On the existence of price equilibria in dynamic economies

20
JOURNAL OF ECONOMIC THEORY 4, 281-300 (1988) On the Existence Price Equilibria in Dynamic JONATHAN BURKE Department of Economics, Texas A&M University, College Station, Texas 77843 Received November 4, 1985; revised August 22, 1986 I extend McKenzie’s general characterization of the existence of competitive equilibria in static (finite horizon) models to a class of dynamic (infinite horizon) economies that subsumes overlapping-generations as a special case. With a few necessary exceptions, the assumptions employed in my existence proof are natural extensions of McKenzie%. In particular, I strengthen the existing literature by imposing McKenzie-type irreducibility only on the whole economy and not on certain (artificial) sub-economies and by imposing McKenzie’s weak continuity and convexity conditions. I also establish the general existence of equilibria with nominal government surplus. Journal of Economic Literature Classification Num- bers: 021, 023, 111. 0 1988 Academic PKSS, IX. 1. INTRODUCTION Perhaps the fundamental problem in the study of competitive markets is to characterize the conditions under which price equilibria exist. For years, classification attempts were restricted to static models; that is, mo involving only finite numbers of agents and goods and, hence, presuppos- ing the existence of some (arbitrary) terminal date. Recently, however, many find that in order to explain some basic market phenomena, such as the use of fiat (unbacked) money in an economy with fully informed and rational agents, one must pass to genuinely dynamic models; precisely, models such as overlapping-generations that involve a double infinity of agents and (dated) goods. Only recently has a charac- terization of those economies with price equilibria been attempted in dynamic setting. I strengthen this foundation both by weakening t assumptions known to guarantee the existence of equilibria and by uncovering, via counter-examples, previously unknown conditions that are essential to the existence of price equilibria. The early competitive equilibrium existence theorems of Arrow an * This paper is a revision of part of the first chapter of my Ph. D. thesis, submitted to in May 1985. I thank Tim Kehoe for stimulating my initial interest in dynamic economies. I thank both Tim and Eric Maskin for their valuable encouragement. 281 2%0531/88 $3.CKl Copyright Q 1988 by Academic Press, Inc. All rights of reproduction in any form reserved.

Transcript of On the existence of price equilibria in dynamic economies

Page 1: On the existence of price equilibria in dynamic economies

JOURNAL OF ECONOMIC THEORY 4, 281-300 (1988)

On the Existence Price Equilibria in Dynamic

JONATHAN BURKE

Department of Economics, Texas A&M University, College Station, Texas 77843

Received November 4, 1985; revised August 22, 1986

I extend McKenzie’s general characterization of the existence of competitive equilibria in static (finite horizon) models to a class of dynamic (infinite horizon) economies that subsumes overlapping-generations as a special case. With a few necessary exceptions, the assumptions employed in my existence proof are natural extensions of McKenzie%. In particular, I strengthen the existing literature by imposing McKenzie-type irreducibility only on the whole economy and not on certain (artificial) sub-economies and by imposing McKenzie’s weak continuity and convexity conditions. I also establish the general existence of equilibria with nominal government surplus. Journal of Economic Literature Classification Num- bers: 021, 023, 111. 0 1988 Academic PKSS, IX.

1. INTRODUCTION

Perhaps the fundamental problem in the study of competitive markets is to characterize the conditions under which price equilibria exist. For years, classification attempts were restricted to static models; that is, mo involving only finite numbers of agents and goods and, hence, presuppos- ing the existence of some (arbitrary) terminal date.

Recently, however, many find that in order to explain some basic market phenomena, such as the use of fiat (unbacked) money in an economy with fully informed and rational agents, one must pass to genuinely dynamic models; precisely, models such as overlapping-generations that involve a double infinity of agents and (dated) goods. Only recently has a charac- terization of those economies with price equilibria been attempted in dynamic setting. I strengthen this foundation both by weakening t assumptions known to guarantee the existence of equilibria and by uncovering, via counter-examples, previously unknown conditions that are essential to the existence of price equilibria.

The early competitive equilibrium existence theorems of Arrow an

* This paper is a revision of part of the first chapter of my Ph. D. thesis, submitted to in May 1985. I thank Tim Kehoe for stimulating my initial interest in dynamic economies. I thank both Tim and Eric Maskin for their valuable encouragement.

281 2%0531/88 $3.CKl

Copyright Q 1988 by Academic Press, Inc. All rights of reproduction in any form reserved.

Page 2: On the existence of price equilibria in dynamic economies

282 JONATHAN BURKE

Debreu [l], McKenzie [ll], and Nikaido [ 14]-for static models-were refined over the years as the assumptions needed to guarantee existence were successively weakened. McKenzie [12] provides a review of this line of research as well as, what appears to be, the minimal (weakest) set of suf- ficient conditions known to date. For dynamic models, Balasko et al. [2] provide an existence theorem for overlapping-generations economies that is generalized by Wilson [lS] to allow both weaker regularity assumptions and a more general demographic structure.

One of the assumptions employed in the proofs of Balasko et al. and Wilson that has no natural counterpart in McKenzie is their irreducibility condition. Not only do they impose McKenzie’s irreducibility condition on the entire economy, but they require the existence of a certain collection of finite sub-economies each of which is irreducible. In this paper, I reline their proof techniques to eliminate the need for this unnatural sub-economy irreducibility assumption. r In addition, I weaken their continuity and convexity restrictions on preferences to the point that they are analogous to McKenzie’s.

I follow Wilson Cl.51 and require the consumption spaces of infinitely lived agents to consist of all non-negative bundles (vectors). This assumption is stronger than in McKenzie’s static model, where con- sumption spaces are arbitrary closed and convex collections of non- negative bundles. However, I provide a counter-example demonstrating that existence is no longer guaranteed when one considers arbitrary closed and convex sets for infinitely lived agents-even in the presence of an additional free disposal condition.

Finally, I adopt the requirement-implicit in Balasko et al. [2] and essential to Wilson [15]-that there be only a finite number of agents desiring (having tastes for) any particular good.2 Again, I provide a counter-example demonstrating the necessity of such a restriction.

I turn my attention next to establishing equilibria with income transfers. This classic problem, as posed by Hahn [9] and later examined by Cass and Yaari [S] among (many) others, concerns equilibria in which agents receive positive transfers (fiat money). However, as is now well known and as my Proposition 5 reiterates, the existence of equilibria with positive transfers is not robust even to variations in endowment streams; in par- ticular, a Pareto efficient autarkic distribution rules out positive transfer equilibria. In contrast, my Proposition 6 establishes the general abundance of equilibria with negative income transfers (taxes).

1 Burke [3] provides an example of an economy satisfying all my restrictions but not sub- economy irreducibility.

z This restriction was not brought out in Wilson [15].

Page 3: On the existence of price equilibria in dynamic economies

EXISTENCE OF PRICE EQUILIBRIA

In this paper, I characterize the existence of both competitive an taxation equilibria for a class of dynamic economies that subsume overla ping-generations as a special case. In Section 2, I introduce my general model with its definitions and assumptions. In Section 3, I establish the compactness of equilibrium prices and allocations. In Section 4, I use compactness to establish the general existence of competitive equilibria. In Section 5, I demonstrate by way of counter-examples that my restrictions-when stronger than those employed in static models- are necessarily so. In Section 6, I return to my compactness result to establish the general existence of equilibria with negative income transfers.

For reference, I extend the techniques developed here to dynamic production economies in Burke [4].

2. THE MODEL

I begin with the standard formulation of a pure exchange economy modified to accommodate an infinite number of agents and goods as in Wilson [ 151. Let A be a countable set of agents and, for each agent o! E A, let Xa be his consumption set, ( > )* his preference relation over bundles in X”, and c# his endowment. The set of commodities is countably i~~~ite being indexed by the natural numbers. In the context of overlapping- generations, there are a finite number of (dated) commodities available in each of an infinite number of time periods.

I say that agent a does not desire good y when for any bundles

i”v 1 > ..-> xY, . ..). (y, ,..., yr, . ..)EXa. (vi, . . . . yy ,...) (>)” (x,, . . ..O. . ..) implies 1 i . . . . Yy, -1 ( > Y (Xl 7 .a-> $3 ..a ). An allocation scheme is an array (x”)

such that xa~ Xa for a E A. For convenience, I only allow agents to con- sume goods they desire.3 The collection of such schemes is thus

XE (x’)E n X”:foraeA andy> 1, i CttA

x; = 0 if agent a does not desire goo (19

Assumptions (2)-(lo), below, are employed throughout this paper. ith the exceptions of (2) and (7), they are analogous (or can be weakened to be analoguous) to those of McKenzie [12]. Each of my assumptions are at least as weak as those of Wilson [15]; which are, in turn, at least as wea as those of Balasko et al. [2].

3 Clearly, given free disposal, restricting agents to consume only goods they desire may be satisfied in any equilibrium by resuffuling allocations of free goods.

Page 4: On the existence of price equilibria in dynamic economies

284 JONATHAN BURKE

ASSUMPTION (regularity of consumption sets). For each a E A:4

X@=RT (2)

COa E xa. (3)

It may be somewhat surprising but, as I demonstrate by Example 1, (2) cannot be replaced by x” being a closed and convex subset of RT satisfying free disposal; that is, x E X’ and y 2 x imply y E X”.

I have developed an equilibrium existence proof that does not employ the survival assumption (3) but will not present it here due to its com- plexity.

For SEA and XEP, let P”(x)={y~X~:y(>)‘x} and P:r(x)= {yEXO”:X(>yy). P”( x are the bundles that agent CI prefers to x while ) PCl(x) are those to which x is preferred.

N.B. All subsets of R” are endowed with the product topology.5

ASSUMPTION (regularity of preferences). For each c( E A and x E 1”:

P”(x) and PFl(x) are both open relative to X” (4)

x 4 convex hull of P*(x). (5)

Assumption (4) is a slightly stronger continuity requirement than that imposed by McKenzie [12] for static economies but is weaker than the continuity condition employed in Wilson’s existence proof for dynamic economies.’ For infinitely lived agents, (4) requires intertemporal discoun- ting. For example, if preferences are represented by the weighted sum of instantaneous utilities C,, r (1 + S)-? u(xy), then (4) requires that the dis- count rate S be positive.7 Assumption (5) is the (clearly minimal) convexity condition imposed by McKenzie [12] and is weaker than Wilson’s convexity conditions.8

4 I adopt the vector notation x > y if xy > y, for y 2 1 and x % y if xy > y, for y > 1. Given thisnotation,Idefine Ry = {xER~: x>O)and R~+={n~R":x%0}.

5 See Munkres [13, p. 1131 for a definition of the product topology. In particular, con- vergence X(K) *x in R" means pointwise convergence X?(K) T. xy for y > 1.

6 Specifically, McKenzie weakens P:,(x) being relatively open at. all xox” to the correspondence P”( .) being lower hemi-continuous. My techniques do allow me to employ a restricted (but unnatural) form of lower hemi-continuity in place of the openess of P”r(x). Wilson employs the openness of the graph of P.( .) in Wilson [IS, p. 103, line 171.

’ For -1 <:S ~0, one may employ the Weizdcker overtaking criterion to induce a preference relation.

s Wilson employs the additional convexity condition: if y E P(x), then ly + (1 -L)xo P*(x) for 0<1<1.

Page 5: On the existence of price equilibria in dynamic economies

EXISTENCE OF PRICE EQUILIBRIA 285

ASSUMPTION (free disposal in preferences). FM all 01 E A and x, y E %“;

x 3 y implies P”(x) c_ P”(y) and PY 1( y) C P? I(x).

ASSUMPTIQN (finite number of consumers per goo

Ckly a finite number of agents desire any particular good. (71

If commodities are dated, then (7) is satisfied when the po~~iat~o~ of agents is finite at every point in time. In Example 2, I demonstrate tha essential to impose a condition like (7) to insure the existence of petitive equilibria. Technically, while (2) guarantees that indi demand is continuous, (7) insures that continuity is passed over to aggregate demand.9

I assume that the total endowment of each good is finite and define w = U‘TA ma to be aggregate endowment of the economy. An allocation scheme

(2) E X is called feasible if C, E A xa = o.

ASSUMPTION (positive aggregate endowments).

0 9 0. (8)

While the (free disposal) assumption (6) allows me to restrict attention to non-negative prices, (8) insures that prices are finite in an equilibriums

ASSUMPTION (irreducibility of the entire economy). For any partition of A into two non-empty subsets A0 and A’ and any feasible allocation (x’) E .X3 there is an agent p E A” such that

xp+ 1 wy>)bx? aeA”

As previously mentioned, my analysis differs from that of Balasko et aP. 121 and Wilson [15] in that the above irreducibility condition is impose only on the full economy.

For x = (x1, . ..) define x2, = (x,, . . . . x,, 0, . ..). for y 2 1. One immediate implication of (2) and (9) is that demand is ~nsatiab~e~

precisely, x E X” and x < w imply x + y ( > )” x for some y E R”. one may then infer from (4) that, for a E A, there is a y(a) < CO su

xEXaandx<oimplyx+~,~,,(>)“x,forsomey~

In words, agent a’s preferences for goods I, . . . . y(a) are insatiable. To establish Proposition 2, I strengthen this implication.

9 The potential problem being that an infinite sum of arbitrary upper hemi-continuous corresponds need not be upper hemi-continuous.

Page 6: On the existence of price equilibria in dynamic economies

286 JONATHAN BURKE

ASSUMPTION (local non-satiation).” For a EA, there is a y(a) < cc such that, for E > 0,

XE Xa and x d o imply x + ~7~~~) (> )a~, for some y E R” with

II ,i)y@) II < E. (10)

A price system for the economy is a vector p = (pl, . ..). where pv denotes the price of good y 3 1. Given prices p 2 0 and income I> 0, agent a’s market demand correspondence is defined by

d*(p, I)= {xEXOL: p.x<landp.z> ZforzEPa(x)). (11)

Following Debreu [6], I employ bounded (pseudo) demand correspon- dences in my equilibrium existence proofs of Propositions 2 and 3. These pseudo correspondences correspond to market demand when consumption sets are particular bounded subsets of Ry. Specifically, for K 2 1,

B,= fi [O,K*O] (12) y=l

d;(p, I)=(xEB,:P .x<Iandp.z>Iforz~(F’~(x)nBJ}. (13)

Given demand and pseudo demand correspondences, I specify three types of price-allocation solutions for the economy.

A rc-solution consists of price system pb 0 and an allocation scheme (x”) E X satisfying, for a E A:

p.x”<co

p.o”< a3

xa E d;(p, p . x”).

(14)

A transfer equilibrium consists of a price system p > 0 and an allocation scheme (xa) E X satisfying, for LX E A:”

p-xa<co

p-of<<

xa E d”(p, p . x”) (15)

lo As usual, local non-satiation follows from non-satiation when preferences are convex (JJEP’(x) and O-CA< 1 imply ,Iy+(l -I)xoP”(x)), as assumed in [lS].

‘I The fact that I may guarantee finite expenditures and finite wealth in equilibrium follows from the discounting induced by the continuity of infinite dimensional preferences (4). It remains to be seen if such discounting can be dropped and the general existence of equilibria be meaningfully established with finite or infinite personal expenditure and wealth.

Page 7: On the existence of price equilibria in dynamic economies

EXISTENCE OF PRICE EQUILIBRIA 287

A competitive equilibrium is a transfer equilibrium where, for a E A,

p.xa=p.oIa. (161

The rc-solutions are merely employed in an intermediate step in the proof of the existence of transfer equilibria in Proposition 2. The transfer equilibria are those that can be supported through competitive markets after a (lump-sum) redistribution of income. As usual, competitive equilibria are those that can attain through competitive markets without governmenta intervention.

3. COMPACTNESS OF TRANSFER ALLOCATIONS

PROPOSITION 1 (compactness of certain collections of rc-solutions). FOP. any collection of positive scalars (Oa),EA, any sequence of pairs ((pi (P(K)))) satisfying

p(K) and (x”(K)) are a K-solution, for kc2 1, (17)

p(K) .Xa*(K) = 1, for K > 1 and some designated a* E A

P(K). Xa(K) 2 Wp(rc) . Coa, fork> 1 unduEA (191

hUS a limit point, i.e., (P(K), (X’(K))) * (p, (CC’)), for some subsequence. Furthermore, the limit (p, (x”)) is a transfer equilibrium and p(K) . X”l(K) * p. xa, for CI E A.

Before establishing Proposition 1, I state a corollary that is useful in proving Propositions 3 and 6. The corollary follows immediately from t simple observation that transfer equilibria constitute rc-solutions for any K> 1.

COROLLARY 1 (compactness of transfer equilibria). For any collection of positive scalars (0”) a E A; the transfer equilibria (p, (xx)) satisfying

p . x”* = 1, for some designated CI* E A

p~x”>O”p~w” for a.eA

constitute a (sequentially)‘* compact subset of Ry xX.

I2 Since the product topology on R” is me&able (consider the metric d(x, y) E

x72 1 2-y min( (x7 - y, 1, 1 }), compactness is equivalent to sequential compactness Mu&es [13, p. 1811.

Page 8: On the existence of price equilibria in dynamic economies

288 JONATHAN BURKE

Proof of Proposition 1. Consider any such sequence of rc-solutions. The Cantor diagonalization process insures that, for some subsequence {(P(G (X%)))L

for CI E A and y 3 1, either (X;(K)} converges to a finite limit or it diverges to infinity as K * cc (23)

for CI, /? E A such that p(x) * x@(rc) 3 0 for large JC, either {P(d .X”(~)lP(~) .x%4> converges to a finite limit or it diverges to infinity as K * cc (24)

for y 3 1, either {P,(K)} converges to a finite limit or it diverges to infinity as IC * co. (25)

I now establish that each of the sequences in (23)-(25) actually converges. Condition (20) implies lim sup,, co x;(x) < c+ < co. In particular, X;(JC)

does not diverge to infinity as K + co. Condition (23) then implies, for CIEA,

xoL(rc) * xa (pointwise convergence), for some xa > 0. (26)

Equation (1) applied to each allocation (x~(K)) E X, together with (7), (20), and (26), yields13

(27)

To guarantee that the sequence in (24) converges, I establish that, for every a and B E A such that P(K) . xB(rc) > 0 for large K,

{P(K) . x’(Ic)/~(K) . X~(IC) > does not converge to 0. (28)

Condition (24) implies that A may be partitioned into two sets

A0 = {LX E A: {P(K) .x”(K)/~(K) +xp(rc)) converges to 0}

I3 Without assumption (7) one could merely conclude CaE A x” Q UJ since, in general, I2 apAxm<liminf,,,~:,,A X”(K) =o. This is the reason I impose (7) and restrict x,“=O unless agent GL desires good y in the definition (1) of the space of allocations X.

Page 9: On the existence of price equilibria in dynamic economies

EXISTENCE OF PRICE EQUILIBRIA 28

and

A’= (aeA: (p(~).x”(~)/p(~).x~(~)~ either

converges to a positive limit or diverges to infinity).

Clearly BEA’ and-assuming (28) is violated--d’ is also non-empty. Hence, irreducibility (9) may be applied to A’, A’ and the ~irnit~~~ allocation (x=)-since it satisfies (27)-to yield an agent 8’ E A’ satisfying

,I?’ + c Wa (> )P’ xP’. Ci6.40

Continuity (4) then implies that there is a A< 1, integer y 2 1, and a finite subset Ai c A* satisfying AZyB’ f C,, Ao, c# ( > )B’ xp’. Again, (4) yields

E,p’ -I- c ma ( > )P’ xqc), atA?

for large K. (29)

Clearly, definition (12) implies XI!;’ + CaeAi wx E B,, for large K. Tberef~re, X”‘(K) E @‘(P(K), P(K). X@‘(K)), (13) and (29) imply

Fix a 1 E (A, 1). Convergence (26) implies Aa{ G A’x+‘(K), for large K. (30) this implies

Therefore,

where the first inequality follows from (31), the second from (19) and t finiteness of At and the equality from the definition of A” (recall At c A’). But, this contradicts @’ E A’.

Page 10: On the existence of price equilibria in dynamic economies

290 JONATHAN BURKE

The above paragraph establishes (28). Clearly (28) implies that the sequences in (24) converge to a positive limit; to show that such sequences do not diverge to infinity, reverse the indices CI and p and apply (28). Therefore, for LX E A, applying positive convergence (24) to CI and /3 equal to the a* designated in (18) yields

(p(ic) . xa(,)} converges to a positive limit. (32)

Assumption (8) and (27) imply that, for any y z 1, there is an a E A such that x;> 0. But, (32) implies that {p,(rc) -a$(~)}~~~ is bounded. Hence, convergence (26) implies that (J+,(K)),> i is bounded. By (25), this guarantees

P(K) * PY for some p 2 0. (33)

I now establish, for a E A,

Since P(K), X’(K) 20; convergence (26) and (33) imply p .x”< lim k=e-oo P(K) -x”(lc)-that is, xa is affordable given prices p and income Pm,+. m P(K) .X’(K)]. Hence, assuming (34) fails, (11) implies that there is some alternative y E x” that is both preferred y (> )” xoL and affordable p-y4 Wm.,, P(K) -X’(K)]. Continuity (4) and positive convergence (32) then imply that for some R < 1 and integer y > 1,

np, (>)“XN (35)

and

Ap.$, < [ lim p(rc)~x”(~)J. K==-cc (36)

But, for large IC, continuity (4) and (35) imply

n.9, t > )” XYK),

convergence (33) and (36) imply

and definition (12) implies

Page 11: On the existence of price equilibria in dynamic economies

EXISTENCE OF PRICE EQUILIBRIA 291

But, the above three expressions contradict definition (13) of X”(K) E d”,(P(K), P(K) .-qK)).

The above paragraph establishes (34). Local non-satiation (IQ) and (34) then imply p . xa = lim, =I o. P(K) .Y(K), for LXEA. Properties (27), (32), (34), and the above equality imply that (p, X) is a transfer equilibrium (see (15)) provided that p . ma < 00, for a E A. But, hypothesis (19) and con- vergence (33) imply

4. EXISTENCE OF COMPETITITVE EQUILIBRIA

In this section, I establish the general existence of competitive equilibria for dynamic economies. Following Balasko et al. [2] and Wilson [15], I find an equilibrium for the full (infinite) economy to be a limit point of equilibria from a sequence of truncated (finite) sub-economies. (The existence of this limit follows from Proposition 1.) In order to em classical results guaranteeing the existence of equilibria for each of the truncated sub-economies, Balasko et al. and Wilson require that each sub- economy be irreducible.

In this paper, I eliminate the need for sub-economy irreducibility assumptions-which, as usual, are imposed to guarantee that each agent has a positive income. My procedure is to apply the above truncation method to first establish existence in the special case of agents having positive endowments of all goods-the positiveness of endowments com- bined with local non-satiation (10) insures the irreducibility of the sub- economies. I then establish existence for my generaI model by perturbing endowments to be positive, applying my special existence result for economies with positive endowments, and then shrinking the perturbations to zero (fast enough) so that the limit of the perturbed-economy equilibria is a competitive equilibrium for the original (unperturbed) economy.

~RoPo§ITIoN 2 (existence when endowments are positive). SJ

for all LX E A and, for some a* E A and E > 0,

then the economy has a competitive equilibrium.

Page 12: On the existence of price equilibria in dynamic economies

292 JONATHAN BURKE

I establish Proposition 2 employing only well-known results for finite economies.

ProoJ For convenience index agents by A = { 1,2, . ..} in such a way that the y(a) defined in (10) are ordered-that is,

Y(a)GY(a+l) for a = 1,2, . . . . (39)

Fix any IC = 1, 2, . . . . Form a K-truncated economy consisting of agents 1 2 . . . . K and goods 1, . . . . y-where 7~ Y(K). For ct < JC, agent a has the consumption space B, = n$= r [0, ‘CXJQ] with a preference relation over bundles (xi, . . . . x7) and (vi, . . . . v,-) E B, defined by

(x 1 > . . . . xy) is prefered to ( y, , . . . . y?)

* (Xl 2 ..*, $2 fqi+ 1, . ..) ( > )” (VI, ..a, y,, Jqr, 1, . ..). (40)

where (> )” is the preference relation of agent a E A in the original economy.

I extend every price system p = (pl, . . . . p,-) for the truncated economy to the system (pl, . . . . pv, 0, . ..) for the original economy. By free disposal (6) and (40), demand 2( .) in the truncated economy is related to pseudo demand e( .bsee (12) and (13kin the original economy by

qp, I) = ((X,) . ..) xv) E B,:

(x 1, . . . . xy, =++I, . ..)EdZ((PI. . ..) py,o, . ..). I)}. (41)

Finally, define truncated endowments W’ = (WY, . . . . ~9) for a < IC. One may readily verify that the rc-truncated economy inherits all of the

properties (2)-(10) of the original economy described Section 2; in par- ticular, irreducibility (9) follows from (37) and the local insatiability of preferences for goods, 1, . . . . jj implied by (lo), (39) and (40). Therefore, I may invoke classical results (e.g., Gale and Mas-Cole11 [7, 81, Mas-Cole11 [lo], or McKenzie [12]) to establish the existence of a competitive equilibrium for the truncated economy.

Let p E RY, (p # 0) denote the (truncated) equilibrium prices and X” E B, the consumption bundle of agent a < IC. That is,

for agents a = 1, . . . . IC (42)

for goods y = 1, . . . . j?. (43)

Page 13: On the existence of price equilibria in dynamic economies

EXISTENCE OF PRICE EQUILIBRIA 293

I define a x-solution (p(x), (P(K))) for the full economy from the above competitive equilibrium for the K-truncated economy by

P(K) = (Pl, . . . . &, 0, .-)

XU(K) = (XY, . ..) “$, KU?, 1, .‘.), for 01 = I, . ..) K (451

XyK) = KO, for a=~+ 1, . . . .

Technically, I restrict X;(K) = 0 unless agent a desires good y in (45) an (46) so that (xa(x)) is a legitimate allocation scheme-see (1). One verify from (5), (6), (12)-(14), and (41)(46) that (p(x), (Y(rc))) is indee a K-solution.

I now allow IC to vary. (37), (42) and p(lc)#O imply P(K) .X”(K) >O for every K. Hence, I may innocuously normalize prices by p .X’(K) = l-see (18). The construction of every (p(K), (x*(K)))-see especially (42)-(46)-w&h (7) implies that the sequence of HP(J4 w(~)))> 1 a so satisfies (19) and (20) of proposition I for parameters Oa = 1, for a E A. Hence, there is a subsequence that converges to a transfer equilibrium (p, (x’))-that is, as K* 00,

P(K) - P and

roposition 1 also implies, for a E: A,

p(K) .Xa(K) =a p .X1.

Local non-satiation (lo), (42), and (44) imply

P(K). XyK) = P(K). co=

(481

(49)

for a! < ic. Convergence (47) implies p . wc( d lim inf, 3 53 P(K). w’; hence, (48) and (49) imply, for SEA,

Applying (15~specifically, p . x”* <a-and (38) and (50) to the CY* of (38), yields

p.o< co. (51)

Since CUEA x0( = C,, A 0.9 = CO, (51) implies that both Cal B A p. ma are convergent and equal to p . o. Hence,

o= c p-x”- c pa d= c (p.x3(-p.d), CZtA CiEA 3EA

Page 14: On the existence of price equilibria in dynamic economies

294 JONATHANBURKE

which, by (50), implies p . xa = p . aa, for every a E A. Since it satisfies (16) the transfer equilibrium (p, (x”)) is also a competitive equilibrium for the full economy. Q.E.D.

The following existence results strengthen Theorems 1 and 2 of Wilson [ 151 in that weaker regularity conditions and no sub-economy irreducibility conditions are imposed.

PROPOSITION 3 (general existence of equilibria with minimal transfers). There is a transfer equilibrium satisfying, for each CI E A:

p*x”>p*o” (52)

p.xU=p.& if 0,” > 0 for only a finite number of goods y. (53)

PROPOSITION 4 (existence of competitive equilibria in special cases). If either

for each CI E A, co,” > 0 for only a finite number of goods y, (54)

or there is a finite subset of agents A’ s A and E > 0 satisfying

c ua>&-u, (55) EEA’

then a competitive equilibrium exists.

Wilson [ 151 provides a counter-example demonstrating that if both (54) and (55) are violated, then the economy need not have competitive equilibria-only transfer equilibria as described in Proposition 3.

Proof of Proposition 4 (given Proposition 3). Consider the transfer equilibrium (p, (x”)) generated by Proposition 3.

If (54) holds, then (16) and (53) assert that (p, (x”)) is a competitive equilibrium. If (55) holds, then (15) implies p .CIJ < (l/s) CasA, p . eY < 00, since A’ is finite. As in the previous proof, p . w < cc and (52) imply p . xoL = p .eY, for a E A; hence, by (16), (p, (x”)) is a competitive equilibrium.

Q.E.D.

Proof of Proposition 3. Let Pti2 E Ry denote the collection of price systems corresponding to transfer equilibria satisfying (21) and (22) with parameters 0” = l/2, for CI E A. Corollary 1 implies that P1j2 is compact; hence, bounded. Let p E Ry be an upper bound; that is,

P G P, for p E P1/2.

Choose p* E Ry + to satisfy

p.p*<co.

(56)

(57)

Page 15: On the existence of price equilibria in dynamic economies

EXISTENCE OF PRICE EQUILIBRIA 295

Choose an array (a’) of consumption vectors-.? E X”, for c( E A-to satisfy

Assumption (8) insures that p* and the E’ may be chosen so that the E’ are small enough to satisfy

0 < ECI < d, for MEA. (59)

Let A= (1,2 ,... >. For rc=4, 5 ,...; form the K-perturbed economy by redistributing endowments from (0’) to (O’(K)), where

flf(k-) = (1 - K1)eJZ + K-1(2-‘“p* -EY),

Wa(K)=(l----)Oa+IC~1(2-~p*-&~)f~---IO) for a=K. (64)

Indeed, (W”(K)) is merely a redistribution of resources inasmuch as (58) (60), and (61) imply

Clearly, p* $0 and (59)-(61) imply that (W=(K)) distributes positive endowments (37) while (59) and (61) imply that (38) is satisfied for TX* = K and E = K-I. Hence, Proposition 2 establishes the existence of a competitive equilibrium (p(x), (X’(K))) for the K-perturbed economy. In particular, (1 yields for 01 E A,

p(K) ~ Xx(K) = p(K). d(K). ($31

Consider the sequence {(P(K), (x~(K)))). Equation (62) implies that the competitive equilibria of the perturbed economies constitute transfer equilibria of the original (unperturbed) economy. By standard arguments, (9) implies p(ic) . of(~) > 0, f or a E A; hence, (21) is an innocuous nor- malization of prices p(x). By inspection, (59)-(61) imply ma(~) >/ (l/2)0”, for aeA and K 24. Hence, (63) guarantees that (22) is also satisfied given parameters 0” = l/2, for a E A. Therefore, Corollary 1 implies that, for some subsequences of equilibria ((p(rc), (X’(K)))},

(P(~)> W(~))) * (P: WY)

and, for o[ E A, Proposition 1 implies

p(Ic) * x=(K) * p . xa,

where (p, (x*)) is some transfer equilibrium of the original economy.

642/44:2-6

Page 16: On the existence of price equilibria in dynamic economies

296 JONATHANBURKE

Since every p(x) E P1j2, (56) implies R(K) < p. Equations (57) and (58) then imply (I . (2-“p* - sa)( < p .p* < GO. In particular,

K-‘P(K) .(2-“p*-&“)*o, as rc*co.

Equation (60) then implies, for CIEA,

lim inf p(lc) . O’(K) K=e-cc

=liminf(l-Ic-‘)p(K).&+ lim K-‘~(Ic).(~-“~*--E~) K=c-cc lc*cn

= lim inf p(rc) . UP. K’Q)

Therefore, by (63) and (65),

p . xa = lim inf p(x) . CD”, K=scc

This equality yields (52) and (53) since, in general, convergence (64) implies p . ua < lim inf, ~ a, p(x) . ma and, if CI$ > 0 for only a finite number of y, (64) implies p . O’ = lim inf, ~ m I . UP. Q.E.D.

5. NECESSITY OF NON-STANDARD ASSUMPTIONS

Example 1 demonstrates the need for a regularity restriction on con- sumption spaces of infinitely lived agents in addition to standard closeness and convexity conditions. Specifically, I present an economy satisfying all the hypotheses of Section 2 with the single exception that the consumption set A’” of one of the infinitely lived agents is not Ry-as asserted in (2)-but rather a particular closed and convex subset of Ry. (The set x” also satisfies the free disposal condition: XEX” and y >x imply VEX’.) Nevertheless, the economy exhibits no equilibria with non-negative transfers as described in Proposition 3. One should therefore view the requirement of consumption spaces to consist of all non-negative bundles not as a mere convenience but the embodiment of an essential non-standard regularity condition on infinitely lived agents.

In example 2, I demonstrate the necessity of (7), which limits the number of agents desiring any particular good to be finite. Specifically, I present an economy of finitely lived agents satisfying all the hypotheses of Section 2 with the single exception that all agents desire one particular good. Nevertheless, the economy has no competitive equilibria as described in Proposition 4.

Page 17: On the existence of price equilibria in dynamic economies

EXISTENCE OF PRICE EQUILIBRIA 297

Although assumption (7) is quite innocuous for dynamic overlapping- generations economies, it may be difficult to incorporate into a general framework that accommodates atomless agents since the latter typically allow every agent to desire every good.

EXAMPLE 1 (necessity of a regularity condition like x” = Ry ). This example requires only two agents, A = (0, 11. Agent 0 has the co~sum~ti~~ set p= (xER~: xy + 2y-3 . (x, - 1) > 0 for y = $4, ~..I, preferences represented by u’(x) = x1, and the endowment w” = (2,2, . . . ). Agent 1 the consumption set x” = RT, preferences represented by u1 (x) = C,, I 4-? .min{x,, 5}, and the endowment o1 = (2,2, . ..).

Assume there is an equilibrium with bob-~egat~.ve transfers, ( p . xa - p . CD”) > 0, for tl E A. Monotonicity implies p $0. arket cleari c tiEA Y = CaeA ma, and x0 E J? imply xi >, 1. p % 0, xs > 1, the definit of x0, and utility maximization by agent 0 imply (x:, x2, xi3 ~..) = (1, 0, 0, . ..). Market clearing, x0 f x1 = (4, 4, 4, . ..). then im (xi, x:, xi, .~.) = (3, 4,4, . ..). In particular, (O,O, 0, . ..) 4 (xi, x:, xi, . ..) +Z (5, 5, 5, . ..) and utility maximization by agent 1 imply (p2, p3, ~..) = p2 0 (1,4CZ, ..-).

A contradiction is now evident in that agent 0 is not maximizing uO(.f by choosing

x0 = (x?, 1, 0, 0, 0, . ..)

since the alternative

y = x’: +fi, 0, 1, 2, 22, -..) ( 2Pl

is preferred ( y1 > x7), in the consumption set 3?, an (p2, p3, . ..) =p2. (1,4-l, . ..) implies

P.Y =plx:+P* .2-l+ f py.2y-3= plx~+p*.(2-i~2-‘)=p.x*. y=3

EXAMPLE 2 (necessity of restricting the number of agents desiring a single good). Index goods by {0, 1, . . . ] and agents by (1,2, . . . >. Agent 013 1 has .T=Ry, preferences represented by u’(x) = x0 + x,, and the endow- ment delined by w; = 1 for y = cx - 1 and c1 with o; = 0 elsewhere. (Note: all agents desire good 0.)

Assume there is a competitive equilibrium. Monot~nicity implies p9

Page 18: On the existence of price equilibria in dynamic economies

298 JONATHANBURKE

p $0 and utility maximization imply x;= 0 unless either y =0 or y = a. Thus, market clearing conditions simplify to

a;l xEf=u;= 1

for good 0 and, for good y 3 1,

(67)

x;=w;+co;+1=2. (68)

Equation (68) allows the budget constraint of agent cr8 1, pox;+pax;= pa _ 1 +poT, to be solved for

G= (Pa-1 -PJPo* (69)

Obviously, the non-negativity of consumption with (69) implies that the price sequence pO, pl, . . . is non-increasing. In particular, p dpO . (1, 1, . ..).

In fact, I can show that the price sequence is constant since if, for some ~12 1, pa <pauI: then p,- r dpO implies p, < pO; which, by utility maximization of agent 0, implies xi = 0; which, by (69), implies per =pa- 1 ; which contradicts p, <pa- r . Therefore, p = pO . (1, 1, . ..).

But, p =pO . (1, 1, . ..) and (69) imply xi = 0 for all agents a; which violates (67). Q.E.D.

6. EXISTENCE OF TAXATION EQUILIBRIA

In this section, I establish first the lack of equilibria with positive income (monetary) transfers and second the abundance of equilibria with negative transfers (taxes). As usual, an allocation scheme (x’) E X is said to be weakly Pareto optimal if there are no alternative schemes ( y”) E X satisfying LA Ya=CcrEA X@ and y’(>)‘x’for UEA.

PROPOSITION 5 (lack of equilibria with positive transfers). If the initial endowment sequence (CO’) E X is weakly Pareto optimal, then there are no equilibria with positive transfers (p . xa - p . CO’) > 0, for CI E A. l4

ProoJ: Suppose (p, (xa)) is such an equilibrium. By the local insatiability of preferences (lo), p . xa > p . o” implies xa ( > )” wc(. But this, along with the market clearing constraint C,, A xa = o = C,, A w”, implies that (ma) is not weakly Pareto optimal. Q.E.D.

l4 If one were to consider transitive preferences (so that a weak relation (2 )” could be deduced), then the concept of strong Pareto optimality is well defined. Given this, one could show that if the initial endowment sequence (of) E X is strongly Pareto optimal, then there are no equilibria with all non-negative transfers (p x’ - p co”) > 0 and at least one positive transfer (p.x”-p.w”)>O.

Page 19: On the existence of price equilibria in dynamic economies

EXISTENCE OF PRICE EQUILIBRIA 299

PROPOSITION 6 (abundance of taxation equilibria). If each agent a has a~ endowment of only a finite number of goods (i.e., o; > 0 for only a finite number of y), then corresponding to any collection of scalars (0”) satisfying 0 < 0” < 1 for CI E A, there is a transfer equilibrium (p, x2) with 0” being the average tax rate imposed on agent a; that is,

p.x”=(l-O”)p.w”>O for EEA.

Note that the abundance of taxation equilibria-like the existence of competitive equilibria-is only guaranteed for finitely endowed agents.

Proof: Let A = { 1, 2, . ..I. Consider any K = 1,2, . . . . Alter the economy by giving the endowments c@(rc) = (1 - W)~r4’ to agents a < K, O’(K) = o” + C”;:: i @%I’ to agent CI = JC, and ma(,) = w’ to agents o! > K.

Clearly, this economy satisfies the assumptions of Proposition 4. there is a competitive equilibrium (P(K), (xX(~))) for the altered economy. In particular, p(ti) .x~(K) = P(K) .c#(Jc) = (1 -S’) P(K) .w’, for Q < K. Note that (p(?c), (Y(K))) constitutes a transfer equilibrium for the original economy since I merely redistributed existing e~dowrne~~s~ t c 121 ma(K) = La 109.

It is a simple matter to verify that the sequence of equilibria i(P(K)Y wwH> sa IS les the hypotheses of corollary 1; hence, the t’ f sequence has a limit point (p, (xX)) that is also a transfer equil Furthermore, Proposition 1 implies P(K) ’ X'(K) a p-l xa as K 3 co. for each 01 E A,

since w; > 0 for only a finite number of goods y.

REFERENCES

1. K. J. ARROW AND G. DEBIWJ, Existence of an equilibrium for a competitive economy, Econometrica 22 (1954), 265-290.

2. Y. BALASKO, D. CASS, AND K. SHELL, Existence of competitive equilibrium in a general overlapping-generations model, J. Econ. Theory 23 (1980), 307-322.

3. J. BURKE, “Essays on Equilibria in Dynamic Economies,” Ph. D. Thesis, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, May 1985.

4. J. BURKE, Equilibria in dynamic production economies, unpublished. 5. D. CAS AND M. YAARI, A re-examination of the pure consumption loans model, J. P&t.

Econ. 74 (1966), 353-367. 6. 6. DEBREU, New concepts and techniques for equilibrium analysis, 1~. Econ. Reu. 3

(1962), 257-273. 7. D. GALE AND A. MAS-COLELL, An equilibrium existence theorem for a general model

without ordered preferences, J. Math. Econ. 2 (1975), 9-15.

Page 20: On the existence of price equilibria in dynamic economies

300 JONATHAN BURKE

8. D. GALE AND A. MAS-COLELL, Corrections to an equilibrium existence theorem for a general model without ordered preferences, J. Math. Econ. 6 (1979), 297-298.

9. F. HAHN, On some problems of proving the existence of an equilibrium in a monetary economy, in “The Theory of Interest Rates” (F. Hahn and F. Breaching, Eds.), MacMillan & Co., London, 1965.

10. A. MAS-COLELL, An equilibrium existence theorem without complete or transitive preferences, J. Math. Econ. 1 (1974), 237-246.

11. L. MCKENZUE, On equilibrium in Graham’s model of world trade and other competitive systems, Econometrica 22 (1954), 147-161.

12. L. MCKENZIE, The classical existence theorem of competitive equilibrium. Econometrica 49 (1981), 819-841.

13. J. MUNKRES, “Topology: A First Course,” Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs, NJ, 1975. 14. H. NIKAIEO, On the classical multilateral exchange problem, Metroeconomica 8 (1956),

135-145. 15. C. WILSON, Equilibrium in dynamic models with an infinity of agents, J. Econ. Theory 24

(1981), 95-111.