sector and multisector models do very poorlyin terms of generating a realistic aggregate RER persistence, even though het-erogeneity still brings the results closer to the levels somehow less inconsistentwith data. The half-life of IRF after a shock to nominal aggregate demand isonly 1:year in the multisector model, which is very low compared to 3� 5 yearsin data. The model does poorly in replicating the other dynamics that can bemeasured by uL and qL as well. This table is reproduced for the DRS case ofCarvalho and Nechio (2011) and the results are very similar for the 1-Sectormodel, while 67-Sector model does poorer under DRS case than our CRS case(Table B.2., Appendix B).

Figure 2. Half-Life as a Function of Aggregate Persistence(CRS)

0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.80

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

Half 

Life

 in M

onth

s

ρz

1­Sector3­Sector Approx.67­Sector

32

Page 33: PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with Variable Markups "Field Paper Requirement for International Economics

When we repeat the same exercise for a range of values of �z between [0; 0:9],we obtain four main results about the interaction of exogenous aggregate persis-tence, RER persistence and heterogeneity in frequency of price adjustment: (i)For all levels of exogenous persistence, the heterogenous multisector does betterthan the counterfactual 1-Sector economy in terms of generating a higher levelof RER persistence, (ii) 1-Sector economy is not capable of producing realisticlevels of RER persistence even under extremely high levels of nominal aggre-gate demand persistence, while the multisector economy is capable of generatingrealistic levels of aggregate RER persistence only with high levels of nominal ag-gregate demand persistence, (iii) unlike Carvalho and Nechio (2011) who claimsthat the ampli�cation ratio, which is de�ned as the ratio of half life of themultisector model to that of 1-Sector model, is strictly increasing in aggregatepersistence, our results for both CRS case and DRS case with their calibrationreveals that "strictly increasing" is a very strong comment (Figure 3). Thereare some ups and downs in the ampli�cation ratios as �z increases. Still, weagree with them on that this ratio has an increasing tendency generally. Hence,we can conclude that, the contribution of heterogeneity in terms of generatinghigher RER persistence increases with nominal aggregate demand persistence.(iv) Once again, 3-Sector arti�cial model approximates the 67-Sector model rea-sonably well for every level of exogenous persistence. Figures B.2. and B.3 inAppendix B reproduce the same results for the DRS case.

Figure 3. Ampli�cation Ratio between Multisector and 1-SectorModels16

(CRS)

0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.81.6

1.8

2

2.2

2.4

2.6

2.8

3

Rat

io o

f Hal

f Liv

es

ρz

In summary, our model�s success in explaining RER dynamics totally de-pends on the existence of a very high level of aggregate persistence. Carvalho16Here, we divide half life of 67-Sector by that of 1-Sector for each level of �z .

33

Page 34: PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with Variable Markups "Field Paper Requirement for International Economics

and Nechio (2011) explain this by the lack of real rigidities in the model (otherthan the DRS in their baseline calibration). To show that real rigidities mightimprove the RER persistence at low levels of nominal aggregate demand per-sistence, they increase both the elasticity of substitution across varieties andelasticity of substitution across sectors to unrealistically high levels.17 Theyshow that, with this calibration, the heterogeneous multisector model is able togenerate realistic aggregate RER persistence even at �z = 0:35. However, onceagain, they do this by only counterfactually high level of elasticities and makean inference from that calibration about the results of having real rigidities inthe model. Our aim is to introduce real rigidities through variable markups totest their prediction against Kehoe and Midrigan (2007) and Chari, Kehoe andMcGrattan (2000), among various others, who claim that real rigidities do notimprove persistence signi�cantly in the absence of high aggregate persistence.When doing so, we will keep the parameters at their empirically consistent levelsand see if prediction of Carvalho and Nechio (2011) is veri�ed under plausibleparameterization.

5.3 Variable Markups

CRS Calibration:

Figure 4. Half-Life as a Function of Aggregate Persistenceand Markup Elasticity

(CRS and Variable Markups)

0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.80

10

20

30

40

50

Half L

ives in M

onth

s

ρz

4.a 1­Sector Economy

Γ=0 (CES)Γ=1Γ=1.5Γ=4Γ=10

0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.80

20

40

60

80

100

120

140

160

4.b. Multisector Economy

Hal

f Li

ves 

in M

onth

s

ρz

Γ=0 (CES)Γ=1Γ=1.5Γ=4Γ=10

First of all, as expected, incorporation of variable markup channel of realrigidities into the model increases the aggregate RER persistence for both 1-Sector and 67-Sector economies at every level of nominal aggregate demandpersistence (Figures 4a and 4b). The question here is whether realistic aggregate

17They set � = 30 and � = 30.

34

Page 35: PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with Variable Markups "Field Paper Requirement for International Economics

RER persistence is generated when �z = 0:35 and markup elasticity is set atempirically supported levels such as � = 1 or � = 1:5. The answer appears tobe "no" when Figures 4 and 5 and Table 3 are examined. The half life of IRFsto a 1 standard deviation shock to nominal aggregate demand increases from12 months to only 16 months, when � = 1:5. The improvement is at relativelysimilar magnitudes for other measures as well.

Figure 5. IRFs of Aggregate RERto 1 Standard Deviation Shock to Nominal Aggregate Demand

(CRS, Variable Markups, �z = 0:35)

0 10 20 30 40 50 600

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5

3

3.5x 10

­3

Months

RE

R

Γ=0 (CES)Γ=1Γ=1.5Γ=4Γ=10

We can generate aggregate RER persistence close to what is observed indata, only when markup elasticity is unrealistically large. Even when � = 10,the half life increases from 12 months under CES case to 30 months, still fallingshort of 36 months, which is the lower bound of empirically plausible half lifemeasure. On the other hand, counterfactual 1-Sector economy falls signi�cantlyshort of data in terms of generating high aggregate RER persistence, even underour extremely high markup elasticity: � = 10.

35

Page 36: PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with Variable Markups "Field Paper Requirement for International Economics

Table 3. RER Persistence Under Lower Exogenous Persistence(CRS, Variable Markups, �z = 0:35)

hL uL qL CIR �1Data 36� 60 28 76 � �

� = 0 1-Sector 5 1 8 6:2 0:872(CES) 67-Sector 12 3 23 18:7 0:948

� = 1 1-Sector 7 2 10 8:5 0:90767-Sector 15 3 31 24:9 0:960

� = 1 :5 1-Sector 7 2 11 9:3 0:91667-Sector 16 4 34 27:3 0:963

� = 4 1-Sector 10 3 15 12:8 0:94067-Sector 21 5 45 36:5 0:972

� = 10 1-Sector 14 5 22 18:7 0:95967-Sector 30 6 65 50:4 0:980

When we calculate the ampli�cation ratio between the baseline CES case andthe model with markup elasticity of � = 4 for all values of �z, several interestingresults emerge: (i) the contribution of variable markups are larger on averagefor 67-Sector economy than their in�uence on counterfactual 1-Sector economyand (ii) more surprisingly, the contribution of variable markups in terms ofincreasing the RER persistence is decreasing in �z for 1-Sector economy andincreasing in �z for 67-Sector economy (Figure 6).

Figure 6. Ratio of Half-Lives of Multisector Model and 1-SectorModel18

(CRS, Variable Markups, � = 4)

0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.81.5

2

2.5

Ratio

 of H

alf 

Liv

es

ρz

6.a. 1­Sector Economy

0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.81.65

1.7

1.75

1.8

1.85

1.9

1.95

2

Ratio

 of H

alf 

Liv

es

ρz

6.b. Multisector Model

18Here, we divide half life when � = 4 by that when � = 0 (CES) for all levels of �z .

36

Page 37: PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with Variable Markups "Field Paper Requirement for International Economics

Despite the failure of variable markups channel of real rigidities in generatinga realistic level of aggregate RER persistence at �z = 0:35, the model withvariable markups is still a better replication of data on RER dynamics. Forinstance, when �z = 0:8 as before and markup elasticity � is set to 1:5 as inGopinath and Itskhoki (2010a), the half life generated by the 67-Sector economyincreases from 40 months to 57 months, still remaining within the realistic limitsin data. Furthermore, upper life and quarter life increase to 36 and 80 months,which are clearly more consistent with data than the our baseline CES model.Thus, we can say that incorporation of variable markups to the baseline modelis better in explaining the aggregate RER dynamics.

Going to back to our main motivation, which is to reduce the required levelof aggregate persistence to generate reasonable RER dynamics, we can still seethat variable markups makes an improvement in this aspect. When we target36 months half life and calculate �z that generates this, we can see that therequired aggregate persistence declines from 0:77 in baseline model with CESdemand to 0:67 for the variable markup model where markup elasticity is set to1:5 (Table 4).The required level of aggregate persistence declines even furtherto 0:55 and 0:43 when � = 4 and � = 10 respectively.

Table 4. Required Aggregate Persistence19

(CRS)� = 0 � = 1 � = 1:5 � = 4 � = 10(CES)

Required �z 0:77 0:69 0:66 0:55 0:43

Summary of �ndings:

(i) The e¤ect of heterogeneity in frequency of price adjustment on the aggre-gate RER persistence is remarkably large. The heterogenous multisector modelampli�es the aggregate RER persistence compared to a counterfactual 1-Sectoreconomy. This is true regardless of the level of aggregate persistence. However,the ampli�cation of RER persistence is higher for the large degrees of nominalaggregate demand persistence.(ii) Con�rming Nakamura and Steinsson (2010), if one sector economy is

calibrated to have frequency of price adjustment of the median (rather thanthe weighted average) of the multisector model, the RER persistence improvesconsiderably. However, di¤erent from Nakamura and Steinsson (2010), it stilldoes signi�cantly worse than the multisector model in terms of matching RERdata.(iii) Introducing variable markups through Kimball (1995) demand adds one

other channel of persistence since �rms will be less willing to change their prices,

19Here, aggregate persistence level �z required to generate half life of 36 month is calculatedfor various levels of markup elasticity �.

37

Page 38: PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with Variable Markups "Field Paper Requirement for International Economics

unless their opponents do so. Hence, the aggregate RER persistence is larger ina model with variable markups than a model with constant markups.(iv) The ampli�cation e¤ect of variable markups remains very modest when

the markup elasticity is set at an empirically supported level. The absolutee¤ect of variable markups gets less signi�cant as exogenous nominal aggregatedemand persistence gets smaller.(v) Some degree of aggregate demand persistence is required for explaining

the RER dynamics realistically. Our model is capable of generating RER persis-tence consistent with the empirically found degree only when markup elasticityis set at implausibly high levels (which corresponds to unrealistically high levelsof superelasticity and thus, too large convexity of demand function).(vi) Despite its inability to fully reconcile the dynamics of nominal and real

exchange rates, the model with variable markups with a markup elasticity setat empirically supported levels closes some of the gap between theory and data.Hence, we can say that the model with variable markups is more successfulin explaining the RER dynamics than our baseline model with CES demandsince it relies on a smaller level of aggregate persistence. Furthermore, thismodel generates measures that are more consistent with RER dynamics in data,compared to the model with constant markups.(vii) All these show that adding variable markups to the baseline model

was a right but insu¢ cient direction of research. Thus, other sources of realrigidities to increase endogenous persistence should be sought. At this point,the �rst candidate would be introducing sector speci�c capital. However, in arecent ongoing paper, Carvalho and Nechio (2012) nest sector speci�c capitalto their model and surprisingly �nd that even though incorporating capital intothe baseline model increases RER persistence, making it sector speci�c reducesthe RER persistence. Similarly, in an extension to their model, Kehoe andMidrigan (2007) change their basic setup and allow the intermediate �rms touse the intermediate goods as inputs. They also �nd that this form of realrigidity does not increase the RER persistence.

DRS Calibration:

We repeat the same analysis for the calibration of Carvalho and Nechio(2011) in order to compare our results with their prediction about incorpora-tion of real rigidities based on their numerical exercise.20 Figure 7 shows thatthe e¤ect of variable markups are even less signi�cant than under our CRS cal-ibration.21 Especially, when markup elasticity is set at empirically supported

20Remember that � = 2=3, = 1 and � = 3 in their baseline model.21Remember that both CRS and DRS cases generate RER persistence at around same

levels under the constant markup case. However, when variable markups are introduced, twomodels di¤er signi�cantly. As explained in Section 3, when markup elasticity � increases,�rms will be less willing to raise their price since the higher their relative price, the lower thedemand will be. This corresponds to "wage e¤ect" as termed by Chari, Kehoe and McGrattan(2000) and it is common for both CRS and DRS cases. On the other hand, when there isdecreasing returns to scale, there also exists a second channel: "output e¤ect", which inducesthe monopolist to raise the price as explained in Section 3. When markup elasticity increases,

38

Page 39: PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with Variable Markups "Field Paper Requirement for International Economics

levels such as 1 and 1:5, the increase in half lives are negligibly small, rangingonly between 0 and 2 months for the 1-Sector economy and between 1 and 8months for the multisector economy.22

Figure 7. Half-Life as a Function of Aggregate Persistenceand Markup Elasticity

(DRS and Variable Markups)

0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.80

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

Half L

ives in M

onth

s

ρz

7.a 1­Sector Economy

Γ=0 (CES)Γ=1Γ=1.5Γ=4Γ=10

0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.80

20

40

60

80

1007.b. Multi Sector Economy

Half 

Liv

es in

 Month

s

ρz

Γ=0 (CES)Γ=1Γ=1.5Γ=4Γ=10

Why are our �ndings signi�cantly di¤erent from the predictions of Carvalhoand Nechio (2011)? First of all, in their analysis to predict the e¤ects of intro-ducing real rigidities, they set the elasticities of substitution across varieties andsectors at unrealistically large levels: � = 30 and � = 30. More important thanthis, they change their calibration from the baseline and set = 0 (linear utilityin labor) and � = 1. However, comparing the results from this alternative pa-rameterization to the results from baseline calibration is fallacious. The modelalready generates higher RER persistence with this calibration (a half life of 67months rather than 39 months in baseline calibration) and hence the results arenot comparable. Indeed, they overstate the likely e¤ects of real rigidities by notreporting the RER dynamics of this alternative calibration when � = 10 and� = 1 as in the baseline. Figure 8 shows that the improvement due to addingvariable markups would "seem" larger if we had used their alternative calibra-tion and compared it to our baseline calibration. Indeed, even when � = 1:5,the multisector model23 is able to replicate the RER dynamics at our targetedaggregate persistence: �z = 0:35, without the need of increasing the elasticitiesof substitution to unrealistically high levels as Carvalho and Nechio (2011) did.Hence, our results are not actually contradicting, but clarifying the �ndings andpredictions from Carvalho and Nechio (2011).

the output e¤ect becomes larger. This is what di¤erentiates CRS and DRS cases. They bothare a¤ected the same by the wage e¤ect, while income e¤ect reverses some of the wage a¤ectunder DRS.22 In this graph, we employed 3-Sector approximating economy, which is already shown to

be a reasonable approximation of the 67-Sectors economy.23Here, again, 3-Sector approximation economy is used.

39

Page 40: PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with Variable Markups "Field Paper Requirement for International Economics

Figure 8. Half-Life as a Function of Aggregate Persistenceand Markup Elasticity

(DRS, Alternative Calibration)

0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.80

20

40

60

80

100

120

140

160

Hal

f Liv

es in

 Mon

ths

ρz

1­Sec, Γ=0 (CES), χ=2/3, γ=1, σ=3M­Sec, Γ=0 (CES), χ=2/3, γ=1, σ=3M­Sec, Γ=1.5, χ=2/3, γ=0, σ=1

6 CONCLUSION

In this paper, we aimed at explaining the PPP puzzle by introducing the vari-able markup channel of real rigidities into a multisector, sticky price model withheterogeneity in frequency of price adjustment and local currency pricing. Tobe more speci�c, we tried to generate realistic aggregate RER persistence, whilekeeping the degree of nominal aggregate demand persistence at levels consis-tent with nominal exchange rate dynamics and all other model parameters atplausible levels. To isolate and analyze the e¤ects of variable markups, we com-pared the �ndings from two models: we had CES aggregation with no strategiccomplementarities that resulted in constant markups. Later, we added a secondchannel of price rigidity through variable markups generated by a non-CES de-mand function a la Kimball (1995), which further reduced the incentive of �rmsto reset their prices unless their opponents do the same.

Our baseline �ndings mainly con�rm those of Carvalho and Nechio (2011).We found that the e¤ect of heterogeneity in explaining the PPP puzzle is remark-able. Regardless of the level of aggregate nominal persistence, the aggregateRER persistence is ampli�ed by heterogeneity in frequency of price adjustment,compared to the counterfactual one sector economy. In the baseline, when thenominal aggregate persistence is set to �z = 0:8, the model generates a halflife of 40 months in response to a nominal shock, which is within the empiricalevidence. The other measures of persistence are also reasonably close to data.Nonetheless, even the multisector heterogeneous economy is unable to gener-ate realistic RER dynamics when the nominal aggregate persistence is set to

40

Page 41: PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with Variable Markups "Field Paper Requirement for International Economics

�z = 0:35- a level consistent with the dynamic properties of nominal exchangerates.

There is no doubt that introduction of the variable markups ampli�es theaggregate RER persistence at all nominal aggregate demand persistence levels.Especially, when �z is kept at 0:8, the persistence measures get more consistentwith data, even with empirically documented levels of a markup elasticity of1:5. Also, the required level of nominal aggregate persistence to obtain a real-istic level of RER persistence decreases when variable markups are introduced.Hence, the model with variable markups is superior to the baseline model withconstant markups in explaining the RER dynamics.

Nevertheless, the model with variable markups is incapable of producingpersistence measures consistent with data either, when �z = 0:35, despite theimprovement achieved compared to the model with constant markups. Theonly way to reconcile the RER dynamics of our model with dynamics of nom-inal exchange rates is to set the markup elasticity over 10 (or equivalently setthe superelasticity over 90). However, this implies a very large curvature of de-mand function and this is not empirically plausible. The improvement made byvariable markups gets even smaller in magnitude once we switch to the baselinecalibration of Carvalho and Nechio (2011), with DRS production technology.The reasons behind this are explained in detail in the previous sections.

Overall, our results with variable markups are more consistent with Kehoeand Midrigan (2007) and several other studies, while they seem to con�ict withthose of Carvalho and Nechio (2011). However, we showed that this seeminglycon�icting results are due to di¤erent calibration and unrealistic elasticities ofsubstitution used by Carvalho and Nechio (2011) to predict the likely e¤ectsof incorporating real rigidities. Finally, we also showed that 67-sector economycan be approximated by a 3-sector representative economy that is calibratedto match the �rst and second moments of frequency of price adjustment andaverage duration of spell.

In summary, we can say that model with variable markups is better in ex-plaining the RER dynamics compared to the baseline model, hence it shouldbe preferred. However, we should also look for other forms of real rigidities.At this point, the �rst candidate would be introducing sector speci�c capital asit is common in the literature. However, in a recent ongoing paper, Carvalhoand Nechio (2012) nested sector speci�c capital to their model and surprisinglyfound that even though incorporating capital into the baseline model increasesRER persistence, making it sector speci�c reduces the half life obtained. In anextension to their model, Kehoe and Midrigan (2007) change their basic setupand allows the intermediate �rms to use intermediate goods as input to produc-tion. They also �nd that this channel of real rigidities cannot increase the RERpersistence. Therefore, we should seek other sources of real rigidities, which willnot require a high degree of nominal aggregate persistence to replicate RER

41

Page 42: PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with Variable Markups "Field Paper Requirement for International Economics

dynamics. Apart from real rigidities, one other research topic might be to esti-mate the markup elasticity for each of those 67 sectors used in this paper andsee if this additional heterogeneity improves the results.

42

Page 43: PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with Variable Markups "Field Paper Requirement for International Economics

REFERENCES:

� Arkolakis, Costas, A. Costinot and A. Rodriguez-Clare, 2012.�New Trade Models, Same Old Gains?,�American Economic Review, Vol.102, Issue 1, pp. 94-130, February.

� Arkolakis, Costas, A. Costinot, D. Donaldson and A. Rodriguez-Clare, 2012. "The Elusive Pro-Competitive E¤ects of Trade," Unpub-lished draft, March.

� Atkeson, Andrew and A. Burstein, 2008. �Pricing-to-Market, TradeCosts, and International Relative Prices,� American Economic Review,Vol. 98, Issue 5, pp. 1998�2031, December.

� Bergin, Paul R. and R. C. Feenstra, 2009. "Pass-Through of Ex-change Rates and Competition between Floaters and Fixers," Journal ofMoney, Credit and Banking, Blackwell Publishing, Vol. 41, Issue 1, pp.35-70, February.

� Bilbiie, Florin O., F. Ghironi and M. J. Melitz, 2012. "Endoge-nous Entry, Product Variety, and Business Cycles," Journal of PoliticalEconomy, Vol. 120, Issue 2, pp. 304-345, April.

� Bouakez, Hafedh, 2005. "Nominal rigidity, desired markup variations,and real exchange rate persistence," Journal of International Economics,Elsevier, Vol. 66, Issue 1, pp. 49-74, May.

� Burstein, Ariel, and C. Hellwig, 2007. �Prices and Market Shares ina Menu Cost Model,�UCLA Working Paper, September.

� Calvo, Guillermo A., 1983. �Staggered Prices in a Utility-MaximizingFramework,� Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 12, Issue 3, pp. 383�98.

� Carvalho, Carlos and F. Nechio, 2011. "Aggregation and the PPPPuzzle in a Sticky-Price Model," American Economic Review, AmericanEconomic Association, Vol. 101, Issue 6, pp. 2391-2424, October.

� Carvalho, Carlos and F. Nechio, 2012. "Real Exchange Rate Dynam-ics in Sticky-Price Models with Capital," Federal Reserve Bank of SanFrancisco Working Paper Series, Working Paper 2012-08, July.

� Chari, V. V., P. J. Kehoe, and E. R. McGrattan, 2000. "StickyPrice Models of the Business Cycle: Can the Contract Multiplier Solvethe Persistence Problem?," Econometrica, Econometric Society, Vol. 68,Issue 5, pp. 1151-1180, September.

� Chari, V. V., P. J. Kehoe, and E. R. McGrattan, 2002. �Can StickyPrice Models Generate Volatile and Persistent Real Exchange Rates?,�Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 69, Issue 3. pp. 533�63.

43

Page 44: PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with Variable Markups "Field Paper Requirement for International Economics

� Chen, Shiu-Sheng, and C. Engel, 2005. �Does �Aggregation Bias�Explain the PPP Puzzle?,�Paci�c Economic Review, Vol. 10, Issue 1, pp.49�72.

� Crucini, Mario J., and M. Shintani, 2008. �Persistence in Law ofOne Price Deviations: Evidence from Micro-Data,� Journal of MonetaryEconomics, Vol. 55, Issue 3, pp. 629�44.

� Dixit, Avinash K. and J. E. Stiglitz, 1977. "Monopolistic Competi-tion and Optimum Product Diversity," American Economic Review, Vol.67, pp. 298-308.

� Eichenbaum, Martin and J. D. M. Fisher, 2004. "Evaluating theCalvo Model of Sticky Prices," NBER Working Paper 10617.

� Feenstra, Robert C., 2003. "A homothetic utility function for monop-olistic competition models, without constant price elasticity," EconomicsLetters, Elsevier, Vol. 78, Issue 1, pp. 79-86, January.

� Feenstra, Robert C. and D. E. Weinstein, 2010. "Globalization,Markups, and the U.S. Price Level," NBER Working Papers 15749, Na-tional Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.

� Gopinath Gita and O. Itskhoki, 2010a. "In Search of Real Rigidities,"Working Papers 10-9, Federal Reserve Bank of Boston.

� Gopinath Gita and O. Itskhoki, 2010b. "Frequency of Price Ad-justment and Pass-Through," The Quarterly Journal of Economics, MITPress, Vol. 125, Issue 2, pp. 675-727, May.

� Imbs, Jean, H. Mumtaz, M. O. Ravn, and H. Rey, 2005. �PPPStrikes Back: Aggregation and the Real Exchange Rate,�Quarterly Jour-nal of Economics, Vol. 120, Issue 1, pp. 1�43.

� Kehoe, Patrick J., and V. Midrigan, 2007. �Sticky Prices and Sec-toral Real Exchange Rates,� Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, Work-ing Paper 656, October.

� Kimball, Miles, 1995. "The Quantitative Analytics of the Basic Neomon-etarist Model," Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 27, Issue 4,pp.1241-1277, November.

� Klenow, Peter J., and J. L. Willis, 2006. �Real Rigidities and Nom-inal Price Changes,� Stanford University Working Paper.

� Mankiw, N. Gregory and R. Reis, 2002. �Sticky Information versusSticky Prices: A Proposal to Replace the New Keynesian Phillips Curve,�Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 117, Issue 4, pp. 1295-1328.

44

Page 45: PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with Variable Markups "Field Paper Requirement for International Economics

� Mussa, Michael,1986. �Nominal Exchange Rate Regimes and the Be-havior of Real Exchange Rates: Evidence and Implications,� Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 25, pp. 117�213.

� Nakamura, Emi, and J. Steinsson, 2008. �Five Facts About Prices:A Reevaluation of Menu Cost Models,�Quarterly Journal of Economics,Vol. 123, Issue 4, pp. 1415�64.

� Nakamura, Emi, and J. Steinsson, 2008. �Five Facts About Prices:A Reevaluation of Menu Cost Models: Dataset,�Quarterly Journal of Eco-nomics, http://www.columbia.edu/~en2198/papers/�vefactsELITable.pdf.

� Nakamura, Emi, and J. Steinsson, 2010. �Monetary Non-Neutralityin a Multisector Menu Cost Model,� Quarterly Journal of Economics,Vol. 125, Issue 3, pp. 961-1013, August.

� Rogo¤, Kenneth, 1996. �The Purchasing Power Parity Puzzle,� Jour-nal of Economic Literature Vol. 34, pp. 647-668.

� Smets, Frank and R. Wouters, 2007. "Shocks and Frictions in USBusiness Cycles: A Bayesian DSGE Approach," European Central BankWorking Paper Series, No 722, February.

� Steinsson, Jon, 2008. �The Dynamic Behavior of the Real ExchangeRate in Sticky Price Models,�American Economic Review, Vol. 98, Issue1, pp. 519�33, March.

� Taylor, Alan M. and M. P. Taylor, 2004. �The Purchasing PowerParity Debate,� Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 18, Issue 4, pp.135�58.

� Woodford, Michael, 2003. "Interest and Prices: Foundations of a The-ory of Monetary Policy," Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

� Woodford, Michael, 2005. "Firm-Speci�c Capital and the New Keyne-sian Phillips Curve," International Journal of Central Banking, Vol. 1,Issue 2, September.

45

Page 46: PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with Variable Markups "Field Paper Requirement for International Economics

APPENDIX A:24

Linearized System of Equations

The system is linearized around a symmetric steady state with zero in�ationrate. At this steady state equilibrium, RER is set to 1 due to the commonpreferences assumption. Furthermore, the stochastic discount factor Qt;t+s isset equal to discount factor �s, while all the prices have a steady value of 1.The latter is due to the symmetry of the countries, which result in equal pricesof all intermediate �rms, levels of employment, and allocations of consumption,imports, and exports for both countries in the steady state. Remember that,all the small case letters refer to log-deviations from the steady state.

Household�s Problem:From the problem of the households we have equations (3), (6) and (10),

which de�ne real wages and real exchange rate:

wt � pt = �ct + lt

w�t � p�t = �c�t + l�t

qt = �(ct � c�t )

Price Equations:25

pt =KXk=1

fkpk;t

p�t =KXk=1

fkp�k;t

pk;t = !pH;k;t + (1� !)pF;k;tp�k;t = (1� !)p�H;k;t + !p�F;k;t

pH;k;t = �kxH;k;t + (1� �k)pH;k;t�1pF;k;t = �kxF;k;t + (1� �k)pF;k;t�1p�H;k;t = �kx

�H;k;t + (1� �k)p�H;k;t�1

p�F;k;t = �kx�F;k;t + (1� �k)p�F;k;t�1

24This appendix mainly follows from appendix of Carvalho and Nechio (2011).25The linearization of these equations are pretty standard and hence the details are skipped

here.

46

Page 47: PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with Variable Markups "Field Paper Requirement for International Economics

We also de�ne domestic price indices for home and foreign produced goodsthat are sold in home country (and same for foreign country):

pH;t =KXk=1

fkpH;k;t

pF;t =KXk=1

fkpF;k;t

p�H;t =KXk=1

fkp�H;k;t

p�F;t =KXk=1

fkp�F;k;t

Output level equations:Output of each individual �rm (variety):

yH;k;j;t+s = yt+s � �[xH;k;j;t � pH;k;t+s]� �[pH;k;t+s � pk;t+s]� �[pk;t+s � pt+s]yF;k;j;t+s = yt+s � �[xF;k;j;t � pF;k;t+s]� �[pF;k;t+s � pk;t+s]� �[pk;t+s � pt+s]y�H;k;j;t+s = y�t+s � �[x�H;k;j;t � p�H;k;t+s]� �[p�H;k;t+s � p�k;t+s]� �[p�k;t � p�t+s]y�F;k;j;t+s = y�t+s � �[x�F;k;j;t � p�F;k;t+s]� �[p�F;k;t+s � p�k;t+s]� �[p�k;t � p�t+s]

with the assumption that �rms keep the same price at time t until they havethe chance of resetting their price at time t+ s.

Foreign and domestic sectoral outputs:

yH;k;t = yt+s � �[pH;k;t � pk;t]� �[pk;t � pt]yF;k;t = yt � �[pF;k;t � pk;t]� �[pk;t � pt]y�H;k;t = y�t � �[p�H;k;t � p�k;t]� �[p�k;t � p�t ]y�F;k;t = y�t � �[p�F;k;t � p�k;t]� �[p�k;t � p�t ]

yk;t = !yH;k;t + (1� !)yF;k;ty�k;t = (1� !)y�H;k;t + !y�F;k;t

47

Page 48: PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with Variable Markups "Field Paper Requirement for International Economics

Final output:

yt =KXk=1

fkyk;t

y�t =KXk=1

fky�k;t

We also de�ne GDP as follows:

gdpt = yt + (1� !)KXk=1

fk(y�H;k;t � yF;k;t)

When we plug y�H;k;t and yF;k;t from above, in the end we obtain:

gdpt = yt + (1� !)[y�t � yt � �KXk=1

fk[(p�H;k;t;�p�t )� (pF;k;t � pt)]]

Analogously:

gdp�t = yt � (1� !)[y�t � yt � �KXk=1

fk[(p�H;k;t;�p�t )� (pF;k;t � pt)]]

Price setting equations:Log-linearization of the equations (32)-(35) around the steady state is stan-

dard in the literature. In the end, a price resetting �rm takes all the futurenominal marginal costs into account when deciding its new prices:

48

Page 49: PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with Variable Markups "Field Paper Requirement for International Economics

xH;k;t = (1� �(1� �k))Et1Xj=0

�j(1� �k)j(pt+j +mck;t+j)

xH;k;t = (1� �(1� �k))(pt +mck;t)

+�(1� �k)(1� �(1� �k))Et1Xj=0

�j(1� �k)j(pt+1+j +mck;t+1+j)

xH;k;t = (1� �(1� �k))(pt +mck;t) + �(1� �k)EtxH;k;t+1

Similarly, by the same steps:

xF;k;t = (1� �(1� �k))(pt + qt +mc�k;t) + �(1� �k)EtxF;k;t+1x�H;k;t = (1� �(1� �k))(p�t � qt +mck;t) + �(1� �k)Etx�H;k;t+1x�F;k;t = (1� �(1� �k))(p�t +mc�k;t) + �(1� �k)Etx�F;k;t+1

where real marginal costs are de�ned as:

mck;j;t = wt � pt + (1� �)lk;j;tmc�k;j;t = w�t � p�t + (1� �)l�k;j;t

Production technology for intermediate �rms:

!yH;k;j;t + (1� !)�yH;k;j;t = �lk;j;t

(1� !)yF;k;j;t + !�yF;k;j;t = �l�k;j;t

Market clearing conditions:

![yt � �(pH;t � pt)] + (1� !)[y�t � �(p�H;t � p�t )] = �lt

(1� !)[yt � �(pF;t � pt)] + ![y�t � �(p�F;t � p�t )] = �l�t

49

Page 50: PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with Variable Markups "Field Paper Requirement for International Economics

KXk=1

fk

1Zlk;j;tdj = lt

0

KXk=1

fk

1Zl�k;j;tdj = l

�t

0

ct = yt

c�t = y�t

Aggregate nominal demand:

zt = pt + yt

z�t = p�t + y�t

50

Page 51: PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with Variable Markups "Field Paper Requirement for International Economics

APPENDIX B:Additional Figures and Tables

Table B.1. RER Persistence Under the Speci�cation of Carvalhoand Nechio (2011)

(DRS: � = 2=3, � = 3, �z = 0:8)Data 1-Sector 1-Sector 67-Sector

(Mean) (Median)hL 36� 60 14 27 39uL 28 9 19 23qL 76 18 35 57CIR � 20:4 49:5 67:2�1 � 0:969 0:988 0:990

Figure B.1. IRFs of Aggregate RERto 1 Standard Deviation Shock to Nominal Aggregate Demand

(DRS: � = 2=3, � = 3, �z = 0:8)

0 10 20 30 40 50 600

0.002

0.004

0.006

0.008

0.01

Months

RE

R

1­Sector3­Sector Approx.67­Sector

Table B.2. RER Persistence Under Lower Exogenous Persistence(DRS: � = 2=3, � = 3, �z = 0:35)

51

Page 52: PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with ... · PPP Puzzle in a Heterogenous Sticky Price Model with Variable Markups "Field Paper Requirement for International Economics

Data 1-Sector 67-Sector(Mean)

hL 36� 60 5 9uL 28 1 2qL 76 8 19CIR � 6:2 16:9�1 � 0:871 0:948

Figure B.2. Half-Life as a Function of Aggregate Persistence(DRS: � = 2=3, � = 3, �z = 0:35)

0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.80

20

40

60

80

Hal

f Life

 in M

onth

s

ρz

1­Sector3­Sector Approx.67­Sector

Figure B.3. Ratio of Half-Lives of Multisector Model and 1-SectorModel

(DRS: � = 2=3, � = 3, �z = 0:35)

0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.81

1.5

2

2.5

3

Rat

io o

f Hal

f Liv

es

ρz

52