Optimal Health Insurance for Prevention and Treatmentblogs.bu.edu › ellisrp › files › 2012 ›...

30
Optimal Health Insurance for Prevention and Treatment Randall P. Ellis Department of Economics Boston University Willard G. Manning Harris School of Public Policy Studies The University of Chicago We thank Shenyi Jiang, Albert Ma,Tom McGuire, Joe Newhouse, Frank Sloan and seminar participants at Boston University and Harvard for their comments.

Transcript of Optimal Health Insurance for Prevention and Treatmentblogs.bu.edu › ellisrp › files › 2012 ›...

Page 1: Optimal Health Insurance for Prevention and Treatmentblogs.bu.edu › ellisrp › files › 2012 › 02 › 2007-EllisManning_JHE_EJM_combined.pdfOptimal Health Insurance for Prevention

Optimal Health Insurance for Prevention and Treatment

Randall P. Ellis Department of Economics

Boston University

Willard G. ManningHarris School of Public Policy Studies

The University of Chicago

We thank Shenyi Jiang, Albert Ma,Tom McGuire, Joe Newhouse, Frank Sloan and seminar participants at Boston University and Harvard for their comments.

Page 2: Optimal Health Insurance for Prevention and Treatmentblogs.bu.edu › ellisrp › files › 2012 › 02 › 2007-EllisManning_JHE_EJM_combined.pdfOptimal Health Insurance for Prevention

Rich literature on optimal health insurance

Zeckhauser JET (1970) is classic article describing tradeoff between risk spreading and moral hazard

Conventional approach emphasizes:

Demand responsiveness

Variance in health care spending

Degree of risk aversion

Insurance loading factor

Focus of paper is on demand side incentives, ignoring supply-side moral hazard and supply-side cost sharing

Page 3: Optimal Health Insurance for Prevention and Treatmentblogs.bu.edu › ellisrp › files › 2012 › 02 › 2007-EllisManning_JHE_EJM_combined.pdfOptimal Health Insurance for Prevention

New questions answered in this paper

How should optimal insurance coverage be modified in the presence of

Preventive care services?

Multiple health care goods with correlated errors?

Cross price elasticities of demand?

Uncompensated losses that are correlated with health spending?

Multiple time periods when health care spending is serially

correlated over time?

Page 4: Optimal Health Insurance for Prevention and Treatmentblogs.bu.edu › ellisrp › files › 2012 › 02 › 2007-EllisManning_JHE_EJM_combined.pdfOptimal Health Insurance for Prevention

Summary of what paper shows

1. Preventive care should be covered generously because consumers will

ignore premium savings in their private prevention decisions.

2. Health care goods that are positively correlated with other health

spending should be more generously covered

3. Health care goods that are substitutes should be covered more

generously than complements.

4. Cover services generously that are positively correlated with

uncompensated losses

5. Services that are positively serially correlated over time should be

covered more generously than those that are uncorrelated

Page 5: Optimal Health Insurance for Prevention and Treatmentblogs.bu.edu › ellisrp › files › 2012 › 02 › 2007-EllisManning_JHE_EJM_combined.pdfOptimal Health Insurance for Prevention

Optimal insurance coverage for preventive care has received relatively little attention

Low variance suggests insurance not needed (Kenkel, AEA presentation 2007)

Demand elasticity low relative to curative care (uncertain)?

Insurance reduces value of prevention

Primary versus secondary prevention

Boundary between prevention and treatment is sometimes blurry (e.g. drugs, preventive treatment)

We define prevention activities as costly services to the consumer that reduce the probability of being sick.

Page 6: Optimal Health Insurance for Prevention and Treatmentblogs.bu.edu › ellisrp › files › 2012 › 02 › 2007-EllisManning_JHE_EJM_combined.pdfOptimal Health Insurance for Prevention

Five types of losses modeled

Ex ante moral hazard loss from too little prevention

Ex post moral hazard loss from overinsurance

Inefficiency due to insurance loading factors

Arrow-Pratt cost of risk

Uncompensated losses due to ill health

Page 7: Optimal Health Insurance for Prevention and Treatmentblogs.bu.edu › ellisrp › files › 2012 › 02 › 2007-EllisManning_JHE_EJM_combined.pdfOptimal Health Insurance for Prevention

Organization of paper

Literature review

Basic model – use consumer surplus measure

no prevention, homoscedastic error

Utility-based models

Prevention + one health treatment good

Key role of uncompensated health losses

Multiple health treatment goods

Multiple periods

Discussion and empirical relevance

Page 8: Optimal Health Insurance for Prevention and Treatmentblogs.bu.edu › ellisrp › files › 2012 › 02 › 2007-EllisManning_JHE_EJM_combined.pdfOptimal Health Insurance for Prevention

Huge literature potentially related to these questions – Most of Audience in this room!

Optimal deductibles and copayments

Demand responsiveness of specific services

Optimal insurance with multiple goods

Dynamic models of health spending

Prevention

Statistical models of the distribution of health care costs over time

Page 9: Optimal Health Insurance for Prevention and Treatmentblogs.bu.edu › ellisrp › files › 2012 › 02 › 2007-EllisManning_JHE_EJM_combined.pdfOptimal Health Insurance for Prevention

Literature is ambiguous on insurance coverage for preventive care

Low variance suggests insurance not needed (Kenkel, AEA presentation 2007)

Demand elasticity low relative to curative care (uncertain)?

Insurance reduces value of prevention (ex ante moral hazard)

Primary versus secondary prevention

Boundary between prevention and treatment is sometimes blurry (e.g. drugs, preventive treatment)

We define prevention activities as costly activities to the consumer that reduce the probability of being sick.

Page 10: Optimal Health Insurance for Prevention and Treatmentblogs.bu.edu › ellisrp › files › 2012 › 02 › 2007-EllisManning_JHE_EJM_combined.pdfOptimal Health Insurance for Prevention
Page 11: Optimal Health Insurance for Prevention and Treatmentblogs.bu.edu › ellisrp › files › 2012 › 02 › 2007-EllisManning_JHE_EJM_combined.pdfOptimal Health Insurance for Prevention

Basic model

One health care good X

Linear demand curve when sick of X = µX – B PX + θ

Θ = random shock affecting demand for X (also health status shock)

Marginal cost = 1

PX = cX = cost share of health care treatment

Page 12: Optimal Health Insurance for Prevention and Treatmentblogs.bu.edu › ellisrp › files › 2012 › 02 › 2007-EllisManning_JHE_EJM_combined.pdfOptimal Health Insurance for Prevention

Adding in insurance and cost of risk

Use Arrow-Pratt approximation for welfare loss from financial risk

Cost of risk = (RA)(variance of out-of-pocket spending)/2

Assume probability of sickness = 1 - (Z)

Health spending only if sick

Insurance loading factor δ implies extra cost of using insurance funding is

= δ (1-(Z)) (1-cX) (µX – B cX)

Uncompensated loss from insurance = L

Page 13: Optimal Health Insurance for Prevention and Treatmentblogs.bu.edu › ellisrp › files › 2012 › 02 › 2007-EllisManning_JHE_EJM_combined.pdfOptimal Health Insurance for Prevention

Ex post moral hazard loss from overinsurance = 2(1 / 2) (1 - )Xc B

Inefficiency due to insurance loading factors = (1 ) ( )X X Xc Bc

Arrow-Pratt cost of risk = 2 2 2AXR c

Uncompensated losses due to ill health = ( )L , with expectation L

Four terms in loss function to be minimized

Min

1 2 2 2(1/ 2)(1- ) (1 )( ) 2AX X X X XWL c B c Bc R c L

*2

2X

X A

B BcB B R

Page 14: Optimal Health Insurance for Prevention and Treatmentblogs.bu.edu › ellisrp › files › 2012 › 02 › 2007-EllisManning_JHE_EJM_combined.pdfOptimal Health Insurance for Prevention
Page 15: Optimal Health Insurance for Prevention and Treatmentblogs.bu.edu › ellisrp › files › 2012 › 02 › 2007-EllisManning_JHE_EJM_combined.pdfOptimal Health Insurance for Prevention

Results are interesting and plausible and many parameters can be calculated empirically

BUT

Does not suggest how to incorporate multiple goods

Does not expand to multiple periods well

Does not incorporate risk aversion in a fully satisfying way

Only approximates a utility maximization framework

Page 16: Optimal Health Insurance for Prevention and Treatmentblogs.bu.edu › ellisrp › files › 2012 › 02 › 2007-EllisManning_JHE_EJM_combined.pdfOptimal Health Insurance for Prevention

Utility-based model

Three kinds of goods

X = health care goods indexed by

Y = all other consumption goods

Z = spending on preventive care

PX, PY, PZ = prices of three types of goods

π = insurance premium

I = Income

I = π +PXX + PYY + PZ Z

Page 17: Optimal Health Insurance for Prevention and Treatmentblogs.bu.edu › ellisrp › files › 2012 › 02 › 2007-EllisManning_JHE_EJM_combined.pdfOptimal Health Insurance for Prevention

Sequence of moves

1. The insurer chooses coinsurance rates cX and cZ for treatment and

prevention.

2. The consumer chooses Z to maximize ex ante utility in Period 1 by

borrowing its cost against Period 1 income.

3. Nature decides on the consumer’s state of illness θ

4. The consumer chooses X and Y

5. If a dynamic model, then repeat steps 3 and 4 (prevention is done one

time in Period 0).

Page 18: Optimal Health Insurance for Prevention and Treatmentblogs.bu.edu › ellisrp › files › 2012 › 02 › 2007-EllisManning_JHE_EJM_combined.pdfOptimal Health Insurance for Prevention

Expected utility framework used

E U = Eθ U(Y, H(X, θ))

Three key assumptions about utility function

1. UYH < 0

Favorable health care shocks reduce the marginal utility of income

2. X/I = 0

Zero income effects, so Consumer Surplus = Compensating Variation for health goods

3. Linear demand curves for X

X = X – B PX +

Page 19: Optimal Health Insurance for Prevention and Treatmentblogs.bu.edu › ellisrp › files › 2012 › 02 › 2007-EllisManning_JHE_EJM_combined.pdfOptimal Health Insurance for Prevention

Assumed Effect of Income Changes on Optimal Consumption Bundles

Medical Service (Xi)

Oth

er G

oods

(Y)

Ideal ICC

Assumed ICC

Page 20: Optimal Health Insurance for Prevention and Treatmentblogs.bu.edu › ellisrp › files › 2012 › 02 › 2007-EllisManning_JHE_EJM_combined.pdfOptimal Health Insurance for Prevention

Demand for each health service when sick:

X

y

XPX A BP

2

2

Use Roy's identity to derive risk neutral utility function when sick

( , ) S X X

Y Y Y

P PIV I P A BP P P

Introduce stochastic element to demand where ( ) with ( ) 0XA F E

Page 21: Optimal Health Insurance for Prevention and Treatmentblogs.bu.edu › ellisrp › files › 2012 › 02 › 2007-EllisManning_JHE_EJM_combined.pdfOptimal Health Insurance for Prevention

Full model with prevention

S 1 2

1 2

X X X Z

( ) ( ) (1 ( )) ( ) ( )

where

( ) , and2

1 1 ( ) 1 1 Z

HX

Z

XX X

EV Z V J Z E V J K c L L

J I c Z

B c LK c

Z c Bc c

Prevention increases probability of being healthy

Prevention reduces treatment costs covered by premium

Prevention costs can either be paid out of pocket or covered by insurance

Benefits of health treatment are quadratic in prices, cX ,+L1

Health shocks theta affect out-of-pocket costs

Health shocks theta also affect uncompensated losses of two types: monetary and health

Insurance loading factor increases premium by proportion delta

Page 22: Optimal Health Insurance for Prevention and Treatmentblogs.bu.edu › ellisrp › files › 2012 › 02 › 2007-EllisManning_JHE_EJM_combined.pdfOptimal Health Insurance for Prevention

Socially optimal choice of preventive care ZSOC

differs from private choice ZPRIV in that private choice ignores change in premium

SOC PRIV

SOC

S S

SOC PRIV

Compare and

'( ) '( ) = , =

if ''( ) 0 Private choice resul

Z PRIVZ

H HI I

Z Z

MCPZ Z

E V E VV E V V E V

Z Z

Z

Z Zts in too little prevention when P = MCTherefore prevention services should be subsidized

Page 23: Optimal Health Insurance for Prevention and Treatmentblogs.bu.edu › ellisrp › files › 2012 › 02 › 2007-EllisManning_JHE_EJM_combined.pdfOptimal Health Insurance for Prevention

*

S

= 1 + 1

where

Z

Z

Z X X X

HI

P QcMC Q c Bc

Q V E V E V

Optimal cost sharing on preventive care

Page 24: Optimal Health Insurance for Prevention and Treatmentblogs.bu.edu › ellisrp › files › 2012 › 02 › 2007-EllisManning_JHE_EJM_combined.pdfOptimal Health Insurance for Prevention

Model with multiple goods and no prevention

Demand curves for two health treatment goods

1 1 1 1 12 2 1

2 2 2 2 12 1 2

- -

X B c G cX B c G c

Page 25: Optimal Health Insurance for Prevention and Treatmentblogs.bu.edu › ellisrp › files › 2012 › 02 › 2007-EllisManning_JHE_EJM_combined.pdfOptimal Health Insurance for Prevention

Optimal cost share One health treatment good, no insurance loading

C1* increases with B1 and

decreases with RA, 12

Confirms conventional results

* 11 2

1 1A

BcB R

Page 26: Optimal Health Insurance for Prevention and Treatmentblogs.bu.edu › ellisrp › files › 2012 › 02 › 2007-EllisManning_JHE_EJM_combined.pdfOptimal Health Insurance for Prevention

Optimal cost share One health treatment good, Insurance loading factor >0

C1* increases with and 1

* 1 1 11 2

1 1 12 A

B BcB B R

Page 27: Optimal Health Insurance for Prevention and Treatmentblogs.bu.edu › ellisrp › files › 2012 › 02 › 2007-EllisManning_JHE_EJM_combined.pdfOptimal Health Insurance for Prevention

S 12

1 11 1 1

2

S B LcEV E V I c c

Optimal cost share One health treatment good Uncompensated losses from health shocks

2 1* 1 1 11 2

1 1

A

A

B R LcB R

c1* decreases with uncompensated losses and can be

zero or negative at optimum

Page 28: Optimal Health Insurance for Prevention and Treatmentblogs.bu.edu › ellisrp › files › 2012 › 02 › 2007-EllisManning_JHE_EJM_combined.pdfOptimal Health Insurance for Prevention

Optimal cost share Two health treatment goods Correlated health shocks and nonzero cross price elasticities

As limiting case, c1* should be lower for services with

positively correlated health shocks

As limiting case, c1* should be higher for complements

than substitutes

2* 12 2 12 12 12 1 2 21 2 2 2

1 1 2 2 12 12

( )( ) ( )( ) ( )( ) ( )

A A

A A A

G B R G G B R BcR B R B R G

Page 29: Optimal Health Insurance for Prevention and Treatmentblogs.bu.edu › ellisrp › files › 2012 › 02 › 2007-EllisManning_JHE_EJM_combined.pdfOptimal Health Insurance for Prevention

Two period model = health shock serial correlation =discount factor

Services should have lower coinsurance when they are more highly serially correlated over time

The higher the savings rate adjustment for health care shocks, the less insurance is needed

If consumers discount the future more highly than the rate of interest, then there should be more insurance

1 21 1 1

*

21 1

11

11

11

A

XA

B R L sc

B R s

Page 30: Optimal Health Insurance for Prevention and Treatmentblogs.bu.edu › ellisrp › files › 2012 › 02 › 2007-EllisManning_JHE_EJM_combined.pdfOptimal Health Insurance for Prevention

Summary of what paper shows

1. Preventive care should be covered generously because consumers will

ignore premium savings in their private prevention decisions.

2. Health care goods that are positively correlated with other health

spending should be more generously covered

3. Health care goods that are substitutes should be covered more

generously than complements.

4. Cover services generously that are positively correlated with

uncompensated losses

5. Services that are positively serially correlated over time should be

covered more generously than those that are uncorrelated