Nomination Committees and Corporate Governance: Lessons...

33
Saïd Business School Research Papers Saïd Business School WP 2018-12 The Saïd Business School’s working paper series aims to provide early access to high-quality and rigorous academic research. Oxford Saïd’s working papers reflect a commitment to excellence, and an interdisciplinary scope that is appropriate to a business school embedded in one of the world’s major research universities. This paper is authored or co-authored by Oxford Saïd faculty. It is circulated for comment and discussion only. Contents should be considered preliminary, and are not to be quoted or reproduced without the author’s permission. Nomination Committees and Corporate Governance: Lessons from Sweden and the UK Sophie Nachemson-Ekwall Stockholm School of Economics Colin Mayer Saïd Business School, University of Oxford April 2018

Transcript of Nomination Committees and Corporate Governance: Lessons...

Page 1: Nomination Committees and Corporate Governance: Lessons ...eureka.sbs.ox.ac.uk/6838/1/2018-12.pdf · While corporate boards, audit committees and remuneration committees have been

Saïd Business SchoolResearch Papers

Saïd Business School WP 2018-12

The Saïd Business School’s working paper series aims to provide early access to high-quality and rigorous academic research. Oxford Saïd’sworking papers reflect a commitment to excellence, and an interdisciplinary scope that is appropriate to a business school embedded in one of theworld’s major research universities.

This paper is authored or co-authored by Oxford Saïd faculty. It is circulated for comment and discussion only. Contents should be consideredpreliminary, and are not to be quoted or reproduced without the author’s permission.

Nomination Committees and CorporateGovernance: Lessons from Sweden and the UK

Sophie Nachemson-EkwallStockholm School of Economics

Colin MayerSaïd Business School, University of Oxford

April 2018

Page 2: Nomination Committees and Corporate Governance: Lessons ...eureka.sbs.ox.ac.uk/6838/1/2018-12.pdf · While corporate boards, audit committees and remuneration committees have been

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3170397

1

Nomination Committees and Corporate Governance: Lessons from Sweden and the UK

Sophie Nachemson-Ekwall, Stockholm School of Economics

Colin Mayer, Saïd Business School, Oxford University

[email protected]

[email protected]

26 April 2018

I Introduction

While corporate boards, audit committees and remuneration committees have been subject to

extensive analysis and research, one of the most important elements of corporate governance

has been largely disregarded: the nomination committee.

The reason why it has been neglected is that it is perceived as falling between stools.

In the widely dispersed ownership systems of the UK and US, the nomination committee is an

organ of the board, and shareholders for the most part rubber-stamp the recommendations of

the committee. In contrast, in the concentrated ownership systems of Continental Europe and

the Far East, the dominant shareholders are able to exert so much control that a nomination

committee is largely irrelevant – the large shareholders appoint at will. The nomination

committee is therefore decisive or irrelevant. Either way it is not very interesting.

This paper suggests that, on the contrary, the nomination committee (NC) should be a

primary focus of attention in corporate governance debates. The reason is that, when used in

a right way, it plays a fundamental role in the appointment and removal of board members

and is a key determinant of the composition of boards and corporate performance. If

companies make the right initial appointments then much else follows; if they do not then no

other aspect of corporate governance - monitoring, measurement or incentives – can fully

rectify the damage. Thus, the legitimacy of the NC in the eyes of the shareholder community

and the trust received from minority shareholders is pivotal to the empowerment of the board.

In particular, the NC is critical to concerns about the ownership of companies and the

engagement of institutional investors in active oversight and monitoring of management. It

1 Corresponding author: Department of Governance and Management Studies Stockholm School of Economics [email protected]: mobile: +46-730703951

Page 3: Nomination Committees and Corporate Governance: Lessons ...eureka.sbs.ox.ac.uk/6838/1/2018-12.pdf · While corporate boards, audit committees and remuneration committees have been

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3170397

2

will be suggested that the NC can be instrumental in both promoting the type of large, long-

term shareholdings that are a prerequisite to effective institutional engagement and a means

by which that engagement is exercised. Furthermore they provide a basis for resolving

potential conflicts that arise between different shareholders, most notably between dominant

and minority shareholders.

The paper will do this by contrasting the operation of NCs in two countries: Sweden

and the UK. These two countries are particularly interesting because Nasdaq Stockholm and

London Stock Exchange (LSE) both pride themselves in being at the forefront of Europe’s

most liberalized and active market economies, based predominantly on self-regulation as

against legal statute. Both countries embody what is termed “shareholder primacy”, namely

legal, regulatory and institutional structures that privilege shareholders over the interests of

other parties, and both countries have a substantial presence of institutional investors as well

as national pension funds. They therefore stand in contrast to several other Continental

European countries and many other parts of the rest of the world where shareholder interests

receive less prominence in relation to that of other parties to the firm. They are in this respect

similar to other common law countries, such as the US, and the analysis reported here has

relevance to them too.

While therefore similar in many respects, the nature of the two countries’ NCs are

very different. In the UK, the NC is an internal committee of the board on which independent

members sit and nominate successor members of the board. In Sweden it is an external

committee in which shareholders play an important role in the selection process. The internal

system of the UK delegates the nomination of new members of the board to its non-executive

members. In Sweden, on the other hand, the nomination process resides with representatives

of shareholders themselves.

As will be described below, in general Swedish companies have large controlling

shareholders who have incentives to exert significant influence over the nomination process,

As a consequence, by giving them a presence on the NC, its nomination process encourages

their direct engagement in the appointment process and mitigates the shareholder

disengagement problems that afflict the UK internal system. On the other hand, it does this at

the expense of creating another problem, namely potential divergences of interests between

different types of shareholders, notably between large, well-informed and small, uninformed,

shareholders.

As we will see, differences in the nature of ownership and norms of governance

explain much of the difference in operation of NCs in the two countries. Understanding the

Page 4: Nomination Committees and Corporate Governance: Lessons ...eureka.sbs.ox.ac.uk/6838/1/2018-12.pdf · While corporate boards, audit committees and remuneration committees have been

3

way in which NCs operate in Sweden and the UK is therefore fundamental to an appreciation

of the merits and deficiencies of different forms of capitalism as reflected in their ownership

and governance of firms. Growing societal pressure on institutional investors to undertake

engaged responsible corporate governance (as proposed by, for example, the Kay Review,

2012 and the EU Shareholders’ Rights Directive, 2014/17) strengthens expectations about the

role of NCs in corporate governance (the UK Stewardship Code, 2012; Lipton, World

Economic Forum, 2016). This paper asks the questions whether the UK system would benefit

from having more engagement by institutional investors in the nomination process and an

external rather than an internal NC and would Sweden be advised to reduce the power of

dominant shareholders in the nomination process and create a greater level of independence

of NCs from large shareholders?

To address these questions, we examine how the institutional corporate governance

settings of Sweden and the UK work to empower institutional investors through the NC. The

paper draws on a mixture of academic research, legal documents and official as well as

semiofficial reports. These sources show how ownership has evolved since the 1980s until

now and the relevance of company law in defining the role of independent directors.

The paper draws on novel research showing how Swedish institutional investors have

begun to take larger stakes in investee companies that are evaluated over longer time horizons

than was previously the case (Nachemson-Ekwall, 2017). In the process, institutional

investors engage in the NC on a longer-term basis, collaborating both with controlling

shareholders and other long-term institutional investors. There are advantages to this in

addressing agency problems but at the expense of the independence of the nomination process

from influence by particular shareholders. We discuss the possibility of achieving superior

outcomes by combining features of the Swedish and UK nomination process.

The rest of the article is structured as follows. In section 2 we describe the legal and

regulatory background to NCs in Sweden and the UK. We then discuss the theoretical

underpinning of NCs in section 3. In sections 4 and 5, we contrast the operation of NCs and

institutional investors in Sweden and the UK. Finally, we draw conclusions and propose

policy recommendations in section 6.

2. The Swedish and UK governance systems The UK choice of internal and the Swedish of external NCs is a reflection of their respective

corporate governance, takeover and stewardship codes, and their companies acts and, stock

Page 5: Nomination Committees and Corporate Governance: Lessons ...eureka.sbs.ox.ac.uk/6838/1/2018-12.pdf · While corporate boards, audit committees and remuneration committees have been

4

exchange listing rules. A summary of relevant soft and hard laws, listing requirements and

regulations, including how they have altered over time, is provided in the Appendix.

Both countries have company acts that state that the board of directors owe fiduciary

duties to promote the success of their companies for the benefit of their shareholders. In both

systems, shareholders vote on director nominees at the annual general meeting (AGM) and

can propose their own directors. In both countries, the NC is part of a self-regulatory system,

based on the principle of comply or explain, set out in their respective corporate governance

codes - the Swedish and UK corporate governance codes. Both countries observe a high

degree of compliance with their governance codes (Lekvall, 2013; Davies, 2015).

However, the countries differ in regard to shareholder influence on board composition

and enrolment, the composition of the NCs, how votes are exercised by the shareholders at

the AGM, and their attitudes towards shareholder collaboration. The countries also differ in

their approach to reflecting the interests of minority shareholders in the nomination process.

Figure 1 illustrates the differences between the two countries’ approaches to the composition

of NCs.

Figure 1: Two different models of the NC

Note: The grey circles represent members of the NC, and the arrow shows who proposes nominations to the AGM.

The Swedish NC

Swedish and Nordic corporate governance are based on a two-tier board with separation

between the organs of the corporation: (i) the shareholders at the AGM: (ii) the board of

directors, and (iii) the chief executive officer (CEO) and management. The Swedish

UKInsideNCModel SWEDENExternalNCModel

Generalassembly

Board

Generalassembly

Largeowner ChairInstitutionalInvestors

Non-exec

Non-exec

Non-exec

Board

Page 6: Nomination Committees and Corporate Governance: Lessons ...eureka.sbs.ox.ac.uk/6838/1/2018-12.pdf · While corporate boards, audit committees and remuneration committees have been

5

Companies Act, Aktiebolagslagen, states that the board should treat all shareholders alike2

and a general meeting should not take decisions that are intended to give an undue preference

to a particular shareholder or other person to the detriment of the company or other

shareholders.

The Companies Act grants a single shareholder or group of shareholders controlling

50 per cent of the votes at the AGM the right to nominate all the directors of the board. The

influence of large shareholders can be intensified through multiple voting shares (Series A

shares assigned 10 votes and B shares assigned 1 vote), and over half of listed companies in

Sweden have multiple voting stocks (Lekvall, 2014), despite there being a trend to initial

public offerings (IPOs) with just one class of shares. Only one executive can be elected to the

board, usually the CEO and approximately half of listed company boards do not include the

CEO (Lekvall, 2008).

The Swedish Corporate Governance Code reflects the dual responsibilities of directors

in the Companies Act. The Code distinguishes between directors being independent of the

company and large shareholders (defined as owning more than 10 per cent of capital and

votes) and recommends that at least two directors be independent of both the company and

large shareholders. No more than 50 per cent of the directors are permitted to have had a

relationship with the company (e.g. as a recent employee, customer or financial institution). In

addition, Swedish co-determination allows two directors to be nominated by the workers’

unions, usually one from each of blue and white-collar unions. The NC is appointed by

shareholders at an general meeting or during the course of the year (Carlsson 2007; Lekvall,

2008).

To avoid the NC being entirely dominated by a controlling shareholder, the Code

requires that at least one member of the committee be independent of the largest shareholder.

A typical NC will comprise one or two representatives of the controlling shareholder, the

chair (who is often associated with the controlling shareholder) and two or three institutional

investors. These are in general Swedish since foreign institutions usually decline offers to

participate in the NC (Ehne, 2014). A representative of small investors is sometimes invited to

2 The Principle of Equality in the Swedish Company Act (Ch. 4. 1 §) is that the shares of a company shall have equal rights. This is supported by two General Clauses: Ch. 7:47 § directed at limiting what constitutes an unfair advantage to a specific shareholder or group of shareholders; and Ch. 8:41 §, 1 addresses the responsibilities of the board of directors and other company signatories.

Page 7: Nomination Committees and Corporate Governance: Lessons ...eureka.sbs.ox.ac.uk/6838/1/2018-12.pdf · While corporate boards, audit committees and remuneration committees have been

6

join the NC but this is unusual. It is common for the NC to comprise members representing 15

to 20 per cent of shares outstanding, which often is enough to control a majority of the votes

at the AGM, particularly if the shares have multiple voting rights attached to them.

The UK NC

NCs became commonplace after the British Cadbury report on corporate governance was

published in 1992.3 UK corporate governance is based on a one-tier board structure. The UK

Companies Act allows boards to be made up of a mixture of inside (the CEO and other

executives) and outside non-executive directors (NEDs). At least half the board, excluding the

chairman, should comprise NEDs who are regarded by the board as independent in having no

relation with the company or its related parties and not having served on the board for a

period exceeding nine years. Exceptions are made for smaller companies, where there should

be at least two independent NEDs.4 Nominations to the board are made by a NC, which is a

sub-committee of the main board. The NC is required to comprise a majority of independent

NEDs with the chairman of the board or an independent NED acting as its chair.

The NC is an important component of corporate governance in both the UK and

Sweden and we turn now to its theoretical underpinnings to understand how it addresses two

sets of issues: (a) conflicts between minority shareholders and management in the UK and

between large and small shareholders in Sweden and (b) long-term relationships between

shareholders and management.

3. Theoretical underpinning of the NC

The traditional view of the governance of the firm is based on the agency problems that exist

between shareholders and management. Adam Smith (1776) discussed the board’s role in

mitigating information asymmetries between shareholders and management. Ronald Coase

(1937) identified the value of empowering the corporate form with a central decision-making

body, substituting entrepreneurial fiat for the price mechanism of the market.

Success is expected to lead to a board that both contributes to corporate value creation and

lower capital costs. Since the beginning of the 1980s the conventional view has been that

3 The UK Corporate Governance Code (the Code) has its origins in the Cadbury Committee in 1992 and paragraph 2.5 defines corporate governance as “the system by which companies are directed and controlled. Boards of directors are responsible for the governance of their companies.” 4 “Smaller companies” are those that are outside the FTSE 350 during the year immediately prior to the reporting year.

Page 8: Nomination Committees and Corporate Governance: Lessons ...eureka.sbs.ox.ac.uk/6838/1/2018-12.pdf · While corporate boards, audit committees and remuneration committees have been

7

corporate value creation is evaluated in terms of shareholder wealth, and the board exists to

monitor, advise and contribute to strategy formation to enhance shareholder value. For

minority shareholders, it is both cheaper and rational to transfer decision-making to a smaller

and informed body with authority (Banbridge, 2015)5 - hence the “duty of loyalty” in

company law.

The “agency-problem” is then defined as aligning the interests of board and managers

with those of their external shareholders, to avoid unprofitable growth or undue complacency

(Berle and Means, 1932/1968; Jensen and Meckling, 1976). However, the agency-problem

can also be related to conflicting interests between a large block holder, with active

participation on the board, and minority shareholders with both less influence and information

giving rise to the principal-principal conflict (Easterbrook and Fischel, 1981/1991; Burkart

and Panunzi, 2008). Minority shareholders need specific protection to ensure that the board is

accountable to all shareholders, i.e. that there are limits to the ability of large shareholders to

divert wealth to themselves.

The shareholder primary model has been questioned in many contexts (i.e. Stout,

2012; Mayer, 2015). According to these critiques, corporate governance is about “ensuring

that the corporation abides by its stated purpose, values and principles”.6 Consequently the

board’s role should focus on creating value in the interest of the corporation itself, its

employees, stakeholders, including shareholders and society. This focus of the board’s

function moves away from the agency view to team production theory (Blair and Stout, 1999;

Huse, 2007).

Research shows that long-term committed owners have great influence on corporate

governance. Almost all Nordic companies have a strong owner who is supported in law

(Sjöstrand et al. 2016; Lekvall, 2013). Studying Danish foundations, Hansmann and Thomsen

(2012) find a correlation between value creation and support of long-term committed

industrial foundations. However, strong ownership is by no means always successful and it is

not clear how much of the success of the Nordic corporate model is attributable to the high

trust nature of Nordic societies, i.e. small country effects (Sinani et al. 2008). In the case of

Sweden, it might just be that respect for large owners, passive support from minority

institutional investors and what is perceived to be a healthy relationship with both the state

5 This reasoning is developed by Bainbridge in Research Handbook on Shareholder Power (2015) Bainbridge adheres to the separation thesis as it strengthens the boards’ accountability, giving it a strong efficiency justification. 6 The shareholder empowerment proposition, Hill and Randall (2015) p. 4.

Page 9: Nomination Committees and Corporate Governance: Lessons ...eureka.sbs.ox.ac.uk/6838/1/2018-12.pdf · While corporate boards, audit committees and remuneration committees have been

8

and labor unions have allowed Sweden to develop profitable, well-run companies (Henrekson

and Bergh, 2013).

Most jurisdictions formulate the director’s fiduciary duty as being accountable to the

company and/or shareholders as a whole. This puts the long-term owner-perspective centre

stage rather than the interests of either current short-term shareholders or management.

However, the role of the NC differs appreciably between Nordic countries and the UK and US.

The Nordic model embraces shareholder nominated directors on the board, including

representatives of large shareholders. All Nordic jurisdictions allow owners controlling 50 per

cent of the votes at the AGM to enroll all shareholder-nominated board members. The

Swedish external NC offers all owners a forum to discuss governance issues and to enter a

dialogue with the company. Collaboration and concerted activities among shareholders,

including institutional investors, are encouraged. A number of studies of the Swedish capital

market suggest that conflicts between large and small shareholders have overall been kept at a

low level, trust between majority and minority shareholders in general being high (Gilson,

2006; Sinani et al. 2008; Lekvall, 2014).

The other Nordic countries have adopted different versions of the external NC model.

The Norwegian NC is specified in the corporate charter, and different stakeholders are elected

to the NC at the AGM – shareholders, employee-representatives and board members. Finish

companies can choose between an internal or external NC model without any co-

determination. The NC in Denmark is internal and has a mixture of executives and

shareholder supported directors and there is Danish codetermination. Thus, the Swedish NC

version with all shareholder representatives, represent an extreme version of the Nordic

corporate governance model.

In contrast, the UK and US have stock markets dominated by dispersed ownership and

companies acts that empower management-led boards. In the US, the board comprises a

mixture of internal and external directors empowered to interpret their fiduciary duty to

protect long-term interest of the company. Board enrolment is an internal matter, with the NC

part of the board and in the control of the chair, the vice chair and the CEO. In the post-

financial crisis era, a number of companies have been pressed by their shareholders to change

their by-laws to facilitate enrolment of shareholder nominated directors.7

7 In 2010 the Obama administration plan to force companies to include directors’ nominees from certain large shareholders in the corporation’s proxy under specific conditions (US 2010, Rule 14a-11) was voted down. Shareholders have since acted to change byelaws instead. For a description see:

Page 10: Nomination Committees and Corporate Governance: Lessons ...eureka.sbs.ox.ac.uk/6838/1/2018-12.pdf · While corporate boards, audit committees and remuneration committees have been

9

The UK Companies Act does empower the General assembly to suggest directors (just

as in Sweden) but shareholders seldom take action. British governance views large

shareholders as stakeholders with specific interests rather than those of shareholders as a

whole. Thus the Companies Act therefore supports the presence of non-executives on the

board but a board composed of only independent NEDs would turn into a pure monitor

(Davies, 2015). To balance the different roles of directors, the Companies Act requires a

mixture of internal and external (independent) directors. The UK corporate governance code

states that a NC should be composed of a majority of independent directors and recommends

that only one representative for a large owner be elected.8

Legal scholars highlight that corporate governance codes, including the original

British Cadbury rules, are unclear about the definition of “independent directors”. Hansen

(2013) draws on the Nordic governance experience to argue that independent directors all too

often fail to monitor and discipline management. Independent directors that are independent

of both the company and owners do not solve the governance problem; instead Hansen claims

that governance should recognize the importance of active owners.9 An extensive study of

board work in 36 large Nordic companies (Sjöstrand et al. 2016) shows that dominant

shareholders in general do not appreciate the work of the NC and handle the enrolment of the

most significant directors outside of the NC.

There is no evidence of significant performance effects from the presence of

independent directors on company boards (Bhagat and Black, 1999, 2002; Hermalin and

Weisbach, 2003; Adams et al. 2010). Examining the rise of independent directors as a legal

transplant from jurisdictions with dispersed ownership to other systems in which controlled

corporations are dominant, Ferrarini and Filippelli (2015) show that countries use different

definitions of, and assign different powers to independent directors of dispersed ownership

and controlled companies. Independent directors of controlled companies have a narrower and

weaker role than their counterparts in companies with dispersed ownership. Independence

requirements in the block-holder context therefore need to be sufficiently broad to encapsulate

IGOPP, institute of governance. Who should pick board members? Proxy Access by Shareholders to the Director Nomination Process. Policy paper no. 8 2015. Canada. www.igopp.org 8 Provision B.2.1 of the UK Code. 9 See, inter alia, the European Commission, Green Paper on Corporate governance in financial institutions and remuneration policies, COM (2010) 284, Brussels, 2 Jun. 2010, 8, where a reason for the failure of shareholders in the recent crisis is explained by ‘the lack of effective rights allowing shareholders to exercise control’, and in the title of its Action Plan, n. 3 supra, specific reference is made to engaging shareholders. �

Page 11: Nomination Committees and Corporate Governance: Lessons ...eureka.sbs.ox.ac.uk/6838/1/2018-12.pdf · While corporate boards, audit committees and remuneration committees have been

10

the relationship between independent directors and controlling shareholders. Andersson

(2013) and Kershaw (2015) question the idea of independent directors as value creation

mechanisms, citing a lack of industrial knowledge, their annual re-election, and dependence

on the support of the executive members of the board as limitations on their effectiveness.

4. Contrasting NCs in Sweden and the UK

Inspired by the Cadbury Code in 1992, the Swedish external NC was developed by the

Swedish Shareholders’ Association, with the support of a group of leading domestic

institutional investors. It was put into practice for the first time in 1993, after the failed merger

between Swedish vehicle conglomerate Volvo and French Renault, which left Volvo without

a board of directors, but it took until 2005 before the NC became standard Swedish procedure

because incumbent owners were in general negative about adopting a corporate governance

code,

The Swedish NC is partly an attempt (dating back to the early 1900s) to embed

minority shareholders in the governance of publicly traded companies. From 1910 onwards,

different versions of the Companies Act limited voting rights of a controlling shareholder

electing directors to 20 per cent of the votes present at the AGM, if not otherwise stated in the

corporate statutes. This remained in place until 2005.10

The external NC model was also inspired by Swedish popular movements11 The

original proposal from the Shareholders Association was to have shareholders setting up NCs

at AGMs, with public exposure to shareholders providing accountability to large and small

shareholders. To ensure the NCs independence from large owners at least one member was

required to be independent of any large shareholder or shareholders working in collaboration.

(Chapter 2 §3). Between 2005 and 2010 the notion of independent directors was part of the

10Swedish Companies Act as of 1944 states that to enhance trust between different groups of shareholders – i.e. large dominating shareholders and minority shareholders –no single shareholder should be able to vote for more than 20 per cent of the votes present at the AGM, though higher or lower levels could be stipulated in the articles of association (p. 348–9, 114–127 §§). This was strengthened in the Companies Act of 1975, with the rule that no shareholder may vote for more than one-fifth of the shares represented at the meeting, unless stated otherwise (SOU 1995:44 p. 20). However, by the millennium most corporate statutes stated that all shares would have full voting rights at the AG, limits only being possible in relation to voting rights of the series. This was removed in the revision 2005. See, also, Nachemson-Ekwall (2018).11 In this democratic structure, with each member assigned one vote, the standard procedure is to carry out director enrolment through the help of external nomination committees, made up of members nominated by different groups at the AGM. For research related to the Swedish popular movement, see Filip Wijkström, Stockholm Centre on Civil Society Studies at SSE Institute of Research (SIR).

Page 12: Nomination Committees and Corporate Governance: Lessons ...eureka.sbs.ox.ac.uk/6838/1/2018-12.pdf · While corporate boards, audit committees and remuneration committees have been

11

Nasdaq Stockholm’s listing requirements but it was removed in 2010.

The Cadbury Committee in the UK stated in 1992 that a majority of directors should

be independent of the company where independence was defined as being free from any

business or other relations that might materially interfere with their exercise of independent

judgment. NEDs were to be selected through a formal process with the support of a

nomination committee and both this process and their appointment was to be a matter for the

board as a whole, thereby limiting risk of stakeholder influence (1992: 4.10–4.17). Re-

election was to be at least every third year. In the preparatory work of the Cadbury code

consideration was given to the idea that shareholders should be more closely involved in the

appointment of directors and auditors through the formation of “shareholders’ committees”.

However, this was ruled out: “…as we have not seen evidence explaining how it would be

possible to form shareholder committees in such a way that they would be both truly

representative of all the company’s shareholders and able to keep in regular touch with their

changing constituencies. Unless these tests of legitimacy are met, the Committee is unable to

see how shareholder committees can become the accepted link between a board and its

shareholders.” (Section Accountability to the Shareholders. 6.3).

5. The British and Swedish institutional investors in the NC

British and Swedish domestic institutional investors’ play an important role in legitimizing

the NC as a corporate governance device. Traditionally, there has been a home-bias in

domestic institutional investments with 30 to 50 percent of equity portfolios being allocated to

domestic stocks (Coval and Moskowitz, 1999; Ferreira and Matos, 2008; Dahlquist et al,

2003). Despite the theoretical merits of global diversification, quantitative limits in many

countries (Yermo, 2008; Nachemson-Ekwall, 2016) and a preference for exit over voice

despite an increasing concentration of stakes (Jackson, 2008), investing in the home market

continues in both the UK and Sweden and is supported by claimed benefits such as better

information, lower asset management costs, and lower transaction costs (Coval and

Moskowitz, 1999; Ferreira and Matos, 2008; Dahlquist et al. 2003).

The role of Swedish institutional investors

Swedish institutional investor influence on the stock market has changed recently (Table 1).

In 1990, the year before Sweden opened up for foreign direct investments on the stock

exchange, Swedish institutional investors such as the four large Swedish National Pension

Funds (SNPFs), life insurance companies, and mutual funds controlled 28 percent of the

Page 13: Nomination Committees and Corporate Governance: Lessons ...eureka.sbs.ox.ac.uk/6838/1/2018-12.pdf · While corporate boards, audit committees and remuneration committees have been

12

Swedish Stock Exchange (SSE), and foreign investors controlled close to 8 percent. By 2000

foreigners controlled almost 40 per cent, while almost all other categories had reduced their

holdings. Swedish institutional investors had reduced their holding to 22 per cent, a level that

has been more or less maintained since then.

Due to regulations, the influence of Swedish institutions has been limited. SNPF and

mutual fund ownership in a company is capped at 10 percent of shares or votes (Law on

investment funds 2004:46). In addition, each SNPF may only own 2 percent of the SSE. In

practice, the SNPFs have pursued diversified investment strategies that have fallen short of

these limits.

Table 1: Ownership on the SSE

Source: Adaption from Statistics Sweden (March 2016), only capital, not voting power. CEIFs (Closed-end investment funds; Investor, Industrivärden etc.) SNPFs (Swedish National Pension Funds, AP1-AP4)

Holdings of private and corporate occupational pension funds are limited by capital

requirements (i.e. solvency rules such as those stipulated through the IORP, 2003/2016).

Consequently, Swedish incumbent block-owners and main shareholders have, despite their

decreased capital holdings have remained in the driver seat of Swedish corporate governance.

Until the end of the financial boom in 2008, Swedish institutional investors, when they

participated in nomination committees, acted passively, either supporting larger shareholders

(Hellman, 2005) or selling during takeovers (Kallifatides et al 2010; Nachemson-Ekwall,

2012). Long-term activism by institutional investors was limited to a few high-profile cases

% Year

Corps. and Orgs. CEIFs Mutual

funds Life

Insur. SNPF State House-holds

Non-profits Foreign Billion

SEK 1986 17 13 6 14 5 2 25 10 8 500 1990 23 10 8 14,5 6 2 18 8 8 545 1995 10 7 9 13 4 3 15 8 30 1 200 2000 9 6 8 10 4 5 13 5 39 4 098 2005 11 5 12 9 3,5 4 15 5 35 3 054 2010 11 5 12 9 3 4 13 4 38 3 701 2015 14 6 12 7,5 2,5 2 11 4 40 6 071

Page 14: Nomination Committees and Corporate Governance: Lessons ...eureka.sbs.ox.ac.uk/6838/1/2018-12.pdf · While corporate boards, audit committees and remuneration committees have been

13

where media campaigns were highly effective.12 Nevertheless, domestic institutions clearly

embrace the model (Lekvall, 2008; Tomorrow’s Company, 2016).

The role of the UK institutional investor

The general picture of UK as a fully dispersed shareholder regime, with atomized

shareholders having large costs for coordination, is not correct (Davies, 2015). Until the

1960s, dispersed shareholders (pensions funds and insurance companies) achieved a sufficient

level of coordinated action to influence the environment in which their investee companies

operated.

British self-regulation, with its roots in the 1960s’ development of the first takeover

rules, were formed in close collaboration with the institutional investor community, the

corporations and the City (i.e. investment banks). This differed from Sweden, where the

Swedish version of self-regulation grew out of the interest of the owners (namely families

such as the Wallenbergs and Handelsbanken). In Sweden, it took until the 1990s before the

voice of institutional investors was heard.

The institutionalization of the British stock market began earlier than in Sweden (and

other European countries). The destocking-process, with pensions funds moving out of the

domestic stock market to global investments and bonds, also started earlier in the UK and has

gone much further. Statistics show the development. Data from the UK Office of National

Statistics (ONS) shows that (Table 2):

• In 1963, individual investors owned 53 per cent of the listed stocks. By 2010 the ownership was down to approximately 10 per cent.

• Rest of the world ownership has risen from below 10 per cent in the years 1963–1980s, to close to 54 per cent in 2014.

• Insurance companies and pension funds have had the most interesting development, growing from 16 percent of the market in 1963 to 52 percent in 1993 and are now down below ten per cent.

• Investment trusts, retail and mutual funds, have been more stable around 12 per cent. Consequently, British domestic institutional investors still hold around 20 per cent of the LSE, but the group comprises many more organizations than the Swedish equivalent.

• Rest of the world ownership stood at an estimated 54 percent of the value at the end of 2014. This was up from 31 percent in 1998.

At the time of Cadbury 1992, UK based institutional investors controlled 62 per cent of the

12 Among high profile cases are the halted Volvo-Renault deal (1993), the crash of the insurance company Skandia (2001), the ABB-scandal (2000) and lately, the criticised cross-holdings between Industrivärden and Handelsbanken (2015).

Page 15: Nomination Committees and Corporate Governance: Lessons ...eureka.sbs.ox.ac.uk/6838/1/2018-12.pdf · While corporate boards, audit committees and remuneration committees have been

14

LSE (in Sweden 28 per cent for 1990). Thus, at the time of market liberalization UK already

lacked controlling shareholders instead placing the interest of British institutional investors

foremost.

Domestic institutions such as pensions funds, insurance companies and institutional

investment trusts, control around 20 per cent of the LSE market cap, just about the same size

as the Swedish. They also invest with a considerable home-bias, 26 per cent of their overall

asset portfolio being invested in British stocks (the UK market makes up 7 per cent of the

World).13 However, the UK stands out both compared to Sweden, and other European

countries, as regards the smaller size of block-holdings by institutional investors (Holderness,

2009; Edmans and Holderness, 2017).

Table 2: Ownership on UK Stock market (LSE)

Source: Office for National Statistics November 2016 Note: Data in 1998 was collected on a different basis compared with more recent years Numbers may not sum due to rounding

Engagement by Swedish institutional investors

A number of studies show that the Swedish version of an external NC has had substantial

impact on shareholder engagement in the nomination process, increased confidence in the

board function and encouraged shareholders to become more involved (Poulsen, Strand and

Thomsen, 2010). Building on comparative material from institutional investor activities and

proxy statements at the AGMs in Denmark and Sweden, Hannes and Strand (2013) claim that

13 Statistics from Vanguard Asset Management 2016 30 November, Morningstar.

Beneficial Owners LSEPer cent £ Billion

1963 1975 1981 1993 1998 2010 2014 1998 2014Rest of the world 7 5,6 3,6 16,3 30,7 43,4 53,8 460,9 928,6Individuals 54 37,5 28,2 17,7 16,7 10,2 11,9 250,8 206,2Unit and investment trusts 1,3 4,1 3,6 9,1 2,0 10,9 11,8 50,0 186,0Other financial institutions 11,3 10,1 10,5 0,4 2,7 12,3 7,1 40,4 123,0Insurance companies 10 15,9 20,5 20 21,6 8,8 5,9 325,5 101,8Pension funds 6,4 16,8 26,7 31,7 21,7 5,6 3,0 325,8 51,7Public, Non-financial/-profit 8,7 9,3 6,6 4,2 2,9 6,2 6,1 42,7 105,0Banks 1,3 0,7 0,3 0,6 0,6 2,5 1,4 8,4 24,3Total 100 100 100 100 100,0 100,0 100,0 1504 1727

Page 16: Nomination Committees and Corporate Governance: Lessons ...eureka.sbs.ox.ac.uk/6838/1/2018-12.pdf · While corporate boards, audit committees and remuneration committees have been

15

the Swedish NC model has transferred power from the board to shareholders across almost all

listed companies at the SSE. Nearly all companies listed on the SSE have domestic

institutional investors on their NC’s, often two,14 thereby reducing both free-rider and

collective action problems (Hannes and Strand, 2013).Also, the “old boys network” has

clearly been broken (Björkmo, 2008).

Domestic institutional investors have enhanced the recruitment of female board

members. There are more females among the independent directors than among the owner

dependent directors (AP2, 2016). Since institutions are only involved in the enrolment of

independent directors, this indicates that engagement of institutional investors on the NC has

had a strong gender effect (Table 3). Other studies claim that institutional investors in NCs

have played a particular role in director enrolment in small and medium sized companies,

where executives and owners often lack access to a network of relevant qualified people

(Grönberg and Kallifatides, 2012).

Table 3: Enrolment of female directors among owner dependent and independent directors. Statistics AGMs 2016.

Source: with courtesy from Lannebo funds, Didner & Gerge, AMF and Swedbank (2016)

An important influence on these development is the larger share stakes in investee companies

held by Swedish institutional investors post the financial crisis. This has resulted in more

engaged investing, leveraging on the external NC. Research by Nachemson-Ekwall (2017)

includes in-depth interviews with fifty representatives of Swedish institutional investors

conducted between 2015 and 2016. Looking at the period 2000–2016 seventy per cent of

them committed more capital to larger stakes than previously and evaluated their investments

over a longer time horizon (Table 4), with a view to enhancing performance.

14 www.holdings.se lists all nomination committees.

Females, % Total Independent Owner dependent

Large 32 44 18

Mid 29 42 8 Small 24 32 10

Page 17: Nomination Committees and Corporate Governance: Lessons ...eureka.sbs.ox.ac.uk/6838/1/2018-12.pdf · While corporate boards, audit committees and remuneration committees have been

16

Table 4: The largest Swedish institutional investors and their stakes on the SSE

Source: Aktieservice, 2007; Holdings.se 2016; In Nachemson-Ekwall (2016)*Bought Skandia AB for SEK 22.5 Billion in 2011, and sold off parts of the Swedish portfolio **Bought 10 % in Swedbank for SEK 10 Billion in 2008

This change in investment style has occurred within the current regulatory framework and

without an overall increase in portfolio asset exposure to the Swedish stock market. To

provide further insight into the rationale for this change in domestic institutional investments,

Nachemson-Ekwall (2017) re-conceptualizes their investment strategy using a three-phase

framework. In the first phase, broadly the period 1980 to 2000, the collectivization of the

Swedish capital market took off and began to move abroad. There were institutional

investments with larger stakes, but engagement remained more or less passive (Hellman,

2005). In the second phase, broadly consisting of the period just before the turn of the

millennium and up to the beginning of the post-financial-crisis era, the globalization of capital

markets was associated with a focusing of the industry on low-cost benchmarking, index

tracking and smaller stakes in each company. The third phase, began during the final stage of

2016 Owner > 3% !! > 5% !!

Focus? No of stocks

Billion SEK 2007 2016 2007 2016

!! !! !! !! 1 Swedbank Robur 57 97 29 67 + 173 171 2 Alecta 21 19 15 12 (-) 30 116 3 AMF pension & funds 8 29 5 13 + 139 116 4 SHB funds 6 47 4 19 + 269 93 5 SEB funds 20 28 6 12 + 233 70 6 Nordea funds 25 48 8 31 + 174 63 7 SNPF4 17 47 8 30 + 131 51 8 Skandia life & funds* 32 11 26 5 (-) 141 42 9 Folksam ins +KPA** 0 1 0 1 (=) 46 42 10 Didner & Gerge funds 16 17 7 12 + 64 37 11 Länsförsäkringar funds 21 22 5 16 + 192 37 12 Lannebo funds 15 43 8 36 + 88 35 13 SNPF3 3 5 0 3 + 116 31 14 SNPF1 2 3 1 3 + 28 31 15 AFA ins 24 5 13 4 - 43 29 16 SNPF2 4 8 1 6 + 134 27 17 Carnegie funds 6 14 0 8 + 56 25 18 SPP funds "! 0 "! 0 = 71 24

Page 18: Nomination Committees and Corporate Governance: Lessons ...eureka.sbs.ox.ac.uk/6838/1/2018-12.pdf · While corporate boards, audit committees and remuneration committees have been

17

the financial-bubble years, but the results – in the form of an increased focus on larger stakes

in the active portfolio mandate on the Swedish stock market – only showed up a few years

into the post-financial crisis era. This change in investment style hinges on a reconsideration

of portfolio-allocation strategies with for example more index-tracking (passive) mandates co-

existing with a domestic focused strategy enabling a shareholder friendly engagement. In the

process, Swedish institutional investors claim that they engage longer-term with the NC,

collaborating both with controlling shareholders and other long-term institutions.

A head of stock equity at a life insurance company explains:

“We believe in home bias. Seventy percent of all our assets are invested in Sweden. We have 10% in Swedish stocks. We have been around for a long time; we know our companies, engage in corporate governance and can talk to the directors. It pays off, long-term. Outside Sweden, my network is weaker. In Asia, I am a nobody.”

Also, all institutional investors highlight the close interaction between domestic institutional

investors in the Swedish corporate governance model. Large shareholders are expected to be

engaged and to coordinate activities. Everyone knows each other. A chair can easily get in

touch with the five largest domestic investors, whereas the foreign institutional investors are

either disengaged or difficult to reach. The head of sustainability and governance of a bank-

controlled mutual fund describes its role:

“We have been practising governance for 20 years now. It is expected of us that we are engaged and responsible. When we make large investments, we engage (for the) long term. Sweden is in the forefront in this process.”

There are also studies critiquing the work of the Swedish external NC. A survey made by

proxy-consultant Nordic Investor Services (2010) of 27 chairs of companies and 33 chairs of

nomination committees from 25 large and 25 smaller companies in April-June 2010 reveal

that there is a problem relating to possible insider information and that institutional investor-

representatives, like corporate governance specialists, often lacked company specific

competencies. This has largely been left un-addressed. A list of the institutional investors on

the NC complied from the AGM season 2016 reveal an overwhelming number of investment

professionals, and a number of them participate on 10 NC (Table 5).

Page 19: Nomination Committees and Corporate Governance: Lessons ...eureka.sbs.ox.ac.uk/6838/1/2018-12.pdf · While corporate boards, audit committees and remuneration committees have been

18

Table 5: Institutional investors with the largest number of members on the NC

Source: Holdings.se 2016. 10 individuals on 69 NC mean an average of 7 each.

Studies also highlight the concentration of power in the hands of the NC. When the NC only

represents 10–15 per cent of the total shareholdings it really lacks legitimacy in the eyes of

other minority shareholders (Björkmo, 2008). The Swedish version of external NC has also

difficulty dealing with controlling shareholders that choose not to collaborate with minority

shareholders, which could also be institutional investors (Nachemson-Ekwall, 2012/ 2017). In

addition, since 2010 there is no regulation in the Nasdaq Stockholm listing requiring large

owner independent directors, and no transparent checking on the quality of the two

independent directors that are enrolled in companies where a large owner controls a majority

of the votes at the AGM (Nachemson-Ekwall, 2012). Discussing the activities taken by hedge

fund activist Cevian in relation to Old Mutual’s hostile takeover of Skandia 2006, Kallifatides

et al (2010) document how Sweden’s external NC appears only to have limited ability to

handle risks of short-termism or stakeholder-interests (Nachemson-Ekwall, 2012; Andersson,

2013).

In the revised Code 2015 two changes were introduced related to the NC. Rule 2 now

states that any person on the NC shall upon acceptance consider possible conflicts of interest.

Apr-16 Nomination committees

Institutional Investor AUM No of

individuals No of companies

Swedbank Robur 172 10 69 Vanguard 140 0 0 Black Rock 132 0 0 Alecta 120 7 18 AMF 115 7 24 SHB funds +Exact 95 7 24 SEB funds and life 87 5 29 Capital Group 63 0 0 Nordea funds 63 13 60 AP4 51 9 52 Fidelity 44 0 0 Skandia Life & funds 42 5 5 Folksam 42 1 1 Didner &Gerge 38 4 14 LF funds 37 4 16 Lannebo funds 35 12 30 Invesco 31 0 0 AP2 28 3 9 Catella funds 15 3 12

Page 20: Nomination Committees and Corporate Governance: Lessons ...eureka.sbs.ox.ac.uk/6838/1/2018-12.pdf · While corporate boards, audit committees and remuneration committees have been

19

It also demands that the NC considers diversity of directors and works to promote gender

equality (Ch. 2 §1).15 There appears to be a dominance of independent directors educated at a

few business schools. Among the independent female board members almost all have a

degree from the Stockholm School of Economics. They are all dependent on good

relationships with the institutional investors. Integrity is not all that matters when there is a

risk of “cold shouldering” creating less opportunities for jobs in the future (Andersson (2013)).

Studying Norwegian female board members, Huse et al (2014) points to the problem with a

growing group of female independent directors that have become professionals, aiming to

gain board positions rather than display loyalty to a company. Consequently, the quality of

independent (female) directors is not assured in the shareholder-led NC.

Foreign institutional investors, such as Vanguard, Blackrock and Capital group abstain

from participation on the NC, thus limiting engagement from the international community to a

few activist hedge funds. The general reason is that they do not understand the model; there is

a language barrier and they are unwilling to devote the necessary time (Ehne, 2014). The

shareholder led NC model, which enrols members on the basis of institutional size, works

against private investor participation. This is especially troubling in SMEs that often lack

enough institutional capital.

Engagement by British institutional investors

There are few studies on the legitimacy and efficacy of the UK NC. In the FRC report on

Corporate Governance and Stewardship published January 2017 it was stated that 90 per cent

of FTSE 350 companies report compliance with all, or all but one or two, of its 54 provisions.

A lack of independent directors remained the highest non-compliant provision. There was

also a need for nomination committees to have a more active role in the alignment of board

composition with company strategy, and to ensure that the board has the necessary skills to

promote long-term success of the company (p. 7).

Tomorrow’s Corporate Governance (2010) highlights the high cost of stewardship for

individual large British institutional investors compared to the Swedish equivalent. Having

conducted a survey, FRC (2011) highlight problems with managing conflicts of interest and

acting through proxy voting agencies.

There is little empirical evidence on institutional investor contacts with the NC,

probably reflecting the low level of involvement and UK stewardship failing to deliver 15 Sweden does not have a gender-quota, that exists in Norway, Spain, France and Germany.

Page 21: Nomination Committees and Corporate Governance: Lessons ...eureka.sbs.ox.ac.uk/6838/1/2018-12.pdf · While corporate boards, audit committees and remuneration committees have been

20

institutional investor engagement (Hill, 2016). Explanations vary. Addressing a lack of

stakeholder voice related to directors’ remuneration BEIS (2016) blames traditional free

riding in relation to engagement costs. Armour and Cheffins (2012) emphasize capital market

regulation that increases costs of engagement as it drives the long-only funds in the direction

of asset diversification and less equity (i.e. the IORP and market-to-market accounting). Tilba

and McNulty (2013) find that only 2 out of 35 British pensions schemes exhibited “engaged

ownership behavior”, such as company research, voting and face-to-face meeting with senior

management and directors. The mandate to promote corporate value creation becomes

progressively more unclear as it works through intermediaries along the so-called asset-value

chain. Institutional investor engagement seems to be more related to specific cases, i.e.

activism and executive remuneration (Edmans, 2014; Becht et al 2009; 2016; The Big

Innovation Centre, 2016/17).16

There are concerns that signatories to the Stewardship Code do not abide by it (Wong,

2015); there is a general difficulty in evaluating the quality of possible collective engagement

by institutions and mandates given to them (FRC, 2011); and there are concerns that the UK

Stewardship Code ultimately targets a relatively small number of shareholders, as the

proportion of UK-listed equity owned by domestic institutional investors has progressively

dropped (Cheffins 2010; Davies, 2015).

6. Conclusions

The board of director nomination-process is a particularly important but largely ignored

aspect of corporate governance. It has been ignored in relation to the attention that has been

paid to other corporate governance committees, such as the remuneration and audit

committees. Both of these appear to have greater relevance to the financial performance of

firms and the correction of managerial failure. EU legislation has addressed both areas.

In actual fact, the nomination process is particularly important because it is a primary

determinant of the composition of corporate boards and therefore the functioning and

performance of the firm. As custodians of the corporate purpose and firm values, the board

plays a critical role in establishing the objectives of the firm and overseeing their

implementation through the formulation of strategy, measurement of performance and setting

of standards and incentives. The identification of the right members of the board is therefore

16 For a description on UK institutional investor activism; Big Innovation Centre, The Purposeful Company, Interim report, May 2016 and final report February 2017.

Page 22: Nomination Committees and Corporate Governance: Lessons ...eureka.sbs.ox.ac.uk/6838/1/2018-12.pdf · While corporate boards, audit committees and remuneration committees have been

21

a primary influence on the operation of the firm.

The comparison of the nomination process in Sweden and the UK has been

particularly insightful because of the similarities between the two countries. Both countries

place considerable significance on self-regulation and liberalized markets, and on shareholder

rights and privileges. Both countries house a large group of domestic institutional investors

such as retail funds as well as national and private pensions funds.

However, the differences are as pronounced as the similarities in particular in terms of

the presence of block-holders or main shareholders, significant concentrations of shares in

Sweden but not in the UK, as well as different approaches in the companies act to

blockholders influence on the directors. This has given rise to pronounced variations in the

way in which the nomination committees have been structured and operate in the two

countries. In Sweden, an external nomination committee provides a forum in which the

contrasting views of dominant shareholders about the composition of boards can be resolved.

Rightly used, it is an effective way of encouraging shareholder engagement in the nomination

process.

In the UK, the highly dispersed nature of share ownership makes the involvement of

shareholders in the nomination process more difficult. There is a serious free rider problem

that has given rise to the phenomenon of the “ownerless corporation” in which no investor

plays an active governance role (Mayer, 2013). As a result, instead of engaging shareholders

in the nomination process, appointments are an internal process in which (independent)

members of the board nominate board members themselves for ratification at shareholder

meetings.

The advantage of the UK procedure is that it keeps the nomination process

independent of any particular shareholding group and promotes the fair treatment of all

shareholders. In the Swedish external nomination process, while there is a requirement on

members of the committee to represent the interests of all shareholders, there is an inevitable

and unavoidable privileging of those present on the nomination committee. Indeed, some

investors regard the fact that appointees inevitably feel a sense of gratitude to those who have

appointed them as a potential advantage of building a relation between investors and boards.

The drawback of the UK system is the lack of effective oversight of the nomination

process by other parties than the board itself. The members of the board owe a fiduciary duty

of care and loyalty to all shareholders and no doubt perform their functions to the best of their

abilities but it is essentially an internal self-election process, albeit subject to ratification by

shareholders.

Page 23: Nomination Committees and Corporate Governance: Lessons ...eureka.sbs.ox.ac.uk/6838/1/2018-12.pdf · While corporate boards, audit committees and remuneration committees have been

22

The more serious consequence is that the British system does not create the feeling of

loyalty and mutual respect between directors and dominant shareholders of the Swedish

system. There are no dominant shareholders with whom to establish relations in the UK

process and therefore relations are transactional in nature. That makes reliance on indirect

mechanisms of corporate control through activism and takeovers particularly commonplace in

the UK context. It exacerbates the impression in the UK of short-term attitudes and

engagement by shareholders.

An external nomination committee is therefore part of the development of the longer-

term relations between domestic institutional investors and firms that appear to be emerging

in Sweden and have been noticeably absent from the UK. In addition to being a consequence

of the presence of share-blocks, Swedish external nomination committees contribute to the

formation of blocks by providing an inducement to shareholders to acquire sufficiently large

and long-term shareholdings to gain representation on the committees. It is in essence a

reward for sacrificing some of the benefits of portfolio diversification, namely insurance for

bad governance and reduced costs of illiquidity. Thus, the external NC works to empower

long-term institutional investors.

Shareholder-empowerment in Sweden relies on collaboration and trust, and makes it

easy for a block-holder or main shareholder to initiate a sale, share buy-back or break-up,

even if their share stake is small. At the same time, a committed owner can contribute to the

survival and success of a company, and newly listed companies in Sweden have in the last

years actively sought main investors at the time of their IPOs to purchase significant blocks of

their shares.

While the Swedish and UK systems may be regarded as contrasting in terms of their

structure and operation, there is no reason why elements of them should not be combined.

Pure external and internal nomination committee can be viewed as lying at two ends of a

spectrum in which the nomination process can vary between an external shareholder and

internal board determined process. For example, some of the board positions could be

nominated by external and other by internal committees. Alternatively, all appointments

could be by internal committee as in the UK but with some external shareholder

representation and, within both models, collaboration between external and internal parties

can be encouraged to ensure the nomination of a cohesive team of directors.

This development has significant implications for the exercise of corporate

governance because it provides for both long-term engaged shareholder participation and

independent self-appointments by the board. It allows, for example, for lead shareholders to

Page 24: Nomination Committees and Corporate Governance: Lessons ...eureka.sbs.ox.ac.uk/6838/1/2018-12.pdf · While corporate boards, audit committees and remuneration committees have been

23

take it in turn to initiate board positions on behalf of other shareholders and benefit

themselves from the lead role played by their co-investors in other companies. In other words,

a flexible application of internal and external nomination committees may help to address

many of the issues associated with free-riding and conflicts of interests in corporate

governance while promoting sustainable wealth creation in the interest of the company and its

shareholders as a whole.

Page 25: Nomination Committees and Corporate Governance: Lessons ...eureka.sbs.ox.ac.uk/6838/1/2018-12.pdf · While corporate boards, audit committees and remuneration committees have been

24

Appendix A

UK DEVELOPMENT OF HARD LAW COMMENT

UK COMPANIES ACT The duty of loyalty is "to promote the success of the company for the benefit of its members as a whole" and Companies Act 2006, § 172have regards to employees, environment, customers and suppliers, society, reputation and fiarness among differnet stakeholders

Companies Act 2006 The board is to be made up of a mixture of inside and outside (non-executive) directorsA shareholder may submit a proposal for the nomination of a director candidate if he holds 5 % of the shares of the company. Before 2009 10 % was required for the EGMIncumbant management and board do not have to treat these candidacies on equal footing with those proposed by the NCExceptions are made for smaller companies; these should have at least two independent non-executive directors Below the FTSE 350

Co-determination UK lacks employee representatives on the board; government plans for introdcuing an advisory board Conservative Party manifest, May 2017

TAKEOVER RULES Directors can consider other issues besides price when making a recommendation to the shareholders Takeover Code 2011 (after Krafts bid on Cadbury)

DEVELOPMENT OF SOFT LAWGOVERNANCE CODE The board must constitute not more than 50% executives and at least 50% independent NEDs. UK CGC 2016: B.2.1

A large shareholder, (with more than 10 % of votes), may only nominate one directorSeparation between the CEO and chairDirectors of the 350 largest listed companies shall stand for annual re-election Change 2010Nomination Committe to include three independent NEDs

Cadbury Code 1992 Introduced the notion of non-executive independent directors, suggested by a NC representing the board as whole Cadbury 1992: 4.10–4.17Myners Report 2001 Encourage investor engagement in corproate governance Was not very effectiveHiggs Report 2003 Cleared the independence of a large shareholder, set at 10 %, introduced a 10 year limit for independence

The NC to be made up of a majority of independent directors, clearer role for senior independent directorWalker Review 2009 Yearly re-election of all directors

Relaxation of definition of independence, to enable enrollment of industry-competence

ROLE OF NON EXECUTIVE DIRECTORS NEDs COMMENTNEDs Defined as independent of the company and an owner that might influence behaviour The Code and Companies Act

A senior independent NED is assigned the role to have contact with large shareholders UK CGC 2012: A.4.1

Controlling Shareholders An owner >30 % of votes must sign a "relationship agreement" codifying the relationship to minority shareholdersListing Rules. The Financial Conduct Authority 2014 FCA PS 14/8.

ROLE OF INSTITUTIONAL INVESTORSStewardship Code Subject to Stewardship Code since 2010

Encourage formation of "investor forum", supported by asset owners in 2013 IMA 2013bCompanies are obliged to state how they interact with their shareholders Code Provision 2014; E.2.2Targeting institutonal investors on the LSE to enhance engagement and monitoring long-term FRC 2010

Shareholder collaboration Owners "Acting in Concert", i e in control over 30 % of stocks must present a mandatory bid The UK Takeover CodeOwners may "collaborate" on director nomination, given that they not aiming for control seeking activities UK CGC 2012 principle 5

Page 26: Nomination Committees and Corporate Governance: Lessons ...eureka.sbs.ox.ac.uk/6838/1/2018-12.pdf · While corporate boards, audit committees and remuneration committees have been

25

SWEDENDEVELOPMENT OF HARD LAW COMMENT

COMPANIES ACT Separation between the CEO and chairman. Directors are voted in by simple majority at AGM. Only one executive on the board1944/75/95 A shareholder/shareholders controlling 50 per cent of the votes at the AGM can vote in all nominated directors Companies act. Voting rights Companies can have multiple voting stocks , no more than 1:10 Since 1995, before 1:1000Voting limits Until the millenium there existed different types of caps on voting i.e. 20 %, 5 %, number of shares (20) Removed over a numbe rof years, the last 2001Companies Act 1944 To enhance trust between different groups of shareholders – i.e. large dominating shareholders and minority shareholders – it

was possible to include in the company’s charter that no single shareholder should be able to vote for more than 20 per cent of the votes present at the AGM.

Companies act 1944 §114–127, p. 348–349.

Companies Act 1975 The chief rule of the stating that no shareholder may vote for more than one-fifth of the shares represented at the meeting, unless otherwise stipulated in the articles of association

Swedish Government SOU 1995:44 p. 20

Companies Act 2005 All directors are to act in the interest of all shareholders The General Clause in the Swedish Companies act 8 Ch. 41 § (ABL 2005:551)

Co-determination Two unionrepresentatives from blue and white color unions Medbestämmandelagen MBL 1974:580

DEVELOPMENT OF SOFT LAWThe Swedish external NC Swedish Shareholders Association suggested a Governance Code 1993, with an NC Sweden introduced a CGC 2005

Shareholders can decide on the NC at the AGM or set up a procedure, usually no later than 6 month before the AGM. The CGC offers different alternatives (CGC Rule 2:2) Smaller shareholders can invite a participant The AGM structure was suggested by the Swedish Shareholders' association in 1993. To provide continuity a member can be asked to stay, even of stocks have been sold 4/5 of the companies apply the Q3 model

Member on NC For long the word "representative" has been used, which the CGC corrected in 2008, instead writing "appointed by", CGC 2008 2 § 1 but "representative is still used, partly as a result of th epresence of large owners.

Setup off external NC Usually the largest 3 or 4 shareholders are invited at the time of the Q3A majority of its members must be independent of the companyAt least one member must be independent of the company's largest shareholder or groups of shareholders acting in concertChair of the board cannot be the chair of the NC, no executives on the NC, CGC Rule 2:3Directors can participate but only one may be dependent on a major ownerA representative of smaller shareholders can be invited to participateTo provide continuity a member can be asked to stay, even of stocks have been sold downShareholders can decide on the NC at the AGM or set up a procedure, usually no later than 6 month before the AGM. 4/5 of the companies apply the Q3 model

ROLE OF INDEPENDENT DIRECTORSListing requirements 2005–2010 the Nasdaq Stockhlm listing requriement of two from large owners independent directors: Two independent in the

Code All listed companies need to follow the code, including comply or explain

Swedish CGC The majority of the members of the board must be independent of the companyAt least 2 directors must also be independent of majority owner (defined as owner with +10 % of shares and votes)

Swedish Shareholders Association

Wants to se 3 directors independent of large owners written in the Nasdaq Stockholm listing rules Suggested in the Owner Policy 2017

ROLE OF INSTITUTIONAL INVESTORSStewardship Code Sweden lacks a Stewardship Code. Many have compiled their own code. Swedish Investment Fund Assoication has a codeLimits on voting The national pensionfunds (SNPF) have a voting cap at 10%. The retail funds have limits, generally viewed to be 10 % too Regulated in law

Cont. Appendix A

Page 27: Nomination Committees and Corporate Governance: Lessons ...eureka.sbs.ox.ac.uk/6838/1/2018-12.pdf · While corporate boards, audit committees and remuneration committees have been

26

Literature Adams, Renée, Benjamin Hermalin, and Michael Weisbach. 2010. The Role of Boards of

Directors in Corporate Governance: A Conceptual Framework and Survey. Journal of Economic Literature 48: 59–108.

Aglietta, M. and Rebérioux, A. (2005) Corporate governance adrift, a critique of shareholder value. Edward Elgar: Cheltenham, UK & Northampton, US. AIFM Directive 2011/61/EU of the European parliament and of the council of 8 June 2011 on

alternative investment funds. Akerlof, George A. 1970 The Market for "Lemons": Quality Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism

The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 84, No. 3. (Aug., 1970), pp. 488-500. Bhagat, Sanjai and Bernard Black. 1999. The Uncertain Relationship between Board

Composition and Firm Performance. The Business Lawyer 54: 921 — 2002. The Non-Correlation Between Board Independence and Long-Term Firm Performance.

Journal of Corporate Law 27: 231. Blair and Stout, 1999 A Team Production Theory of Corporate Law, Margaret M. Blair and Lynn A.

Stout Virginia Law Review, 85:2. pp. 247-328 Banbridge, 2015, Stephen M Bainbridge Preserving director primacy by managing shareholder

interventions. In Hill and Randall (Eds.) Dito. pp. 231–248. Becht, M., Franks, J., Mayer, C. and Rossi, S. 2009. ‘Returns to Shareholder Activism: Evidence from

a Clinical Study of the Hermes UK Focus Fund’. Review of Financial Studies, 22, 3093–3129. Bergh, Andreas och Magnus Henrekson. 2012. Varför går det bra för Sverige? Fores/Ivrig förlag. Berle, Adolf A. and Gardiner C. Means. 1932. The Modern Corporation and Private Property.

MacMillan: New York. Big Innovation Center, 2016 The Purposeful Company, Interim report, May

http://www.biginnovationcentre.com _ 2017. Also, final report, February 2017

http://biginnovationcentre.com/media/uploads/pdf/TPC_Policy%20Report.pdf Björkmo, Malin 2009. ’Fyra dyra fonder? Om effektiv förvaltning och styrning av AP-

fonderna’, Report for Expertgruppen for studies in public management (ESO), 4, Swedish Government Department of Finance.

Black, Bernard S. 1992. ’Agents Watching Agents: The Promise of Institutional Investor Voice’, UCLA Law Review, 39: 811–893

Blair, Margaret M. and Lynn A. Stout. 1999. A Team Production Theory of Corporate Law. Virginia Law Review. March. 85:2 pp. 247–328

Burkart, Mike and Sara Lee 2008. ‘One Share - One Vote: The Theory’, Review of Financial Economics. 12:1–49

Burkart, Mike, Gromb, Denis and Fausto Panunzi. 1997. ‘Large Shareholders, Monitoring and the Value of the Firm’, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, August: pp. 693–728.

Burkart, M. & Panunzi, F. 2008. Takeovers. In X. Freixas, P. Hartmann & C. Mayer (Eds.), Handbook of European financial markets and institutions: 265–297. Oxford: Oxford University Press

Cadbury, Sir Adrian, 1992 The Cadbury Code Commission. The Financial aspects of Corporate Governance. UK Code of Best Practice, Gee (a division of Professional Publishing Ltd) December.

Carlsson, R. H. (2007) “Swedish corporate governance and value creation”, Corporate Governance; An International Review, 15(6), pp. 1038–1055.

Chandler, A. D. (1962, 1977) The visible hand: The managerial revolution in American Business. Cambridge, MA: Belknap.

CEPS-ECMI Task Force 2012. ‘Rethinking Asset Management. From Financial Stability to Investor Protection and Economic Growth’, Brussels: Center for European Policy Studies, European Capital Markets Institute

Cheffins, Brian R., 2010. The Stewardship Code's Achilles' Heel. The Modern Law Review, Vol 73, Issue 6, pp. 1004–1025, November.

Page 28: Nomination Committees and Corporate Governance: Lessons ...eureka.sbs.ox.ac.uk/6838/1/2018-12.pdf · While corporate boards, audit committees and remuneration committees have been

27

Chandler, Alfred D. Jr describes in a seminal article from 1984 the emergence of managerial capitalism in the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries in the United States. Here the CEO is center core of the corporation, rather than the owners.

Cioffi, J. 2002 “Restructuring Germany inc.: The politics of company and takeover law reform in Germany and the European Union”, Law and Politics, 24(4), pp. 355–402.

Coase, Roland 1937 “The nature of the firm”, Economica 4(16), pp. 386–405. Commission Green Paper on Corporate governance in financial institutions and remuneration policies,

COM (2010) 284, Brussels, 2 Jun. 2010, 8 Commission Green Paper on Long Term Financing of the European Economy, COM/2013/0150 final Commission Proposal of European Long-Term Investment Funds ELTIF, Bruxselles. 26.6.2013 COM

(2013), 462 final, 2013/0214 (COD). Commission Proposal Amending Directive 2007/36/EC as Regards the Encouragement of Long Term

Shareholder Engagement and Directive 2013/34/EU as Regards Certain Elements of the Corporate Governance Statement, COM (2014), 213 final, 2014/0121 (COD).

Coval, Joshua D. and Tobias J. Moskowitz 1999, ‘Home Bias at Home: Local Equity Preference in Domestic Portfolios’, Journal of Finance, 54: 2045–73

Dahlquist, Magnus, Pinkowitz, Lee, Stulz, René and Rohan Williamson 2003. ‘Corporate Governance, Investor Protection and the Home Bias’, Journal of Financial Quantitative Analysis, 87–110

Davis, Stephen, Lukomnik, John and David Pitt-Watson 2006. The New capitalists: How Citizen Investors are Reshaping the Corporate Agenda. Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press.

–– 2009. ‘Active Shareowner Stewardship: A New Paradigm for Capitalism’, Rotman International Journal of Pension Management, 2: 10–17

Davies, Paul L. and Klaus J. Hopt 2013. Boards in Europe – Accountability and Convergence American Journal of Comparative Law 61. April 1. 301-375; Davies, Paul, 2015 Shareholders in the United Kingdom,. In Hill and randall (ibid), pp. 355–382. De Graaf, F. and K. Johnson, 2009. “Modernizing pension fund legal standards for the

Twenty-first century”. Rotman International Journal of Pension Management, 2: 44– 51.

Dent, George W Jr. 2012. Corporate Governance: The Swedish Solution, 64 Florida Law Review 1633.

ECGI Corporate Governance Codes http://www.ecgi.org/codes/all_codes.php Edmans Alex and Gustavo Manso 2011. Governance Through Trading and Intervention: A Theory of

Multiple Blockholders’, Review of Financial Studies, 247: 2395–428 Edmans, Alex 2014. Blockholders and Corporate Governance. Annual Review of Financial

Economics, (6), 23–50. Edmans, Alex and Cliff Holderness, 2017. Block-holders: A Survey of Theory and Evidence.

Handbook of Corporate Governance, forthcoming. Ehne, Mikael 2014. International Institutional Investors in Swedish Corporate Governance,

Conference Paper Presented at the Nordic Corporate Governance Network Annual Workshop, June 11-12, Stockholm.

Easterbrook, F. and Fischel, D. 1981. The proper role of a target’s management in responding to a tender offer, Harvard Law Review, 94(1161). — (1991) The economic structure of corporate law. Harvard University Press:

Ferreira, Miguel A. and Pedro Matos 2008. ‘The Colors’ of Institutions’ Money: The Role of Institutional Investors Around the World’, Journal of Financial Economics, 88: 499–533

Ferrarini, Guido and Filippelli Marilena, 2015. Independent directors and controlling shareholders around the world. In Hill and Randall (ibid.) (pp. 269- 294) Financial Conduct Authority (FCA) 2014. Conduct of Business Sourcebook (COBS), COBS 2.2.3R. Response to CP13/15 – Enhancing the effectiveness of the Listing Regime (on LSE). Policy Statement. May — FCA PS 14/8. https://www.fca.org.uk/publication/policy/ps14-08.pdf Financial Reporting Council, FRC 2011. Development in Corporate Governance 2011.

https://www.frc.org.uk/Our-Work/Publications/Corporate-Governance/Developments-in-Corporate-Governance-2011-The-impa.pdf

Page 29: Nomination Committees and Corporate Governance: Lessons ...eureka.sbs.ox.ac.uk/6838/1/2018-12.pdf · While corporate boards, audit committees and remuneration committees have been

28

– FRC, 2012. Stewardship Code evaluation. https://www.frc.org.uk/Our-Work/Codes-Standards/Corporate-governance/UK-Stewardship-Code.aspx

– FRC 2016. Developments in Corporate Governance and Stewardship 2016: https://www.frc.org.uk/Our-Work/Publications/Corporate-Governance/Developments-

in-Corporate-Governance-and-Stewa-(2).pdf Financial Service Authority, FSA 2009. Shareholder engagement and the current regulatory regime.

August 19. https://www.frc.org.uk/FRC/media/Documents/shareholder_engagement_FSA_letter.pdf

Gilson, Ronald J. 2006. ‘Controlling Shareholders and Corporate Governance: Complicating the Comparative Taxonomy’, Harvard Law Review, 119: 1642–79

Gore, Al and David Blood 2012. ‘Sustainable Capitalism’, White Paper. February. Gourevitch, Peter A. and James Shinn 2005. Political power and corporate control: The new global

politics of corporate governance. Princeton, N.J., Princeton University Press. Grossman, Sanford J. and Oliver D. Hart 1980a. ‘Disclosure Laws and Takeover Bids’, Journal of

Finance, 35: 323–34 — 1980b. ‘Takeover Bids, the Free-rider Problem and the Theory of the Corporation’, Bell

Journal of Economics, 11: 42–64 Grönberg, Lars and Kallifatides, Markus 2012. Presented at the EIASM 11th Workshop on corporate governance, St Gallen, October 2014. Hannes, Birkmose and Therese Strand, 2013. Institutional Investors: The Way to Active Ownership. To be published as Institutional Investors: Active Ownership through the Nomination Committees, in Susanne Young and Stephen Gates (eds.), Institutional Investors and Corporate Responses; Actors, Power and Responses, Emerald. Hansen, Jesper Lau (2013) “Active ownership and accountable directors. Board of directors in

European companies.” European Company Law Series. Vol. 10. Hansen, Jesper Lau (2007) “A Scandinavian Approach to Corporate Governance.” Scandinavian

Studies in Law, Vol. 50, p. 125–142. Hansmann and Thomsen (2012) Virtual Ownership and Managerial Distance: The

Governance of Industrial Foundations. Prepared for the conference on Corporate Governance after the Crisis, Oxford, January, 13-14.

Hellman, Niclas 2005. Can we expect institutional investors to improve governance?’, Scandinavian Journal of Management, 21: 293–327

Henrekson, M. and Jakobsson, U. 2012) “The Swedish corporate control model: convergence, persistence or decline?” Corporate Governance: An International Review, 20(2), pp. 212–227.

Hu, Henry T. C. and Bernhard S. Black 2006. ‘The New Vote Buying: Empty Voting and Hidden Morphable Ownership’, Southern California Law Review, 79: 811–908 Hill, Jennifer G. 2016 Images of the shareholder – shareholder power and shareholder powerlessness.

In Hill, J G. and Randall, S. T, 2015 (Eds.) Research Handbook on Shareholder Power. EE Elgar Cheltenham, pp.53–73.

Hill, Jennifer G. and Randall, S. Thomas, 2015 (Eds.) Research Handbook on Shareholder Power. EE Elgar Cheltenham,

Higgs, Derek 2003 Higgs Report: Review of the role and effectiveness of non-executive directors. Department of Trade and Industry. United Kingdom. Stationery Office. http://www.ecgi.org/codes/documents/higgsreport.pdf

Holderness, Cliff. (2009). “The Myth of Diffuse Ownership in the United States.” Review of Financial Studies, 22(4), 1377-1408;

Holdings. Statistics from Nasdaq Stockholm and Euroclear. Former SIS Ägarservice. www.holdings.se

Huse, Morten (2007) Boards, Governance and Value Creation. The Human Side of Corporate Governance, Cambridge. P. 370

Huse, M., Hoskisson, R., Zattoni, A. and Vigano, R. (2009) “New perspectives on board research: Changing the research agenda", Journal of Management and Governance 15, pp.5–25.

Huse et al (2014) http://fjolbreyttforysta.is/wp-content/uploads/2015/04/Professor-Dr-Morten-Huse-

Page 30: Nomination Committees and Corporate Governance: Lessons ...eureka.sbs.ox.ac.uk/6838/1/2018-12.pdf · While corporate boards, audit committees and remuneration committees have been

29

Conference-Iceland-Dec-2014.pdf IORP, Institutions for Occupational Retirement Provision (IORP) Directive:

http://www.theactuary.com/news/2016/01/european-parliament-approves-iorpii/# sthash.RrNZstAq.dpuf

Jackson, Gregory 2008. ‘A New Financial Capitalism? Explaining the Persistence of Exit Over Voice in Conteporary Corporate Governance’, European Management Review, 5: 23–6

Jackson, Gregory and Anastasia Petraki 2011. ‘How does corporate governance lead to short-termism? In: The Sustainable Company: a new approach to corporate governance’, S. Vitols and N. Kluge. Brussles, European Trade Union Institute. 199–226

Jensen, M. and W. Meckling, 1976. “Theory of the firm: managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure”, Journal of Financial Economics, 3(4): 305–360.

Kallifatides, Markus, Nachemson-Ekwall, Sophie and Sven-Erik Sjöstrand 2010. Corporate governance in modern financial capitalism. Old Mutual's hostile takeover of Skandia. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar

Kallifatides, Markus and Sophie Nachemson-Ekwall 2016. ‘Awakening Giants? The Politically Contested Modification of Institutional Investors’, Corporate Governance, 16:2: 278–94

Kristiansson, Björn and Skog, Rolf, 2004, Betänkande från Kod-gruppen; Svensk corporate governance-kod. SOU 2004:46. https://www.djoef-forlag.dk/sites/ntsdemo/PDF/2004_4/NTS04-2004_353_363.pdf

Kay, John 2012. ‘The Kay Review of UK Equity Markets and Long Term Decision Making’, London: The Kay Review Larsson, Ulf Olaisson “The Translation of Transplanted Rules: the Case of the Swedish Nomination

Committee”, part of doctoral thesis 2014. Lekvall, Per (2008), Nomination Committees in Swedish Listed Companies. Article in ICGN Yearbook 2008. Lekvall, Per (ed.) 2015. The Nordic Corporate Governance Model. Stockholm: SNS Forl Kershaw, David 2015.Corporate Law and self-regulation LSE Law, Society and Economy Working Paper Series, 5/2015. The London School of Economics and Political Science, London, UK. Lipton, Martin 2016. Corporate Governance. The New Paradigm. A Roadmap for an Implicit

Corporate Governance Partnership Between Corporations and Investors to Achieve Sustainable Long-Term Investment and Growth. Prepared for the World Economic Forum 2016. By Lipton, Wachtell Lipton Rosen and Katz. https://corpgov.law.harvard.edu/2017/01/11/corporate-governance-the-new-paradigm/

– 2013 The Bebchuck Syllogism. in The Harvard Law School Forum on Corporate Governance and Financial Regulation, August 26, 2013. http://www.wlrk.com/webdocs/wlrknew/AttorneyPubs/WLRK.22753.13.pdf London Stock Exchange 2012. Corporate Governance, for main market and main companies; LSE

First published: September 2012 http://www.londonstockexchange.com/companies-and-advisors/aim/publications/documents/corpgov.pdf

Mayer, Colin 2013. Firm Commitment: Why the Corporation is Failing Us and How to Restore Trust in It. Oxford: Oxford University Press

– 2015. Conceiving corporate commitment: creation and confirmation. In Hill and Randall (ibid.), pp. 211-230) Nachemson-Ekwall, Sophie (2018) Sweden: The Swedish Shareholders' Association Proposes 200

Policy Changes to Strengthen the Voice of Small Shareholders. International Company and Commercial Law Review, ICCLR.

Nachemson-Ekwall, Sophie 2016. ‘Leveraging on Home Bias. Larges Stakes and Long-Termism by Swedish Institutional Investors’, Nordic Journal of Business. Vol. 66 No. 3, pp.128–158. Autumn 2017.

Nachemson-Ekwall, Sophie 2012. ‘An Institutional Analysis of Cross-Border Hostile Takeovers: Shareholder Value, Short-Termism and Regulatory Arbitrage on the Swedish Stock Market During the Sixth Takeover Wave’, PhD-thesis. Stockholm School of Economics

Page 31: Nomination Committees and Corporate Governance: Lessons ...eureka.sbs.ox.ac.uk/6838/1/2018-12.pdf · While corporate boards, audit committees and remuneration committees have been

30

Nachemson-Ekwall, Sophie 2016. ‘A Sustainable Ownership Architecture for Sweden’, Report for independent think-tank Global Challenge. In Swedish. April, pp. 140. www.globalutmaning.se

Nordic Investor Services, 2010. Works of nomination committees in Swedish listed companies. How does the Swedish nomination committee work and how can it work better? 19 September. www.nordicinvestorservices.com Norwegian Corporate Governance Board (NCGB). 30 October 2014. The Norwegian Code of Practice

for Corporate Governance Code. Eight edition. http://www.nues.no/filestore/Dokumenter/Anbefalingene/2014/2014-10-30Code2014ENGweb.pdf

OECD 2008. ‘Governance and Investment of Public Pension Reserve Funds in selected OECD countries’, Yermo, Juan. OECD Working paper on insurance and private pensions, 15

OECD 2013. Promoting longer-term investment by institutional investors: Selected issues and policies, http://www.oecd.org/daf/fin/private-pensions/48616812.pdf.

OECD 2015. G20/OECD Principles of Corporate Governance, OECD Publishing, Paris. http://www.keepeek.com/Digital-Asset-Management/oecd/governance/g20-oecd-principles-of-corporate-governance-2015_9789264236882-en#.WRQ55FJ7HVo#page3

Office for National Statistics, UK. Ownership of UK Quoted Shares: 2014, released 2 September 2015. https://www.ons.gov.uk/economy/investmentspensionsandtrusts/bulletins/ownershipofukquotedshares/2015-09-02

Page, David (2010) “Distilling the debate on proxy access”, Harvard Business Law Review Online. Vol 1, pp. 15–17.

Petersson, Hans and Emma Sandberg Thomsen (2011) “Sweden, Chapter 23”. The Corporate Governance Review, Calkoen, Willem J K ed. Law Business Research, June. Reproduced by Mannheimer and Swartling Law firm, pp. 226–256.

Poulsen, Thomas, Therese Strand, and Steen Thomsen (2010). "Voting power and shareholder activism: A study of Swedish shareholder meetings." Corporate Governance: An International Review 18, no. 4: 329-343.

Romano, Roberta 2001. ‘Less is More: Making Institutional Investor Activism a Valuable Mechanism of Corporate Governance’, The Yale Journal on Regulation, 18: 174–252.

Second Swedish Nation Pensionfund (AP2) statistics http://www.ap2.se/en/news-reports/news/2016/ap2-female-index-2016-women-now-comprise-more-than-30-percent-of-boards-in-quoted-companies/

Securities and Exchange Commission SEC (2010) Facilitating Shareholder Director Nominations. US 2010, Rule 14a-8 and 11. November 15.

https://www.sec.gov/rules/final/2010/33-9136.pdf Shareholders’ Rights Directive, 2017. 23 March 2014/0121 (COD) amending Directive 2007/36/EC as

regards the encouragement of long-term shareholder engagement Sinani, Evis, Stafsudd, Anna, Thomsen, Steen, Edling, Christoffer and Trond Randøy

2008. ’Corporate Governance in Scandinavia: Comparing Networks and Formal Institutions’, European Management Review, 5: 27–40

Sjöstrand, Sven-Erik, Tom Berglund, Lars Grönberg, Markus Kallifatides, Flemming Poulfelt, Salla Pöyry and Olaf Sigurjonsson. 2016. Nordic Corporate Governance. An Extensive In-depth Study of Corporate Governance and Board Practices in 36 Large Companies. SSE Institute of Research. Elanders,. p. 173.

Smith, Adam 1776/1976. An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, University of Chicago Press

Stewart Fiona and Juan Yermo 2008. Pension Fund Governance: Challenges and Potential Solutions. OECD Working papers on insurance and private pensions, no. 18, OECD publishing

Stout, Lynn (2013). The Shareholder Value Myth. How Putting Shareholders First Harms Investors, Corporations, and the Public. Behret Koerher Publishing, San Francisco

SIS Ownership Service, Ägarservice, (2003–15), also Fristedt, Daniel and Sven-Ivan Sundqvist

Page 32: Nomination Committees and Corporate Governance: Lessons ...eureka.sbs.ox.ac.uk/6838/1/2018-12.pdf · While corporate boards, audit committees and remuneration committees have been

31

Swedish Companies Act (ABL 1944) Sixth edition. Aktiebolagslagen jämte dithörande författningar och med förklaringar. Wijkblad, Mauritz ans Nial, Håkan. Stockholm P.A. Nordstedt & Sönder forlag.

Swedish Companies Act (ABL 2005:551) Aktiebolagslagen Swedish Corporate Governance Board. 2016. The Swedish Code. 1 December.

http://www.corporategovernanceboard.se/UserFiles/Archive/619/The_Swedish_Corporate_Governance_Code_1_December_2016.pdf

Swedish Government SOU 1988:38 Ägande och inflytande i svenskt näringsliv. Huvudbetänkande från ägarutredningen. Isaksson, Mats and Skog, Rolf.

Swedish Government SOU 1995:44. The Company Law Committee. Aktiebolagets organisation. Rolf Skog (secretary).

Swedish Parliament. ‘Law 2004:46 on Investments Funds’. Lag 2004:46 om Värdepappersfonder. 19 February

Swedish Parliament. ‘Law 2000:192 on Swedish National Pensions Funds SNPFs’ Lag 2000:192 om Allmänna Pensionsfonder 13 April 2000

Swedish Shareholders Association, 2017. Value creative corporate governance. Owner Governance 2017. Stewardship, market development and the AGM. Sophie Nachemson-Ekwall acted as secretary for the committee. April.

The High Pay Centre, CPID “Corporate governance reform Submission to the Department for Business, Energy and Industrial Strategy”, report February 2017. http://highpaycentre.org/files/CIPD_and_HPC_response_to_BEIS_Green_Paper_on_Corporate_Governance_%281%29.pdf

The UK Companies Act 2006 (the Act) http://www.legislation.gov.uk/ukpga/2006/46/pdfs/ukpga_20060046_en.pdf

– Meaning of “significant control”. Part 21A of the Act. http://www.step.org/sites/default/files/Policy/PSC-register-Draft-Statutory-Guidance-3-December-2015.pdf

The UK Corporate Governance Code (the Code), 2012/16. April. Financial Reporting Council https://www.frc.org.uk/Our-Work/Publications/Corporate-Governance/UK-Corporate-

Governance-Code-April-2016.pdf The UK Stewardship Code. 2012. Financial Reporting Council https://www.frc.org.uk/Our-

Work/Publications/Corporate-Governance/UK-Stewardship-Code-September-2012.pdf The UK Small Business, Enterprise and Employment (SBEE) Act. Department of Business,

Innovation and Skills. 25 June 2014. https://www.gov.uk/government/news/the-small-business-enterprise-and-employment-bill-is-coming.

The UK Department for Business, Energy & Industrial Strategy (BEIS 16/56) 29 November. 2016. Corporate Governance Reform. Green Paper. Prome Minister Theresa May. Thompson, Robert B. 2015. The Power of Shareholders in the United States. In Hill and Randall

(Eds.) Dito, pp. 441–458. Tilba, Ann and Tilba McNulty 2013. ‘Engaged Versus Disengaged Ownership: The Case of Pension

Funds in the UK’, Corporate Governance: An International Review, 21: p. 165–82 Tomorrow’s Corporate Governance (2010): Bridging the UK engagement gap through Swedish-style

nomination committees. Mark Goyder and Harlan Zimmerman, senior partner Cevian Capital. http://tomorrowscompany.com/bridging-the-uk-engagement-gap-through-swedish-style-nomination-committees

UCITS 2009 Directive 2009/65/EC of 13 July on the coordination of laws, regulations and administrative provisions relating to undertakings for collective investment in transferable securities (UCITS)

http://eur-lex.europa.eu/LexUriServ/LexUriServ.do?uri=OJ:L:2009:302:0032:0096:en:PDF Walker, David, 2009. The Walker Review: a review of corporate governance in UK banks

and other financial industry entities. 29 November. http://webarchive.nationalarchives.gov.uk/+/http:/www.hm.treasury.gov.uk/d/walker_review_261109.pdf

Wijkström, Filip, Stockholm Center on Civil Society Studies at SSE Institute of Reserach (SIR), also

Page 33: Nomination Committees and Corporate Governance: Lessons ...eureka.sbs.ox.ac.uk/6838/1/2018-12.pdf · While corporate boards, audit committees and remuneration committees have been

32

Ideella föreningar – regler, föreningsstyrning, redovisning, Filip Wijkström (red.) Studentliteratur (2017).

Wong, Simon C Y 2015. Is Institutional Investor Stewardship Still Elusive. Butterworths Journal of International Banking and Financial Law July/August, 508–512. World Economic Forum. 2011. The future of long-term investing, in collaboration with Oliver

Wyman, Genève, http://www3.weforum.org/docs/WEF_FutureLongTermInvesting_Report_2011.pdf