Pomfret (2009)_Regional Integration in Central Asia

download Pomfret (2009)_Regional Integration in Central Asia

of 22

Transcript of Pomfret (2009)_Regional Integration in Central Asia

  • 8/17/2019 Pomfret (2009)_Regional Integration in Central Asia

    1/22

    Regional integration in Central Asia

    Richard Pomfret

    Published online: 12 October 2008  Springer Science+Business Media, LLC. 2008

    Abstract   This paper analyses the interaction of regionalism and multilateralism in

    the five Central Asian countries’ trade policies. The basic question is why have

    leaders been willing to sign so many regional agreements, which often include

    visions of regional trading arrangements (RTAs), and yet so unwilling to implement

    any preferential trading arrangements? The paper examines the durability of mul-

    tilateralism and the added incentives for joining the World Trade Organization in

    light of China’s WTO accession in 2001 and Russia’s expected accession. The finalsection draws together arguments for multi-dimensional (bilateral, plurilateral, and

    regional) regional cooperation within a WTO framework.

    Keywords   Central Asia    Regional integration    Multilateralism

    The trade policy experience of the five Central Asian countries since they became

    independent at the end of 1991 has been a microcosm of trends in international trade

    policy. Many regional and bilateral trade agreements have been signed, often at thehighest political level, since 1991. The rhetoric of these agreements has envisioned

    recreating the economic space (but not the economic system) part of the Soviet

    Union or establishing a customs union on the European Union model or establishing

    a free trade area, but their striking feature is the general lack of progress in

    establishing or implementing preferential trade policies. Despite their presidents’

    espousal of regionalism, in practice the Central Asian countries have in their trade

    policies largely followed the path of policy autonomy combined with non-

    Paper presented at the Conference on ‘‘The Political Economy of Regional Economic Integration: TheChallenges for the Emerging Economies’’, held in Ravenna, Italy, 18–19 November 2005. Parts of this

    paper draw on background papers which I prepared for UNDP (2005) and ADB (2006).

    R. Pomfret (&)School of Economics, University of Adelaide, Adelaide, SA 5005, Australia

    e-mail: [email protected]

     1 3

    Econ Change Restruct (2009) 42:47–68DOI 10.1007/s10644-008-9060-6

  • 8/17/2019 Pomfret (2009)_Regional Integration in Central Asia

    2/22

    discriminatory multilateralism. Their actual trade patterns have become much more

    diversified since independence, with greater integration into global rather than

    regional markets. Nevertheless, the governments have been cautious about

    accession to the World Trade Organization and so far only one of the five countries

    has become a WTO member.This paper analyses the interaction of regionalism and multilateralism in the trade

    policies of the Central Asian countries and their neighbors. The opening section

    provides a brief economic survey of the five countries. The second section assesses

    regional economic agreements involving the Central Asian countries; the common

    question running through these assessments is why have the Central Asian leaders

    been willing to sign so many regional agreements, which often include visions of 

    regional trading arrangements (RTAs), and yet so unwilling to implement any

    preferential trading arrangements? Section 3  examines the durability of multilat-

    eralism and the added incentives for joining the World Trade Organization in lightof China’s WTO accession in 2001 and Russia’s expected accession. The fourth

    section analyses the political economy of the choice between regionalism and

    multilateralism, and sets out the distinction between regional trading arrangements

    and regional cooperation in trade, and why the latter is a desirable concomitant of 

    WTO membership. The final section draws together the arguments for multi-

    dimensional (bilateral, plurilateral, and regional) regional cooperation within a

    WTO framework and offers some conclusions.

    1 Background1

    The five Central Asian countries became independent with the dissolution of the

    Soviet Union at the end of 1991. Their role in the Soviet economy had been

    primarily as producers of raw materials, mainly cotton, minerals, oil, and natural

    gas. The four southern republics had, together with Azerbaijan, been the poorest

    republics in the Soviet Union, while Kazakhstan had higher incomes and a more

    diversified economy. In the early 1990s all five countries suffered substantial

    economic decline following the end of central planning, the breakdown of economic

    links within the former Soviet Union, and hyperinflation. The five countries’

    economies began to grow after the mid-1990s and by 2005 they had essentially

    completed the transition from central planning, although the timing and the type of 

    market-based economy varies substantially from country to country.

    During the 1990s Uzbekistan, which pursued a gradual reform strategy, was the

    most economically successful of all former Soviet republics, but a tightening of 

    economic controls after 1996 hurt long-term growth and its economic performance

    has been less positive since the turn of the century. Turkmenistan has an even more

    repressed economy with highly limited economic freedom, but the regime has been

    able to survive thanks to large rents from natural gas. The most liberal economy in

    the region is that of the Kyrgyz Republic, but economic performance has been

    stymied by lack of natural resources, poor transport links, and poor institutional

    1 This highly condensed account is based on my two books on Central Asia (Pomfret  1995, 2006).

    48 Econ Change Restruct (2009) 42:47–68

     1 3

  • 8/17/2019 Pomfret (2009)_Regional Integration in Central Asia

    3/22

    development. Tajikistan’s history has been dominated by a bitter civil war which

    lasted until 1997, and which effectively swept away the old economic structure; like

    the Kyrgyz Republic it is resource-poor and with a difficult location for accessing

    world markets. Kazakhstan has pursued more liberal polices than Uzbekistan, but

    the privatization process in the 1990s was characterized by large-scale corruption;the country’s economic performance has been a tale in two acts with disappointing

    results until 1998, and an oil-fuelled boom since 1998 which made it the richest and

    fastest growing economy in the region.

    Table 1 provides summary statistics on the five countries’ economies. Uzbekistan

    and Kazakhstan are the two leading regional powers, the former with the largest

    population and the latter with the highest GDP. The data from Turkmenistan are the

    most suspect and few observers would accept that the reported per capita GDP

    figures reflect true living standards in the country, especially in rural areas which

    have experienced serious economic and environmental problems. The KyrgyzRepublic and Tajikistan have become impoverished, with Tajikistan now ranking

    among the least-developed countries in the world. All five countries have

    maintained the relatively high social indicators of the Soviet Union, with life

    expectancies of 66–70 years and almost universal literacy, although there are

    concerns about declining educational and health standards.

    In all five countries the leaders from the Soviet era repositioned themselves as

    national leaders, and in all but Tajikistan the President in the early 2000s was the

    first secretary appointed by Gorbachev in the final phase of the USSR. All of 

    these leaders established systems which gave power to the president, and limitedthe role of the legislature. In Tajikistan the situation was confused by the civil

    war, but by the mid-1990s the President was establishing a super-presidential

    system similar to that in the other Central Asian countries. In spring 2005 this

    uniformity began to crack, as the Kyrgyz President fled the country, although it is

    unclear whether his successor will, despite asserted commitments to greater

    democracy and transparency, establish a less centralized system. In May 2005

    protests in Andijan were violently suppressed by the Uzbek government,

    signaling its President’s willingness to use force to retain power. At the time

    of writing a question mark hangs over the political future of Kazakhstan whose

    Table 1   Economic and social indicators, 2002

    Population(Millions)

    Life expectancyat birth (years)

    GDP(BillionUS dollars)

    GDP per cap(US dollars)

    GDP per cap@ PPP(Internationaldollars)

    Kazakhstan 15.5 66 24.6 1,656 5,870

    Kyrgyz Rep 5.1 68 1.6 320 1,620

    Tajikistan 6.2 69 1.2 193 980

    Turkmenistan 4.8 67 7.7 1,601 4,300

    Uzbekistan 25.7 70 7.9 314 1,670

    Source: UNDP Human Development Report 2004—online statistical database at   http://hdr.undp.org/statistics

    Econ Change Restruct (2009) 42:47–68 49

     1 3

    http://hdr.undp.org/statisticshttp://hdr.undp.org/statisticshttp://hdr.undp.org/statisticshttp://hdr.undp.org/statistics

  • 8/17/2019 Pomfret (2009)_Regional Integration in Central Asia

    4/22

    President is less likely to allow a peaceful revolution than his Kyrgyz counterpart

    was, but he is also unlikely to be as ruthlessly repressive as his Uzbek 

    counterpart. In Turkmenistan the political future is highly uncertain because the

    regime is highly personalized with no obvious successor when the President

    becomes incapacitated or dies.When the five Central Asian countries became independent, they had open

    economies measured by the ratio of exports and imports to GDP, but their trade

    was geographically heavily concentrated, with 85–90% involving partners from

    the former Soviet Union. Both trade and GDP were adversely affected by the

    negative shocks of the early 1990s, but trade flows began to recover in the mid-

    1990s and in the process became substantially more diversified, with over half of 

    the five countries’ international trade being outside the CIS after 1996. By the

    early twenty-first century, all five countries were substantially involved in the

    global economy, almost entirely as raw material exporters. Export/GDP ratiosestimated by World Bank staff with 2000 data were: Kazakhstan 59%, Kyrgyz

    Republic 42%, Tajikistan 81%, Turkmenistan 63%, and Uzbekistan 25% (World

    Bank   2004, p. 9).2

    The trade policies of the five countries have generally been liberal, with low

    average tariffs (Table 2) and without great tariff variance. This has not always

    been true, as countries have levied high duties in reaction to external shocks

    (e.g., Kazakhstan’s response to the 1998 Russian Crisis) or to protect specific

    producers (e.g., the UzDaewoo car factory), and liberal trade policies have been

    nullified by exchange controls introduced in Uzbekistan in 1996 (but loosened

    since 2003) and Turkmenistan in 1998. Nevertheless, as might be expected of 

    export-oriented economies, the general picture is of tariff barriers which are not

    especially high and which are collected on a multilateral rather than preferential

    basis.3

    Table 2   Average import tariff, 2002 (%)

    Kazakhstan 7.9

    Kyrgyz Republic 5.2

    Tajikistan 8.3

    Turkmenistan 0.5

    Uzbekistan 19.0

    Source: IMF data reported in World Bank (2004, Table 3.2)

    2 Especially for Turkmenistan and Uzbekistan whose forex markets were tightly controlled suchcomparisons are subject to caveats about data and the appropriate exchange rate. For Kazakhstan and

    Turkmenistan the high export/GDP ratios are driven by energy exports, while for the Kyrgyz Republicand Tajikistan they reflect a low denominator. Uzbekistan’s relatively low ratio hides its dependence on

    cotton, of which Uzbekistan is in most years the world’s fourth largest exporter.3 Especially in the early years after independence, borders within the former Soviet Union were looselymonitored and customs duties were rarely collected on goods crossing these borders. Collection wastightened in the late 1990s and early 2000s, although some differential treatment for intra-CIS trade mayhave remained as a result of still-porous borders with corrupt officials or of the agreements described in

    the next section.

    50 Econ Change Restruct (2009) 42:47–68

     1 3

  • 8/17/2019 Pomfret (2009)_Regional Integration in Central Asia

    5/22

    2 Regional trading arrangements in Central Asia

    The Central Asian countries are involved in several regional organizations, some of 

    which seek to create a regional trading arrangement, as well as having signed

    numerous bilateral trade agreements. This section analyses the evolution and current

    activities of the various organizations and arrangements.4 Most have at some time

    envisaged preferential trade policies—variously described as free trade areas,

    customs unions, common markets, or a common economic space. These self-

    descriptions do not always follow the normal usage, and it is better to examine the

    specific content of each arrangement.

    The membership of the various regional organizations in 2005 is summarized in

    Table 3. The bilateral trade agreements are even harder to track, and the list of such

    agreements with the date of signing in Table 4 is both too long, because some of the

    agreements have not been implemented, and probably too short, because some

    agreements may have been omitted. These often overlapping agreements, to the

    extent that they envisage preferential treatment of regional or bilateral trade, exhibit

    a spaghetti bowl effect.5

    Table 3   Membership in regional organizations

    CIS EAEC UES CACO SPECA ECO SCO CAREC

    Azerbaijan   9 9 9

    China   9 9

    Kazakhstan   9 9 9 9 9 9 9 9

    Kyrgyz Rep   9 9 9 9 9 9 9

    Mongolia   9

    Tajikistan   9 9 9 9 9 9 9

    Turkmenistan   9 9 9

    Uzbekistan   9 9 9 9 9 9

    Russia   9 9 9 9 9

    Iran   9

    Pakistan   9

    Turkey   9

    Afghanistan   9

    Armenia   9

    Belarus   9 9 9

    Georgia   9

    Moldova   9

    Ukraine   9 9

     Note: See text for details

    4 This section summarizes material in Pomfret (2003) and Sect.  4  of Pomfret (2005a), which provide

    more details on the historical evolution of the various organizations.5 The term spaghetti bowl effect originated from Jagdish Bhagwati, and for Central Asia the effect is

    illustrated in UNDP (2005, Fig. 2.1).

    Econ Change Restruct (2009) 42:47–68 51

     1 3

  • 8/17/2019 Pomfret (2009)_Regional Integration in Central Asia

    6/22

    The five Central Asian countries are all members of the Commonwealth of 

    Independent States (CIS), which was initially conceived as a framework in which to

    maintain economic ties among the Soviet successor states. In both the political and

    the economic spheres, however, the replacement of the Soviet Union by sovereign

    nations created conflicts that the CIS framework was unable to contain. The CIS has

    made no progress in introducing special treatment for trade among members,

    although some members’ trade and tax policies continue to favor CIS partners.

    In December 1994, Kazakhstan announced the formation of a customs union with

    Russia and Belarus, which came into effect in 1995. The Kyrgyz Republic acceded

    in 1996 and Tajikistan in 1999 making it a Union of Five. Despite the formal

    agreements between 1994 and 2000, there was little evidence of implementation bythe Central Asian countries, and members’ actual policies were going in

    contradictory directions. For example, the tariff bindings which the Kyrgyz

    Republic agreed to in the negotiations leading to its 1998 WTO accession would for

    Russia or Belarus be unacceptably low as part of the custom union’s common

    external trade policy, and for similar reasons President Nazarbayev indicated in

    September 1996 that Kazakhstan would leave the customs union when it acceded to

    the WTO (Webber 1997, p. 56).6

    In October 2000 the Union of Five was renamed the Eurasian Economic

    Community (EAEC) and a new treaty was signed in Astana, which came into effectin May 2001. Although the institutional framework was strengthened in a bid to

    ensure better implementation, the functional areas of the EAEC differ little from

    those agreed within the earlier frameworks, with emphasis on free intra-community

    trade and a common external tariff as well as a common market for labor and

    capital, common policies towards migration, and more general policy harmoniza-

    tion. A specific intention was to coordinate WTO accession negotiations, but even

    this attempt at a common external trade policy is dubious given that the Kyrgyz

    Table 4   Bilateral free trade agreements involving Central Asian republics and other CIS members

    Kazakhstan Kyrgyz Rep Tajikistan Turkmenistan Uzbekistan

    Armenia 1994

    Azerbaijan 1997 2004 1996 1996

    Belarus 1998 1993

    Georgia 1999 1996 1995

    Moldova 1995 1995 1993 1995

    Russia 1992 1993 1992

    Ukraine 1998 1994

    Source: Tumbarello (2005, Table 1)

    6 In 1996 Kazakhstan’s WTO accession seemed more imminent than proved the case. For both theKyrgyz Republic and Kazakhstan, harmonizing their tariffs with Russia’s would bring no benefits, andwould lead to trade diversion and trade destruction; (a) Russian goods would have a larger preferencemargin, encouraging greater replacement of imports from the least-cost supplier by more costly Russiangoods, and (b) higher external tariffs would encourage displacement of some imports by inefficient

    domestic producers.

    52 Econ Change Restruct (2009) 42:47–68

     1 3

  • 8/17/2019 Pomfret (2009)_Regional Integration in Central Asia

    7/22

    Republic is already a WTO member and that Belarus appears to have differing

    WTO goals than Russia.

    The EAEC was from its 1995 origins explicitly aimed at being a customs union.

    A formal agreement on the common external tariff (CET) for the customs union,

    signed in February 2000, envisaged a CET consisting of tariff lines that werecommon to Belarus, Kazakhstan and Russia with the remaining tariff lines to be set

    at a subsequent stage. The implementation period was 5 years, but by 2005 the CET

    covered only 6,156 of the 11,086 tariff lines identified in the Union’s classification

    system. The remaining tariffs are set independently by each member. Although

    substantial harmonization of external tariffs is often reported, this applies to non-

    contentious tariff lines; for example, the Kyrgyz Republic still has to align a third of 

    its tariff lines, and these are presumably the ones where the costs of change are seen

    to be highest.

    An alternative grouping among CIS countries emerged in February 2003 whenthe leaders of Russia, Belarus, Ukraine and Kazakhstan reached a tentative

    agreement to create a United Economic Space (UES). Russia promoted the concept,

    but the other three countries have to varying degrees bridled at suggestions of 

    establishing supranational institutions and of adopting the Russian ruble as a

    common currency. The outcome of the December 2004 Ukraine election makes

    cooperation even less likely.7

    After the collapse of the ruble zone in November 1993, the presidents of 

    Kazakhstan, the Kyrgyz Republic and Uzbekistan agreed to create the Central Asian

    Economic Union, announced in the Tashkent Declaration of January 1994 andformalized in the Cholpon-Ata Treaty signed by the heads of state in April 1994.

    Intended to be modeled on the European Union, this organization evolved into the

    Central Asian Economic Community (CAEC), when Tajikistan joined in 1998.

    Apart from the activity of the now effectively defunct Interstate Central Asian Bank 

    of Cooperation and Development, the CAEC had little in the way of practical

    achievements.8 Officials claimed to have made contributions in tax harmonization

    and elimination of double taxation, but these are difficult to document, and the

    CAEC had little impact on intra-regional trade. By some counts, at the CAEC

    meetings the Central Asian leaders passed over 250 resolutions, but the implemen-

    tation record fell far behind the statements of intentions.

    In February 2002 the four Presidents proclaimed the Central Asian Cooper-

    ation Organization (CACO) as the successor to the CAEC. They attempted to

    7 Although Ukrainian President Yushchenko attended the August 2005 UES summit (held in conjunctionwith the CIS summit), he was only willing to sign 15 of the 29 agreements signed by the other three UESmembers and made it clear that any economic cooperation within the UES was subordinate to the largeraim of pursuing EU membership. Earlier in the same month the presidents of Ukraine and Georgia

    announced a plan to create a Commonwealth of Democratic Choice, which was supported by Poland andLithuania, but not by Russia.8 The Interstate Central Asian Bank of Cooperation and Development was created in June 1994, but byJanuary 1997 the participating countries had given the Bank only some two-thirds of its charter capital,and it was clearly incapable of drawing substantial external funds into Central Asia for investment incollaborative projects. Borrowers in Uzbekistan were effectively excluded after the introduction inOctober 1996 of strict exchange controls, because the Bank made hard currency loans and required

    repayment in hard currency.

    Econ Change Restruct (2009) 42:47–68 53

     1 3

  • 8/17/2019 Pomfret (2009)_Regional Integration in Central Asia

    8/22

    distinguish the CACO from its predecessor by emphasizing improved effective-

    ness, but the founding agreement of the CACO continued to make lofty

    aspirations without paying much concern to institutionalizing implementation.

    The CACO summit in Dushanbe in October 2002 was combined with the

    meeting of the four heads of state of the International fund to save the Aral Sea,and a regional business forum held its first session in November 2002 in

    Tashkent, but after this initial flurry of activity the CACO seemed little different

    from its predecessor. In May 2004 Russia became a CACO member, but this was

    a sign of Uzbekistan-Russian rapprochement rather than a strengthening of the

    CACO. The logical next step was for Uzbekistan to join the EAEC, or

    equivalently, as announced at the CACO summit in Saint Petersburg in October

    2005, for CACO and the EAEC to merge.

    The newly independent Central Asian countries, Azerbaijan and Afghanistan

     joined the Economic Cooperation Organization (ECO) in 1992.9

    ECO aspires tobe a RTA, and the three founding ECO members (Iran, Pakistan, and Turkey)

    offer preferential tariff treatment to one another. However, the list of eligible

    products for preferential tariff treatment is extremely restricted, and, although the

    Central Asian countries have expressed commitment to ECO principles, they

    have not accepted even the limited preferential trading arrangements agreed

    among the three founding members. Trade between the Central Asian countries

    and their southern neighbors has expanded since 1992, but from a low base and

    more slowly than many observers expected. Moreover, it has done so on a non-

    discriminatory MFN basis rather than within an RTA such as the ECO foundingmembers envisaged in the early 1990s. In 1996 the Council of Ministers

    approved the establishment of a permanent ECO Secretariat in Tehran, but this

    was a highpoint for ECO at which subsequent summits broke down in acrimony.

    As with the CAEC/CACO, the practical impact of ECO has been limited. In both

    organizations a fundamental obstacle to regional integration is the similarity of 

    the member countries’ economies, which all tend to be specialized on a small

    group of primary products (oil, gas, minerals, and cotton).

    The Special Programme for the Economies of Central Asia (SPECA) was

    launched in 1998 as a forum for regional cooperation, and differs from the

    EAEC, CACO or ECO insofar as it has no intention of promoting preferential

    regional trade.10 The main purpose of SPECA is to support the Central Asian

    countries in strengthening their cooperation in order to both stimulate their

    economic development and facilitate their integration with the economies of Asia

    and Europe. Although SPECA could have become an institutional framework for

    trade cooperation, its achievements have been minimal. In part, this is because it

    has no self-funding mechanism, but the lack of achievement also reflects

    incomplete participation; Uzbekistan and Turkmenistan have not attended the

    9 The history and evolution of ECO are analyzed in Pomfret (1999).10 With the support of the United Nations Economic and Social Commission for Asia and the Pacific andthe United Nations Economic Commission for Europe, the presidents of Kazakhstan, the KyrgyzRepublic, Tajikistan and Uzbekistan signed the Tashkent Declaration on 26 March 1998 creating SPECA,and in September 1998 Turkmenistan officially indicated its intention to sign the Declaration and to

    participate in SPECA projects.

    54 Econ Change Restruct (2009) 42:47–68

     1 3

  • 8/17/2019 Pomfret (2009)_Regional Integration in Central Asia

    9/22

    meetings of the Regional Advisory Committee, the governing body of SPECA

    which is responsible for strategic decisions, and as SPECA became closely

    associated with the EAEC’s members it became divisive rather than uniting for

    the Central Asian region as a whole. The existence of SPECA is symptomatic of 

    the proliferation of institutions in Central Asia; if, for example, the CAEC/CACOhad been an effective regional organization, there would have been little need for

    SPECA.

    Another institutional vehicle for regional cooperation is the Central Asia

    Regional Economic Cooperation (CAREC) program, an initiative to encourage

    economic cooperation in transport, energy, trade policy, and trade facilitation

    between Azerbaijan, Kazakhstan, the Kyrgyz Republic, Mongolia, Tajikistan,

    Uzbekistan, and Xinjiang autonomous region of China.11 Despite slow progress

    since its launch in 1997, CAREC has some achievements in coordinating transport

    and trade facilitation among the member states. The IMF has led support for theoperations of the CAREC trade policy coordinating committee, which was

    established in September 2004 and which may signal a willingness to take definite

    steps on trade facilitation (including cooperation on transport and on transit), where

    the greatest gains from regional cooperation lie in the short-run. Expansion of 

    CAREC to include Afghanistan and Russia will increase its coverage in

    geographically relevant directions, although it may dilute the decision-making

    ability of CAREC.

    Another overlapping configuration, dubbed the Shanghai Five, emerged from a

    meeting in 1996 of China, Russia, Kazakhstan, the Kyrgyz Republic, andTajikistan intended to demilitarize borders. At a summit in Dushanbe in July

    2000, the Shanghai Five, with Uzbekistan as an observer, took up a number of 

    economic issues, and the group changed their name to the Shanghai Forum. At the

    June 2001 summit Uzbekistan became the sixth member and the group was

    renamed the Shanghai Cooperation Organization (SCO). At the 2004 summit

    Mongolia was admitted as an observer. After the June 2004 SCO summit,

    Uzbekistan and Russia signed a strategic partnership agreement and China

    announced plans to extend $900 million in loans and credits to Central Asian

    countries. There has, however, been no move towards creating preferential trading

    among SCO members.

    The regional arrangements described in this section have often been in

    implicit competition, reflecting differing and mutually exclusive political pacts,

    and such ebbing and flowing of interest in alternative regional permutations has

    inhibited the institutional development of any regional organization involving

    the Central Asian countries. The main caveat to this generalization is that intra-

    CIS trade tends to be freer than trade with non-CIS countries, and the internal

    free trade regime is especially true with respect to trade among EAEC

    11 CAREC is, like SPECA, supported by an alliance of multilateral institutions led by the AsianDevelopment Bank, and also including the United Nations Development Program, the European Bank forReconstruction and Development, the International Monetary Fund, the Islamic Development Bank andthe World Bank. In June 2005 consideration was being given by CAREC members to invite the RussianFederation and Afghanistan to participate as new members. Turkmenistan has been invited but has so far

    refused to participate.

    Econ Change Restruct (2009) 42:47–68 55

     1 3

  • 8/17/2019 Pomfret (2009)_Regional Integration in Central Asia

    10/22

    members,12 but progress towards proposed customs unions has been slow overthe past decade.13 Otherwise, steps to make preferential trade policies

    mandatory or to harmonize external trade policies have been practically

    fruitless, and none has posed a threat to multilateralism in the Central Asian

    countries’ trade policies. The economic impact of all of the manifold regional

    agreements signed by Central Asian countries since 1991 has been minimal.

    3 Multilateralism and the World Trade Organization

    Membership in the World Trade Organization (WTO) is a natural institutional

    counterpart to economic openness. In the 1990s, however, the Central Asian

    countries (apart from the Kyrgyz Republic) were suspicious of international

    obligations which placed constraints on their policy autonomy. They were happy to

     join the United Nations as a signal of nationhood, and to join the International

    Monetary Fund and World Bank and the regional development banks as potential

    sources of capital, but they held back on WTO accession. For Turkmenistan, this

    attitude remains even in 2005, as the President views WTO membership as

    incompatible with the country’s neutrality.With low average tariffs, the main obstacle to WTO membership has been

    governments’ unwillingness to formally abjure their policy independence, and right

    to impose temporary tariffs or artificial non-tariff barriers. So far, only the Kyrgyz

    Republic has joined the WTO (Table 5). Kazakhstan’s application is fairly far-

    advanced, with an active program of Working Party meetings in recent years. The

    accession process of Uzbekistan and Tajikistan is at an earlier stage than

    Table 5   Status of WTO accession negotiations to mid-2005

    Applied Working parties Member

    Kazakhstan January 1996 7 meetings 1997–2004

    Kyrgyz Rep. 1993 DeD December 1998

    Tajikistan May 2001 1 meeting, March 2004

    Uzbekistan December 1994 2 meetings, July 2002 & June 2004

    Turkmenistan Not applied

    China 1986 December 2001

    Russian Fed. June 1993 28 meetings, 1995–2005

    Source: WTO website

    12 There have been exceptions when trade barriers have been imposed at internal CIS borders, but some

    of these measures have been temporary.13 Tajikistan did increase some tariffs in 2004 in order to give itself more leeway in negotiating WTOaccession without committing to bound tariff levels which would be unacceptable to Russia as a commonexternal tariff for the customs union. As mentioned above, however, there is a strong economicdisincentive for the smaller economies to accept a Russian-devised tariff which would discourage their

    citizens from buying imports from the most competitive source.

    56 Econ Change Restruct (2009) 42:47–68

     1 3

  • 8/17/2019 Pomfret (2009)_Regional Integration in Central Asia

    11/22

    Kazakhstan’s, although for all three countries the process has speeded up since

    2002.14

    WTO membership brings both costs and benefits, although the costs are often

    misinterpreted. The Kyrgyz Republic’s WTO accession was followed by recession,

    which critics of the WTO ascribe to the onerous obligations of WTO membership,but this confuses before/after and with/without comparison. The Kyrgyz post-WTO

    troubles arose because non-WTO factors (such as the Russian Crisis, Kazakhstan’s

    50% devaluation, and the collapse of three of the country’s four largest banks)

    dominated any positive WTO effect. The WTO is no panacea, and for the Kyrgyz

    Republic the positive effect of accession was weak because transport and transit

    conditions stymied Kyrgyz trade.

    A more robust criticism of the Kyrgyz Republic’s accession experience is that the

    negotiators, whether due to inexperience or by intent, failed to make transitional

    arrangements or gain exemptions that would have protected Kyrgyz interests. Somelearning process is reflected in Kazakhstan’s lengthier and more detailed WTO

    negotiations, and harder stance on some of the voluntary codes. The appropriate

    negotiating balance must reflect a country’s preferences and compliance capabil-

    ities; immediate compliance may be problematic and a phasing-in period desirable.

    Nevertheless, even this criticism lacks much force, because WTO-based restrictions

    on trade practices are largely what a small open economy should be doing in its own

    interests, and WTO members retain flexibility over applied tariffs as long as they are

    below the bound level.

    The more substantial costs of WTO accession are in building institutionsto ensure compliance with the various WTO codes, even though bilateral and

    multilateral donors can assist with this institution-building. Many of these non-core

    elements of the WTO are, like the commitments to non-discriminatory trade policies

    and not to increase bound tariffs, in the interest of the acceding country, but the

    introduction, implementation, and enforcement costs may outweigh the benefits for

    a poor country.15 One lesson learned from the Kyrgyz Republic’s brief accession

    negotiations is the desirability of being selective in entering into non-core

    commitments.

    14 The timing and number of Working Party meetings provides a reasonable but imperfect guide to theprogress of accession negotiations. Uzbekistan’s Working Party did not meet 1994–2002 because little orno progress was being made during that period. A large economy or a more complex case will requiremore Working Party meetings than simpler or less contentious cases. The 28 meetings of Russia’sWorking Party reflect more progress than in the case of Uzbekistan, but also the complexity of Russiannegotiations and the relative importance of the Russian economy, so that existing WTO membersscrutinize Russia’s offers more carefully than the offers of, say, the Kyrgyz Republic or Kazakhstan.15 An oft-cited example is the cost to Cambodia of adopting and implementing legislation consistent withthe Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS) code, which was signed as part of 

    Cambodia’s 2004 WTO accession. Despite external assistance in training officials and the private sectorin anticipation of TRIPS enforcement, the government still spent much legislative time drafting laws, andlawyers, judges, law enforcement and customs officials were taken away from other duties to be trained inTRIPS compliance. Given the low probability of Cambodia producing intellectual property that canbenefit from TRIPS protection, the net benefit from all of these activities is unlikely to have outweighedthe opportunity cost of scarce human capital. For more detailed treatment of these compliance costs,

    including a box on Cambodia’s experience, see Hoekman and Bernard (2005).

    Econ Change Restruct (2009) 42:47–68 57

     1 3

  • 8/17/2019 Pomfret (2009)_Regional Integration in Central Asia

    12/22

    The most important benefit of WTO membership is to place trade on a common

    basis of international trade law, and potentially to separate trade from politics.

    Accession by more Central Asian countries would provide a common framework 

    for formal trade policies and dispute resolution with respect both to a greater

    proportion of intra-regional trade and to trade with all of the region’seconomically important neighbors. The WTO rules also impose some consistency

    on customs and border practices which will help to facilitate trade within the

    region. The benefits to Central Asian countries from WTO membership have been

    accentuated by China’s accession in 2001 and will be further reinforced by

    Russia’s imminent accession.16 Pakistan and Turkey have long been WTO

    signatories, and Iran’s WTO accession is also on the horizon after a March 2005

    announcement by the USA that it would not oppose an application. There are

    important network benefits from WTO rules. When Mongolia and the Kyrgyz

    Republic joined the WTO in 1997 and 1998, the benefits were limited becausetheir neighbors were not members. Chinese accession in December 2001 and the

    imminent Russian accession dramatically transform the situation. The benefits of 

    common rules are greater as more people play by them.

    The importance of a common and enforceable institutional framework is

    illustrated by the Kyrgyz Republic’s experience. The Kyrgyz Republic has formal

    free trade agreements with all CIS members except Georgia, and yet Kyrgyz trade

    with partners covered by these bilateral agreements has been subject to many

    restrictions whether as emergency reactions to the 1998 Crisis in Kazakhstan, or

    Uzbekistan’s attempts to discourage shuttle traders by tariff increases, or byarbitrary anti-dumping duties imposed by CIS trading partners. Most of these

    measures would be illegal under WTO rules, but the Kyrgyz Republic has been

    unable to do much about the restrictions and WTO membership offers little

    protection as long as most of its CIS partners are not bound by WTO

    membership. While WTO accession would limit the ability of countries to

    suddenly increase their own tariffs, the benefits from guarantees against partners

    doing the same thing is more valuable and increasingly so as more neighbors

    accede to the WTO.

    A basic explanation of the disappointing trade performance of the Central Asian

    countries is the poor institutional environment. WTO membership could alleviate

    this major obstacle to trade by providing the framework in which regional and wider

    trade can flourish. Trade is difficult if players play by different rules, and the WTO

    provides a set of rules to ensure that one country isn’t playing soccer rules while

    another plays hockey rules. Access to the strengthened dispute resolution process of 

    the WTO is an important benefit for smaller trading nations, who have a credible

    recourse against large countries which bend the rules.17

    16 The Russian Federation, at the 27th session of its Working Party on 13 and 15 April 2005, completedbilateral negotiations on goods with 29 WTO members (the EU counting as one), who account for 87% of total Russian imports.17 The lack of dispute resolution or enforcement mechanisms has often been a weakness of RTAs, so thatfor the Central Asian countries common WTO membership is likely to provide superior recourse against

    large neighbors’ RTA- or WTO-illegal trade measures than membership in an RTA would.

    58 Econ Change Restruct (2009) 42:47–68

     1 3

  • 8/17/2019 Pomfret (2009)_Regional Integration in Central Asia

    13/22

    WTO accession could bring further benefits by encouraging liberal policies and

    punishing backsliding on commitments. At a minimum, WTO membership ensures

    that tariff rates are bound, but as members sign on to more codes of behavior there is

    a greater legal commitment to policy stability, and WTO dispute settlement

    mechanisms offer some recourse for people damaged by unforeseen policy changes.Such an environment helps to attract foreign direct investment, as well as making

    domestic investment more attractive.

    With a positive domestic environment, WTO membership helps to ensure that a

    country can reap benefits from specialization and trade with diminished fear of 

    protectionist responses in foreign markets. Small trading nations have always been

    open to unilateral restrictions on their exports to larger trading nations, but one of 

    the major developments in the WTO, as opposed to the pre-1995 situation, is that

    the dispute settlement mechanism provides a more credible means of redress. Less

    powerful trading nations have won cases against the major trading nations, and the judgments have been implemented by the latter. Of particular interest to Central

    Asian countries is the October 2004 WTO ruling in support of Brazil’s complaint

    against US subsidies for cotton production; although the USA is drawing out the

    year-long appeal process, there is a time limit to this and little doubt that the

    eventual outcome will be some reduction in support for US cotton producers.

    Finally, WTO membership would grant some leverage to reduce existing illiberal

    polices. Most immediately, Uzbekistan and Tajikistan would want to join WTO

    member countries lobbying for reduced subsidies to cotton producers in the USA

    and EU.

    18

    Four West African countries have had success in publicizing the harmfulimpact of these subsidies on some poor countries’ export earnings, and they

    formally introduced the Cotton Initiative into the Doha Development Agenda in

    April 2003. Central Asian cotton-producing nations would broaden the coalition and

    highlight the iniquity of subsidizing rich country farmers to the detriment of poor

    farmers in areas with a comparative advantage in growing cotton. More generally, a

    feature of the WTO negotiating process, especially since the September 2003

    Cancun ministerial meetings, has been the formation of various groupings of 

    countries to lobby on particular issues. The Central Asian countries may want to

     join the group of 19 developing and emerging economies pressuring for changes to

    WTO rules on agriculture, or conceivably in future Kazakhstan might want to join a

    group lobbying against EU and US iron and steel policies, or Azerbaijan and

    Kazakhstan might be interested in an energy-related trade group.

    There is symmetry in the analysis of regional trading arrangements and WTO

    membership as routes to realizing greater gains from trade. Regionalism may appear

    attractive, but on deeper investigation using preferential tariffs to encourage imports

    from a neighbor who is not the least-cost producer of a good has economic costs.

    Multilateralism formalized by WTO membership may look like an unattractive

    restriction on policy autonomy, but on deeper investigation it provides the best

    18 Removing subsidies to US and EU cotton producers would lead to a higher world price for cotton.Pomfret (2005c), using World Bank data, estimates that in Uzbekistan, Turkmenistan and Tajikistan GDP

    per annum would be 3–6% larger in the absence of the EU and US subsidies.

    Econ Change Restruct (2009) 42:47–68 59

     1 3

  • 8/17/2019 Pomfret (2009)_Regional Integration in Central Asia

    14/22

    framework within which the Central Asian countries can develop their international

    economic relations.

    4 The political economy of regional trading arrangements versus regionalcooperation

    Despite the lengthy history of non-achievement by RTAs signed since 1992,

    proposals for regional trading arrangements continue unabated, whether in the form

    of a free trade area, a customs union, or deeper economic union. At the eighth ECO

    summit in Dushanbe in September 2004, Iran proposed committing to an ECO free

    trade zone by 2015. Also in 2004 President Karimov of Uzbekistan called for a

    Central Asian customs union, even though it seems implausible that Uzbekistan

    would accept the Kyrgyz tariff as the common external tariff of a customs union,and the Kyrgyz Republic would have to renounce its WTO obligations to raise its

    tariffs in March 2005 Presidents Karimov and Nazarbayev set up a working group

    on the creation of a free trade zone between the two countries.19 What is the

    fascination with RTAs in Central Asia despite their abject record?

    Part of the motivation behind announcements of regional initiatives is political,

    and the various groupings must be viewed in light of individual countries’ political

    objectives. Among the smaller countries, Turkmenistan, with abundant rents from

    natural gas and cotton and with an autocratic leadership, has seen no need to impose

    any limits on its policy independence.

    20

    At the other extreme, the Kyrgyz Republicwith limited natural resources and relatively liberal leadership was most open to the

    suggestions of international institutions that it integrates rapidly into the global

    economy. Tajikistan went through a bitter civil war for most of the 1990s, and the

    leadership is well aware of its debt to Russia for military assistance. The two largest

    countries have had broader visions of their role on the international stage and

    competition for regional leadership has never been far from the surface, but

    Kazakhstan is constrained by the large Russian minority whose location near the

    Russian border poses a constant implicit threat of secession. Thus, Kazakhstan has

    leaned closer to Russia, but both Kazakhstan with its oil and Uzbekistan with cotton

    and gold are open economies supplying global commodity markets in which

    preferential treatment is irrelevant for export promotion and undesirable in

    constraining import choice.

    Superimposed on these more or less structural political considerations have been

    fluctuating international relations objectives. In 1992 and 1993, after the unexpected

    and largely unwanted independence of their countries, the Central Asian presidents

    were concerned with nation-building, cementing their own authority, and

    19 In 2004 there were also proposals for monetary integration. The Chairman of the Kazakhstan central

    bank proposed a common currency for the EAEC and senior Russian political leaders proposed adoptingthe ruble as a common currency for the UES, both aspiring to follow the European Union’s adoption of the euro.20 The centerpiece of Turkmenistan’s diplomacy was obtaining recognition of its neutrality by the UNGeneral Assembly in 1995. The President rarely participated in meetings of regional organizations of 

    which Turkmenistan is a member, e.g., he was a non-attendee at the CIS August 2005 summit in Kazan.

    60 Econ Change Restruct (2009) 42:47–68

     1 3

  • 8/17/2019 Pomfret (2009)_Regional Integration in Central Asia

    15/22

    minimizing, or at least controlling, economic change. They retained the ruble for

    longer than most other former Soviet republics, and they participated in the many

    summits aimed at maintaining the Soviet economic space. As the collapse of the

    ruble zone became inevitable during the second half of 1993, the presidents of 

    Kazakhstan and Uzbekistan made several statements on the need to maintain acommon economic space in Central Asia. After 1994, however, as Uzbekistan

    attempted to assert a stronger leadership role in Central Asia, Kazakhstan’s interest

    in the CAEC waned and interest in a Russian-centered RTA grew.

    The rapid accession to ECO in 1992 reflected a keenness of all of the Central

    Asian leaders to diversify their countries’ direction of trade and to assert their

    solidarity with Islamic neighbors, especially if they supported secular Islam. The

    southern orientation was reinforced by linguistic and cultural ties between Tajiks

    and Iran and between the other four countries and Turkey, but the willingness of the

    three ECO founders to provide practical assistance to the new ECO members fellshort of the Central Asian countries’ expectations. In 1995 and 1996 Uzbekistan,

    partly responding to Kazakhstan’s pro-Russia shift, moved closer to the USA. This

    undermined relations with Iran, and the 1996 ECO summit ended early amid

    acrimonious insults between Iran and Uzbekistan. Within the CIS a split deepened

    between the Union of Five members (Russia, Belarus, Kazakhstan, the Kyrgyz

    Republic, and Tajikistan) and the GUUAM (Georgia, Ukraine, Uzbekistan,

    Azerbaijan, and Moldova) group, and the fault line ran down the middle of Central

    Asia.21

    The role of the USA in the region grew in the early 2000s, as the USA establishedbases in Uzbekistan and the Kyrgyz Republic for military operations in Afghanistan.

    This development was viewed with suspicion by other regional powers, but Russia

    and China at least initially were constrained to pay lip-service to a common cause

    against terrorism. China had been shifting away from support for the USA during

    the late 1990s.22 This was reflected in China’s participation in the predecessors to

    the SCO; China’s first real experiment with regional arrangements. In the 1990s and

    early 2000s China obtained little response from the Central Asian countries, who

    harbored lingering suspicions of their large neighbor’s territorial ambitions and fear

    of Chinese immigration.23 After the 2003 invasion of Iraq, however, the welcome

    for US troops in Central Asia began to be reassessed. A greater emphasis on the

    SCO, especially by Uzbekistan, reflected growing concerns about the reliability of 

    21 Turkmenistan remained ostentatiously neutral. Armenia, in a cold war state with Azerbaijan, waseffectively in the Russian-led camp, although the diaspora kept Armenia’s profile positive in the USA.Uzbekistan formally joined the four GUAM countries in 1999, effectively withdrew from the alliance in

    2002, and withdrew  de jure  in May 2005.22 China had been a strong supporter of the US-led multilateralist response to the 1997 Asian Crisis, but

    by the turn of the century it was cooperating with Japan in building regional monetary institutions such asthe Chiang Mai Initiative (Pomfret 2005b). The US bombing of the Chinese embassy in Belgrade appears

    to have been a catalyst.23 The xenophobic fears of the 1990s reflected the isolation of Soviet Central Asia and inheritedterritorial claims by China. By the end of the decade Kazakhstan, the Kyrgyz Republic and Tajikistan hadall reached border delimitation agreements with China, and were ready for normal relations. ForUzbekistan the presence of China as a counterweight to Russia made the SCO acceptable at a time (1999–

    2002) when Uzbekistan was a member of the anti-Russian GUUAM group.

    Econ Change Restruct (2009) 42:47–68 61

     1 3

  • 8/17/2019 Pomfret (2009)_Regional Integration in Central Asia

    16/22

    the USA. Although the economic motives for closer ties with China and Russia had

    not changed, the political motives became stronger as Uzbekistan recognized

    kindred spirits in the Chinese and Russian leaderships’ attitude towards democracy

    and civil rights.

    The relative position of the USA, China, and Russia was highlighted after theMarch revolution in the Kyrgyz Republic and the Andijan events of May 2005. US

    calls for an independent inquiry into the deaths at Andijan were met by an Uzbek 

    demand that the US base in Uzbekistan be vacated within 6 months. On 5th July the

    SCO requested the USA to set a deadline for the withdrawal of US military

    personnel from Central Asia. The Russian foreign minister meanwhile justified his

    country’s complaisance with the Uzbek regime by saying that ‘‘Uzbekistan is not a

    CSTO member, and we do not interfere in the internal affairs of other countries’’.24

    A China Foreign Ministry spokesman said ‘‘About what happened in Uzbekistan

    recently, we think it’s their internal affair, but we strongly support the governmentcrackdown on separatists, terrorists and extremists’’.25

    The apparent shift towards China and Russia was, however, incomplete, as the

    Kyrgyz Republic, despite the SCO policy, renewed the US lease on an airbase near

    Bishkek. When US secretary of state Condoleezza Rice visited Central Asia in

    October 2005, she visited Kazakhstan, the Kyrgyz Republic, and Tajikistan, while

    pointedly avoiding the formerly strongest US ally in the region, Uzbekistan.

    Superficially at least, there had been a reversal of alliances as the three countries

    formerly closest to Russia now tilted towards the USA, and the two most repressive

    regimes shifted towards Russia.26

    The speed with which political alignments have changed in Central Asia since

    1991 helps to explain the ephemeral nature of the many regional arrangements. For

    the presidents, treaties of friendship and economic cooperation are cheap ways of 

    signaling political alignments. From a Soviet culture which paid little respect to

    economic contracts, there was most likely little expectation that these agreements

    would ever be implemented in their economic details. That was, however, not the

    Table 6   Welfare effects of implementing the eurasian economic community customs union (million USdollars)

    Kazakhstan Kyrgyz Republic

    Change in tariff revenue   ?223.4   ?22.8Change in consumer surplus   -255.2   -26.3

    Net welfare effect   -31.8   -3.5

    Source: Tumbarello (2005, Table 4)

    24 Quoted in ‘‘The Geopolitical Balance in Central Asia tilts towards Russia’’, posted 6 July 2005 at

    www.eurasiant.org. The Collective Security Treaty Organization (CSTO) includes the members of theEurasian Economic Community and is headed by a Russian ex-general.25 Quoted in ‘‘International Pressure on Tashkent mounts over Andijon’’, posted 1 October 2005 at

    www.eurasiant.org.26 Turkmenistan had begun to deviate from its strict neutrality, bordering on political isolationism, by

    seeking Russian economic assistance.

    62 Econ Change Restruct (2009) 42:47–68

     1 3

    http://www.eurasiant.org/http://www.eurasiant.org/http://www.eurasiant.org/http://www.eurasiant.org/

  • 8/17/2019 Pomfret (2009)_Regional Integration in Central Asia

    17/22

    point. The political twists and turns work against the establishment of any strong

    regional organization; even the CIS is the subject of continual speculation about its

    imminent death.

    There are also strong economic reasons why the Central Asian countries do not

    implement preferential regional trading arrangements (Pomfret   1997/2001). Theprinciple argument is the likelihood of trade diversion. Preferential duties on

    imports from a neighbor will encourage consumers to purchase some goods which

    appear to be better value than the tariff-inclusive price of lower-cost or higher-

    quality imports. The government of the importing country loses tariff revenue, and

    consumers are worse off than they would be with non-discriminatory tariff 

    reductions. Although the political leaders may not express their concerns in terms

    such as ‘trade diversion’, there is a strong recognition when agreements come down

    to implementation that, while a country may want to expand the market for its own

    sheltered industries, they do not want to give preferential status to their neighbors’manufactured goods.

    The most advanced RTA in the region is the Eurasian Economic Community. For

    both the Kyrgyz Republic and Kazakhstan, harmonizing their tariffs with Russia’s

    higher tariff rates would lead to trade diversion and trade destruction. This comes

    out clearly in the scenarios for EAEC customs union analyzed by Tumbarello

    (2005). Using a simple partial equilibrium model of the response of trade flows to

    changes in tariff rates, she shows that both Kazakhstan and the Kyrgyz Republic

    would receive more tariff revenue as customs union members, but the welfare

    effects would be dominated by the loss of consumer surplus (Table 6). On the otherhand, if the Eurasian Economic Community members were to join the WTO and

    hence bind their tariff rates before implementing the customs union, then the lower

    tariffs would mean that although Kazakhstan would still lose from entering into a

    RTA with Russia and Belarus, the welfare loss to Kazakhstan ($2.4 million) would

    be less than ten percent of that in Table 6.

    Similar quantitative exercises are not available for other RTAs in the region,

    primarily because they are far from realization. Nevertheless, given the similarity of 

    economic structure of the members of ECO or CACO, it is apparent that the

    potential for trade creation is small and the opportunities for trade diversion are

    large. In sum, the potential for RTAs, whether simple preferential tariffs as among

    the three founding ECO members or more ambitious free trade areas or customs

    unions, is limited because they are likely to be economically harmful and there is no

    political will to accept economic costs in the name of creating an economic or

    political union. The prospects for deeper regional integration are likewise limited

    under current circumstances, because no government in the region is ready to accept

    constraints on its policy autonomy in the kind of areas that other deeper regional

    integration schemes have entered such as financial sector regulation, competition

    policy or monetary integration.

    There remains, however, an important role for regional cooperation (UNDP

    2005). Many of the obstacles to trade in Central Asia require regional

    cooperation in order to reduce the costs of trade. Tariffs and traditional non-

    tariff barriers, which are the subject of national policy, are only a small part of 

    the story. Trade facilitation, while more mundane, is an area in which progress

    Econ Change Restruct (2009) 42:47–68 63

     1 3

  • 8/17/2019 Pomfret (2009)_Regional Integration in Central Asia

    18/22

    could be made to reduce foregone opportunities for mutually beneficial trade and

    also to enable landlocked countries to facilitate transit of goods to the wider

    international market. With respect to trade facilitation, transport and transit,

    regional cooperation is complementary to multilateralism in trade and must not

    be confused with regional trading arrangements whose goal is preferential tradepolicies.

    Regional cooperation in areas not covered by the WTO is a complementary

    element of the new institutional environment. The need for regional cooperation

    appears to be recognized by the Central Asian leaders, but they have failed to

    create suitable institutional mechanisms. This is highlighted by the example of 

    the ECO transit agreements, which on paper could have alleviated many of the

    region’s transit problems. Only eight countries signed the 1995 transit trade

    agreement, and the two non-signatories, Afghanistan and Uzbekistan, straddle

    some of the most important routes in the region. The agreement officially enteredinto force in December 1997, but by early 1999 only five national governments

    had ratified the agreement. The modified, and much watered down, 1998 transit

    agreement had, as of mid-2000, only been approved by Azerbaijan and

    Tajikistan, whose geographical position makes them marginal countries to an

    ECO-wide transit arrangement. Many of the free trade agreements among CIS

    members contain provisions on transit which have likewise not been honored.

    The unwillingness of key countries to accept the principle of unhindered passage

    of goods in transit remains a major obstacle to trade in Central Asia.

    Apart from trade issues there is a pressing need for regional cooperation onenvironmental issues, most dramatically the desiccation of the Aral Sea, and

    perhaps on security matters in the face of insurgent threats. In the longer term a

    more formal regional arrangement may be beneficial for some countries in the

    region. Advocates of regional agreements often point to the success of the

    European Union, and call on Central Asian leaders to follow this example. In the

    current Central Asian context, this is a red herring, because the political will is

    less and the economic costs greater. On the political level, the EU has been the

    vehicle for closer political ties, whereas the Central Asian countries have no wish

    to compromise their political autonomy. On the economic level, the least-cost EU

    producer’s price (aside from agriculture) is generally little different from the

    world price, so the costs of trade diversion have been low; among the

    economically similar Central Asian countries the least-cost producer of an

    import-competing good is unlikely to be close to matching the world price, and

    trade diversion costs will be high. In the future, however, if a group of countries

    in the region wish to pursue deeper regional integration, then a formal

    arrangement may be desirable.

    At the same time there are some less powerful pressures working against the

    assertion of policy autonomy in trade matters. Increasing WTO coverage will

    highlight the distinction of non-membership. Turkmenistan is the only country in

    the region not to have applied for WTO membership and, if all other countries

    acceded, this would highlight the unwillingness of Turkmenistan to accept the

    norms of international trade law, exposing producers to specific risks such as sudden

    changes in tariffs on imported inputs or in customs practices and deterring potential

    64 Econ Change Restruct (2009) 42:47–68

     1 3

  • 8/17/2019 Pomfret (2009)_Regional Integration in Central Asia

    19/22

    investors by the general institutional uncertainty. If Uzbekistan or Azerbaijan,

    whose WTO negotiations are proceeding more slowly, were to remain non-members

    as Russia, Kazakhstan, Tajikistan, and Iran became members, then these countries

    would also share the outsider status of Turkmenistan. As mentioned above, there are

    good reasons for taking care over the accession negotiations,27

    but it is alsoimportant to recognize the costs of non-membership and that these costs will

    become more salient as the neighborhood is transformed from a non-WTO to a

    WTO zone.

    5 Conclusions

    It has become commonplace to state that regional or bilateral trading

    arrangements are becoming a major feature of the global trading system. Suchstatements are supported by counting the number of RTAs notified to the WTO,

    which reached at an all-time high in the early 2000s. Crawford and Fiorentino

    (2005) state that ‘‘Between January 2004 and February 2005 alone, 43 RTAs

    have been notified to the WTO, making this the most prolific RTA period in

    recorded history’’. One reason for the rapid increase in the number of RTAs

    during the 1990s was the proliferation of bilateral and plurilateral free trade

    agreements among former Comecon countries, which were a response to regional

    disintegration, rather than a trend towards regionalism. On 1st May 2004 when

    eight eastern European countries joined the EU, the web of bilateral tradingarrangements among the accession countries and of preferential agreements

    between the accession countries and the EU became redundant, although with the

    incorporation of eight more countries into the EU customs union the degree of 

    regionalism was increased. As a result of the EU enlargement in 2004 the

    number of registered RTAs fell from 285 to 229 (World Bank   2005, p. 53n), so

    that allowing for abrogation after the EU enlargement the net change in number

    of RTAs during the period identified by Crawford and Fiorentino as ‘‘the most

    prolific RTA period in recorded history’’ was negative (Pomfret   2007). Some

    RTAs are important, but counting RTAs is nonsense because some arrangements

    are of little importance and some are never implemented. In sum, the economic

    significance of such arrangements (as opposed to the extent to which they

    preoccupy trade negotiators and economic journalists) is not obvious. In contrast,

    it is arguable that, despite the increased attention being paid to regional

    arrangements, the hold of multilateralism is stronger than ever as practically all

    trading nations have now acceded to the WTO, with lower trade barriers and

    stronger trade dispute settlement procedures.

    27 For both Azerbaijan and Uzbekistan some of the major obstacles to concluding the accessionnegotiations are policies which are not in their own national interest, notably the desire to retain throughhigh bound tariff levels the ability to protect inefficient import-competing industries and the desire toexclude structural reforms of subsidized public utilities. More fundamentally, the governments seem toshare, albeit in less extreme form, Turkmenistan’s reluctance to accept the external constraints on policy

    autonomy which are inherent in fuller participation in the global economy.

    Econ Change Restruct (2009) 42:47–68 65

     1 3

  • 8/17/2019 Pomfret (2009)_Regional Integration in Central Asia

    20/22

    The gap between negotiated and actual RTAs is nowhere more apparent than in

    Central Asia.28 The economic reasons for not implementing the many preferential

    trading agreements signed by Central Asian countries since 1992 are powerful. They

    are not a practical approach to realizing the gains from specialization and trade, and

    they would impose substantial trade diversion costs as consumers responding todistorted relative prices would be encouraged to purchase goods from favored

    suppliers who are not the least-cost or best-quality producers. Quantitative estimates

    of a Eurasian Economic Community customs union point to negative net economic

    effects for Kazakhstan and the Kyrgyz Republic. Other putative RTAs are likely to

    have even more strongly negative economic effects for the Central Asian countries,

    especially when they involve competing economies whose exports are concentrated

    in a narrow range of primary products. These are not just abstract exercises; they

    help to explain why the many RTAs which have been signed have not been

    seriously implemented.Why have so many RTAs been signed in Central Asia? In the early 1990s many

    were flailing attempts to limit the impact of huge negative shocks, by preserving

    anachronistic trade flows or by establishing new markets, but RTAs were not an

    effective strategy. By the mid-1990s a more powerful driving force was the use of 

    trade agreements as a foreign policy instrument, especially by the two largest

    countries (Kazakhstan and Uzbekistan). The effectiveness of this policy tool is hard

    for an economist to assess; the RTAs had little economic impact either for good or

    for ill, apart perhaps from distracting the attention of policymakers from multilateral

    trade diplomacy. Whether they achieved political goals of signaling friendship isless clear. Because political allegiances in the region were shifting over the first

    decade and a half after independence, none of the regional agreements led to

    establishment of an effective regional organization in Central Asia.

    The positive feature of the  de facto  multilateralism in trade relations is that the

    region remains well-placed to take advantage of opportunities offered by China’s

    WTO accession and Russia’s imminent accession. Central Asian countries which

    are or become WTO members will benefit from a rule-based environment in their

    trade with all neighboring economies except Afghanistan and Iran. Moreover, WTO

    rules are generally the most desirable trade practices for small open economies. The

    costs in terms of restrictions on import-substitution strategies and other anti-liberal

    trade policies and in terms of reduced potential for political grandstanding via

    economic proposals in regional fora are minor—and indeed the tying of 

    governments’ hands in such activities should benefit the countries’ citizens.

    Additional benefits from WTO membership include a possible reform-reinforcing

    effect, as well as access to the WTO dispute resolution mechanism and the ability to

     join coalitions working towards reducing trade barriers facing important exports.

    Regional cooperation to reduce trade costs is fully compatible with WTO

    membership. To date there is no pre-eminent institutional setting for such

    cooperation in Central Asia; existing organizations have either found it difficult

    28 Because they do not involve WTO members, many of the agreements negotiated by the Central Asiancountries are not notified to the WTO or recorded by the WTO. Thus the count of RTAs on the WTOwebsite, which is used by most authors, is lower than the true number, but the actual significance of RTAs

    is not understated by omitting the Central Asian RTAs.

    66 Econ Change Restruct (2009) 42:47–68

     1 3

  • 8/17/2019 Pomfret (2009)_Regional Integration in Central Asia

    21/22

    to implement agreements, or they do not include all relevant countries. In practice,

    regional cooperation does not require a single institution; sometimes bilateral

    agreements are appropriate (e.g., for coordination of border crossing arrangements),

    while for other purposes a plurilateral agreement may be more appropriate (e.g.,

    transit agreements). Regional regulatory regimes may be harmonized under theGeneral Agreement of Trade and Services (GATS) as more Central Asian countries

    accede to the WTO and GATS is extended. Regional regulatory cooperation is

    desirable in, for example, air transport, which was explicitly taken outside the WTO

    in a Uruguay Round GATS annex; air transport is regionally poorly connected in

    Central Asia (e.g., there are no direct flights between Almaty and Bishkek or

    between Tashkent and Dushanbe) and could benefit from a regional open skies

    agreement similar to the European Civil Aviation Area model which has greatly

    increased the number of point-to-point services and brought down prices.29

    Regional cooperation on environmental issues such as the desiccation of the AralSea is even more desirable, although progress is slow. Deeper integration may be a

    longer term goal for some countries in the region, e.g., some commentators in

    Kazakhstan talk about deepening the EAEC after Russia and Kazakhstan have

     joined the WTO, although this would clearly have a strong political dimension.

    Although the trade policy experience of the five Central Asian countries has been

    a microcosm of trends in international trade policy, with many regional and bilateral

    trade agreements signed, often at the highest political level, since 1991 but with

    limited implementation, there are distinctive features. The Central Asian govern-

    ments faced almost uniquely traumatic shocks, for which they were ill-prepared andwhich they had to deal with in the midst of nation-building from scratch.30

    Policymakers had little experience of market economies and few instruments of 

    foreign policy. In this context, failure to appreciate the full economic impact of 

    trade policy decisions is understandable, while the Soviet experience encouraged

    grandiloquent statements of international amity without seeing any obligation to

    deliver on trade policy commitments. Fifteen years later, such excuses are wearing

    thin, and WTO accession will harden the constraints on seeing RTAs as

    opportunities for cheap talk rather than serious negotiations.

    References

    ADB (2006) Central Asia: increasing gains from trade through regional cooperation in trade policy,transport and customs transit. Asian Development Bank, Manila

    Crawford J-A, Fiorentino R (2005) The changing landscape of regional trade agreements. WTOdiscussion paper No. 8, World Trade Organization, Geneva

    Hoekman B (2005) Making the WTO more supportive of development. Finance and Development,March, 14–18

    29 Such an approach to air transport is advocated by Chorobek Imashev ‘‘Trade Facilitation in CentralAsia: Perspective for Kyrgyz Republic’’ (paper commissioned by the Swiss government and presented at

    an ADB workshop in Almaty on 10–11 June 2005).30 The economic shock was bigger perhaps only in Mongolia, which has bucked the regionalism/ 

    bilateralism trend insofar as it is in the only WTO member with no RTA.

    Econ Change Restruct (2009) 42:47–68 67

     1 3

  • 8/17/2019 Pomfret (2009)_Regional Integration in Central Asia

    22/22

    Pomfret R (1995) The economies of Central Asia. Princeton University Press, PrincetonPomfret R (1997/2001) The economics of regional trading arrangements. Clarendon Press, Oxford

    Paperback edition with new Preface, Oxford University Press, Oxford, 2001Pomfret R (1999) Central Asia turns south? trade relations in transition. Royal Institute of International

    Affairs, The Brookings Institution, London UK, Washington DC

    Pomfret R (2003) Trade and exchange rate policies in formerly centrally planned economies. World Econ26(4):585–612

    Pomfret R (2005a) Trade policies in Central Asia after EU enlargement and before Russian WTOaccession: regionalism and integration into the world economy. Econ Syst 29(1):32–58

    Pomfret R (2005b) Sequencing trade and monetary integration: issues and application to Asia. J AsianEcon 16(1):105–124

    Pomfret R (2005c) Development lessons for Central Asia. In: Fukasaku K, Kawai M, Plummer MG,Trzeciak-Duval A (eds) The impact and coherence of OECD country policies on Asian developingeconomies. Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development, Paris (forthcoming)

    Pomfret R (2006) The Central Asian economies since independence. Princeton University Press,Princeton

    Pomfret R (2007) Is regionalism an increasing feature of the world economy? World Econ 30(6):923–947

    Tumbarello P (2005) Regional integration and WTO accession: which is the right sequencing? Anapplication to the CIS. IMF working paper 05/94, February (summary in IMF Survey 34, 19th

    September 2005, 272–273)UNDP (2005) Central Asia human development report: regional cooperation for human development and

    human security. United Nations Development Programme, Bratislava (forthcoming, December)Webber M (1997) CIS integration trends: Russia and the Former Soviet South. The Royal Institute of 

    International Affairs, The Brookings Institution, London, Washington DCWorld Bank (2004) Trade performance and regional integration of the CIS countries, poverty reduction

    and economic management sector unit, Europe and Central Asia regionWorld Bank (2005) Global Economic Prospects 2005. World Bank, Washington DC

    68 Econ Change Restruct (2009) 42:47–68