Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who...

26
Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who Joins Them and How Can They Do Better? Benoît Malan Assistant Professor University of Cocody – Abidjan [email protected] Tina L. Saitone Project Economist University of California, Davis [email protected] Richard J. Sexton Professor and Chair University of California, Davis [email protected] Selected Paper prepared for presentation at the 2015 Agricultural & Applied Economics Association and Western Agricultural Economics Association Annual Meeting, San Francisco, CA, July 26-28 Copyright 2015 by Malan, Saitone, and Sexton. All rights reserved. Readers may make verbatim copies of this document for non-commercial purposes by any means, provided that this copyright notice appears on all such copies.

Transcript of Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who...

Page 1: Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who …ageconsearch.umn.edu/bitstream/205522/2/Malan_Saitone_Sexton_AAE… · Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who Joins

Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who Joins Them and How Can They Do Better?

Benoît Malan Assistant Professor

University of Cocody – Abidjan [email protected]

Tina L. Saitone

Project Economist University of California, Davis

[email protected]

Richard J. Sexton Professor and Chair

University of California, Davis [email protected]

Selected Paper prepared for presentation at the 2015 Agricultural & Applied Economics Association and Western Agricultural Economics Association Annual Meeting, San

Francisco, CA, July 26-28

Copyright 2015 by Malan, Saitone, and Sexton. All rights reserved. Readers may make verbatim copies of this document for non-commercial purposes by any means, provided that this copyright notice appears on all such copies.

Page 2: Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who …ageconsearch.umn.edu/bitstream/205522/2/Malan_Saitone_Sexton_AAE… · Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who Joins

  2

Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who Joins Them and How Can They Do Better?

Agricultural marketing cooperatives have the potential to enhance the rate of economic

development in poor countries and improve the lot of small farmers because the

economic problems that are potentially addressed through cooperatives (Sexton 1986;

Sexton and Iskow 1988; World Bank 2008; Soboh et al. 2009) are widespread in

developing country settings. For example, cooperatives can enable small farmers to

agglomerate production and jointly capture the benefit of downstream scale economies in

value chains that are beyond the reach of individual producers. Marketing cooperatives

also enable farmers to avoid selling to for-profit buyers who may exercise monopsony

power due to the farmers’ limited access to outside selling options (Sexton 1990).

However, cooperatives in developing countries were traditionally creations of the

government, staffed and controlled by government employees, and generally

unsuccessful (World Bank 2008). Liberalization beginning in the 1980s led to the

creation of voluntary cooperative organizations at the volition of producers. For example,

nowadays on the African continent seven percent of the population belongs to a

cooperative, and 50% of all cooperatives are for agricultural marketing purposes

(Develtere, Pollet, and Wanyama 2009). This cooperative movement within developing

countries has received considerable attention by researchers, international development

agencies, and donors (e.g., Uphoff 1993; Berdegue 2001; Rondot and Collion 2001; Bosc

et al. 2002).

Empirical evidence suggests that the potential of cooperatives has been fulfilled in

at least some instances, with cooperatives paying a price premium to their members,

relative to what can be earned in the open market. For example, Shiferaw et al. (2009)

Page 3: Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who …ageconsearch.umn.edu/bitstream/205522/2/Malan_Saitone_Sexton_AAE… · Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who Joins

  3

showed that producer marketing groups in Kenya paid 22-24% higher prices than other

buyers of pigeon pea, while Bernarda, Taffeseb, and Gabre-Madhina (2008) found that

cooperatives in the cereal sector in Ethiopia paid 7.2-8.9% higher prices than private

traders.

However, despite their emergence and strong raison d’être within developing

countries, there are widespread concerns that marketing cooperatives have not fulfilled

their potential (e.g., Braverman et al. 1991). In this paper we examine two related

considerations endemic to cooperatives that can impede their effectiveness in developing-

country settings. One key concern is the delay with which cooperatives make payments.

While private buyers pay farmers cash at the time of delivery, cooperatives usually do

not. Instead payment is often delayed for several weeks after delivery to the cooperative,

until the crop has been marketed and related expenses have been paid. Such delays in

payment can be very problematic, particularly for the most cash-constrained and, thus,

impatient households, and may constitute a significant barrier to cooperative membership

for them.

Delay in payments has been found to be an important problem for cooperatives in

many African countries (Calkins and Ngo 2005; Shiferaw, Obare, and Muricho 2008;

Shiferaw et al. 2009; Markelova and Mwangi 2010; Mujawamariya, D’Haese, Speelman

2012; O’Brien, Banwart and Cook 2013; Theriault, Serra, and Sterns 2013; Verhofstadt

and Maertens 2014). Shiferaw, Obare, and Muricho (2008) found, for example, that the

time lag for producer marketing groups to make payment after delivery could reach five

weeks in the case of the grain marketing in Kenya, while Calkins and Ngo (2005)

reported delays by cooperatives of three weeks in payment to cacao farmers in Cote

Page 4: Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who …ageconsearch.umn.edu/bitstream/205522/2/Malan_Saitone_Sexton_AAE… · Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who Joins

  4

d’Ivoire. In the case of cotton marketing cooperatives in Mali, the delay in payment

averaged about six weeks, but ranged from less than one week to 25 weeks (Theriault,

Serra, and Sterns 2013).

A delay in receipt of the promised payment means, of course, that farmers will

discount its value when considering their marketing options. Discount rates and types of

discounting have been studied in various developing-country settings, mostly through

experiments (e.g., Pender 1996; Botelho et al. 2006; Tanaka, Camerer, and Nguyen

2010). Although the specific results from such studies differ widely, consensus

conclusions are that people discount future payments at rates above market interest rates

and that considerable heterogeneity in discount rates exists across individuals.

A second and related concern among developing-country farmers regarding

selling through cooperatives is the problem of default in payments. Inherent to the fact

that the payments to members are not made upon delivery is a possibility that the

cooperative will default and not pay the member at all (Braverman et al. 1991), creating a

problem of risk and uncertainty for farmers selling through these cooperatives.

A large number of studies have established that farmers in developing countries

are generally averse to such risk, but that there is considerable heterogeneity among a

farmer cohort as to the degree of risk aversion (Moscardi and de Janvry 1977; Dillon and

Scandizzo 1978; Binswanger 1980, 1981, 1982; Binswanger and Sillers 1983; Wik et al.,

2004; Yesuf and Bluffstone 2009; Harrison, Humphrey and Verschoor 2010; de Brauw

and Eozenou 2014). However, no consensus has emerged as to the form of risk aversion

and its relationship, if any, to wealth. Accordingly, risk of default can be a considerable

deterrent to marketing through a cooperative for at least the most risk averse farmers.

Page 5: Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who …ageconsearch.umn.edu/bitstream/205522/2/Malan_Saitone_Sexton_AAE… · Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who Joins

  5

Thus, a typical developing-country setting is that a risk-averse and cash-

constrained farmer can sell either on the spot market to a private trader who has

monopsony power but who pays at the time of delivery or through a marketing

cooperative which promises a premium above the trader’s price, but delays the payment

and carries the concomitant risk of default.

We construct a microeconomic model to study this decision and cooperative

marketing among a group of heterogeneous, developing country farmers. The goal is to

understand what types of farmers will choose to join a marketing cooperative and sell

some or all of their production through the cooperative. We show that this decision can

be expressed as a function of the farmer’s relative impatience (i.e., discount factor),

initial wealth, and degree of risk aversion, and as a function of the price premium offered

by the cooperative relative to the open market, the length delay in the promised payment,

and the probability of default risk.

We then construct a simulation model that is parameterized to fit, as best possible,

a profile of farmers within a prototype developing-country village, and study the optimal

decisions of this heterogeneous group regarding marketing production, in all or part,

through a cooperative vs. a private trader. The goal is to understand the factors that limit

the size and market share of cooperatives and, ultimately, restrain their effectiveness, and

thereby identify policies to improve marketing cooperatives’ performance in developing-

country settings.

Page 6: Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who …ageconsearch.umn.edu/bitstream/205522/2/Malan_Saitone_Sexton_AAE… · Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who Joins

  6

The Model

We assume each farmer i’s impatience can be represented by a unique exponential

discount function, with discount parameter, 𝛿! ≤ 1.1 We further assume that each farmer

is characterized by a von Neumann-Morgenstern utility function, 𝑈! 𝑊! , where 𝑈!! > 0,

and 𝑈!!! ≤ 0, and where 𝑊! is the farmer’s wealth, which is comprised of 𝑊!! in initial

wealth and net income received from farming.2 We also assume that each farmer’s degree

of risk aversion can be represented by the Arrow-Pratt coefficient of absolute risk

aversion 𝜆! = − !!!!

!!! where 𝜆! ≥ 0.3

Each farmer, i, thus, is characterized by the triple (𝛿! ,𝑊!!, 𝜆!), and produces one

unit of commodity that can then be marketed in any share, 0 ≤ 𝛼! ≤ 1, through a

cooperative, with the remaining share marketed through a private trader.4 For simplicity

we assume that there is a single co-op marketing alternative for farmers within the

village.

We normalize the price offered by the outside trader net of farmers’ variable

production costs to be 1.0. The trader makes payment immediately, at time 𝑡 = 0. The net

                                                                                                               1  The exponential discounting model does not allow the discount function to decline at a greater rate in the short term than the long term, an outcome which has found support in some experimental settings and isincorporated in hyperbolic or quasi-hyperbolic discount models (Laibson 1997; Frederick, Loewenstein, and O’Donoghue 2002; Angeltos et al. 2001). Whereas this consideration is of paramount consideration in some instances, e.g., models of life cycle consumption, it is less important here where delays in payment by a cooperative are typically only a few weeks. Further, empirical evidence in support of exponential vs. hyperbolic discount models in developing-country settings is mixed (Botelho et al. 2005, Tanaka, Camerer, and Nguyen 2010). 2 Prospect theory (Kahneman and Tversky 1979) presents itself as an alternative to expected utility theory. See Tanaka, Camerer, and Nguyen (2010) for a study that evaluates prospect theory and expected utility theory in an experimental setting. We opted to use expected utility theory due to its analytical simplicity relative to prospect theory. 3 See Binswanger (1981) for a discussion and comparison among alternative measures of risk aversion. 4 The special case where cooperatives require exclusive membership can be readily characterized by restricting 𝛼  𝜖   0,1 .

Page 7: Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who …ageconsearch.umn.edu/bitstream/205522/2/Malan_Saitone_Sexton_AAE… · Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who Joins

  7

price promised by a cooperative is 𝜇 > 1,5 where 𝜇 − 1 represents the percentage margin

premium promised by the cooperative, and its discounted value to the 𝑖!! farmer is 𝜇𝛿!! ,

where T > 0 is the number of time periods scheduled for the delay in payment. A

cooperative also has a positive probability, 1− 𝜌 > 0 of defaulting on the payment. A

co-op, j, is thus characterized by the triple (𝜇! ,𝑇! ,𝜌!).6

We assume a farmer seeks to maximize expected utility with respect to the

allocation of his crop between market outlets. A farmer’s optimization problem is the

following:

1                max 0 ≤ 𝛼 ≤ 1  𝜓 𝛼 𝜌, 𝜇,𝑊!, 𝜆, 𝛿,𝑇

= 𝜌𝑈 𝛼𝛿!𝜇 + (1− 𝛼)+𝑊! + 1− 𝜌 𝑈 1− 𝛼 +𝑊! ,

The first expression on the right-hand side of (1) reflects the utility from marketing 𝛼

share of production through the cooperative in the no-default case. The second term

represents the utility in the case of co-op default.

Let the solution to (1) be denoted as 𝛼∗. The optimum may lie at either “corner”

of the admissible range for 𝛼, i.e., 𝛼∗ = 0, marketing exclusively through a trader, or

𝛼∗ = 1, marketing exclusively through the cooperative. Interior solutions, 0 < 𝛼 < 1, are

also possible, however, as farmers seek to balance the promised higher payment from the

cooperative with the risk that the cooperative may default.

                                                                                                               5 Marketing cooperatives in developing countries sometimes provide free or subsidized inputs to their members. Our model readily handles such cases given the interpretation of prices as net of production costs. Thus, the margin premium, 𝜇, offered by a cooperative may consist of both a price premium and lower input costs compared to marketing through a private trader. 6  Although we characterize 1 − 𝜌 as a default probability, its function in our model is very similar to a parameter to measure “present bias” in models with quasi-hyperbolic discounting (Angeletos et al. 2001, Tanaka, Camerer, and Nguyen 2010). Present bias measures the degree to which people prefer an immediate reward to one that is deferred at all. One explanation for present bias is the belief that a future reward will not materialize, for whatever reason, but in our specific context because the cooperative may default on the promised payment.

Page 8: Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who …ageconsearch.umn.edu/bitstream/205522/2/Malan_Saitone_Sexton_AAE… · Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who Joins

  8

The first-order condition for an interior solution to problem (1) is the following:

2                  𝑑𝜓𝑑𝛼 = 𝑈!𝜌 𝛿!𝜇 − 1 − 𝑈! 1− 𝜌 = 0.

Lemma 1: The condition 𝜌𝛿!𝜇 > 1 is necessary and sufficient for a farmer with discount

factor 𝛿 to market production through the cooperative defined by (𝜌,𝑇, 𝜇), i.e., for

𝛼∗ > 0.

Proof: The derivative !"!"

, when evaluated at 𝛼 = 0, simplifies to 𝜌𝛿!𝜇 − 1. Thus,

𝜌𝛿!𝜇 > 1 establishes that expected utility is increasing in 𝛼, when evaluated at 𝛼 = 0,

and, therefore, that the farmer can increase utility by selling some production to the

cooperative if and only if this condition holds.

Lemma 1 establishes that even a highly risk averse farmer will market positive

production through the cooperative as long as the expected discounted net price promised

by the cooperative exceeds the certain and immediate net payment offered by the outside

trader.

Lemma 2: The derivative !"!"

is non-increasing in 𝛼 whenever 𝜌𝛿!𝜇 > 1, and it is strictly

decreasing in 𝛼 for a risk-averse farmer.

Proof: The condition 𝜌𝛿!𝜇 > 1 establishes that expected discounted revenue is higher

for product marketed through the cooperative than through the trader, but 𝑈′ is non-

increasing in expected income due to 𝑈′′ ≤ 0, and it is strictly decreasing in expected

income when 𝑈!! < 0, i.e., the farmer is risk averse.

Lemma 3: The condition 𝜌𝛿!𝜇 < 1 is necessary and sufficient for the farmer with

discount factor 𝛿 to market production exclusively through the outside trader and to not

patronize the cooperative defined by (𝜌,𝑇, 𝜇).

Page 9: Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who …ageconsearch.umn.edu/bitstream/205522/2/Malan_Saitone_Sexton_AAE… · Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who Joins

  9

Proof: The lemma follows directly from Lemmas 1 and 2.

Lemma 4: conditions 𝜌𝛿!𝜇 > 1 and    !"(!!!)!"

> 0 are sufficient for a farmer to market

production exclusively through the cooperative.

Proof: Lemma 1 establishes that a farmer will market positive production through a

cooperative whenever 𝜌𝛿!𝜇 > 1. The condition on !"!"

establishes that expected utility is

increasing in 𝛼 throughout its admissible range.

Collectively Lemmas 1 – 4 establish conditions on the model parameters for a

farmer to (i) sell exclusively to the outside trader, (ii) sell exclusively to the cooperative,

and (iii) sell part of his production to the cooperative and part to the trader. In this latter

case the farmer balances the higher discounted expected income promised by the

cooperative with the increasing risk exposure due to the default possibility as 𝛼 increases.

Marketing through the trader in effect works as an insurance policy, with the premium set

by the magnitude of 𝜌𝛿!𝜇 − 1. The comparative statics of the model are straightforward;

a farmer’s propensity to market some product through the cooperative or increase the

share he markets through the cooperative is increasing in 𝛿, 𝜇, and 𝜌 and decreasing in 𝜆

and T.

Figures 1 – 3 illustrate the three possible outcomes for reasonable model

parameter values. In each instance we focus on farmers whose income is solely from sale

of the crop, i.e., 𝑊! = 0. The hypothetical cooperative offers a 25% price premium

relative to the trader, consistent with the finding of Shiferaw et al. (2009), delays

payment for T = 5 weeks, consistent with the findings of Shiferaw, Obare, and Muricho

(2008), and has a 10% default probability, i.e., 𝜌 = 0.9. Figure 1 illustrates a highly risk

Page 10: Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who …ageconsearch.umn.edu/bitstream/205522/2/Malan_Saitone_Sexton_AAE… · Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who Joins

  10

averse and impatient farmer, with CARA coefficient 𝜆 = 10,7 and discount parameter

𝛿 ≈ 0.956, consistent with findings of Tanaka, Camerer, and Nguyen (2010).8 For this

farmer 𝜇𝛿!𝜌 = 0.9 < 1, so the necessary condition of Lemma 1 is not satisfied, and she

markets exclusively through the trader.

Figure 2 illustrates a farmer who is only mildly risk averse, 𝜆 = 0.25, and less

impatient than the figure 1 farmer, 𝛿 = 0.99. This farmer’s optimal marketing decision is

to sell exclusively to the cooperative. Figure 3 depicts a farmer with the same discount

factor as the figure 2 farmer, but who is moderately more risk averse, 𝜆 = 1.0. This

farmer maximizes expected utility with 𝛼∗ = 0.44, i.e., by splitting his crop nearly

equally between the trader and the cooperative

Simulation Model

The analytical model is useful in understanding individual farmers’ decisions regarding

marketing through a cooperative or a private trader and the factors that influence them.

However, even greater interest lies in understanding the decisions of a group of

heterogeneous farmers in terms of marketing through a cooperative or a private trader.

Such analysis can give us a sense of how the cooperative’s performance, as measured by

(𝜌,𝑇, 𝜇), can impact the market share a cooperative can attain and, ultimately, determine

its economic viability and the role it can play in the market place. Here we set forth a

simulation framework designed to accomplish this objective.

                                                                                                               7 Risk aversion of this magnitude is consistent with findings of Binswanger (1981) for some Indian farmers and also with levels reported by Chavas and Holt (1996). 8 Panel B is a blow up of Panel A, which depicts the full range of 𝛼.

Page 11: Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who …ageconsearch.umn.edu/bitstream/205522/2/Malan_Saitone_Sexton_AAE… · Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who Joins

  11

The simulation model involves structuring a synthetic developing-country village

consisting of 100 farmers, who grow a particular crop such as cacao or raise a particular

type of livestock. We draw the village population from distributions for 𝜆, 𝛿,  and 𝑊!

constructed to be representative of such settings based upon the prior literature, i.e., a

village, V, is defined by V = { 𝛿!, 𝜆!,𝑊!! , 𝛿!, 𝜆!,𝑊!

! ,… , (𝛿!"", 𝜆!"",𝑊!""! )}. We then

construct a synthetic marketing cooperative, j, by defining a set of values for (𝜇! ,𝑇! ,𝜌!)

consistent with results from the prior literature.

For each farmer, i, we then determine her optimal share of product, 𝛼!∗, to market

through cooperative j, and aggregate across all 100 farmers to determine the

cooperative’s market share within the village and compile information on the types of

farmers who market exclusively through the cooperative, exclusively through the private

trade, or who divide sales between the two market options.

By repeating the simulations for alternative characterizations of a cooperative in

terms of (𝜇! ,𝑇! ,𝜌!) we can determine how the cooperative’s performance interacts with

farmer characteristics to determine cooperative market shares and, implicitly, its

economic viability. We can consider various policies in terms of the parameters that

define the model. For example, policies to improve capitalization of a cooperative reduce

𝜌, policies to improve cash flow and cash management reduce T. Similarly improved

access to credit on the part of farmers increases 𝛿. Policies to help farmers attain greater

financial reserves or crop diversification may reduce 𝜆 and increase 𝛿. The impacts of

any such policies on a cooperative’s share in the relevant market can be evaluated within

this framework.

Page 12: Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who …ageconsearch.umn.edu/bitstream/205522/2/Malan_Saitone_Sexton_AAE… · Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who Joins

  12

Model Parameterization

We assume farmers’ utilities can be represented by the negative exponential utility

function, 𝑈 𝑊 = −𝑒!!", where W consists of initial wealth, 𝑊!, plus income from

farming. This utility function exhibits constant absolute risk aversion (CARA), with

𝑅! = 𝜆 and increasing relative risk aversion (𝑅! = 𝜆𝑊). Empirical results are mixed as

to whether CARA is an appropriate characterization of risk preferences in developing

country settings, but it is virtuous in our setting due to the simplicity of utility

formulations, like the negative exponential, that embody CARA.

Absolute risk-aversion parameter estimates in the literature vary widely. Most

estimates are in the range of 𝜆  𝜖  [3, 5], e.g., Saha, Shumway, and Talpaz (1994), although

Chavas and Holt estimated 𝜆 =12.17 for U.S. corn and soybean producers. To fully

capture heterogeneity in farmer risk aversion, we simulated values for 𝜆 chosen from a

uniform distribution with supports [0.5, 8.0].

Estimates of discount rates for developing-country settings vary widely. Early

work by Pender (1996), using experiments conducted in rural India, found median

annualized discount rates that ranged from 26% to 119% (implying a range of weekly

discount factors of 𝛿  𝜖  [0.9850, 0.9956]), depending upon the experiment, with most

rates falling in the range of 40 – 70% (𝛿  𝜖  [0.9898, 0.9936]). Botelho et al. (2005),

however, estimated a much lower average exponential discount rate of 12.7% per annum

across a group of 30 college students in Timor-Leste, which implies 𝛿 = 0.9977. More

recently Tanaka, Camerer, and Nguyen (2010) estimated a continuous-time discounting

model from a market experiment in Vietnam and obtained parameter estimates of

Page 13: Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who …ageconsearch.umn.edu/bitstream/205522/2/Malan_Saitone_Sexton_AAE… · Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who Joins

  13

𝑟 = 0.021 ( 𝛿 = 0.9790) for exponential discounting, i.e., 𝑒!!" , and of 𝑟 = 0.046

(𝛿 = 0.9594) for true hyperbolic discounting, i.e. 1/(1+ 𝑟𝑡).

Importantly, each of these studies found considerable heterogeneity in impatience

among study participants. Pender, depending upon the specific experiment, found several

participants with discount rates below 20% (including some that were negative), while

other participants were bunched at the maximum implied discount rate that was allowed

by the experimental design (usually 80% or more).9 Wealthier respondents had lower

discount rates in all of Pender’s experiments. However, wealth was not a statistically

significant explanatory variable for Botelho et al., but participant age was found to be

inversely related to discount rate (positively related to 𝛿), as was living in one’s own

home. Tanaka, Camerer, and Nguyen found age, income, and education to be negatively

correlated with the discount rate.

To capture fully the range of discount rates observed in the experimental literature

and the heterogeneity among respondents, we drew 𝛿 values for each farmer from a

uniform distribution with supports [0.9600, 0.9975], with the lower support consistent

with Tanaka, Camerer, and Nguyen’s findings for Vietnam and the upper support

consistent with values reported by both Pender and Botelho et al.

We found no useful information in the literature to characterize a distribution of

ex ante wealth, which clearly will vary widely across countries, regions, and crops. Since

our interest is primarily in cooperatives as a tool of economic development for the

poorest farmers, it made sense to consider small values for ex ante wealth. Accordingly

we drew ex ante wealth from a discrete distribution of 𝑊!𝜖  {0, 0.5, 1.0}, i.e., ex ante                                                                                                                9 Among a set of explanatory variables that included wealth, age, education, and gender, the only factor found to be significant in explaining variation in discount rates was wealth, with wealthier participants tending to have lower discount rates in most experiments.

Page 14: Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who …ageconsearch.umn.edu/bitstream/205522/2/Malan_Saitone_Sexton_AAE… · Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who Joins

  14

wealth that ranged from none to the equivalent of one-year’s crop income in savings and

other assets.

To construct synthetic cooperatives for the simulation, we need to define sets of

plausible values for 𝜇,𝜌, and T. Comparative statics experiments can then be performed

by adjusting these parameters in turn and observing how participation in the cooperative

is impacted. For 𝜇 we considered values in the range of 1.07 to 1.25, which represents a

range of premiums consistent with findings in the literature (Bernarda, Taffeseb, and

Gabre-Madhina 2008; Shiferaw et al. 2009). We chose values for T in the range of 1 to 8

weeks. These bounds encompass most findings in the literature, but stop short of the

lengthiest delays reported by Theriault, Serra, and Sterns (2013).

We were unable to locate objective information on default probabilities, 1− 𝜌,

but some hints can be gleaned from the “present bias” parameters estimated for quasi-

hyperbolic discount models in the experimental literature, given the similarity already

noted between those parameters and the default risk in this model. Tanaka, Camerer, and

Nguyen (2010) generated statistically significant estimates of this parameter of 0.644 and

0.820, depending upon the form of discount model being estimated. Botelho et al.,

however, estimated a much higher value, 0.963. Setting values of 𝜌 in the vicinity of

Tanaka, Camerer, and Nguyen’s lower value would cause no one to market through a

cooperative, given the plausible range of price premiums. Thus, we chose values for 𝜌 in

the range [0.82, 0.97].10

                                                                                                               10 Our model treats 𝜌 as an objective parameter that is known by market participants. However, unlike values for 𝜇 and T, which can be known, e.g., from a cooperative’s past behavior or from objective reports by the cooperative, it would be difficult for farmers to objectively evaluate 𝜌 because it is almost certain to be a one-time phenomenon, i.e., a cooperative that defaults is unlikely to resume business. Nor is it likely that an industry’s structure would permit calculating 𝜌 from the behavior of a cross section of similar cooperatives. Thus, an alternative formulation of the   model could involve farmers forming subjective

Page 15: Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who …ageconsearch.umn.edu/bitstream/205522/2/Malan_Saitone_Sexton_AAE… · Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who Joins

  15

Preliminary Simulation Results

Figure 4 shows marketing decisions for the simulated village for a cooperative defined by

𝜇 = 1.25 , T = 5, and 𝜌 = 0.97 , i.e., a 3% default rate. The comparatively high

probability that this cooperative will not default makes the villagers’ degree of risk

aversion a less important explanatory variable in explaining the marketing choice than

their discount rate, given the relatively lengthy delay in payment. Thus the 23 most

impatient villagers market exclusively through the trader. Only eight villagers market

exclusively through the cooperative. They are characterized by low degrees of risk

aversion and high values for 𝛿.

The remainder, 69 villagers, market through both the cooperative and the private

trader. However, most of this group, 60 villagers, markets less than half of their

production through the cooperative. These villagers, depicted by green rectangles in

figure 4, have comparatively high degrees of risk aversion but are less impatient than the

farmers who marketed exclusively with the trader. The nine villagers who marketed a

majority of their production with the cooperative have a similar set of discount rates as

those who marketed exclusively with the cooperative, but are moderately more risk

averse. Despite the fact that 77 of the 100 farmers marketed some production through this

cooperative, its share of the available market output is only 29%.

As a comparative static analysis figure 5 repeats the preceding simulation, but

with T = 3. We can think of this change as being accomplished through various means,

including improved marketing efficiency by the cooperative, and providing it access to

short-term credit to pay farmers before the crop is fully marketed. The modest reduction

                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                         estimates of the likelihood that the   cooperative will default.  This formulation would bring our model into even closer conformity to models with quasi-hyperbolic discounting.

Page 16: Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who …ageconsearch.umn.edu/bitstream/205522/2/Malan_Saitone_Sexton_AAE… · Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who Joins

  16

in T from five to three weeks causes the cooperative’s market share of the village

production to increase to 46%. Now all villagers market positive production through the

cooperative. Seventeen, the least risk averse among the villagers, market exclusively

through the cooperative. Another 15, moderately risk averse, combined with relative

patience, market the majority of the production through the cooperative, while the

remainder, the most risk averse and least patient, market less than 50% of their crop

through the co-op.

Figure 6 further explores the relationship between delay in payment and market

share for a cooperative with 𝜇 = 1.25 for alternative values of default rate. A cooperative

that delays payment only one week and has a small default rate of 3% (blue line) can

attain a 50% share of the village’s output. However, the share drops to below 30% if this

cooperative delays payment by three weeks and to about 15% if the payment delay

reaches eight weeks. If this same cooperative’s perceived default rate rises to 10.5% (red

line), it achieves only a 20% market share with a one-week delay in payment. The share

falls rapidly to near zero as the time delay rises to eight weeks. If the co-op is considered

sufficiently unreliable that its perceived default rate is 18% (green line), the co-op attains

almost no market share regardless of the delay in the promised payment.

Conclusion

Marketing cooperatives are potentially a valuable tool for economic development because

the economic functions a cooperative can perform are especially valuable in developing-

country settings. Such benefits include extending farmers’ presence downstream in the

Page 17: Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who …ageconsearch.umn.edu/bitstream/205522/2/Malan_Saitone_Sexton_AAE… · Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who Joins

  17

value chain and capturing benefits of scale economies, while enabling farmers to avoid

selling to private intermediaries who may exercise monopsony power.

This study has investigated two elements of cooperatives’ performance in a

developing-country setting that can severely inhibit their market share and, ultimately,

their economic viability—delay in payment for a crop relative to a private trader and,

concomitant with such delay, the risk of default on payment. Through a series of lemmas

the theoretical model established necessary and sufficient conditions for a farmer to

market exclusively with a cooperative, exclusively with a private trader, or to sell jointly

to both marketing options. A relatively simple condition, namely that the expected

discounted payment from the co-op exceed the certain and contemporaneous payment

from a private trader, was established as both necessary and sufficient for a farmer,

regardless of degree of risk aversion, to sell a positive amount of production to the

cooperative.

Simulation analysis involved creating a synthetic developing-country village

based upon parameterizations derived from the empirical and experimental literature and

investigating these farmers optimal marketing decisions in the presence of different

cooperative structures as defined by relative price premium offered, time delay in receipt

of payment, and risk of default. Results showed that even modest delays in payment or

minor risk of default could drastically reduce a cooperative’s market share in the

presence of highly risk averse and impatient farmers, even if the cooperative promised a

substantial price premium above the offer by a private trader.

The simulation results provide a guide to improved cooperative performance in

developing country settings in that they show how modest improvements in reducing a

Page 18: Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who …ageconsearch.umn.edu/bitstream/205522/2/Malan_Saitone_Sexton_AAE… · Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who Joins

  18

default probability or lag in payment can markedly improve the cooperative’s market

share and, hence, overall impact on the market and farmer welfare. A variety of policies

and interventions can be considered to achieve such improvements.

Page 19: Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who …ageconsearch.umn.edu/bitstream/205522/2/Malan_Saitone_Sexton_AAE… · Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who Joins

  19

References

Angeletos, G-M., Laibson, D., Repetto, A., Tobacman, J. and Weinberg, S. 2001. “The Hyperbolic Consumption Model: Calibration, Simulation, and Empirical Evidence.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 15(3): 47-68.

Berdegué, J. 2001. Cooperating to Compete, Associative Peasant Business Firms in

Chile. Ph.D. thesis, Wageningen University, Netherlands. Bernarda, T., Taffesseb, S.A., Gabre-Madhina, E. 2008. “Impact of Cooperatives on

Smallholders’ Commercialization Behavior: Evidence from Ethiopia.” Agricultural Economics 39(2): 147-161.

Binswanger, H.P. 1980. “Attitudes Toward Risk: Experimental Measurement in Rural

India.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 62(2): 395-407. Binswanger, H.P. 1981. “Attitudes Toward Risk: Theoretical Implications of an

Experiment in Rural India.” Economic Journal 91(364): 867-890. Binswanger, H.P. 1982. “Empirical Estimation and Use of Risk Preferences: Discussion.”

American Journal of Agricultural Economics 64(2): 391-403. Binswanger, H.P. and Sillers, D.A. 1983. “Risk Aversion and Credit Constraints on

Farmers’ Decision Making: A Reinterpretation.” Journal of Development Studies 20(1): 5-21.

Bosc, P-M., Eychenne, D., Hussein, K., Losch, B., Mercoiret, M-R., Rondot, P. and

Mackintosh-Walker, S. 2002. “The Role of Rural Producer Organizations in the World Bank Rural Development Strategy.” Rural Development Background Strategy Paper No. 8, The World Bank, March.

Botelho, A., Harrison, G.W., Pinto, L.M.C., Rutström, E.E. and Veiga, P. 2006.

Discounting in Developing Countries: Experimental Evidence from Timor-Leste. Faculty Working Paper No. 31. Economics Department, University of Central Florida. Orlando, FL.

Braverman, A., Guasch, J.L., Huppi, M. and Pohlmeier, L. 1991. “Promoting Rural

Cooperatives in Developing Countries: The Case of Sub-Saharan Africa.” World Bank Discussion Papers, 121.

de Brauw, A. and Eozenou, P. 2014. “Measuring Risk Attitudes Among Mozambican Farmers.” Journal of Development Economics 111: 61-74.

Calkins, P. and Ngo, A-T. 2005. Impacts of Farmer Cooperatives on the Standard of

Living of Cocoa Producing Villages in Cote d’Ivoire and Ghana. SOCODEVI, Québec, Canada.

Page 20: Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who …ageconsearch.umn.edu/bitstream/205522/2/Malan_Saitone_Sexton_AAE… · Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who Joins

  20

Chavas, J.P. and Holt, M.T. 1996. “Economic Behavior Under Uncertainty: A Joint Analysis of Risk Preferences and Technology.” Review of Economics and Statistics 78(2): 329-335.

Develtere, P., Pollet, I. and Wanyama, F. 2009. Cooperating Out of Poverty: The

Renaissance of the African Cooperative Movement, Geneva: International Labor Organization.

Dillon, J.L. and Scandizzo, P.L. 1978. “Risk Attitudes of Subsistence Farmers in

Northeast Brazil: A Sampling Approach.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 60(2): 425-434.

Frederick, S., Loewenstein, G., and O’Donoghue, T. 2002. “Time Discounting and Time

Preferences.” Journal of Economic Literature 40(2): 351-401. Harrison, G., Humphrey, S. and Verschoor, A. 2010. “Choice Under Uncertainty:

Evidence From Ethiopia, India and Uganda.” The Economic Journal 120(543): 80-104.

Laibson, D. 1997. "Golden Eggs and Hyperbolic Discounting." Quarterly Journal of

Economics 112 (2): 443–477. Markelova, H. and Mwangi, E. 2010. “Collective Action for Smallholder Market Access:

Evidence and Implications for Africa.” Review of Policy Research 27(5): 621-640. Moscardi, E. and de Janvry, A. 1977. “Attitudes Towards Risk Among Peasants: an

Econometric Approach.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 59(4): 710-716.

Mujawamariya, G., D’Haese, M. and Speelman, S. 2012. “Exploring Double Side-selling

in Cooperatives, Case Study of Four Coffee Cooperatives in Rwanda.” Food Policy 39(2): 72-83.

O'Brien, D.J., Banwart, L. and Cook, M.L. 2013. “Measuring the Benefits of Smallholder

Farmer Membership in Producer-Controlled Vertical Value Chains: Survey Findings from a Development Project in East Africa.” Poverty & Public Policy 5(4): 399-416.

Pender, J.L. (1996). “Discount Rates and Credit Markets: Theory and Evidence from

Rural India.” Journal of Development Economics 50(2): 257-296. Rondot, P. and Collion, M-H. (2001). “Agricultural Producer Organizations: Their

Contribution to Rural Capacity Building and Poverty Reduction.” World Bank, Rural Development Department.

Page 21: Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who …ageconsearch.umn.edu/bitstream/205522/2/Malan_Saitone_Sexton_AAE… · Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who Joins

  21

Saha, A., Shumway, R. and Talpaz, H. 1994. “Joint Estimation of Risk Preference Structure and Technology Using Expo-Power Utility.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 76(2): 173-84.

Sexton, R.J. 1986. “The Formation of Cooperatives: A Game-Theoretic Approach with

Implications for Cooperative Finance, Decision Making, and Stability.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 68(2): 214-225.

Sexton, R.J., and Iskow, J. 1988. “Factors Critical to Success or Failure of Emerging

Agricultural Cooperatives.” Giannini Foundation Information Series No. 88-3. Division of Agriculture and Natural Resources, University of California,  June.

Sexton, R.J. 1990. “Imperfect Competition in Agricultural Markets and the Role of

Cooperatives: A Spatial Analysis.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 72(3): 709-720.

Shiferaw, B., Obare, G, Muricho, G and Silim, S. 2009. “Leveraging Institutions for

Collective Action to Improve Markets for Smallholder Producers in Less-Favored Areas.” African Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 3(1): 1-19.

Shiferaw, B., Obare, G., and Muricho, G. 2008. “Rural Market Imperfections and the

Role of Institutions in Collective Action to Improve Markets.” Natural Resources Forum 32(1): 25-38.

Soboh, R.A.M.E., Lansink, A.O, Giesen, G. and Dijk, G.V. 2009. “Performance

Measurement of the Agricultural Marketing Cooperative: The Gap Between Theory and Practice.” Review of Agricultural Economics 31(3): 446-469.

Tanaka, T., Camerer, C.F., and Nguyen, Q. 2010. “Risk and Time Preferences: Linking

Experimental and Household Survey Data from Vietnam.” American Economic Review 100(1): 557-571.

Theriault, V., Serra, R. and Sterns, J.A. 2013. “Prices, Institutions, and Determinants of

Supply in the Malian Cotton Sector.” Agricultural Economics 44(2): 161-174. Uphoff, N. 1993. “Grassroots Organizations and NGOs in Rural Development:

Opportunities with Diminishing States and Expanding markets.” World Development 21(4): 607-622.

Verhofstadt, E. and Maertens, M. 2014. “Smallholder Cooperatives and Agricultural

Performance in Rwanda: Do Organizational Differences Matter?” Agricultural Economics 45(S1): 39-52.

Wik, M., Kebede, A.T., Bergland, O. and Holden, S. 2004. “On the Measurement of Risk Aversion from Experimental Data.” Applied Economics 36(21): 2443-2451.

World Bank. 2008. Agriculture for Development, World Development Report 2008.

Page 22: Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who …ageconsearch.umn.edu/bitstream/205522/2/Malan_Saitone_Sexton_AAE… · Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who Joins

  22

Yesuf, M. and Bluffstone, A.R. 2009. “Poverty, Risk Aversion, and Path Dependence in

Low-Income Countries: Experimental Evidence From Ethiopia.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 91(4): 1022-1037.

Page 23: Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who …ageconsearch.umn.edu/bitstream/205522/2/Malan_Saitone_Sexton_AAE… · Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who Joins

  23

Panel A: 0 ≤ 𝛼 ≤ 1.0

Panel B: 0 ≤ 𝛼 ≤ 0.3

Figure 1. Case 1: Farmer Marketing through Trader Only (𝜌 = 0.9, 𝛿! = 0.8, 𝜇 = 1.25, 𝜆 = 10, 𝑊! = 0).

0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0�

-0.10

-0.08

-0.06

-0.04

-0.02

0.00

EU

EUMixed

EUCo-op

EUTrader

0.05 0.10 0.15 0.20 0.25 0.30�

-0.00012

-0.00010

-0.00008

-0.00006

EUMixed

EUTrader

Page 24: Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who …ageconsearch.umn.edu/bitstream/205522/2/Malan_Saitone_Sexton_AAE… · Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who Joins

  24

Figure 2. Case 2: Farmer Marketing through Co-op Only (𝜌 = 0.9, 𝛿! = 0.95, 𝜇 =1.25, 𝜆 = 0.25, 𝑊! = 0).

Figure 3. Case 3: Farmer Marketing through both the Co-op and Trader (𝜌 = 0.9, 𝛿! = 0.95, 𝜇 = 1.25, 𝜆 = 1, 𝑊! = 0, 𝛼∗ = 0.44).

0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0�

-0.778

-0.776

-0.774

-0.772

-0.770

EU

EUMixed

EUCo-op

EUTrader

0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0�

-0.374

-0.372

-0.370

-0.368

-0.366

-0.364

-0.362

EU

EUMixed

EUCo-op

EUTrader

� * = 0.44

Page 25: Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who …ageconsearch.umn.edu/bitstream/205522/2/Malan_Saitone_Sexton_AAE… · Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who Joins

  25

Figure 4. Marketing Decisions for Villagers (𝜌 = 0.97, 𝑇 = 5, 𝜇 = 1.25).

Figure 5. Marketing Decisions for Villagers (𝜌 = 0.97, 𝑇 = 3, 𝜇 = 1.25).

0"

1"

2"

3"

4"

5"

6"

7"

8"

9"

0.95" 0.955" 0.96" 0.965" 0.97" 0.975" 0.98" 0.985" 0.99" 0.995"

Lamda

%

Delta%

Co/op"Only" Trader"Only" Mixed"(Alpha*<50%)" Mixed"(Alpha*>50%)"

0"

1"

2"

3"

4"

5"

6"

7"

8"

9"

0.95" 0.955" 0.96" 0.965" 0.97" 0.975" 0.98" 0.985" 0.99" 0.995"

Lamda

%

Delta%

Mixed"(Alpha*<50%)" Mixed"(Alpha*>50%)" Co?op"Only"

Page 26: Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who …ageconsearch.umn.edu/bitstream/205522/2/Malan_Saitone_Sexton_AAE… · Marketing Cooperatives in Developing Countries: Who Joins

  26

Figure 6. Impact of 𝜌 and T on the Cooperative’s Market Share (𝜇 = 1.25).

0.0%$

10.0%$

20.0%$

30.0%$

40.0%$

50.0%$

60.0%$

1$ 5$ 8$

Market'S

hare'of'C

o-op

'in'Village'

T'

Rho$=$0.97$ Rho$=$0.895$ Rho$=$0.82$