On the Impact of Call-Back Competition on International Telephony

download On the Impact of Call-Back Competition on International Telephony

of 21

Transcript of On the Impact of Call-Back Competition on International Telephony

  • 7/31/2019 On the Impact of Call-Back Competition on International Telephony

    1/21

    Journal of Regulatory Economics; 20:1 2141, 2001

    # 2001 Kluwer Academic Publishers. Manufactured in The Netherlands.

    On the Impact of ``Callback'' Competition onInternational Telephony*

    FABIO M. MANENTIUniversity of York (U.K.),

    Department of Economics,

    Universita di Padova (Italy){. Dipartimento di Scienze Economiche ``M. Fanno''

    Abstract

    In this paper we build a simple three-country model to evaluate the impact of ``callback'' on international

    telephony. The effects on both accounting rates and collection prices are studied. Callback rms exploit

    arbitrage opportunities in collection prices among countries, rerouting calls that originate in countries

    with high prices for international phone calls via countries with low prices. Contrary to what is commonly

    perceived, we show that callback tends to magnify the distortions associated with the current accounting

    rate regime. In particular, callback puts upward pressure on low price countries' accounting rates and on

    collection charges. Callback companies are assumed to enjoy a volume price discount on each rerouted

    call; we show that the larger the price discount offered to callback companies, the higher the prices for

    international calls in the country hosting callback.

    1. Introduction

    The aim of this paper is to analyze and evaluate the impact of ``callback'' on retail and

    interconnection charges in international telecommunications. Callback is an alternative

    way of placing international calls (alternative calling procedure1 in the industry jargon)

    that new technologies have made available to customers for international voice

    communications. Until recent market liberalization decisions by many national

    * Paper presented at the 25th EARIE conference, Copenhagen and at the 1998 ASSET Meeting, Bologna. I

    would like to thank Gianni De Fraja for his continuous and constructive help. Gabriella Chiesa, Riccardo

    Faini, Indrajit Ray, Carlo Scarpa, Paola Valbonesi, Julian Wright and the seminar audiences at the

    University of Brescia and Pavia provided many helpful comments on earlier versions of the paper. Two

    anonymous referees and the editor, Michael Crew, are also acknowledged. I am particularly indebted to

    the Alcuin college of the University of York (U.K.) for the nancial support for my studies.

    { Address for correspondence: Dipartimento di Scienze Economiche, Universita di Padova, Via del Santo

    33, 35123 Padova (Italy). E-mail: [email protected]

    1 ACP hereafter.

  • 7/31/2019 On the Impact of Call-Back Competition on International Telephony

    2/21

    governments are effectively put in place, ACPs, and callback in particular, are one of the

    main challenges to the monopolistic power of national carriers.2

    Callback is based on a very simple idea: suppose a customer in Italy wants to speak with

    a friend in a different country (the U.S.). If the price of a call from the U.S. to Italy is lower

    than the price of a call in the opposite direction, then it may be cheaper for the Italian

    resident to be called rather than to call the friend located in the U.S. He will then

    compensate the friend for the cost of the call. Instead, he can use a public callback service

    and get a computer to do the call-rerouting.

    In the typical callback call, rst a customer in one country places a free call to the

    callback operator equipment (usually just an automated system) in a second country. The

    operator, which detects the caller's identity without answering the call, calls the customer

    back at a predesignated number providing the customer with a dial tone in the secondcountry and connects the customer to a number in the second or third country. The original

    call is now ``rerouted'' via the country where the callback rm operates.

    Most callback enterprises are located in the U.S. where lower prices for international

    phone calls provide wide margins for arbitrage opportunities; callback calls are usually

    provided at a rate 2050% cheaper then that of the carriers. Unfortunately, the FCC does

    not compile explicit data on callback trafc. Callback falls under the umbrella of ``resale''

    trafc and there is no way for the FCC to track callback trafc versus other types of resale

    trafc.3

    Although price competition and deregulation together with the emerging of new

    services, namely voice over IP, have made callback less protable than it was when this

    service was introduced in 1992, global callback generated in 1999 estimated revenues of

    around $800 million.4 It is widely accepted that the demand for callback services will

    remain high in developing nations where international calls are still expensive. Nowadayscustomers place their calls using callback services in more than 200 countries.5

    Despite its growth, callback is still a very controversial phenomenon. On the one hand

    the FCC, the U.S. regulatory authority that provides the licenses to U.S.-based callback

    rms, and international organizations such us the OECD and, more recently, the ITU

    (International Telecommunications Union) have argued in favor of callback.6

    Accordingly, callback should be encouraged because it would engineer downward

    pressure on prices for international phone calls. On the other hand, 100 countries around

    2 An exhaustive description of the ACPs is provided in OECD (1995). The most common practices of

    ACPs are: reverse charge calling, credit card calls, country direct service, country and beyond service,

    callback, international free-phone service, international leased lines and rele (hubbing).

    3 In 1997 pure-resale trafc accounted for 15% of the whole outgoing U.S. trafc; this gure is expected

    to grow even more with time. See Lande and Blake (1997).

    4 See Nye (1999).

    5 See Choi et al. (1999).

    6 After more than two years of legal disputes, the FCC gave its nal assent to the provision of callback

    services in 1995 (10 FCC Rcd 95-40). See Propp (1996) for a discussion of the legal issues related to the

    FCC decision to authorize callback operators in the U.S. But note that not all types of callback are

    allowed: the so called ``call-bombardment'' and ``answer suppression'' are fraudulent since they interfere

    with the billing mechanism of the national operators.

    22 FABIO M. MANENTI

  • 7/31/2019 On the Impact of Call-Back Competition on International Telephony

    3/21

    the world, mainly developing countries, have so far prohibited callback in their territories 7

    and are putting pressure on the FCC to stop licensing of new callback operators. These

    countries perceive callback as a problem because it deprives the local operator of revenues

    from the international telecommunications sector.8 This controversy has been, and still is,

    a source of strong debate among operators.

    The surprising growth and development of this particular form of competition has been

    made possible by the way in which international telecommunications is organized. The

    typical method of governing interactions among national telecom operators is the

    accounting rate system. Consider, for example, a call from Italy to France: the Italian

    carrier keeps the revenue for this call but, for this call to be terminated (i.e., received by a

    user in France), it must pay an access fee to the French operator for the use of its network.

    The same fee applies to each call that goes from France to Italy; this fee (called theaccounting rate or the interconnection charge) is arranged in bilateral negotiations

    between the two operators. As suggested by Frieden (1997), under this regime, carriers

    have failed to negotiate adequate interconnection charges. Even though accounting rates

    are falling over time, they are still well above the cost of providing interconnection.9 This

    distortion in the access charges has kept prices for international phone calls at an

    articially high level, preventing them from reecting the dramatic costs reduction

    implied by the development of new technologies.

    Callback advocates, such as the OECD, argue that this form of competition between

    international operators creates downward pressure both on retail prices and accounting

    rates. According to Frieden (1997), the more nations authorizing callback, the more

    accounting rates and collection charges10 decrease in consequence.

    In a recent paper, Choi et al. (1999) provide a formal treatment of the callback

    phenomenon. Interestingly, they show that one of the main reasons for the existing ofcallback services is the inefciency of the accounting rate system. Nonetheless, in their

    paper, the inefciency is not fully explained; in addition, the authors use a two country

    model, while most callback operators reroute calls between two high price countries and

    are located in a third country with low international rates. We use a three country model in

    order to capture the basic structure of a callback call; furthermore, by making endogenous

    the determination of the accounting rates between countries, we are able to highlight the

    consequences of callback both on accounting and retail charges. We show that with

    callback, accounting rates and collection prices on different routes, otherwise

    uncorrelated, become interconnected. As a consequence, the effects of the accounting

    rate regime are no longer restricted to a few specic routes, but rather are extended to the

    interconnection agreements between the countries involved in the calls rerouting.

    This paper demonstrates that callback puts upward pressure on the accounting ratesbetween ``high price'' countries (called target countries), which in turn pushes up

    7 The list of these countries is kept up-to-date on the ITU web-site (http://www.itu.int/).

    8 Arguments for and against callback are summarized in Kelly (1996).

    9 Data about accounting rates are condential and, apart from the U.S. and the U.K., they are not

    published; estimates of the accounting rates can be found in OECD (1997).

    10 According to the industry jargon, the price for a phone call is also dened as ``collection charge''.

    IMPACT OF ``CALLBACK'' COMPETITION 23

  • 7/31/2019 On the Impact of Call-Back Competition on International Telephony

    4/21

    collection prices for calls between the same countries. In addition, it is shown that the

    impact of callback on the prices charged by the low price carrier (called the host carrier)

    depends upon the price discount offered to callback rms. Quite surprisingly, it is found

    that the larger the discount, the higher the host carrier mark-up.

    Although in a different context, these results conrm similar arguments presented in

    Alleman (1998) and are easily understood once the effects of the reciprocal accounting

    rate regime are fully considered. Indeed, instead of undermining it, callback exacerbates

    the distortions that this regime has on accounting rates and collection charges. Consider

    target countries: carriers in target countries may nd it optimal to push up prices for

    international calls placed between their customers by raising the reciprocal interconnec-

    tion fee; this stimulates alternative callback rerouting and increases trafc imbalances

    between target and host countries. According to the accounting rate regime, this impliesthat carriers in target countries receive higher settlement payments from the country

    hosting the callback rms. On the other hand, also the host country carrier may be induced

    to increase its tariffs for calls directed to target countries; this is to reduce the amount of

    calls rerouted via callback and to lower the settlement payment due to the carriers in target

    countries.

    These results must be evaluated considering the evolving context of the market for

    international telephony. Many factors are inducing a decline in prices for international

    phone calls; technologies are more efcient, in many countries markets are now open to

    competition and new communications services (typically, the Internet) are eroding the

    market for traditional telephony;11 our main argument is that callback instead of

    accelerating the decline of collection prices has indeed prevented them from converging

    down to costs.

    The paper is organized as follows. In section 2 we present the model of callback. Section3 evaluates and discusses the solution of the game and section 4 concludes the paper.

    2. The Model

    We model a world with three countries A, B and C. For the sake of simplicity, we assume

    that in each country, telecommunications services are provided by only one operator

    (carrier). This assumption may appear rather unrealistic, especially in relation to the

    country hosting the callback rms. In the real world, price differences occur mainly

    because some countries have opened the market to competition. Nonetheless, as it will

    become clear later, the main arguments of the paper are not affected by this assumption. Inthis stylized world only international telephone services are provided, that is, calls

    originating in one country and terminating (i.e., received by a user) in another country. We

    make the following assumptions:

    11 In Manenti (2000) it is estimated that the demand for international telecommunications in Italy for the

    period 199197 is signicantly and negatively affected by the dimension of the Internet; this suggests

    that the new Internet-based communications channels are substitutes for standard telephony services.

    24 FABIO M. MANENTI

  • 7/31/2019 On the Impact of Call-Back Competition on International Telephony

    5/21

    (i) National carriers in countries A and B have the same cost conditions. We denote

    with c the cost incurred by these operators in collecting a call on their local

    network and sending it to the ``half-way point''.12 Instead, carrier C (C for

    cheaper) is more efcient: it incurs a lower cost per outgoing call: cc5c. Given its

    superior technology, carrierC can set lower prices for calls directed to countries A

    and B: prices for international calls differ according to the direction of the call (i.e.

    a call from C to A costs less than a call in the opposite direction).

    (ii) Each call directed to a country must transit on that country's network in order to

    reach the nal user. The transmitting carrier pays an access fee for each call to the

    receiving carrier for the use of its network. This fee, called the ``accounting rate'',

    is reciprocal (i.e. the same access charge for a call from A to B applies to a call

    from B to A) and is negotiated between the carriers involved in the calltransmission. The accounting rate is determined according to a Nash-bargaining

    process.

    (iii) The cost of providing access (the cost of delivering other carriers' calls) is co and is

    the same across countries.

    (iv) Callback rms (CB hereafter) are located in country C. The CB sector is

    characterized by price competition with free-entry. CB enterprises exploit

    arbitrage opportunities based on calls rerouting: a CB rm located in C, the

    cheap country, can reroute a call from A to B (or vice versa) transforming it into

    two outgoing calls from C. For these reasons, we denote A and B as target

    countries and C as the host country.

    2.1. The Demand for International Telecommunications

    Our main purpose is to investigate the impact of CB on high price countries' reciprocal

    accounting rates and tariffs. For this reason we assume that CB services are provided only

    on the main route AB: a customer located in a target country can place his calls to users in

    the other target country either by demanding the services of his national operator or via

    callback. In order to differentiate these two kinds of calls, we dene the former as

    ``standard calls'' and the latter as ``callback calls''.

    We rule out the possibility that CB rms offer to reverse calls from A orB to C. This is a

    simplication because, usually, once the customer located in the target country (for

    example A), is connected with the CB terminal equipment, he can then place a call either

    in the host country C or to a foreign destination (B).13

    CB rms act symmetrically with respect to the target carriers: each CB rm offers to

    reroute calls both from A to B and from B to A. This is what happens in practice in the CBmarket: unless a country has banned CB, then CB rms provide connection in both the

    directions of the call.

    12 This is called the imaginary point of interconnection between national networks.

    13 However, if markets are separated and there are no economies of scale, the introduction of CB even

    between target and host countries would not affect our results. For an analysis of CB between target and

    host countries, see Choi et al. (1999).

    IMPACT OF ``CALLBACK'' COMPETITION 25

  • 7/31/2019 On the Impact of Call-Back Competition on International Telephony

    6/21

    There are n CB rms, indexed by h 1; . . . ; n, all located in the host country C. Theyhave two main effects: on the one hand they compete with networks A and B by lowering

    the amount of calls that they place with each other and, on the other hand, they increase the

    number of calls originating in C.

    We model standard calls and CB calls as imperfect substitutes: the demand for CB

    services increases with the price for standard calls charged by the national operator.

    Formally, denoting by Qji the demand for standard calls from i to j, by Y

    ji the demand for

    CB services on the same route, and by pji and v

    ji the prices for these calls, the following

    assumption is made:

    Assumption 1:

    (a)qQ

    j

    i

    pj

    i

    ;vj

    i

    qpj

    i50

    qYj

    i

    vj

    i

    ;pj

    i

    qvj

    i50

    qYj

    i

    vj

    i

    ;pj

    i

    qpj

    i40 i;j A; B and i T j.

    (b) The demand for standard calls and the demand for callback calls are the same

    across countries and have constant price elasticity, denoted by Z andE respectively:

    Z qQ

    ji

    qpji

    pji

    Qji

    i;j A; B; C and i T j

    e qY

    ji

    qvji

    vji

    Yji

    i;j A; B and i T j

    (c) e4Z41.

    The assumption of imperfect substitutability (1a) is taken on practical grounds: on the onehand, although CB is becoming a very popular telecommunication service, its use is still

    conned to a restricted share of well informed customers. In addition, calls placed via CB

    are often of a lower quality when compared to standard calls (delays in the conversation,

    echoes, noise etc.): quality considerations may reduce the attractiveness of these services

    affecting customers' demand. According to these observations, it is even natural to assume

    that the demand for CB calls is more reactive to change in prices than the demand for

    standard calls (assumption 1c): although we cannot empirically support this assumption,

    we believe it is reasonable to think of CB users more concerned with changes in prices

    than the customers of standard calls.14

    2.1.1. Trafc Flows

    Only standard calls are placed between target countries but, as explained, the demandfor calls between target carriers depends not only on the collection price p

    ji charged by the

    local monopolist, but also on the price for a CB call vji : Q

    ji Q

    ji p

    ji ; v

    ji .

    For each call that is rerouted from the main line AB via C, two outgoing calls from C

    are placed, one directed to each country. This implies that the amount of calls delivered on

    14 The condition Z41 is necessary to guarantee positive equilibrium prices and is supported by some

    studies of elasticity of demand for international calling. See OECD (1997) or Lande and Blake (1997).

    26 FABIO M. MANENTI

  • 7/31/2019 On the Impact of Call-Back Competition on International Telephony

    7/21

    carrier C's network and directed to country i is the combination between the amount of

    standard calls Q ic and CB rerouting Yji . Therefore, the trafc ow between host and target

    carriers is given by

    Traffic Flow

    TFic ?

    standard calls

    Qicpic

    callback rerouting

    Yji v

    ji ;p

    ji Y

    ijv

    ij;p

    ij

    with i A, B and i T j.According to our simplication, CB rms reverse calls only on the route AB. This

    implies that the trafc of calls from countries A and B to country C is not affected by CB.

    It is useful to provide a graphical representation of the trafc ows between the three

    countries; see gure 1.

    2.2. Fundamentals of the Reciprocal Accounting Rate Regime

    The current system of multilateral collaboration in the transmission of international

    calls is the accounting rate regime. According to this regime, the transmitting carrier pays

    for each call sent to the foreign carrier an access fee (the accounting rate) for the use of its

    network and receives an equal payment for each incoming call from this operator. The

    accounting rate is negotiated at bilateral meetings between telecom carriers.

    We assume that these negotiations take the form of a Nash-bargaining process in which

    the contracting parties have the same bargaining power.15 Formally, the accounting rate

    between country i and j ai;j is given by

    ai;j argmax p1=2i p1=2jh i

    1

    where pi is the carrier i's prot function. For the sake of simplicity, we assume that the

    disagreement point of this bargaining process is that there is no interconnection agreement,

    namely the carriers cannot provide international services between the two countries and

    both their prots are zero. This is a simplifying assumption since each carrier always has

    the option of rerouting calls through the third country.16

    a is the accounting rate between target carriers (A and B) while ti is the accounting rate

    between carrier C and carrier i. Table 1 summarizes the adopted notation.

    The analysis of the current accounting rate regime is beyond the scope of this work.

    Nonetheless, as it will become clear later, since CB is intrinsically related to the process

    15 This is realistic in this framework, in which international telephony services are supplied by monopolies

    but it applies even when competition is considered. In this case we can think of a regulatory policy that

    assigns to a representative carrier a monopoly equivalent bargaining power.

    16 We wish to thank an anonymous referee for this observation. Nonetheless, taking into account for each

    carrier the option of rerouting calls via a third country would require modeling transit tariffs for rerouted

    calls and also the additional bargaining processes between the countries of transit in which these tariffs

    are determined. This would make the analysis much more complicated without, at the same time, adding

    any new relevant insight to the model. The assumption of zero prot disagreement point is frequently

    adopted in the existing literature; see Wright (1999) and De Fraja and Valbonesi (2001).

    IMPACT OF ``CALLBACK'' COMPETITION 27

  • 7/31/2019 On the Impact of Call-Back Competition on International Telephony

    8/21

    through which collection charges are determined, it is important to recall briey how this

    regime works; in particular two main effects are worth noting: 17

    (1) When carriers face the same demand and cost conditions (perfect symmetry), trafc

    ows between countries are balanced (outgoing traffic incoming trafc) and thebargained access price is set equal to the cost of providing access. In our case, since

    carriers A and B are identical, then a co.(2) When there is asymmetry between countries either at the demand or at the cost

    level, trafc is no longer balanced and the bargained access price is shown to be

    above the cost of providing access. In this model, due to the technological

    asymmetry, trafc ows between host and target countries are unbalanced; thisimplies that ti4co.

    Perfect symmetry is a very special situation. In more general cases trafc ows among

    countries are unbalanced. That is, due to the reciprocity of the accounting rate regime, the

    carrier that terminates more calls than it originates receives more than it pays to the foreign

    carrier for interconnection to its network.18

    When the trafc is unbalanced, carriers fail to set the reciprocal access charge at the cost

    level. This is considered one of the reasons why international calls charges are higher

    when compared to national long distance calls. The accounting rate is ``de facto'' an

    additional cost per call that each carrier must pay to deliver its calls. The higher the

    accounting rate, the higher the cost per call and the higher the collection prices.19

    Figure 1. Trafc ows.

    17 For a formal treatment, we refer to an earlier version of this paper; in Manenti (1997) we study the

    consequences of demand and cost asymmetries on bargained accounting rates.

    18 The growing imbalances in trafc ows between countries have generated large decits in countries like

    the U.S., Sweden or Australia and large surpluses in other countries such as Mexico or Germany. Data on

    trafc ows are in ITU (1999).

    19 For these reasons many governments and organizations are promoting the introduction of new

    interconnection arrangements. See De Fraja and Valbonesi (2001) for a discussion of the proposed

    reforms of the accounting rate regime.

    28 FABIO M. MANENTI

  • 7/31/2019 On the Impact of Call-Back Competition on International Telephony

    9/21

    2.3. Firms' Prots

    2.3.1. Callback Firm's Prot

    CB rms are assumed to be identical and, as stated above, they are established in

    country C. For each rerouted call from one target country to the other, they must pay the

    hosting carrier for the price of two outgoing calls. In practice, CB rms enjoy lower prices

    than residential customers since they fully exploit the volume discounts offered by the host

    carrier: assuming that CB rms do not face additional costs for each call, the CB cost per

    call is equal to a discounted sum of two outgoing calls from C. We denote the price

    charged to CB companies by pcb, with pcb ypac pbc , where y [ 0; 1 represents thevolume discount. For the moment, let us assume that y is exogenous. Note that pcb is

    independent of the direction of the rerouted call.

    Since each CB rm reroutes calls both from A to B and from B to A, the prot function

    for the h CB rm is then

    phCB

    i;j A;B

    vji;h pcbYji;h ? h 1; . . . ; n and i T j 2

    where vji;h is the price for calling from i to j charged by the h CB operator and Y

    ji;h is the

    demand it faces.

    2.3.2. Carriers' Prots

    The prot functions for each established carrier are given by

    pi pji c a

    h iQ

    ji ? a coQ

    ij ? p

    ci c ti Q

    ci ?

    ti coQic ? Y

    ji ? Y

    ij ? i;j A; B and i T j 3

    Table 1. Notation

    Name Description (i;j A;B and i T j, h 1; . . . ; n)

    a Accounting rate between A and B

    ta Accounting rate between C and A

    tb Accounting rate between C and B

    pji Price for a call from country i to country jvia domestic carrier

    pic Price for a call from the host country C to country i

    vji;h Price for a callback call from country i to country jvia operator h

    Qji ? Demand for standard calls from target country i to target country j

    Qic ? Demand for standard calls from country C to target country j

    Yj

    i;h?

    Demand for callback calls from country i to country jvia operator h

    IMPACT OF ``CALLBACK'' COMPETITION 29

  • 7/31/2019 On the Impact of Call-Back Competition on International Telephony

    10/21

    pc pcb 2cc ta tb Yba ? Y

    ab ?

    i;j A;B

    pic cc ti

    Qic ? ti coQci ? 4

    where pji is the price for a call between target countries via established carriers i;j A;

    B, while pic and pci are the prices forCs outgoing and incoming calls respectively. a and ti

    are the bargained accounting rates between target countries and between the host country

    and country i respectively. In (4), the rst term represents the prot from selling calls to

    CB operators. Each rerouted call implies two outgoing calls from C; each pair of calls is

    charged pcb and costs 2cc ta tb to the host carrier.Using the denition of trafc ow between host and target countries, TFic, and

    rearranging, it is useful to rewrite carriers A and B prot as follows:

    pi pji c coQ

    ji a coQ

    ij Q

    ji

    pci c coQci ti co TF

    ic Q

    ci

    where the rst and the third terms represent the revenues from collecting standard calls and

    sending them to the called country, while the second and the fourth terms represent the net

    interconnection payments with the other national operators. These are known as the

    ``settlement payments''.

    Note that if the access charge exceeds the marginal cost of giving access co, then the

    carrier makes money on access (accounting revenues) only if it terminates more calls than

    it originates. When volumes of incoming and outgoing trafc are unbalanced, then the

    operator which generates more trafc pays for the difference to compensate the

    terminating carrier, namely the settlement payment. For example, if a4co then carrier Areceives from B a positive settlement payment ifQab Q

    ba40. The reciprocal accounting

    rate regime implies that part of the ``high trafc'' carrier's prot is ``stolen'' by the ``low

    trafc'' rm through the bargaining process.

    It is therefore clear how this system reduces the incentives for a rm to cut its prices:

    lower prices imply more outgoing calls and, as a consequence, a lower (even negative)

    settlement payment.

    2.4. The Timing

    We model CB competition as a four stage game; the timeline is in gure 2.

    In the rst stage, each monopolist negotiates the reciprocal accounting rates with each

    of the other carriers. At this stage a, ta and tb are determined.

    Figure 2. The timing.

    30 FABIO M. MANENTI

  • 7/31/2019 On the Impact of Call-Back Competition on International Telephony

    11/21

    Given these values, collection prices are dened in the second stage. This sequence of

    events is justied on practical grounds: accounting rates are negotiated during periodical

    meetings between telecom operators. Retail prices are then adjusted accordingly. In the

    third stage CB competition occurs. CB rms exploit arbitrage opportunities between

    carriers' prices. This means that CB rms observe the retail prices for international phone

    calls charged by carriers and then compete in the market for CB calls. In the last stage,

    rms' prots are realized.

    3. The Impact of Callback Competition

    CB is a textbook example of a market with no cost of entry. Indeed, to set up a CB rm and

    to start competing, only switched equipment terminals are required. For this reason, in the

    last few years there has been a proliferation of CB companies, especially in the U.S.

    Accordingly, we analyze CB assuming price competition with free entry.

    3.1. t 2: Callback CompetitionStarting from the last stage of the game, we solve the model by backward induction. At

    date t 2, CB competition occurs: CB rms observe the collection prices charged by thecarriers at t 1 and then compete in the market for rerouted calls.

    CB rms compete on prices: given the collection prices set by domestic carriers, each

    company sets its prices vji;h, with h 1; . . . ; n. The prot function for the h CB rm is

    given in (2). Note that at this stage of the game, carriers' collection prices are determined:

    Yji;h ? is now function only of the prices charged by CB rms.Since the CB industry is characterized by price competition, then CB calls are priced at

    marginal cost. The cost for each rerouted call is a discounted sum of the prices of two

    outgoing calls from C; this implies that at the equilibrium:

    v vji;h ypbc p

    ac i;j A; B and h 1; . . . ; n: 5

    We note that: (i) the equilibrium price for a CB call is independent of the direction of the

    call, and (ii) since pic is a component of the marginal cost of the CB rms, then an increase

    in Cs outgoing prices implies, for given y, a reduction in CB rerouting:

    qYji

    qpic qY

    ji

    qvdv

    dpic50:

    3.2. t 1: Second Stage Collection ChargesAt date t 1 carriers set their prices given the reciprocal access charges a and ti that

    they have bilaterally negotiated at t 0. The following proposition presents the secondperiod mark-ups at the symmetric equilibrium.

    IMPACT OF ``CALLBACK'' COMPETITION 31

  • 7/31/2019 On the Impact of Call-Back Competition on International Telephony

    12/21

  • 7/31/2019 On the Impact of Call-Back Competition on International Telephony

    13/21

    trafc on any other route. With CB part of the trafc ows on one route is moved to a

    different route; this makes prices and quantities of calls more correlated than otherwise.

    Nevertheless, since at date t 1 retail prices are dened as functions of the negotiatedaccounting rates, in order to analyse the impact of CB services on carriers' collection

    prices it is necessary to characterize the behavior of the interconnection charges between

    networks. This analysis is conducted in the following section.

    3.3. t 0: Accounting Rates

    3.3.1. The Accounting Rate Between Target Countries

    Interconnection charges (or accounting rates) are dened at date t 0 according to a

    Nash-bargaining process. We assume that rms have equal bargaining power. Thefollowing proposition presents our main result:

    Proposition 2: When callback rms reroute calls between target countries, the

    interconnection charge between these countries increases with respect to the solution

    without callback:

    a4co:

    Proof: See the Appendix. &

    This is a surprising result: the presence of CB enterprises located in C pushes up the access

    price between A and B. Proposition 2 has a clear explanation. Consider rst the solution

    without CB. This situation is close to the analysis of ``symbiotic production'' reported inCarter and Wright (1994). In this case, perfect symmetry between operators A and Boccurs; these carriers have identical demand and cost conditions which implies that, at the

    equilibrium, trafc on the route AB is perfectly balanced Qba Qab. As a consequence,

    the access is not an issue for the carriers: with reciprocal access price, the interconnection

    payment that one monopolist pays to the other is exactly the same it receives for delivering

    the other carrier's calls.

    Nonetheless the interconnection rate a matters since, according to expression (9), it

    affects collection prices. Without CB rms A and B set it equal to the cost of providing

    access a co; in doing so each carrier enjoys the highest level of prot (monopolisticlevel) charging the monopolistic price

    pM c co

    Z

    Z 1:

    As explained in Carter and Wright (1994), collusion over the access price lowers

    collection charges: both the rms increase their prot by lowering the access price. The

    cost of providing interconnection co represents the lower bound below which it is not

    optimal for both the carriers to set the accounting rate.

    Consider now the solution with CB. Since CB acts symmetrically towards target

    carriers, the relationship between networks A and B is still symmetric: trafc ow is

    perfectly balanced and there is no settlement payment; the accounting rate is still a means

    IMPACT OF ``CALLBACK'' COMPETITION 33

  • 7/31/2019 On the Impact of Call-Back Competition on International Telephony

    14/21

    of collusion. Nevertheless now target carriers deal with the new CB effect: the higher the

    price they charge for a call on the route AB, the more the calls rerouted via callback and

    the higher the settlement payment that they receive from carrier C.

    In other words, since t4co, rerouted calls are attractive because they increase the target

    countries settlement payments. Target carriers may agree upon a higher interconnection

    charge and, as a consequence, a higher collection price thus stimulating CB and increasing

    their access revenues. Moreover, (12) implies that, other things being equal, the

    accounting rate between countries A and B increases the more calls are rerouted via

    callback.

    This result gives evidence on how CB rerouting exacerbates the inefciency of the

    current accounting rate regime: CB puts upward pressure on accounting rates that,

    otherwise, would have been set at the cost level.

    3.3.2. The Accounting Rate Between Host and Target Countries

    The characterization of the impact of callback on the interconnection charge between A

    (or B) and C is much more complex and cannot be unambiguously dened.

    Given the asymmetry between host and target countries, we know from the previous

    analysis that the reciprocal interconnection charges ta and tb are set above the cost of

    providing access; at the symmetric equilibrium ta tb t and t4co.Nevertheless the interactions between prices, accounting rates and prots are very

    complex. The presence of CB affects both the prices between target countries and between

    target and host countries making the overall impact of Yon t undetermined.22

    3.4. The Impact of Callback on Collection Prices

    3.4.1. The Price for a Standard Call Between Target Countries

    Applying the results of the previous section to the second stage prices given in section

    3.2, we now discuss the impact of CB on retail prices. Let us start with the price for a

    standard call between A and B; the following corollary holds:

    Corollary 1: The collection price for a call between target countries is increased by

    callback:

    p c coZ

    Z 1 t cor

    Y

    Q

    Z 1

    Z 14pM: 10

    22 In an extended version of this paper, we show that, under very mild conditions, the accounting rate

    increases with the asymmetry in the size of demand faced by the countries involved in the bargaining

    process. This argument is conrmed in Wright (1999) where it is shown that the accounting rate between

    two countries is higher the more the two countries differ in per capita income: other things being equal,

    higher differences in income imply higher trafc imbalances which translate into higher accounting rates.

    According to this argument, since CB rerouting increases the asymmetry in the size of demand between

    host and target countries, then the bargained accounting rate should be xed at a higher level when CB

    rms are in the market.

    34 FABIO M. MANENTI

  • 7/31/2019 On the Impact of Call-Back Competition on International Telephony

    15/21

    Proof: See the Appendix. &

    On the one hand, with CB, both the interconnection charges a and tput upward pressure on

    A and B collection prices. As stated in Proposition 2, the access charge between A and B is

    higher when CB rms are in the market: the cost per call incurred by each target carrier is

    increased with respect to the equilibrium without CB thus putting pressure on retail prices.

    In addition, now, even the interconnection charge between target and host countries

    enters in the determination of the equilibrium price: all the other things equal, the higher t,

    the higher the price for a call from A to B (or vice versa). On the other hand, CB reduces

    the demand faced by target carriers thus pushing down collection prices; this effect is more

    than compensated by the effect of t on both accounting and collection charges and the

    equilibrium price increases with respect to the solution without CB. These arguments arestrengthened by the presence of the term Y/Q in expressions (12) and (10). The term Y/Q

    represents the ratio between the amount of CB calls and the amount of standard calls on the

    route AB. Ceteris paribus, the larger this ratio the higher the accounting rate bargained by

    target carriers and, therefore, the collection price they charge for calls on the route AB.

    Together with Proposition 2, this result is the central message of the paper. CB does not

    put downward pressure on the accounting rate a between target countries and it does not

    put pressure on collection prices pji i;j A; B either. Instead of undermining the

    accounting rate regime, the presence of CB tends to expand its distortions. Our conclusion

    provides a formal support to the intuition presented in Alleman (1998); in his paper,

    Alleman raises many concerns about the widespread view of CB as a device to induce a

    reduction in foreign collection rates and accounting charges. For this reason, the author

    claims that foreign countries should welcome CB, not make it illegal because it can

    improve their monopolists' revenue and prot.

    3.4.2. The Price for a Call From Country C to Target Countries

    Consider now the impact of CB on the price for calls from host to target countries;

    although we don't know the exact impact of CB on the bargained accounting rates between

    host and target countries, ti, we can still say something relevant on the impact of CB on

    carrier C's mark-up.

    Corollary 2: For a given accounting rate between target and host country, the mark-up

    for calls that originate in C and terminate in A or B tends to decrease with the price

    discount offered to CB rms; in particular:

    (i) with full price discount, y 0, CB competition increases the mark-up;(ii) without any price discount, y 1, CB competition reduces the mark-up.

    Proof: See the Appendix. &

    By offering a large price discount to CB companies (low y), the contribution of CB to

    carrier C total prot is relatively small. At the same time, a large discount implies that

    more calls between A and B are rerouted via C by CB companies. This entails an increase

    in the trafc imbalance between C and foreign countries and, as a consequence, a higher

    IMPACT OF ``CALLBACK'' COMPETITION 35

  • 7/31/2019 On the Impact of Call-Back Competition on International Telephony

    16/21

    settlement decit for the host carrier. By increasing pc, the carrier limits the number of

    outgoing calls; this reduces the trafc imbalance and the payment due to foreign carriers

    for interconnection. However, with little or no volume discount (y close to 1), CB becomes

    protable for carrierC, which now fully exploits the increased demand by reducing the

    price for a call.23

    These observations might become useful in a competitive marketplace. As mentioned,

    in some countries, and in the U.S. in particular, prices are lower because of the pressure of

    competitive forces. This creates the ideal environment for callback to proliferate. What

    could become relevant in a competitive context, is the relationship between the price

    charged by the host country carrier and the volume discount offered to CB companies.

    Competition in the country C has two main effects. Firstly, it lowers the host country

    collection prices which accentuates further the trafc imbalance between host and targetcountries. Secondly, as discussed in Choi et al. (1999), it increases the price discount

    offered to CB companies: rival rms compete not only for standard market shares but even

    to attract CB trafc: competition reduces y.24 According to our discussion, larger

    discounts translate into higher equilibrium prices; this might prevent competition from

    achieving its goal, namely driving prices down to costs.

    Finally, our model does not say anything about the impact of CB on the price for calling

    from target to host country. By assumption, there is no CB service for calls from country A

    (respectively B) to country C and the retail price is the standard monopoly price given in

    expression (9). Everything now depends on the impact of CB on the accounting rate t

    which, as already discussed, is not dened.

    4. Conclusions

    Callback is an alternative calling procedure that allows customers located throughout the

    world to place international calls at lower rates by rerouting calls via foreign and cheaper

    23 For the sake of completeness, the endogenous choice ofy by the host carrier is

    y e

    e 1

    1 2e YQc

    Z 4e YQc

    It is easy to see that y40. For sufciently high levels of the elasticity of demand for CB services, e, a

    corner solution occurs, y 1.24 We must note that competition does not necessarily affect the bargaining process over the

    interconnection terms. In the U.S., the market for incoming trafc is divided up in proportion to the U.S.

    carrier's own share of outgoing trafc with the corresponding country. This follows the FCCs rules called

    proportional return rules. These rules were introduced to prevent U.S. carriers competing against each

    other for calls termination, when dealing with a monopoly foreign carrier. Such competition could

    decrease the bargaining power of the U.S. carriers and it could also lead the incumbent U.S. carrier to

    reach an exclusive deal with the foreign carrier, to prevent entry of other carriers into the U.S. market

    (wipsawing). As discussed in Wright (1999), these rules imply that U.S. carriers act jointly in the

    bargaining over the accounting rate; similarly, a representative host country operator can be assigned

    with a monopolistic bargaining power thus keeping the process equivalent to the monopolistic case.

    36 FABIO M. MANENTI

  • 7/31/2019 On the Impact of Call-Back Competition on International Telephony

    17/21

    phone lines, usually located in the U.S. Although the international callback market has

    been growing at a fast pace in the last ten years, it is still one of the least understood

    telephony markets.

    The use of a three country model allows us to evaluate the impact of callback rms that

    reroute calls between two high price countries via a low price country. Contrary to what

    has been claimed by many inuential observers, we show that callback puts upward

    pressure on the interconnection rates between the high price carriers; furthermore, we

    show that this form of call rerouting might induce a general increase in collection prices.

    Transferring this into a real world scenario, we demonstrate that callback is slowing down

    the fall in retail and termination charges induced by all those factors, basically

    competition, deregulation and new technologies, that currently characterize the

    market.This is the effect of the reciprocal accounting rate regime, which is the current system

    used for charging and settling inter-country telecommunications. It is now widely

    recognized that the reciprocal accounting rate system is inefcient and prevents the

    providers of international telephony services from setting adequate interconnection tariffs

    and, therefore, retail prices.

    Callback rms move telephone trafc from one route to different ones; this makes

    trafc and tariffs on different routes more correlated than otherwise. As a consequence,

    callback expands the distortions induced by the current accounting rate regime. Our results

    are easily understood once the full effects of callback are considered; with callback, the

    carriers in target countries receive an extra settlement revenue from the carrier where

    callback rms are located. In order to maximize these extra revenues, the carriers agree on

    higher reciprocal accounting rates which in turn pushes prices up and stimulates call

    rerouting.The effects on prices charged by the carrier of the country where callback rms are

    located depend upon the price discount offered to callback rms.

    Callback proponents argue that callback helps to bring settlement rates, and therefore

    retail prices, more closely in line with costs. We show that the opposite is true.

    Paradoxically, the inadequacy of callback rerouting is the effect of what callback was

    originally intended to correct: the distortions of the reciprocal accounting rate regime.

    Rather then promoting trafc rerouting to bypass the accounting rate regime, it would be

    preferable to speed up the current process of reform of the accounting rate regime towards

    the introduction of new interconnection arrangements.

    Our approach is highly simplied; further research should be devoted to analyzing less

    restrictive models in order to provide a more general support to our results and to test

    empirically the impact of callback on retail prices. An interesting area for future researchwould be to study the other forms of call rerouting, such as hubbing and reling. These are

    additional alternative calling procedures that are frequently considered as instruments to

    reduce the inefciencies of the international interconnection system. Other issues that

    deserve to be studied concern the impact on traditional telephony ( pricing and

    interconnection) of the new forms of communications based on the use of the Internet

    and characterized by partially or completely circumventing the current interconnection

    regime.

    IMPACT OF ``CALLBACK'' COMPETITION 37

  • 7/31/2019 On the Impact of Call-Back Competition on International Telephony

    18/21

    Appendix

    Proof of Proposition 1: Let us rst consider the prices for standard calls on the route

    AB. From the denition ofpi the rst order condition with respect to pji is

    qpi

    qpji

    Qji pji c a

    qQji

    qpji

    ti coqY

    ji

    qpji

    0:

    Due to the symmetry of the game,25 we can rewrite this expression as follows

    p c aqQ

    qp

    Q t coqY

    qp

    recalling the denition of the cross-elasticity r and rearranging

    p c a

    p

    1

    Z

    t cop

    r

    Z

    Y

    Q

    and expression (6) follows immediately.

    The collection price for calls form A (or B) to C solves the following f.o.c.

    qpiqpci

    Qci pci c ti

    qQciqpci

    0:

    This is a standard monopoly's prot maximizing condition. Given the symmetry it is easy

    to derive expression (7).

    Finally let us consider the price for an outgoing call from country C; using the fact that

    pcb ypic p

    jc and rearranging, (4) becomes:

    pc ypic p

    jc 2cc ti tjY

    ji ? Y

    ij ?

    i;j A;B

    pic cc tiQic ? ti coQ

    ci ?

    differentiating, the rst order condition is:

    qpcqpc

    ypic pjc 2cc ti tj

    qYji

    qvji

    qvjiqpic

    qYij

    qvij

    qvij

    qpic

    2 3

    yYji Yi

    j Qic p

    ic cc ti

    qQicqpic

    0

    25 At the symmetric equilibrium pji p

    ij p;p

    ic p

    jc pc and v

    ji v

    ij v. These conditions imply that

    Qji Q

    ij Q; Q

    ic Q

    jc Qc.

    38 FABIO M. MANENTI

  • 7/31/2019 On the Impact of Call-Back Competition on International Telephony

    19/21

    since qvji =qp

    ic qv

    ij=qp

    ic y, and given that, at the symmetric equilibrium,

    qYji

    qvji

    qvji

    qpicqYij

    qvij

    qvij

    qpic 2y

    qY

    qv

    and that v 2ypc, this expression reduces to

    qpcqpc

    Qc pc cc tqQcqpc

    2yY 4y2pcqY

    qv 4ypc

    qY

    qv

    pc cc t4yqY

    qv 0

    rearranging:

    pc cc t

    pc1 2

    e

    Z

    Y

    Qc

    !

    1

    Z 2

    y

    Z

    Y

    Qc 2

    e

    Z1 y

    Y

    Qc

    and expression (8) is obtained.

    Second order conditions are assumed to hold. &

    Proof of Proposition 2: Using second stage prices provided in Proposition 1, carriers'

    prots can be expressed in terms of the access carges only. Therefore, according to

    expression (1) the accounting rate between carriers A and B is given by

    a argmax log pa pbaa;p

    aba; a

    logpb p

    baa;p

    aba; a

    :

    Differentiating the argument of the above expression and using the fact that, by the

    envelope theorem, qpi=qpi 0, the bargained accounting rate solves the equation

    qpaqpab

    dpabda

    qpaqa

    !pb

    qpbqpba

    dpbada

    qpbqa

    !pa 0:

    In our symmetric environment, this expression reduces to

    a coqQ

    qp

    t coqY

    qp

    0 11

    rearranging

    a co t cor

    Z

    Y

    Q: 12

    Where t is the interconnection charge between host and target countries.26 By

    construction, the trafc ow between the host country C and target country i is

    IMPACT OF ``CALLBACK'' COMPETITION 39

  • 7/31/2019 On the Impact of Call-Back Competition on International Telephony

    20/21

    unbalanced. Then, as we saw before, the negotiated accounting rate between the host

    carrierC and the target carrier i is set above the cost of interconnection: t4co; given that

    CB calls and standard calls are substitutes r40, it follows from expression (12) thata4co.

    Without CB, Y 0 and therefore a co. This proves the proposition.27

    &

    Proof of Corollary 1: Without CB, the price for a standard call between A and B is the

    monopolistic price pM. Instead, from expression (6), the price for the same call when CB

    rms are in the market is

    p c co a co t corY

    Q !Z

    Z 1

    using expression (12), then p4pM if

    t corY

    Q

    Z 1

    Z 140

    which is always satised for t co40. &

    Proof of Corollary 2. When y 0, (8) becomes:

    pc co t

    pc

    1

    Z

    1 2e YQc

    1 2 eZ

    YQc

    : 13

    Without CB, the monopolist sets the standard mark-up 1=Z, which is clearly smaller than(13).

    Fory 1, (8) becomes:

    pc cc t

    pc

    1

    Z

    1 2 YQc

    1 2 eZ

    YQc

    14

    which, fore4Z, is always lower than the mark-up without CB. &

    26 Recall that, given the symmetry of the game, at the solution ta tb.27 To guarantee the existence of an internal equilibrium Y40, we implicitly assume that CB rms enjoy a

    price discount y, such that there is always room for CB services. In reality the presence of competition in

    the host country, which we do not model here, justies this assumption. Competition has two effects: on

    the one hand it implies lower prices for standard calls in the host country thus providing bigger arbitrage

    opportunities; on the other hand, it induces carriers in country C to compete for rerouted trafc (namely,

    by offering greater volume discounts). This additional form of competition drives down further the price

    charged to CB companies, hence reducing their marginal cost.

    40 FABIO M. MANENTI

  • 7/31/2019 On the Impact of Call-Back Competition on International Telephony

    21/21

    References

    Alleman, J. 1998. ``International Settlements: An Analysis of Rates.'' University of Colorado & Hagler Bailly

    Consulting. Paper presented at the 1998 EARIE Conference in Copenhagen.

    Armstrong, M. 1998. ``Network Interconnection in Telecommunications.'' Economic Journal 108: 545564.

    Carter, M., and J. Wright. 1994. ``Symbiotic Production: The Case of Telecommunication Pricing.'' Review of

    Industrial Organization 9: 365378.

    Carter, M. and J. Wright. 1999. ``Interconnection in Network Industries.'' Review of Industrial Organization 14:

    125.

    Choi, H. W., K. L. Yun, I. J. Kim, and B. H. Ahn. 1999. ``On the Economics of Call-Back Services.'' Journal of

    Regulatory Economics 15: 165181.

    De Fraja, G., and P. Valbonesi. 2001. ``Revenue Sharing Rules for International Telephony.'' Journal of

    Regulatory Economics 20: 120.

    Frieden, R. M. 1997. ``The Impact of Call-Back and Arbitrage on the Accounting Rate Regime.''Telecommunications Policy 21: 819827.

    ITU. 1996. Direction of TrafcTrends in International Telephone Tariffs. Geneva: ITU Press.

    ITU. 1999. Direction of TrafcTrends in International Telephone Tariffs. Geneva: ITU Press.

    Kelly, T. 1996. ``Call-Back, Cash-Back?'' Global Telecoms Business. August/September 1996 edition.

    Laffont, J. J., P. Rey, and J. Tirole. 1998a. ``Network Competition: I. Overview and Nondiscriminatory Pricing.''

    Rand Journal of Economics 29: 137.

    Laffont, J. J., P. Rey, and J. Tirole. 1998b. ``Network Competition: II. Price Discrimination.'' Rand Journal of

    Economics 29: 3856.

    Lande, J., and L. Blake. 1997. ``Trends in the U.S. International Telecommunications Industry.'' Report of the

    Federal Communications Commission.

    Manenti, F. M. 1997. ``The Reciprocal Accounting Rate Regime and the Impact of Call-Back on International

    Telephony.'' University of Brescia, Discussion Paper n. 9713, December 1997.

    Manenti, F. M. 2000. The Demand for International Telecommunications in Italy. Mimeo: University of Padua.

    Nye, S. 1999. ``Call-Back Patents Yields Slim Pickings.'' Communications Week 25 October 1999.

    OECD. 1995. ``Rele and Alternate Calling Procedures: Their Impact on Accounting Rates and CollectionCharges.'' OECDCommittee for Information, Computer and Communications Policy.

    OECD. 1997. ``New Technologies and Their Impact on the Accounting Rate System.'' OECDCommittee for

    Information, Computer and Communications Policy.

    Propp, K. R. 1996. ``The Eroding Structure of International Telecommunications Regulation: The Challenge of

    Call-Back Services.'' Harvard International Law Journal 37: 493520.

    Wright, J. 1999. ``International Telecommunications, Settlement Rates and the FCC.'' Journal of Regulatory

    Economics 15: 267291.

    IMPACT OF ``CALLBACK'' COMPETITION 41