Ornstein-Uhlenbeck Processes - Michael...

30
Ornstein-Uhlenbeck Processes Michael Orlitzky Michael Orlitzky Towson University

Transcript of Ornstein-Uhlenbeck Processes - Michael...

  • Ornstein-UhlenbeckProcesses

    Michael Orlitzky

    Michael Orlitzky Towson University

  • Introduction

    Goal. To introduce a new financial dervative.

    • No fun.

    • I’m bad at following directions.

    • The derivatives based on Geometric Brownian Motiondon’t model reality anyway.

    So we’re going to replace the underlying stochastic processinstead.

    Michael Orlitzky Towson University

  • Introduction

    Claim. GBM doesn’t work in real life.

    Proof.Bekaert and Hodrick (1992), Bessembinder and Chan (1992),Breen, Glosten, and Jagannathan (1989), Campbell and Ammer(1993), Campbell and Hamao (1992), Chan (1992), Chen(1991), Chen, Roll, and Ross (1986), Chopra, Lakonishok, andRitter (1992), DeBondt and Thaler (1985), Engle, Lilien, andRobbins (1987), Fama and French (1988a, 1988b, 1990), Ferson(1989, 1990), Ferson, Foerster, and Keim (1993), Ferson andHarvey (1991a, 1991b), Ferson, Kandel, and Stambaugh (1987),Gibbons and Ferson (1985), Harvey (1989), Jegadeesh (1990),Keim and Stambaugh (1986), King (1966), Lehmann (1990), Loand MacKinlay (1988, 1990, 1992), and Poterba and Summers(1988).

    Michael Orlitzky Towson University

  • Wiener Processes

    Definition (Wiener Process). You should know thisalready [1] (Chapter 4).

    Recall two important properties:

    1. W0 = 0.

    2. s < t implies [Wt −Ws] ∼ N[0,√t− s

    ]Note. As the time period t− s approaches infinity, so does thestandard deviation!

    Michael Orlitzky Towson University

  • Wiener Processes

    0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0

    −1.0

    −0.5

    0.5

    1.0

    1.5

    WtWtWtWt

    Michael Orlitzky Towson University

  • Wiener Processes

    What’s wrong here?

    • If you’re unlucky, the Wiener process can go bonkers.

    • When it does, it tends to stay there.

    This doesn’t accurately reflect what happens in real life.

    Michael Orlitzky Towson University

  • Geometric Brownian Motion

    The Black-Scholes model that we’ve been using assumes thatthe stock dynamics follow Geometric Brownian Motion:

    dXt = αXtdt+ σXtdWt

    X0 = x0

    with solution,

    Xt = x0 exp

    {(α− σ

    2

    2

    )t+ σWt

    }

    Since this contains Wt, it inherits all of its problems.

    Michael Orlitzky Towson University

  • Geometric Brownian Motion

    0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0

    0.5

    1.0

    1.5

    2.0

    2.5 α=1σ=1/5

    x0exp{(α−σ2

    2)t+σWt

    }x0exp

    {(α−σ2

    2)t}

    Michael Orlitzky Towson University

  • Ornstein-Uhlenbeck

    Definition (Ornstein-Uhlenbeck Process). TheOrnstein-Uhlenbeck process is a stochastic process withdynamics,

    dUt = θ (µt − Ut) dt+ σdWtU0 = u0

    where Wt is a Wiener process.

    • Can be seen as a modification of a Wiener process.• µt is the mean of the process.• θ is the tendency of the process to return to the mean.

    Michael Orlitzky Towson University

  • Ornstein-Uhlenbeck

    0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0

    0.2

    0.4

    0.6

    0.8

    1.0

    θ=2σ=1/5µ=1dUt=θ(µ−Ut)dt+σdWt

    Michael Orlitzky Towson University

  • Ornstein-Uhlenbeck

    0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0

    0.2

    0.4

    0.6

    0.8

    1.0

    θ=2σ=1/5µ=1/2dUt=θ(µ−Ut)dt+σdWt

    Michael Orlitzky Towson University

  • Ornstein-Uhlenbeck

    0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0

    0.2

    0.4

    0.6

    0.8

    1.0

    θ=10σ=1/5µ=1/2dUt=θ(µ−Ut)dt+σdWt

    Michael Orlitzky Towson University

  • Ornstein-Uhlenbeck

    Theorem. When µ is a constant, the solution to theOrnstein-Uhlenbeck SDE is given by,

    Ut = µ[1− e−θt

    ]+ x0e

    −θt + σN [0, ξ]

    where,

    ξ =

    √1

    2θ[1− e−2θt]

    Michael Orlitzky Towson University

  • Ornstein-Uhlenbeck

    Proof.

    • Look up the solution on Wikipedia.• Assume that it’s correct.• Then, the solution is of the form,

    f(xt, t) = xteθt

    • Apply Itô’s formula.

    (or you can apply Proposition 5.3 from our textbook withA = −θ and bt = µθ)

    Michael Orlitzky Towson University

  • Ornstein-Uhlenbeck

    0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0

    0.2

    0.4

    0.6

    0.8

    1.0

    1.2

    θ=2σ=1/5µ=1Ut

    Michael Orlitzky Towson University

  • Lo & Wang Process

    That’s great, but we want to price some derivatives.

    Let Pt be some price process, and pt = ln (Pt). We’re going toassume that pt has the dynamics,

    dpt = (−θ (pt − ηt) + η) dt+ σdWtp0 = p0

    We see that pt is shifted by ηt – we want to get rid of that.

    Michael Orlitzky Towson University

  • Lo & Wang Process

    We can rewrite that SDE as,

    d (pt − ηt) = −θ (pt − ηt) dt+ σdWt

    Now if we let ηt = µt, the right-hand side looks like theOrnstein-Uhlenbeck SDE!

    d (pt − µt) = −θ (pt − µt) dt+ σdWt

    Michael Orlitzky Towson University

  • Lo & Wang Process

    We’ll rename pt − µt = qt to reduce the amount of ugly. Thuswe have,

    dqt = −θqtdt+ σdWt

    Compare with Geometric Brownian Motion:

    d ln (Xt) =

    (α− σ

    2

    2

    )dt+ σdWt

    Since we have a function of t in the dt term, our process isactually a slight generalization of GBM. It allows us to modeltrends and predictability.

    Michael Orlitzky Towson University

  • Lo & Wang Process

    Oh, and we can still solve our new process explicitly [3]:

    qt = e−θtq0 + σ

    t∫0

    e−θ(t−s)dWs

    Translating back into the original price process...

    pt = µt + e−θt (p0 − µ0) + σN [0, ξ]

    where again,

    ξ =

    √1

    2θ[1− e−2θt]

    Michael Orlitzky Towson University

  • Lo & Wang Process

    0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0

    0.2

    0.4

    0.6

    0.8

    1.0

    1.2

    µt=0θ=1σ=1/5

    P0exp{µt+e

    −θt(p0−µ0) +σN[0,ξ]

    }P0exp

    {µt+e

    −θt(p0−µ0)

    }

    Michael Orlitzky Towson University

  • Lo & Wang Process

    0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0

    0.5

    1.0

    1.5

    2.0

    2.5

    3.0

    µt=tθ=1σ=1/5

    P0exp{µt+e

    −θt(p0−µ0) +σN[0,ξ]

    }P0exp

    {µt+e

    −θt(p0−µ0)

    }

    Michael Orlitzky Towson University

  • Lo & Wang Process

    0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0

    1.0

    2.0

    3.0

    4.0

    5.0

    µt=0θ=5σ=1/5

    P0exp{µt+e

    −θt(p0−µ0) +σN[0,ξ]

    }P0exp

    {µt+e

    −θt(p0−µ0)

    }

    Michael Orlitzky Towson University

  • Lo & Wang Process

    0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0

    5.0

    10.0

    15.0

    20.0

    25.0

    30.0

    35.0

    40.0

    µt=3tθ=5σ=1P0exp

    {µt+e

    −θt(p0−µ0) +σN[0,ξ]

    }P0exp

    {µt+e

    −θt(p0−µ0)

    }

    Michael Orlitzky Towson University

  • Lo & Wang Process

    0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0

    20.0

    40.0

    60.0

    80.0

    100.0

    120.0

    140.0µt=5tθ=10σ=1/5

    P0exp{µt+e

    −θt(p0−µ0) +σN[0,ξ]

    }P0exp

    {µt+e

    −θt(p0−µ0)

    }

    Michael Orlitzky Towson University

  • Option Pricing

    Theorem. The Black-Scholes formula works for the processwe defined earlier, qt.

    This sounds rather amazing at first (see [3] for a citation), butthere is a caveat. While the formula still works, the numericalvalue of σ will differ between GBM and Ornstein-Uhlenbeck.

    The short version:

    σ2OU = σ2GBM ·

    [θτ(

    1− e−θτ)−1]

    (Here, τ is the length of the time period over which yourobservations are made.)

    Michael Orlitzky Towson University

  • Option Pricing

    Example (IBM, March 2012).

    Table: Observed prices for March 2012

    Date Closing Price

    2012-03-01 whatever

    2012-03-02 whatever

    2012-03-05 whatever

    2012-03-06 whatever

    . . . . . .

    2012-03-30 whatever

    Michael Orlitzky Towson University

  • Option Pricing

    190.0 195.0 200.0 205.0 210.0 215.0 220.0

    5.0

    10.0

    15.0

    20.0

    25.0

    θ=1FGBM(t=0, s)FOU(t=0, s)

    Michael Orlitzky Towson University

  • Option Pricing

    2.0 4.0 6.0 8.0 10.0θ

    5.0

    10.0

    15.0

    t=0s=205[FOU−FGBM]

    Michael Orlitzky Towson University

  • Option Pricing

    As θ increases, the tendency to vary from the mean decreases.Therefore, a large θ corresponds to a “predictable” stock.

    Conclusion. Options on a predictable stock are morevaluable!

    Michael Orlitzky Towson University

  • References

    [1] Björk, Tomas. Arbitrage Theory in Continuous Time, 3rdEd. Oxford University Press, Oxford, 2009.

    [2] Doob, J. L. The Brownian Movement and StochasticEquations. The Annals of Mathematics, Second Series, Vol.43, No. 2 (Apr., 1942), pp. 351-369.

    [3] Lo, A. W.; Wang, J.: Implementing Option Pricing Modelswhen asset returns are predictable. The Journal of Finance50, pp. 87–129, 1995.

    [4] Stein, William A. et al. Sage Mathematics Software (Version5.0), The Sage Development Team, 2012,http://www.sagemath.org.

    [5] Uhlenbeck, G. E. and Ornstein, L. S. On the Theory ofBrownian Motion. Phys. Rev. 36, pp. 823-841. 1930.

    Michael Orlitzky Towson University