New Final Growth

download New Final Growth

of 200

Transcript of New Final Growth

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    1/200

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    2/200

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    3/200

    Annual Average Growth Rate, g, for Y from

    1960 to 1997 comes from:

    ( Y1997/Y1960 ) = (1+g)1997-1960

    Thus, g = ( Y1997/Y1960 )(1/37) - 1

    Or: g = exp{(1/37)( ln(Y1997) - ln(Y1960 ) )} - 1

    Rule of 70:If Y grows at g percent per year, then:

    The level of Y Doubles every 70/g years

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    4/200

    t

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    5/200

    Table 1.1

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    6/200

    The world income distribution is highly

    skewed About 2/3 of the world population has at most

    20% of the GDP per worker of the US

    About 1/10 of the world population at least

    80% of the GDP per worker of the US

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    7/200

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    8/200

    The world income distribution is changing

    over time

    The bulk of the worlds population issubstantially richer today than it was in 1960.

    The fraction of people living in poverty has

    fallen since 1960.

    A major reason for these changes is therecent economic growth in China and India

    which together account for 40 percent of the

    world population.

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    9/200

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    10/200

    In addition to the level of income rising

    over time, the growth rate of world incomehas also been rising over time

    Note the ratio or logarithmic scale in thefollowing graph

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    11/200

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    12/200

    In contrast to world income growth rates

    that are accelerating, the growth rate ofincome for the US has not been growing at

    a faster and faster rate over time

    But the US growth rate has tended to be

    positive over time and has been roughly

    constant over the long run

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    13/200

    Fig. 1.4

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    14/200

    Growth Theory

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    15/200

    Chapter 2

    The Solow Model

    Norton Media Library

    Charles I. Jones

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    16/200

    The Production Function

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    17/200

    A production function describes the way we canuse inputs to produce outputs technically speaking, a production function tells us the

    maximum amount of output we can produce for everycombination of inputs

    An equation for the production functionY=AF(K,L)

    where :

    F is some function of A, K and L,

    K=stock of capital,L=labor

    and A is productivity, which accounts for all

    other factors that may be involved

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    18/200

    For a production function

    Y=AF(K,L)

    we typically assume:

    Positive marginal products

    when A rises Y rises

    when K rises Y rises when N rises Y rises

    Diminishing marginal products for K and N

    As K gets larger, an additional unit of K causes Y toincrease by a smaller amount

    As N gets larger, an additional unit of N causes Y toincrease by a smaller amount

    But as A rises, Y rises proportionally

    no diminishing marginal product here

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    19/200

    These conditions on marginal productstranslate directly into the derivatives on the

    production function Positive marginal products

    First derivative of F with respect to K is positive

    First derivative of F with respect to L is positive

    Diminishing marginal products Second derivative of F with respect to K is negative

    Second derivative of F with respect to L is negative

    It is easy to show that any percentage change in

    A has the same percentage effect on Y in thisproduction function

    The elasticity of Y with respect to A is 1

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    20/200

    We like to compare countries in terms of

    output per capita, so divide both sides of the

    equation by L

    Assume L is population, not number of

    workers, and for now dont worry about the

    distinction (Y/L) = (1/L)F(K,L) = F(K,L)/L

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    21/200

    A common assumption in economics is that

    the production function has constant returns

    to scale (CRS)

    That means if we double the inputs we will

    double the amount of output that we can

    produce CRS has a certain intuitive appeal

    If we own one factory and build a second factory

    that has precisely the same facilities and we employ

    identical workers in the second factory, we shouldbe able to produce twice as much output

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    22/200

    More generally, CRS means that a givenpercentage change in every input will change the

    amount of output we can produce by precisely thatsame percentage

    Assume F(K,L) is a CRS production function

    Suppose z is some percentage change in the factors

    CRS means that if Y=F(K,L) for particular values of K,L and Y, then zY=F(zK,zL)

    This makes it easy to turn our production functioninto a per capita measure

    Let z=(1/L):

    (Y/L) = F( (K/L), 1 )

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    23/200

    It is convenient to redefine variables in percapita terms

    y=Y/L output per capita

    k=K/L capital per capita

    And to use f to represent the new function

    y = F(k,1) = f(k)

    A graphical version of the production

    function

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    24/200

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    25/200

    Properties of the f(k) production function Positive marginal product with respect to k

    Increased k raises the maximum amount of output that can be

    produced Upward sloping

    Diminishing marginal product of k Increased k raises the amount of y that can be produced, but

    does so at a diminishing rate Concave shape

    These properties derive from our initial productionfunction, F(K,N), which has positive anddiminishing marginal products for K and for Nseparately

    Recall that F(K,N) has constant returns to scale (CRS)when K and N each change proportionately this feature was used to derive the production function in terms

    of output per person and capital per person

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    26/200

    A popular example of a production functionis the Cobb-Douglas production function

    Y=AKL1- with 0 < < 1where Y = output, K = capital, L = labor,

    and A is productivity.

    We need this productivity term in a productionfunction since there are times when twoeconomies use essentially the same amount ofthe factors of production, K and L, and yetproduced substantially different amounts of Y

    The assumption that is bounded between zero andone comes from the marginal product being positiveand diminishing

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    27/200

    HomeworkShow that the Cobb-Douglas production

    function has:

    A. Positive marginal product of capital

    B. Positive marginal product of labor

    C. Diminishing marginal product of capital

    D. Diminishing marginal product of laborE. Constant returns to scale.

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    28/200

    This production function can be converted

    into y as a function of k by dividing it by L

    y = Y/L = (1/L) AK

    L1-

    = L-1AKL1-

    = AKL1- L-1

    = AKL1--1

    = AKL-

    = AK(1/L)

    = A(K/L)

    Therefore, we get y = Ak

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    29/200

    For the Cobb-Douglas function The marginal product of y with respect to k is equal to

    the derivative of y with respect to k:

    Ak-1 Assuming A and k are positive, in order for marginal product

    of y with respect to k to be positive, must be positive number

    Using our rules for taking derivatives, the derivative ofthis marginal product with respect to k is:

    (-1)Ak-1-1

    OR (-1)Ak-2

    Since A, k and are positive numbers, the only way formarginal product to be diminishing is if

    (-1) < 0Which means < 1

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    30/200

    Graphing the Cobb-Douglas function

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    31/200

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    32/200

    The Basic Solow Model Solow won the Noble Prize primarily for his

    contributions to Growth Theory

    His model is the foundation of all modern

    growth theories

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    33/200

    The simplified Solow model

    Accumulation of physical capital, K, is animportant feature in this model Capital is built by investing in capital goods.

    Each dollar of investment, I, builds an additional dollarof capital. This means the capital stock will increase.This suggests

    K=I

    Where K is the change in the capital stock Capital increases if we invest

    This simple equation implies the capital stock willnever fall since I can never be negative. But thatimplication is not true empirically.

    What is missing is the fact that capital depreciates andthat a lot of investment is done to replenish depreciatedcapital. Let D=depreciated capital, and the equationbecomes:

    K=I-D

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    34/200

    Capital depreciates by

    wearing out from use or age

    becoming technologically obsolete (i.e. out of date)

    Since we model variables in per capita terms to

    compare across countries, divide all variables in

    the equation by L

    Redefine variables so that lower case letters denote

    per capita values:k=i-d

    For now assume that L is fixed not growing

    I

    L L L

    (!

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    35/200

    Assume that investment is a fixed share of

    income: =i/y noting that I/Y=i/y and

    that 0 < < 1

    Assume that capital depreciates at a constant rate:

    d=k

    (from D= K and then dividing by L ) Assume a general form for a production function:

    y=Af(k)

    K

    K

    K

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    36/200

    Putting all of these assumptions into the equation for

    capital accumulation ( k=i-d )

    We obtain:

    This equation tells us how the capital stock k is

    determined given specific values of , A, and

    parameters in the production function (e.g. in a

    Cobb-Douglas production function).

    It is convenient to analyze this model graphically (To

    make my equation line up with the following graph let

    A in the equation be 1, but this is only temporary itwill be very important to allow for changes in A)

    k A f (k) k ( ! K H

    K

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    37/200

    The graph plots three equations

    Investment per capita:

    Depreciation per capita:

    Output per capita:

    The gap between the investment per capita line and

    depreciation per capita tells us how much the capital

    per capita will change

    (k)K

    kH

    (k)

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    38/200

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    39/200

    If the levels of , A, and the parameters in theproduction function ( if its a Cobb-Douglas productionfunction) are constant, these 3 curves will be fixed that is

    they will never moveAn important implication of these assumptions is that

    the economy eventually settles down to a steady state levelof k - and consequently to a steady state level of y as well.

    Why?

    If we start out with k>kss depreciation exceeds investment and thecapital stock falls

    If we start out with k

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    40/200

    Output is determined by the production function

    and the level of capital

    Output follows movements in the capital stock

    At this point, nothing else is changing in the production

    function

    When capital settles down to its steady state, output

    reaches its steady state, yss, which is determined usingthe production function:

    yss = Af(kss)

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    41/200

    Homework Solve for the steady state values of y and k

    in our Solow model, using the Cobb-

    Douglas production function.

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    42/200

    The parameters that we have assumed are constantneed not always be constant.

    For example, may change because:

    Policymakers implement a policy to stimulate more investmentOR

    More savings becomes available to a country, which induces moreinvestment in that country

    Why? Investment is financed by savings (I=S-CA)

    A or also may change for various reasons (we willconsider this later)

    What happens when the investment rate (investmentshare of income) increases in our model?

    That is to say, when rises from to curves move and what happens as a result?

    K

    K

    2

    KK1

    K

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    43/200

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    44/200

    When considering how the economy responds to

    some change in a parameter or an exogenous

    variable, it is useful to assume the economy startsoff in an equilibrium position

    Then we can analyze

    If a change in some parameter (or exogenous variable) pushes the

    economy away from equilibrium

    And if so, how this works in the economy and in what way are

    variables affected

    If the economy eventually returns to equilibrium

    And if so, how it does this and how is the equilibrium position of

    the economy affected

    In the picture the initial position of the economy is

    ss1 ss1k k and y y! !

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    45/200

    An increase in the investment rate causes

    the steady state value of k to increase

    In the graph the new steady state k is kss2

    kss2 is greater than kss1

    So k must rise from kss1 and eventually reaches

    kss2

    Once k reaches kss2 it will stop rising and stay

    there (until, and unless, something else

    happens)

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    46/200

    Similar behavior is found for y

    The initial steady state is yss1.

    As k rises so does y

    This comes from the production function and the fact that k has

    a positive marginal product

    k stops rising when it reaches its steady state

    at that point y also reaches its new steady state labeled yss2 inthe graph

    An important implication: A one time increase in the

    investment rate will not make the output per capita

    grow faster in the long-run since it settles down to asteady state value in this model

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    47/200

    The previous analysis explained what happens if theinvestment rate rises for a country

    But it can just as well describe what happens if two countries have

    different investment rates Suppose Country 1 has an investment rate of

    Country 2 has an investment rate of and

    Our graphical model predicts that a higher investment shareyields a higher steady state level of output per capita

    What does the cross-country evidence tell us?

    1K2K

    2 1K " K

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    48/200

    At this point in the course, we dont knowhow to measure steady state output per

    capita But we do know how to measure output per

    capita in a given year

    Also, we can measure the averageinvestment share over a period of time

    When we plot actual y in a given yearagainst the average investment rate

    (investment share of GDP) we find there isa significant positive relationship

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    49/200

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    50/200

    This positive relationship between output-per-

    capita and the investment share across countries is

    predicted by the Solow model But we also saw that a permanent increase in the

    investment share WILL NOT lead to persistent

    growth in y or k

    Eventually k and y settle down to a steady state andgrowth discontinues

    The model still needs something to make y and k

    both grow over a long period of time as is

    observed in most countries In order to get y to grow in the Solow model,

    productivity (A) must grow over time

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    51/200

    Some may think y and k could grow forever if theinvestment share were to continually increase over time

    This is NOT reasonable for at least 2 reasons: First, many of the worlds economies have had output per capita growconsistently over long periods of time even while their investmentshares have stayed roughly constant

    Second, the investment share, I/Y, can not grow forever

    If it kept rising eventually all a countrys income would go toward

    investment leaving nothing for consumption, This would make peoplevery unhappy, in fact dead, since we all need a minimum amount ofconsumption just to survive

    And once again, after this share stops rising a country will eventuallyarrive at a steady state and stop growing. There could be no persistentgrowth.

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    52/200

    STOPPED HERE FOR

    MIDTERM #1

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    53/200

    Homework: Suppose that falls from 1 to

    2

    in our model (1

    >2

    ). Hold all other

    parameters as exogenous. Explain what

    happens to y and k over time. Do y and k

    grow forever or will they eventually arrive

    at a steady state? How does the new steadystate compare to the initial steady state?

    How would have to change in order for y

    to grow forever? Is it reasonable to thinkthat the depreciation rate can continue to

    change like this over time?

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    54/200

    Homework: Suppose that A rises from A1 to

    A2

    in our model (A1

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    55/200

    The conclusion from class and the two most recenthomework problems is: Rising investment share can not cause continuing growth of y

    and k for reasons cited a few pages back The only way that changes in may cause y and k to grow

    indefinitely is if the depreciation rate continues to fall. But theproblem with this hypothesis is that

    Depreciation rates do not exhibit any tendency to fall over time

    The depreciate rate can not fall below zero. This means that eventuallythere would come a time when depreciation would stop falling - thus kand y would eventually stop rising

    The only plausible way for y and k to grow indefinitely is if Acontinues to rise

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    56/200

    Unfortunately, Solow assumed productivity

    grew at some exogenous rate Exogenous means outside of or external to thesystem. Hence, Solows growth model doesntexplain what determines growth in productivity orthe economy

    While Solows model does not explain whyproductivity grows it has been used byeconomists to try to explain cross-countrydifferences in income per capita. We willalso examine some of these cross-countrydifferences.

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    57/200

    An advantage of the Cobb-Douglas production

    function is that it allows us to get an analytical

    solution for all variables of interest in the model

    Putting Cobb-Douglas in to our capital accumulationequation yields

    If there is no growth in A, then k settles down to a

    steady state: k=0

    k A k k E( ! K H

    An Analytical Solution to Solows Model

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    58/200

    When k=0:

    Solve for the kss:

    ss ssk k 0EK H !

    ss ssk kEK ! H

    1/(1 )

    ssk

    EK ! H

    ss

    ss

    k

    kE

    K !

    H1

    sskE K !

    H

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    59/200

    Then we can solve for yss: : ss ssy kE!

    /(1 )

    ssyE EK ! H

    1 / ( 1 )

    s sy

    E E K ! H

    /(1 ) /(1 )(1 )/(1 ) /(1 ) 1/(1 )

    ssyE E E E

    E E E E EK K ! ! H H

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    60/200

    Our final result is:

    Suppose we have two countries, Country i and

    Country j. Each will have its own steady state, yi

    and yj and the ratio of the steady states is:

    /(1 )

    1/(1 )

    ssy A

    E E

    E K ! H

    i i

    i

    j j

    j

    /(1 )

    1 /(1 ) ii

    ii

    /(1 )j 1 /(1 ) j

    j

    j

    Ay

    yA

    E E

    E

    E E E

    K H

    ! K H

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    61/200

    The previous equation allow each country to

    potentially have a unique value , , A or

    Suppose the investment share is the only thing that

    differs across countries.

    Then Ai=Aj, i=j and i=j,

    And our general result simplifies as follows:

    i i

    i

    j j

    j

    / (1 )

    1 /(1 ) i/ (1 )

    i

    ii i

    / (1 )

    j j1 /(1 ) j

    j

    j

    Ay

    yA

    E E

    EE E

    E E

    E

    K H K

    ! ! K K H

    K

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    62/200

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    63/200

    Numerical examples

    If

    then

    If

    then

    The ratio of income between richest and poorest countriesis more that 50 today

    This evidence suggests that cross-country variation in investment

    rates will not be sufficient to make the Solow model explain cross-

    country differences in income per capita

    i

    .2 (20 ) and .05 (5 )K ! K !

    1 / 2iy 4 2y

    ! !

    1 / 2iy 1 6 4y

    ! !

    i .32 (32 ) and .02 (2 )K ! K !

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    64/200

    Lets look at a broad selection of countries to seehow well or poorly the model performs

    We use a graph and a large cross section ofcountries that plots

    actual data yi/yj along with

    predicted yi/yj which equals:

    (this prediction comes from assuming countries onlydiffer in terms of the investment share and =1/3 for allcountries)

    1/ 2

    i

    j

    K K

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    65/200

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    66/200

    If this simple version of Solows model is correct,

    all the data points will be on a straight line with a

    slope of 1 that goes through the origin The model is perfectly correct if the only thing thatdiffers across countries is the investment share

    We dont expect any macroeconomic theory to be perfectly

    correct because macroeconomies are rather complicated social

    systems How far the data points are from this line yields some

    indication of how well or how badly the simple version of

    Solows model actually works

    So putting that specific line on the previous graph

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    67/200

    Th US i b t ti th li

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    68/200

    The US is, by construction, on the line Output per capita in US relative to output per capita in the US is always

    equal to 1 Nothing is learned here, but this helps us draw the line

    What do we learn from this picture? First, there is a positive relationship between the investment

    rate and income per capita, as is predicted by the model Countries with higher investment rates have higher GDP per capita

    Of course, we already saw this in a previous graph

    Second, the Solow model with only the investment ratediffering across countries does NOT do a good job ofexplaining the observed differences in output-per-capita

    Ireland is the only other country on the line (the US is also, but it is byconstruction - incomes are measured relative to the US level)

    Different investment rates seem to explain the difference in output-per-

    capita between Ireland and the US Except for Luxemburg which is well above the line, all other countries

    are below the line, and most of them are well below the line

    Interpretation: For nearly all of the countries, the model predicts thatoutput-per-capita should be much higher in countries than is actuallyseen when we examine the cross-country data

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    69/200

    So the model in its current form does not lookvery promising

    It doesnt explain why countries grow for an extendedperiod of time

    It doesnt explain most of the variation in income percapita that we observed across countries

    But dont give up totally on Solow We can reexamine the model under alternative

    assumptions

    The key conclusion from the last graph: Cross-

    country variation in investment rates, by itself, isunable to explain some of the most importantfeatures in the data

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    70/200

    Our current simplistic version of Solows model

    does have an interesting property: The farther a country operates below its steady state,

    the faster capital-per-worker and output-per-worker will

    grow

    And similarly, the farther a country operates above itssteady state, the slower capital-per-worker and output-

    per-worker will grow

    that property turns out to be a general property of

    the Solow model under all kinds of conditions It is also a feature of many other growth theories

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    71/200

    To see this point, return to the capital accumulation

    equation

    Divide both side of the equation by k

    Define the growth rate of k as:

    Then

    1k

    kk

    E(

    ! K Hkk

    k

    (!

    k k k

    E

    ( ! K H

    1k kE! K H

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    72/200

    We can plot the function that determines growth in k. It isconstructed from two terms

    1. The function of k:

    Which is

    A declining function of k

    (negative first derivative with respect to k,

    which stems from diminishing marginal product of k) A convex function of k

    (positive second derivative with respect to k)

    2. the depreciation rate

    (a straight line since it is not a function of k) The difference between the two terms gives us the growth

    rate of k

    1A kE

    K

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    73/200

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    74/200

    First notice that the graph provides another way of

    seeing why kss is a steady state

    k rises when kkss

    This graph also shows that the farther k is below kss,

    the larger is the growth rate of k

    And similarly, the farther k is above kss the slower

    is the growth rate of k

    in this case, growth of k is negative when k is above kss

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    75/200

    Output per capita is determined by the production function,

    and so it behaves like capital per capita

    Recall the Cobb Douglas production function

    It turns out that if y is determined by this production function, one can

    show that the growth rate of y is equal to the growth rate of A plus

    time the growth rate of k:

    The farther y is below yss, the larger is the growth rate of y

    The farther y is above yss the slower is the growth rate of y in this case, when productivity growth is zero, the growth of y is negative

    when y is above yss

    y AkE!

    y A k! E

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    76/200

    We can derive 3 important conclusions from thisanalysis (these can also be are found in a more general

    Solow model that would allow more than just theinvestment share to vary)

    1. If two countries have the same levels of productivity,

    depreciation rate and investment rate and they both usethe same production function, but one country starts outat a lower level of k and y, that country will grow at afaster rate (until both countries get to the steady state)

    This result is a direct implication of the last graph

    This illustrates a concept known as convergence holding allparameters the same across economies, poorer economies willgrow faster than richer economies

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    77/200

    2. If two countries start at the same level of y, but oneof the countries has a higher investment rate, thenthat country will grow at a faster rate The country with higher has higher steady state levels

    for k and y.

    If both countries start at the same levels of k and y, the one thathas farther to go (higher steady state levels of k and y) must growat a faster rate to make it to these higher levels of k and y (untilboth countries get to their steady states)

    In the following graph, country 2 has a higher investmentrate than country 1:

    and so country 2 is growing faster (vertical gap betweenpoints b and a) than country 1 (which is in steady state)

    K

    2 1K " K

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    78/200

    1

    1 A k

    E

    K

    1

    2 A kEK

    2 1

    K K

    c

    a

    b

    kak ck

    Growth rate of k

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    79/200

    3. When a country raises it will begin to grow a

    faster rate The higher investment rate causes k to grow faster whichof course causes y to also grow at a faster rate

    This is seen in the previous graph, by assuming a countrys

    growth rate rises from to

    Hence, the growth rate for k is initially equal to the

    vertical gap between points b and a in the previous graph

    However, as k rises the growth rate begins to slow (the

    vertical gap decreases) until the economy reaches the new

    steady state (kc) at which point growth stops

    Note: We still are assuming no productivity growth

    2K

    K

    1K

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    80/200

    Savings and Investment Savings and investment are intimately connected

    by an important national income accountingidentity

    I = S - CA

    (I/Y) = (S/Y) - (CA/Y)

    If CA (the current account) is equal to zero (mustbe zero for a closed economy) then savings isequal to investment. Furthermore,

    (I/Y) = (S/Y)

    investment rate = savings rate

    B t i l CA i t ll d d th

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    81/200

    But in general CA is not small and so we need the moregeneral result:

    (I/Y) = (S/Y) - (CA/Y)

    Feldstein and Horioka (1980) showed a very closecross-country relationship between the investment rate(I/Y) and the savings rate (S/Y)

    This is called the Feldstein and Horioka puzzle because:

    International capital markets should funnel savings toward the highestrate of return, adjusted for risk

    The fact that people do not invest that much in these high yieldingforeign assets implies a level of risk aversion that is unbelievably high

    Hence, the positive relationship between investment

    shares and savings rate implies a positive relationshipbetween savings rates and income-per-capita, which isvery evident in aggregate data

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    82/200

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    83/200

    Using our definition of national savings

    S=Spvt+Sgovt

    In the equation from before yields:

    OR

    Thus for the domestic investment rate to increase, at least one ofthe following must occur:

    An increase in the private savings rate;

    An increase in the government savings rate;

    An increase in the rate at which net foreign savings flows in (the netinflow of foreign savings is equal to CA)

    pvt govtS +SI CA= -

    Y Y Y

    pvt govtS SI CA= -

    Y Y Y Y

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    84/200

    The empirical evidence relating savings

    rates to income per capita provides somesupport for Solows model But other

    interpretations are possible

    Frequently, alternative structural explanations

    for a set of empirical evidence exist, and many

    times an alternative works in the opposite way

    to the first theory

    H d l ti th ff t

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    85/200

    How does population growth affect

    variables in the Solow model?

    For a fixed level of capital (K), a higher population

    (L) reduces capital per person (k) and so output per

    person (y) would also be smaller

    This effect of population on capital is known as capitaldilution (As L gets larger a given stock of capital must

    be shared by more workers)

    for output per capita to reach a steady state, capital

    per person must also reach a steady state Thus if population grows, capital must grow at the same

    rate as population growth to maintain a steady state

    capital per person

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    86/200

    We need to modify the capital accumlation

    equation to allow for population growthsince we derived the earlier version

    assuming there was no population growth

    First, we will show that the earlier capital

    acummulation equation doesnt work

    properly and then we will repair it

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    87/200

    Recall our capital per person accumulation equation

    (assuming fixed population)

    We know that by dividing both sides of this

    equation by k we get an expression for the growth

    rate of k

    k k f (k) / k

    k

    (! ! K H

    k f (k) k ( ! K H

    S h h i d h d i i

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    88/200

    Suppose that the investment rate and the depreciation rate are

    equal to zero. In that case the last equation says that k grows at

    the rate zero. If k growth is zero then k is at some constant

    value.

    Recall an even earlier equation: K=I-D

    If the investment rate = 0, investment = 0

    If the depreciation rate = 0, depreciation = 0

    Thus K=0, which means K grows at a rate of zero (divide both side ofthe equation by K, to get K/K

    K

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    89/200

    Heres the problem: k=K/L

    If K is NOT growing while L is growing then k must be shrinking ---- itcan NOT reach a positive steady state level

    We need to fix our k/k equation

    The fix is simple and intuitive: If and are zero then K mu

    also be zero. And, if L grows at a constant rate, n, k will be

    shrinking at that rate, that is k will grow at the rate n

    This suggests that the fix obtains by subtracting the population

    growth rate from the right side of the previous growth rate of k

    equation

    K

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    90/200

    We change the capital accumulation

    equation in specific ways It is convenient to change capital accumulation from a

    difference equation to a differential equation (this

    means changing from discrete time to continuous timemodel)

    From calculus we know that:

    Dividing by some finite number doesnt change that, so:

    K dK

    as t 0, lim t dt

    (

    ( p !(

    1 K 1 dK as t 0, lim

    K t K dt

    (( p !

    (

    Thus our original capital accumulation equation

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    91/200

    Thus our original capital accumulation equation

    becomes:

    We, also, will modify our Cobb Douglas production

    function to have labor augmenting productivity

    Labor augmenting means that in the production

    function A multiples L. AL is sometimes called effective labor input.

    It adjusts labor effort by the productivity of labor

    d (A , , L )d t ! K H

    1(A, , L) (AL)

    E E!

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    92/200

    Putting this all together yields our

    new capital accumulation equation

    But we want to put things in terms of output per capita and

    given constant returns to K and L that means when the

    production function is divided by L that will make of output

    per capita a function of productivity and capital per capita.

    Thus we would like to put our capital accumulation equation

    in terms of capital per capita.

    1dK K (A L ) K dt

    E E! K H

    We will assume for convenience:

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    93/200

    We will assume for convenience:

    Population (or the work force) grows

    at a constant rate

    Where n is a constant equal to the growth rate

    This is a differential equation that is easy to solve (if

    you know something about differential equations) The solution is: L(t)=Loent

    This is the equation for the level of L if it grows at aconstant rate

    1 dLn

    L dt

    !

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    94/200

    How are capital growth and capital

    per capita growth related? First, recall that k = K/L

    We can take the logarithm of the last equation

    Then take time derivative of this equation

    And finally obtain

    log(k) log(K) log(L)!

    d d dlog(k) log(K) log(L)

    dt dt dt!

    1 d k 1 d K 1 d L

    k d t K d t L d t

    !

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    95/200

    Thus, we can take the production capital accumulation equation from beforedivide by K, and use the last equation plus the assumption that labor grows ata constant rate to get:

    Or simplifying we obtain:

    Note that the resulting equation:

    Is the same as our previous equation for growth rate of k, except that we havean additional term, -n. We need that sort of adjustment for population growth,to make the analysis right in terms of k.

    1 1 1 11 dk

    K (AL) ( n) k A ( n)k dt

    E E E E ! K H ! K H

    1 11 dk

    k A ( n)k dt

    E E

    ! K H

    11 d k 1 K ( A L ) K nk d t K

    E E ! K H

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    96/200

    Thus we will see that there is a steady state for this

    model too, and the condition is the same as before:

    It comes essentially from the same graph, assuming all

    the parameters, including productivity, stay fixed. In this case, the steady state is the solution for kss to:

    Which has the following solution:

    1 1

    ss0 k ( n)E E! K H

    dk0

    dt!

    1/(1 )

    ssk

    n

    EK !

    H

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    97/200

    To prove that the model reaches a steady state, first

    multiply the growth of k equation by k:

    And note that from our previous Cobb-Douglas

    production function for Y, it is easy to show that:

    Thus we can graph the dynamic equation in k, assumingall parameters (including A) are fixed

    (note that =d in the graph, both refer to the

    depreciation rate)

    1dk k A ( n)k dt

    E E! K H

    1y k AE E!

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    98/200

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    99/200

    We can add the production function toanswer questions about what happens to

    output per capita and consumption percapita

    Output per capita comes directly from theproduction function

    Consumption per capita comes from: y i,which is the gap between the productionfunction and the investment line

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    100/200

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    101/200

    We can use this model (or any

    model) to do experiments The first experiment examines the effects of

    an increased investment rate

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    102/200

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    103/200

    The model predicts that countries with

    higher investment rates will tend to have

    higher levels of output per capita (andhigher levels of capital per capita)

    There is some empirical support for the

    hypothesis that countries with higherinvestment rates have higher output per

    capita

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    104/200

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    105/200

    A second experiment examines the

    relationship between population growth rate

    and output per capita

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    106/200

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    107/200

    The model predicts that countries with higherpopulation growth rates will tend to have lowervalues for output per capita (and lower capital per

    capita) We could also examine the effects of an increase in thedepreciation rate, using the previous graph. The resultsare the same, both qualitatively and quantitatively. Butwe dont expect there to be great differences indepreciation rate across countries.

    There is some empirical support for the hypothesisthat countries with higher population growth rateshave lower output per capita

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    108/200

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    109/200

    We can take the previous capital accumulation equation

    and divide by k:

    This is the growth equation for k, similar to one we

    derived before when there was no population growth Compared to the earlier graph, the only differences are that

    we used a differential equation and we allowed for population

    growth

    It looks very similar and has similar implications

    1 11 dk k A ( n)k dt

    E E! K H

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    110/200

    This model maintains the key conclusions we mentioned before

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    111/200

    y

    in a model without population growth

    - Convergence

    - Transition dynamics

    If two countries have the same levels of productivity,

    depreciation rate, investment rate and NOW POPULATION

    GROWTH, they both use the same production function, but onecountry starts out at a lower level of k and y, that country will

    grow at a faster rate (until both countries get to the steady state)

    Another way of looking at this graph: The farther below (above)its steady state the faster (slower) an economy will grow

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    112/200

    You can also show that: If two countries start at the same level of y, but one of

    the countries has a higher investment rate, then that

    country will grow at a faster rate initially

    When a country raises it will begin to grow at a fasterate (though not forever because it will again reach a

    steady state in the long run)K

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    113/200

    This version of Solows model maintains a keylimitation: There is no growth in k or y in the long-run

    That is the implication of these two variables settling downto a steady state

    You might conjecture that a continual decline in thepopulation growth rate could be a plausible explanation forpersistent increases in output per capita. But it is not.

    Eventually n would have to become negative for this decliningpopulation growth rate story to explain continual growth in y. And

    once population growth becomes negative the level of population isheaded to zero

    Also, many countries experience growth in output per capita with nochange in population growth rate

    Now we will allow for productivity growth

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    114/200

    If productivity grows at a constant rate, g, then, we can write this

    as the following differential equation

    As before, we can solve this sort of differential equation for the

    level of A: A(t)=Aoegt

    Productivity growth occurs whenever there is a new idea about a

    product innovation or a new idea about how to produce a product

    more efficiently (e,g, producing the same goods at a lower cost or

    producing more goods at no additional cost)

    We will see that productivity growth is the only thing that yields

    a plausible explanation for growth in y, k or any other per capita

    variables

    1 dA gA dt

    !

    It would be nice if we could put the model in

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    115/200

    It would be nice if we could put the model in

    terms of variables that do not grow. Then we

    might be able to obtain variables that achievesteady states.

    We saw previously that by dividing by labor

    achieved steady state when that was the only

    thing growing. Since we now have labor andproductivity growing, we can try to divide by

    both to see if that will give us a transformation of

    variables that achieves steady state.

    Recall our newest production function

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    116/200

    p

    If we divide by AL we get:

    Define

    Then the production function becomes y kE! %%

    1Y K (AL) K K

    AL AL (AL) AL

    EE E E

    E

    ! ! !

    1Y F(A, K, L) K (AL)E E! !

    K

    k AL!%Y

    y AL!%

    these transformed variables are defined as:

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    117/200

    these transformed variables are defined as:

    output per effective labor unit:

    capital per effective labor unit:

    where AL measures effective labor units, being the

    quantity of labor adjusted for productivity

    Jones likes to call the capital technology ratiok

    y

    k

    Now, return to our capital accumulation equation

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    118/200

    , p q

    First lets use a new notation that is common for

    growth modeling and common in mathematics.

    For any variable Z, define:

    That means:d

    d t

    !&

    d ZZd t

    !&

    d

    Yd t ! K H

    Using this definition in the capital accumulation

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    119/200

    equation

    Then dividing by K yields:

    Note that

    And so we obtain:

    1

    YY yA L k

    KK k

    A L

    E ! ! !% %%

    K Y

    K K! K H

    K Y K! K H

    1K k

    K

    E ! K H%

    We need an expression for the growth rate of capital in

    terms of capital per effective labor unit.

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    120/200

    p p

    Given that:

    We know we can take logarithms:

    Then take time derivative of this equation

    And finally obtain

    log(k) log(K) log(L) log(A)! %

    d d d dlog(k) log(K) log(L) log(A)

    dt dt dt dt

    ! %

    1 dk 1 dK 1 dL 1 dA

    dt K dt L dt A dtk

    !

    %

    %

    Kk

    AL

    !%

    And the last equation becomes:

    k K

    %

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    121/200

    And plugging this result into:

    Yields:

    Which can be written as:

    1K

    kK

    E

    ! K H%

    1k k (g n )

    k

    E ! K H%

    %%

    k Kn g

    Kk

    !

    %

    %

    k k (g n )k E! K H% % %

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    122/200

    Homework Solve for the steady state values of capital and output per

    effective labor unit in our model with population growthand productivity growth, assuming a steady state occurs.(This means solve for the values of endogenous variables

    in terms of parameters and exogenous variables) Calculate the steady state ratio of K to Y (called theaggregate capital to output ratio). Is it the same as theratio of k to y or is it different?

    On a ratio scale, graph steady state values of K and Y

    (hint the ratio scale and the logarithm scale are thesame). How fast are these variables each growing?

    On the same ratio scale, graph steady state values of kand y. How fast are each of these variables growing?

    Does this model achieve a steady

    state?

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    123/200

    state?

    Yes The two lines are fixed that is they stay in one

    position for fixed values of parameters of n, g, ,

    and

    There is only one positive steady state value for

    And starting from any positive level ofthe dynamics will push the economy in the direction

    of this steady state.

    K

    K

    K

    k

    k

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    124/200

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    125/200

    Now we can examine an important question

    that weve asked before with these models:

    What happens to the economy when theinvestment rate increases?

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    126/200

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    127/200

    An increase in the investment rate shifts the

    investment per effective labor unit line up

    Capital per effective labor unit begins to rise sinceinvestment exceeds depreciation, with both of

    these now measured per effective labor unit

    Finally, the economy settles down to a new steady

    state level of capital per effective labor unit

    We can also analyze this model using the growth rate

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    128/200

    We can also analyze this model using the growth rate

    of capital per effective labor unit form of the

    equation

    Graphing this equation yields the following whichillustrates how an increase in the investment rate

    causes fast growth of capital per effective labor unit

    initially,

    But, as the economy gets closer and closer to the

    steady state, the growth rate of capital per effective

    labor unit slows down

    1k k (g n )k

    E ! K H&

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    129/200

    And using the last equation it is easy to solve for

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    130/200

    And using the last equation it is easy to solve for

    the steady state value of capital:

    And steady state output per capita comes from

    putting the previous solution into the production

    function:

    1 /(1 )

    sskg n

    E K

    ! H %

    /(1 )

    ssyg n

    E

    E

    K! H %

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    131/200

    This model yields the same predictions as

    before:

    The farther an economy is below its steady statethe faster it grows

    The farther an economy is above its steady state

    the slower it grows

    We now examine the growth of

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    132/200

    We now examine the growth of

    output per capita

    We can get output per capita from the definition of

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    133/200

    output per effective labor unit. Since

    Multiplying both sides by A gives: If we divide by

    AL we get:

    This means that:

    YyAL

    !%

    Yy yA

    L! ! %

    y y A

    y y A!

    %

    %

    And from our production function, in per effective

    l b i

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    134/200

    labor units:

    We know that:

    So finally,

    y kE!

    y A k

    y A k! E

    &&&

    y k

    y k! E

    &&

    Using the constant growth assumption for A, we get:

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    135/200

    This equation tells us that:

    In the steady state y grows at the rate of g

    When the economy is below its steady state, y grows at a rate greater

    than g

    And when the economy is operating above its steady state y is grows

    at a rate less than g

    Thus, when the investment rate went up, y grows faster than g

    for a while, but eventually the economy returns to steady state

    and y growth rate returns to g

    y kgy k! E

    %

    %

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    136/200

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    137/200

    Recall that:t t ty y A! %

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    138/200

    Using our expression for A, we obtain: :

    This equations tells us how y behaves over time inthis model:

    Changes in output per effective labor unit shift the level of

    y, but dont affect its long-run trend which is given by the

    trend in A

    Changes in A0 will also shift the level of y, but not its

    trend line

    This idea inspired what became known as Real Business Cycle

    models (the first generation of those models)

    gt

    t t 0y y A e! %

    t t ty y

    Thus we see that an increase in the investment rate

    ill th l l f t i b t t ff t it

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    139/200

    will cause the level of y to increase, but not affect its

    long-run growth rate The following graph illustrates precisely what would

    happen in this model, plotting how the log of y

    changes over time:

    t t 0log y log(y ) gt!

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    140/200

    Once again the model predicts

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    141/200

    Once again the model predicts

    convergence and transition dynamics The economy converges to a steady state for

    fixed values of the parameters

    In the steady state real per capita variables growat the rate g

    The farther below/above steady state the

    faster/slower the economy will grow.

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    142/200

    Suppose there are two economies named

    InitiallyBehind (IB)

    InitiallyAhead (IA) We know that IB will grow faster in this

    model

    Transitional dynamics are the driving forcebehind convergence

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    143/200

    How well do the data support the

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    144/200

    How well do the data support the

    convergence hypothesis?

    We have convergence when we look

    h l f i f hi h

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    145/200

    at the sample of countries for which

    we have long time series

    For some countries we can obtainreasonably reliable estimates of GDP and

    population dating back at least as far as the

    late 1800s

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    146/200

    We also find convergence when we

    l k t l ti l ll d l d

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    147/200

    look at relatively well-developed

    countries in the postwar period

    This is a broader selection of countries, as well

    as a more recent and more reliable sample ofdata for the countries

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    148/200

    However, when we broaden the set

    of countries to include all countries

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    149/200

    in the postwar period, there isabsence of convergence

    Many of the countries that are much poorerthan the developed countries of the world are

    growing slower than those developed countries

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    150/200

    Adding Human Capital to the model

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    151/200

    g p

    It seems plausible that human capitaldifferences across countries may provide areasonable explanation for why countrieshave different performance levels

    Specifically, a low level of human capital mayexplain why many poor countries show noevidence of converging

    We also want to allow for differences in

    population growth and investment rate acrosscountries

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    152/200

    Assume that a persons human capital augments

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    153/200

    their labor input (labor measured in terms of hours

    or people) In that case, human capital enters the production

    function like productivity

    We multiply labor input, L, by human capital perperson, h

    This change will lead us to redefine output pereffective labor unit as:

    But, after that redefinition our analysis remainsessentially the same

    Yy

    h L A

    !%

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    154/200

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    155/200

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    156/200

    So we can plot the predicted ratio of GDP

    per capita versus the actual GDP per capita,

    holding A to be the same for each country

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    157/200

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    158/200

    This is a standard problem with Solow type

    models: They tend to over-predict how much

    income per capita countries will have, relative to

    US income per capita when we fix productivity inall countries to be the same

    So what if we allow productivity to differ across

    countries? We can use the equation to measure

    productivity in each country

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    159/200

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    160/200

    When you allow productivity to be differentacross countries, and use the Solow modelssteady state to calculate it, you find

    extremely wide variation in productivity in theworld

    Productivity is highly correlated with incomeper capita

    richer countries are more productive thanpoorer countries

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    161/200

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    162/200

    In fact, if you were to decompose cross

    country output per capita differences into

    productivity differences and differencesexplained by all the other factors in the

    Solow model, productivity differences

    account for most of the cross country

    differences in y

    Conditional Convergence

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    163/200

    Conditional Convergence

    Our model allows each country to have its own

    steady state depending on its own investment rate,

    population growth rate and human capital.

    Conditional convergence is the idea that countries

    converge to their own steady state, and how far

    they are away from their own steady state is what

    determines how fast they are growing

    We are assuming that g is the same for all countries

    Conditional convergence holds up

    fairly well in the data

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    164/200

    fairly well in the data

    Growth rate since 1960 is plotted against1960y

    y *

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    165/200

    Growth Accounting

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    166/200

    is is a technique for decomposing economicgrowth into contributions from various sources

    More specifically, growth accounting decomposes

    output per capita growth into contributions from

    the various factors (e.g. capital per capita growth)and also from productivity growth

    This last component is sometimes called

    the Solow residual or

    the contribution from multifactor productivity

    And is sometimes also called our measure of ignorance since

    it is the part of growth that we cant explain with measurable

    changes in factors

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    167/200

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    168/200

    A simplistic example of how to do a

    decomposition calculation

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    169/200

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    170/200

    In practice economists have tried to furtherdecompose growth into additionalcomponents such as

    Labor composition

    This is how labor may be shifting from productionto R D, or vice versa

    Also, the capital per worker contribution can be

    separated into IT (information technology)capital and other components

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    171/200

    Table 2.1

    Growth accounting teaches us that the big changesin the growth rate of output per capita (or per

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    172/200

    worker) are largely the result of changes in the

    growth rate of productivity From this accounting we observe the productivity

    growth slow-down that plagued all countriesstarting in the early 1970s

    This was particularly problematic for most of thedeveloped countries

    And we can also see that strong productivitygrowth returned starting in the mid 1990s for the

    US. The US benefited more from this productivity growth

    than most other developed countries

    Why did productivity growth slow

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    173/200

    down in the early 1970s? Historically, the slow-down has been attributed to

    various sources

    One that looked particularly promising was the

    rapid rise in oil price shocks in the 1970s

    In out model this amounts to a reduction in A0, or better

    yet, a persistent decline in A0 which would lead to a

    persistent slow down in the growth rate of output per

    capita

    The problem: In the 1980s there was no resurgence of

    rapid productivity growth as oil prices fell dramatically

    A variety of other explanations have also beenoffered . For example:

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    174/200

    Running out of ideas

    Natural resource depletion

    Excessive regulatory burden on firms

    Reduced labor ability and/or reduced labor force

    work ethic No single explanation seems a totally

    satisfactory by itself

    Each one may provide a partial explanation

    But none of them, or all taken together, seem tobe a good candidate for explaining whyproductivity growth picked up in the mid-1990s

    An explanation for both why the productivity growth slowed andwhy it then increased in 1990s: Technological revolution

    The revolution is thought to be the expanding use of computersand information technology. The basic idea:

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    175/200

    Computers (and later, the Web) represent a general purpose technology

    that can broadly affect how we produce and the types of goods we make Any new technology requires time to learn how to utilize it properly

    This takes labor time away from production causes output to fall relativeto the amount of labor input

    A larger share of labor is being devoted to learning rather than production

    Economic historians, such as Paul David, have examined how

    the introduction of new general purpose technologies (e.g. steamengines, electricity, etc.) in earlier periods coincided with adecline in output per capita that lasted for some period of time,but eventually in all those cases more rapid growth returned

    This story can explain the resurgence of productivity growth in

    the 90s, By then, people understood the new technologies wellenough to make significant and frequent improvements inproductivity. Thus caused output per capita to start growing at afaster rate

    Endogenous Growth Models

    E d th ll k th

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    176/200

    Endogenous growth usually make the

    growth rate of productivity endogenous

    However, some models generate growth by

    having constant returns to scale for capital

    in the production function This can be generated from learning by doing,

    for example.

    However, CRS for capital yields implicationsthat do not appear valid in the data

    So Im going to ignore these models from now on

    Romers model of Endogenous

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    177/200

    Growth

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    178/200

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    179/200

    The effectiveness of workers depends on

    how many ideas there are in the economy

    Assumption: The more ideas there are, the moreways ideas can be combined to create new ideas

    OR the more ideas can be refined/extended to

    create new ideas

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    180/200

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    181/200

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    182/200

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    183/200

    World population has been increasing since

    the dawn of man (with some notable

    exceptions like the Dark Ages)

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    184/200

    p g )

    But while the population was rising thepopulation growth was at a very small rate,

    until relatively recently in human history

    Around 300 years ago the rate of output

    growth started to increase and that coincides

    with the increasing world population growth

    rate

    There is some evidence that the number of

    new ideas has been growing rapidly,

    Suppose new ideas are measured by the number

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    185/200

    Suppose new ideas are measured by the number

    of patents US patents have increased dramatically over

    time

    But the growth rate of ideas has not been rising

    Trust me it may not be evident from this graph

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    186/200

    However, the number of scientists has risen

    dramatically over time

    This implies that if the model is correct, the

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    187/200

    This implies that if the model is correct, the

    growth rates for productivity and output percapita should have been rising during this time

    period

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    188/200

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    189/200

    Romers model predicts that this rise in the

    number of scientists and engineers will lead

    to faster productivity growth

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    190/200

    There is no clear relationship between the

    number of scientists and either the pace of

    output growth in the developed world or the

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    191/200

    p g p

    pace at which ideas are created. Since 1970 the dramatic increase in

    scientists and engineers in the developed

    world has not cause these countries to growat noticeably faster rates

    This has suggested to Jones and others thatwe modify our growth model along certain

    plausible lines

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    192/200

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    193/200

    Therefore, this version of the endogenous growth

    model predicts that higher growth rates of

    productivity and output will coincide with a higher

    population growth rate

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    194/200

    population growth rate.

    This is what the evidence shows, in contrast to the

    first endogenous growth model which predicted

    that higher level of population would lead to

    higher growth rates in productivity and output. This implication of the model will be tested in

    your (expected) lifetime.

    World population growth will slow down substantially

    within about 50 years maybe go to 0%. This model predicts productivity growth will slow

    dramatically, maybe even stop growing

    Schumpeterian models of endogenous

    growth

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    195/200

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    196/200

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    197/200

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    198/200

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    199/200

  • 8/7/2019 New Final Growth

    200/200