levo~ution and the -...

40
levo~ution and the What the Transformation of Telecommunications Markets Means .for liegulation Peter Smith Liberalizing Telecommunications and the Role of the World Trade Organization Carlos A. Primo Braga rile Drivers of the Information Revolution--Cost, Computing I'ower, and Convergence Telecommunications Is Dead, Long Live Networking- The Effect of the Information Revol~~tion on the Telecom Industry The l'rivate Sector and the Internet Carlos A. Primo Braga and Camten Fink The Information Revolution and the Role of Government Fran~oise Clottes Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized

Transcript of levo~ution and the -...

Page 1: levo~ution and the - documents.worldbank.orgdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/pt/888891468164944771/pdf/454660WP0BOX... · levo~ution and the What the Transformation of Telecommunications

levo~ution and the

What the Transformation of Telecommunications Markets

Means .for liegulation

Peter Smith

Liberalizing Telecommunications and the Role of the

World Trade Organization

Carlos A. Primo Braga

rile Drivers of the Information Revolution--Cost, Computing

I'ower, and Convergence

Telecommunications Is Dead, Long Live Networking-

The Effect of the Information Revol~~tion

on the Telecom Industry

The l'rivate Sector and the Internet

Carlos A. Primo Braga and Camten Fink

The Information Revolution and the Role of Government

Fran~oise Clottes

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Page 2: levo~ution and the - documents.worldbank.orgdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/pt/888891468164944771/pdf/454660WP0BOX... · levo~ution and the What the Transformation of Telecommunications

The v i m ex~regsad In

and shrdlt n@t Lve attributed tb +ff W ~ d d Bank er&rr of Irq tiffiliatad or#allirfition& Her do any of pe cant6nrs r@rmnr offifiiel pdioy of the wodd Bmk of af its Ewaoutive Uhctats or the countries they represene

Edtor: Butnnna S w i Rum El'-1 The Wwrld ImN tarn H tR$8& NW Waahlngton, Q.C, 30433

Telaphene: ZBW12a! FanairnUa: mmm1 Ema it aasnrrtrM w~rUbwnkafg

The elrUre Content8 @I497 Wmld Bank. You aru authorieeB tt~ reproduos. dyp1iWfl. and diswminat. all ar prrt rrf this publkbtian PP tuw aavw intludq the name of the publlcatktn qnd the nam oi the rrraplctive r&m Yuu may Ant. hwbver, m e I altar, w athemlq change m y pafl at this puhlihatlpn rrr hell trensfnr, ar otberwi~& h m i n a t a any part sf the puh%bmln fbr profiLTb~wnhniaf this puhlirat!~n Is

Page 3: levo~ution and the - documents.worldbank.orgdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/pt/888891468164944771/pdf/454660WP0BOX... · levo~ution and the What the Transformation of Telecommunications
Page 4: levo~ution and the - documents.worldbank.orgdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/pt/888891468164944771/pdf/454660WP0BOX... · levo~ution and the What the Transformation of Telecommunications

The Information Revolution and the Future of Telecommunications June 1997

3 Introduction-How information Infrastructure Is Changing the World Economy James Bond

7 The Drivers of the Information Revolution--Cost, Computing Power, and Convergence James Bond

11 Telecommunications Is Dead, Long Live Networking-The Effect of the Information Revolution on the Telecom Industry James Bond

15 What the Transformation of Telecommunications Markets Means for Regulation Peter Smith

20 Liberalizing Telecommunications and the Role of the World Trade Organization Carlos A. Primo Braga

27 The Private Sector and the Internet Carlos A. Primo Braga ancl Carsten Fink

32 The Information Revolution and the Role of Government Franqoise Clottes

Page 5: levo~ution and the - documents.worldbank.orgdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/pt/888891468164944771/pdf/454660WP0BOX... · levo~ution and the What the Transformation of Telecommunications

Introduction How information infrastructure is changing the world economy

James Bond

A cluster of powerful forces is recasting the business world in a new, fleeter, and more com- petitive form. These forces, largely grouped around information infrastructure and new communications technologies, have come to be known collectively as the information revo- lution. The information revolution affects all businesses, in industrial and developing coun- tries alike. One of the most dranzatic results is the tremendous growth in international trade in services made possible by cheaper tele- communications. In Casablanca, for example, a Moroccan company called SAGMA provides clesktop publishing services for publishing com- panies in Paris. The Parisian firms fax texts to SAGMA, whose employees then lay out ancl proofread them, and send them back to Paris as print-ready binary files through a 64-kilobit dedicated line. Similarly, dedicated data links allow Swissail to handle part of its cost ac- counting near Mumbai (Bombay) airport in India and enable Boeing to carry out computer- aided design and digitalization of blueprints in the Eastern Caribbean.

Less recognized are the empowering effects of the information revolution. In CBte d'lvoire, for example, whose economy has been built on the twin pillars of coffee and cacao, traders used to buy raw products from small-scale farmers at prices way below international levels, then sell them for much higher prices o n world markets. The "tax" on farmers has financed the impres- sive growth of Abidjan and Yamoussoukro and created a class of wealthy middlemen. The tax depended on an asymmetry of information be- tween middlemen, who have had access to in- ternational prices, and farmers, who have not. But now Ivorian farmers, often illiterate, pool their resources to buy cellular phones, which

they use to check the current prices of cacao and coffee on the London commodity markets. Armed with these quotes, they can negotiate better prices with the middlemen The farmers have eliminated the information asymmetry- and raised their standard of living.

A similar empowering effect is under way in Mamelodi, a dormitory township near Pretoria created under apartheid to ensure that black workers left white residential areas at night. In sharp contrast to the South African capital, Mamelocli is a place of poverty and poor infra- structure. Inhabitants must go to nejghboring Pretoria to obtain information on schooling op- portunities for their children, to learn of social services available to them, to find a doctor. To

BOX 1 WHAT IS INFORMAT ION INFRASTRUCTURE?

r t r e t r r s p B t f s r m P t l a R ~ r r $ n m ahmad m q p o t ~ h t w l g k ~ ~ r ~ ~ d m ~ ~ r t 6 k r k m m e l ~ l l y , g a a e d y b a dlp)bPIfmW~Wummtkn a n M e L e lorn d a Inman voice b w d d u a l depbnyt e sranad h ( l e , ~ w ~ L m .

m k h i ~ t w ~ o g ~ bblmg br 40 t&eummudowlms aadinlennfde~lbchndoly 0T)arpspaRd-dm dhptM

iaicmeampdn# md -1 a l g d gdmarotrtiaP by Ww- DME cI Im (In 40 bm of IigU a d small wldm (vvllkl wea mwwsian@ d i m b-dc speolnm as aUoient)y as pwsihl~l .

S d r e r wrd prohesilud re m 14e Mmdar id re

i=Me l h ~ a m m d d Pe. Um celhhr fiu h m m ~ gcniceL padmg. ekchmrlc ~ e n ~ f t q aid dfPsl luwdcwl dl#Ml'V.

Page 6: levo~ution and the - documents.worldbank.orgdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/pt/888891468164944771/pdf/454660WP0BOX... · levo~ution and the What the Transformation of Telecommunications

improve the community's access to informa- tion, a public-private consortium with funding from the In fo rn~a t ion for Development (inJoDev) program (initiated by the World Bank) has established an "intranet" using com- puters and servers donated by IBM. Computer- savvy teenagers use the network at the local school, the municipal center, and the local li- brary to find answers to people's questions. And there is an added benefit: Mamelodi schoolchildren communicate by ernail with other children around the world via the Inter- net, broadening their education and, through their hands-on experience with computers, im- proving their chances in the labor market. Thus, new technologies are offering real opportuni- ties to reduce the exclusion of the poor.

The scope for new technologies to reduce ex- clusion has much to do with the proliferation of new products and the way they respond to consumers' needs and ability to pay-far bet- ter than conventiona1 telephones do. In south- ern China, the huge growth in economic activity has had an unusual side-effect: an explosion in the number of pagers. Today, there are about 30 nill lion pagers in China-more than in the United States (28 mil l ion tand the number is growing fast. But while in the United States pagers are used to summon doctors, plumb- ers, and deliverymen to a phone to call head- cluarters for instructions, in China, there are no public phones and a different use for pag- ers has been developed. Callers punch in a fifteen-digit number to send any one of the tens of thousands of standard messages re- corded in code books.

The forces at work

These applications of new technology have their origin in several trends and breakthroughs: the costs of co~nmunicating are declining rap- idly, the power of computers is doubling ev- ery two years. and information is now stored, transmitted, and manipulated in binary rather than analog form. As these technological driv- ers translate into economic trends, they are leading to a convergence of the once separate

industries of broadcasting and telecommuni- cations. The differences between a telephone call, a fax, a photo, a video image, a database search, and a television broadcast are blurring and may soon disappear. This process is the heart of the information revolution.

Convergence represents a real difference from what the world has known for the past Fifty years: basic telephony is shifting from wires to raclio, and television broadcasting is nloving from wireless to cable and to direct satellite broadcasting. Most significant, the telecommu- nications industry, which used to operate as a public utility and supply the same standard tek- phone to everybody, is being transformed by an avalanche of new communications devices. And as t h s revolution gathers speed, profit mar- gins in the converged "bit industry" are increas- ingly shifting away from the players that control the infrastructure and toward those that pro- vide value added services and supply the con- tent. This shift has major implications for the telecoinrnunications industry.

But as the examples above show, the informa- tion revolution means more than just a shake- up of telecommunications and information technology. It is creating powerful forces that are profoundly modifying the fabric of global economic activity: = A decline in transaction costs in the economy

at large. Low-cost com~nunications have ex- ended the reach of the markct into product areas-such as services-prev io ~lsly consid- ered impossible to deliver t h r o ~ ~ g h market- based solutions. Because co~nmunications have become cheap and ubiquitous, compa- nies can now outsource a much wicler range of functions than they could before. And as a result, they can now focus on their com- parative advantage much more narrowly, sig- nificantly improving their efficiency. Shrinking natural monopolies. Smart informa- tion technology and cheap communications are chipping away at natural n~onopolies. Utilities such as electric power and telecom- ~ ~ ~ ~ n i c a t i o n s , ancl infrss~ructure such as ports and roads, can now 1 ~ : "unl3unciled" so that

Page 7: levo~ution and the - documents.worldbank.orgdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/pt/888891468164944771/pdf/454660WP0BOX... · levo~ution and the What the Transformation of Telecommunications

The World Bank Group 5 -. .- --

the segments that cantlot be cluplicated (for example, the power transn~ission network) are the only parts of the sector run as stand- alones. The rest of the sector (such as the power generating plants) can then be man- aged 17): competing providers in a competi- tive fra~nework. Cornpetition leaclj to more cost-effective provision of infrastructure ser- vices. This shift, which is worldwide and multisectoral, is only possil~le because of the inforn~ation revolution. The rise of the service sector. Services now account for 70 percent of gross domestic proci- uct (GDP) in industrial countries, 45 percent in developing countries. The informatior1 in- frastructure is tl-le backbone on which many of these services are delivered. And the fall- ing cost of international communications has significantl~. increased the potential to trade senlices. Trade in services is growing twice as fast as overall trade, and services already ac- count for nearly n quarter of the total value of worlcl tcicle. Airline ticketing, data input and processing, and crttd~t card transaction pro- cessing are all now carriecl out across inter- national bordefi, tangible exarnplcs of the growing cross-border trade in services. New areas of expansion are software cievelopriient (1)espoke software and maintenance), com- puter-aicfed design, and education ancl train- ing. Service exports provide an important route for developing cotlntries integrating into the glohal economy. Globalization of the economic system. Per- haps the most profound effect that the infor- [nation revolution is having on the economy is the I~lurr.ing of national boundaries In many areas of economic activity. Hypothetically, for example, it woulcl I7e possible for a firni rep- isterecl in Bermuda to locate the *'production" of a n intellectual goocl (such as a rnovie car- to(31-1 or the design of an automobile part or s o h a r e program) in Hong Kong, even though its five employees are physically located in New Jersey and it oursources rnost of the pro- duction process to Malaysia. In cases like this, it is very cl~fficult to identify the geographic location of value added (complicating taxa- tion ancl statistical analysis). Regulating such

economic activity on a national level becomes increasingly complex-and perhaps irrelevant.

The focus here

This booklet contains six shor t nsticles on the information revolution ancl the l'~11ure of tele- communications. The focus is on the role of government, especially in regul.ation. The first article examines the scale ancl scope of the drivers of the information revolution-the clecline in the cost of transmitting information, tlie increase in the power of computing. and the shift from analog to digital inforn~ation tecll- nologies, a shift that has joined the telecommu- nications ancl computing inclustries and merged segments of the infonna~ion industry. The sec- ond article looks at the impact of these drivers on the structure, pricing, and regulation of the telecon~munications industry. The old moclel based on public service and a n~onopoly state provicler no longer fits. With scale econo~nies and natural monopoly disappearing, the best n 7 a y to deli\/el- sel-vice is now through compet- ing providers. Ancl the rr2clitionaI sources of rev- enue for teleco~nmunications companies are eroding as the international pric,ing cartel collapses and prices fall

The third article looks more closely at the impact of the changes in the industry on teleco~~imuni- cations regulation. As detnancl clzanges, services converge, ancl new players emerge. the key is- sue for regulators is promoting co~npetition. Regulation is becoming increasingly complex at the same time that convergence ancl inter-na- tional trade agreements are lirniting the discretion of national regulators. One way for regulators to deal with complexity is to privati~e some as- pects of regulation-in particular, by creating property rights to the spectnlln and outsourcing o l n e regulator)/ tasks. But telecomm~inications regulatory agencies themselves will increasingly I->ecorne specialized competition agencies and may eventually becorne merged into multi- sectoral antitrust agencies.

The fourth :irlicle reviews the evolution of the services and telecommunications negotiations

Page 8: levo~ution and the - documents.worldbank.orgdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/pt/888891468164944771/pdf/454660WP0BOX... · levo~ution and the What the Transformation of Telecommunications

introduction

under the umbrella of the World Trade Organi- zation. Commitments made by sixty-nine coun- tries earlier this year should lead to significant market liberalization. Countries making commit- ments account for 90 percent of world telecom- munications revenues.

The fifth article looks at the rise of the Internet as the main application in the emerging global information infrastructure. Many now believe that the Internet provides a window into the future-when access to information will be in- dependent of geographic location and inter- activity in a multimedia environment will be ubiquitous. The article reviews the need for a regulatory framework for the Internet in three critical areas: provision of backbone access, Internet service providers, and information ser- vices. I t also explores the problem of the appropriability of content and ways to recover costs, such as intellectual property rights. For developing countries, the critical bottleneck is a weak information infrastructure.

The sixth article briefly surveys potential ap- plications of technology (in health, education, social services, and so on), the bottlenecks, and the role of government in addressing these bottlenecks.

J~zmcs Bond (jhonclQzuouldbnnk, or&, Division Chiel Teleconamunications and InJ-brmatics

Page 9: levo~ution and the - documents.worldbank.orgdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/pt/888891468164944771/pdf/454660WP0BOX... · levo~ution and the What the Transformation of Telecommunications

The Drivers of the Information Revolution- Cost, Computing Power, and Convergence

@nes Bond

In the past few years, there has been a techno- logical phase-shift as computers have become ubiquitous, communications technologies have multiplied, and the Internet has become a wiclely used means of doing business. The three most powerful trends driving these develop- ments are the decline in the cost of transmit- ting information, the increase in the power of computing, and the shift from analog to digital information technologies that has joined the telecommunications and computing industries and merged market segments of the informa- tion indust~y. This article surveys these drivers of the information revolution.

Cost of communicating

The cost of communicating has declined dra- matically in the past twenty years. 'The cost of a voice transmission circuit, for example, has fallen by a factor of 10,000 as a result of the development of fiber optics, cheap electron- ics, ancl smart wireless (figure 1).

Fiber optics. First producecl commercially by Corning Glass in 1970, fiber-optic cable has become the increasingly dominant means of signal transmission in telephony since the mid- 198Os, replacing copper cables, microwave transmission, and satellite. Optical fiber has ex- tremely high capacity (bandwidth) because of the light it transports. The high frequency of light allows higher information density than conventional cable: a fiber thinner than a single hair can carry a laser signal combining many thousancls of telephone conversations, so that the cost per voice circuit becomes almost in- finitesimal. Because fiber optics reduces the cost of signal transmission so much, and be- cause this cost is increasingly fixed (with main-

tenance costs much lower than for conventional 11 cable, the cost is mostly in installation), the generalization of fiber optics is profoundly ,

changing the industty's cost structure, moving g it away from existing tariff-setting mechanisms.

Cheap electronics. A key part of the telephone infrastructure a network exchanges, made up

I of switching equipment. Automatic switches were originally electromechanical, but the switches installed today are electronic-essen- tially specialized computers. The advent of cheap, powerful, microprocessor-based comput- ing has altered the economics of switching, re- ducing costs and increasing reliability while also delivering new value added services for the user (such as call waiting and caller ID). Cheap elec- tronics are also at the heart of cellular telephony ancl personal communications services, which use electromagnetic spectrum more efficiently than conventional wireless. And computing power now makes it possible to run existing telecommunications infrastructure as an "intel- ligent network," improving capacity utilization, lowering the cost of maintaining switches, and creating new services, such as virtual private networks.

Smart wireless. \Vireless technology is evolving toward higher frequencies (inherently more information dense), with a range of clever corn- pression algorithms to squeeze many conver- sations into a given frequency (such as time d. lvlsion ... multiple access, or TDMA, and code division multiple access, or CDMA). This de- velopment, coupled with cheap electronics, permits mobility for the user-in some situa- tions, wireless has become an alternative to conventional wireline technology for basic ser- vices. Cellular telephony is growing rapidly,

Page 10: levo~ution and the - documents.worldbank.orgdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/pt/888891468164944771/pdf/454660WP0BOX... · levo~ution and the What the Transformation of Telecommunications

The Drivers of the Information Revolution--Cost, Computing Power, and Convergence

more than doubling worlclnride evely two years, while fixed wireless is increasingly being de- ployed for the '-local loop," or local access net- work-that part of the network providing access to the end user. So, besides bringing overall costs down, fixed wireless has also in- troduced real opportunities for competing pro- viders of local services. an area earlier deemed to be a natural monopoly. Finally, the cost of deploying wireless is much less sensitive to subscriber density (the number of customers in a given area) than that of installing wireline, so wireless is of great interest to developing countries, particularly for rural areas.

These three trends have necessarily been ac- companied by a move away from analog to digital technology, in which signals arc trans- mitted as binary code. Digital telephone net- works ensure better quality and allow the use of pack~ng protocols for data transmission! such as frame relay, Asynchronous Transfer Mode (ATM), and the Internet protocol TCI'/IP.

Power of computing

The second important driver of the informa- tion revolution has been the relentless increase in the power of computing. Computing power per dollar invested has risen by a factor of 10,000 in twenty years (figure 2). Power has increased and costs have fallen because of the development of integrated circuits and micro- chips, because of increasing transistor density on microchips, and because of economies of scale in production.

Integrated circuits, miniaturization, and micro- chips. The modern electronics en began with [he invention of the integrated circuit in a Texas Instruments labor at or)^ in Dallas in 1958. The integrated circuit. which groups transistors and other electronic circuits on a tiny piece of semi- conductor. is a breakthrough in product design because of its enormous potential for miniatur- ization and for reducing unit costs. The micro- chip, essentially an entire computer on a chip, was developed by Intel (as the four-bit 4004 processor) in 1971. Its 2,300 transistors provide all the essential functions of a computer.

Page 11: levo~ution and the - documents.worldbank.orgdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/pt/888891468164944771/pdf/454660WP0BOX... · levo~ution and the What the Transformation of Telecommunications

The World Bank Group 9

Increasing transistor density. The density of transistors has been rising exponentially-a phenomenon sometimes characterized as Moore's law. In the 1960s, Gordon Moore, an electrical engineer and a cofounder of Intel, observed that the number of transistors on a microchip doubles every one to two years. Be- cause computing power is roughly proportional to the number of transistors, or "gates," on the microprocessor, this would translate into a doubling of computing power per microchip every eighteen months or so. And because the cost of a microchip rises only slowly from one generation to the next and sepresents only about 5 to 15 percent of the cost of the corn- puter, h/loore's law would translate into a near doubling of computing power for a given in- vestment every eighteen months. In fact, the growth in power over twenty-Four years-from the Intel 4004 (2,300 transistors) of 1971 to the Pentiurn IT (7.5 million) of 1997-averaged nearly 40 percent a year, corresponding to a doubling every twenty-five and a half months- close enough to moo re's estimate (figure 3).

Economies of scale. Computing has also be- come far cheaper and more powerful because of economies of scale in production, not only of microcl~ips but of such essential ancillaty equipment as mass storage (disk drives), removable storage, and computer network equipment. The emergence of a set of de facto industry standards-based on the first IBM per- sonal computer (PC) of 1981, the Intel micro- processor instruction set, and the Microsoft operating systems (DOS and Windows)-has also enabled producers to standardize equip- ment ancl software and encouraged price competition.

One result of the increase in the power of com- puting and the decllne in the cost of cornrnu- nicating is the rise of networks. When PCs began penetrating the business environment around 1981, they were used mainly as stand- alone workstations. Inclepenclent mainframe computers, accessed by "dumb" terminals, con- tinued to hanclle much of the heavy process- ing. Today's business computers are connected to one another in local area networks (LANs),

and increasingly, these private networks are interconnected through the Internet, the inter- national "network of networks," which is dou- bling in size every year. Because of the growing interconnection, PCs' primary function has shifted from document and spreadsheet man- agement to communication and information processing. The growth of the Internet illus- trates Metcalfe's law (Metcalfe was the co- founder of modern computer networking), which states that the value of a network equals the square of the number of interconnected nodes. As new users join the Internet, its value for all users Increases geometrically. Metcalfe's law illustrates how networking PCs radically increases their value as a knowledge tool.

Convergence

As costs have fallen and digitalization has re- placed analog technologies in telecommunica- tions, the telecommunications, information technology, and media industries are merging into a "bit industry" that manipulates voice, im- age, video, and computer data in binary form. This convergence has profound implications for the industries involved. = Communications and information services are

being delinked from their underlying deliv- ely infrastructure: telephone setvices can be delivered through coaxial cable, data services and Internet access through telephone lines, and cable TV through direct broadcast satellite. Accompanying the delinlting is increasing overlap between the two primary components of the communications industry, which have traditionally been segregated: common car- rier conduit systems ancl networks designed to transmit signals anonymously (telephony) and content-based information sources and tecl~nologies (broadcasting).

Thus, it is now possible to receive radio broad- casts over the Internet (using telephone net- works), and telephone services can be provided by companies in cable T\r (a broadcasting me- dium). Broadcasting (from one to many) now shades from narrow-casting (custom-tailored in- formation) to one-to-one communication like telephony (figure 4).

Page 12: levo~ution and the - documents.worldbank.orgdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/pt/888891468164944771/pdf/454660WP0BOX... · levo~ution and the What the Transformation of Telecommunications

10 The Drivers of the Information Revolution--Cost, Computing Power, and Convergence

FlQURE 4 T)IE CHANGING WORMATION INFRASTRUCTURE UNDER CONVERGENCE

I transmission

Convergence has important implications for po.licy1naker.s. Fil-st, it has made existing models for the telecommunications industry obsolete. Those models have assumecl that telecommu- nications is a public service, delivered through a network that is a natural monopoly. But these rnodeis are negated by the competition now possible between segments of the clelivery infrastructure (intermodal competition) and, increasingly, within segments (intramoclal competition). Convergence thus means that governments must lower barriers to ently and overhaul telecorn~~~unications regulatory sys- tems to promote competition, moving away from utility-type regulation.

Seconcl, convergence raises serious issues re- lating to content regcrlation. In broadcasting, countries have applied standards of decency, privacy, and protection of intellectual property rights using different mechanisms, but usually relying on a combination of self-regulation and legal sanctions (through the courts). Telecom- munications content has been largely unregu- lated, because it is not technically possible to do so using existing content regulation mecha- nisms. And convergence opens new realms of com~nunications where traditional content regu-

lation canno[ be applied. In this context, what clo policp~nakers do about decency, privacy, and intellectual property rights?

Convergence also opens up huge opportuni- ties for cleveloping countries to accelerate the rollout of connectivity to their populations using innovative technologies and private sector-lecl investment in a competitive mode. Cheaper communications are offering new possibilities for countries to be internationally competitive and to ,'plug in" to the global economy-ancl providing much more cost-effective ways to deliver essential public services to the poor.

Thus, convergence has major implications for the future of the telecommunications indust~y worldcrlide-the subject of the next article.

James Bond [email protected]), Division ChieJ Telecommunications and Informcltics

Page 13: levo~ution and the - documents.worldbank.orgdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/pt/888891468164944771/pdf/454660WP0BOX... · levo~ution and the What the Transformation of Telecommunications

Telecommunications Is Dead, Long Live Networking The effect of the information revolution on the telecom industry

Janzes Bond

Economic history teaches us that no industry is immune to change. Canals gave way to rail- roads, which in turn bowed to I-oacl transport when the cost of motor vehicles fell enough to make it more cost-effective. Banks are scram- bling to adjust to a world in which debt can be raised on bond markets and consumers can obtain many traditional lhanl<ing services on- line. And the telecommunications giants, which ha1.e reigned supreme for the past fifty years, are being besieged in their turn as the infor- mation revolution overturns the certainties o n which their strength is based.

The threat to the giants arises from the huge de- cline in the cost of cornmunicating, the increase in the power of computing, and the shift to digi- tal technology. These forces have led to indus- trial convergence as communications a n d infor~nation services (such as basic telephone sel-vice and cable W ) have been delinked from their delive~y infrastn~ctures (the telecommuni- cations and cable networks). With the delinking has come increasing overlap between the two main components of the communications indus- tly: common carrier conduit systems (delivering telephony) and content-based information sources and technologies (broadcasting). As a result of these changes, new competitors are emerging from unexpected directions, and the mal-ket domination on which telecommunications companies base theil- strength is melting away.

The economics of telecommunications

New technology has profoundly altered the ind~~s t ry ' s cost structure, and as a result, the existing structure of the industry and its pric- ing methods have now become incoherent. The end of natural monopoly, the trend toward new

pricing structures, and the increasing competi- tion and globalization in the industry are forc- ing radical change.

The e n d o f scale and na tu ra l monopoly

In a conventional wired network, most of the investment goes to establish the local loop, par- ticularly the civil works needed to extend the network to the end user. About two-thirds of the assets on the balance sheet of telecommu- nications operators are "holes in the groundJ'- the trenches needecl to lay the cables. Thus, in a traditional network, 70 to 85 percent of the cost of a call, even an international one, con- sists of the cost of the low-technology link cov- ering only the last couple of miles.

BOX 1 WHAT IS THE TELECOMMUNICATIONS INDUSTRY?

TELECOMMUNICATIONS INFRASTRUCTURE has three main components:

terminal equipment, such as telephones and fax machines in

users' homes and businesses; the local loop, generally a pair of

copper wires connecting the terminal equipment to switching

equipment in the local exchange; and long-distance or interna-

tional transmission networks, made up of fiber-optic cables,

microwave links, and satellites.

TELECOMMUNICATIONS SERVICES have focused on calling services: local

calls (within the local exchange network) and long-distance or

international calls. Increasingly, however, these basic services have

been augmented by the transmission of data in binary form and by

value added services (such as call waiting and Internet access),

which increase functionality for the end user and generate

supplementary income for the telecommunications operator.

Page 14: levo~ution and the - documents.worldbank.orgdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/pt/888891468164944771/pdf/454660WP0BOX... · levo~ution and the What the Transformation of Telecommunications

Telecommunications Is Dead, Long Live Networking

- a T 0 WLIIELESS I LOCAL LOOP AS4fEWNOlOGY DWJES' COST D m

FIGURE 3 WLOQfFN OF: IIEW T1EG#&MMWSai

Because in the conventional local loop basecl on copper wires the marginal cost of each new subscriber declines no matter how many existing subscribers there are, the telecommu- nications sector-or at least its local loop portion-has been considered a natural mo- nopoly. Economic theory suggests that the best way to manage a natural rno~~opoly is to cre- ate a regulated utility, granting it a franchise to deliver the service in exchange for certain ob- ligations (such as nondiscriminatoly treatment of consumers) and regulating the prices it can charge for the end product. This explains the nearly universal model for the telecommuni- cations sector: a local monopoly company, of- ten a public enterprise, with regulated prices.

But wireless, cable TV, and other technologies are now challenging the conventional local loop based on wireline technology and buried cop- per (figure 1). In many cases, wireless is already cheaper per new subscriber than wireline. And the rnuch flatter cost curves of wireless show that size no longer brings any real cost advan- tage. It is possible to have several competing providers of local service without raising the network's overall costs much. The implications are considerable: the best way to deliver service to customers is no longer through a utility but through competing providers of local telecom- ~nunications services. The existing telecommu- nications sector model in most of the world is simply wrong. Furthermore, the telecommuni- cations reforms sweeping the world should focus more on the structure of the sector- providing as much potential for competition as possible-than on the transfer of the mono- poly telecommunications company from the pul~lic to the private sector. In many cases, how- ever, the reverse is true.

he move to bandwidth-based pricing

Almost universally, how much you pay for a telephone call depends on how long you talk and how far away your correspondent is. If you are m Paris, it is much more expensive to call New York than to call Toulouse, and the price you pay (beyond the monthly rental fee for the

Page 15: levo~ution and the - documents.worldbank.orgdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/pt/888891468164944771/pdf/454660WP0BOX... · levo~ution and the What the Transformation of Telecommunications

The World Bank Group

BOX 2 THE IMPENDl#B COLLAPSE OF THE INTERNATIONAL ACCOUNTING RATE SYSTEM

line) is propo~.tional to the time you talk. But that is not how costs are built up for the opera- tors in the sector. For example, tariffs for inter- national calls, based on the current but outdated accounting rate system, nearly always far exceed the cost of providing the service (box 2).

A seconcl psol~lern relates to new services. The new communications services that customers increasingly demand send varying amounts of information per second clown the transrnission line. Paging, for example, requires narrow bandwidth (a s~nall amount of information per second), while new multimedia services (such as teleconferencing) require a huge amount of Ihandwidth hecause transmitting video sends inuch more information down the line than does transmitting sound alone. But most tele- communications operators do not offer choice in handwidth: customers get a standard tele- phone line, accommodating 64 kilobits per second (kbps) in Europe and 56 kbps in the United States.

To an increasing clegree, the costs borne by telecommunications operators are made up of three elements: a fixed monthly amount, which corresponds to the capital costs of the local loop; a one-time cost for each connection, cor- responcling to the cost of switching that call; and a transn~ission cost, which is proportional to the bandwidth. But actual customer charges are quite different. And because i t is increas- ingly possible to compete for customers, new, agile operators are emerging that take advan- tage of the possibilities for arbitrage between tariffs and actual costs. Much of the new activ- ity is in international service. But new players are also emerging in other areas, such as Inter- net service providers, which enable customers to place long-distance calls for the price of the local loop connection (figure 2 ) .

I t is safe to predict that competition and mar- ket forces will drive tariffs closer to long-run incremental costs, both in level and in struc- ture. And within a couple of years, consumers will probably be able to buy the bandwidth capacity they need for a given connection,

LntPrordlonal mriffs are b a d on the accounting rnte system which war dmlepsd as part of a rsguEsto#ytradition holding fbat interna- 1 5 d ~ o n m n t m i d o n r services are sapplied through a bilatersl comspo4ent FBJlltjOnshSp bstWBBll national mnopdy &em. An atcru- rate is lhe price Ike lwo d n e l d e n (or tbeir govemmm) negot-rate for handling one minuto ol iAtenwtiona1

felephone service. Rerenuw are shared W e e m the two carriers

Rm DO- nap tyrtu was originally intended to allow ench carrlcr to ~ O ~ P V ~ C )L1 CWB tar handling an intwdonal call.

The main problem with Ihe accountinp rate system it thst for nearly every country the cost d transm-Wag a call has fallen dmmatically wer the past twenty yeus, but the fell in pliw has lagged this d e c l i . As r result tbe rate greatly exceeds L e cost of

providinq L a m i c e . so acc~llliting reb~,whith &ill swum tbet lhe sactor is a monopoly, generrrte huna economic mts for tole-

phone c o ~ h s handling intenwtional calls. In wms -, intematienal erlk account for thr -re pmfiiof tba sector a d m n generate foreign exchange fwthe gwwnment

7his sysim is showing signs of imminent ctollepoa New possibili- dea for comp&Uon in i & m n a l awke dw SWW a femle araa for a r b i i l m g ~ n d so we am seeing sigaiicant a m in call- back redcea eallinfi cards, latemettdepbny, and tbe like. These

new sourcrra of campetition undercut the hugely isftaed accounting rattbs and eat inb the Rcome of telecomnunicatienr opetatom-

especially those offering the lowest pricee As 8 mu& the U.S. regula(or, tha Federal G o m ~ w n i m t h s ion, ia seaking ta replace i d ~ l aocodng rates with a new benchmark system based mom closely on actual cosEa

which, because of declining transmission costs, will cost no more than a few cents per hour even for international calls (in addition to the monthly rental for local access).

lntermodal competition, globalization, and the \KT0 negotiations

Policynlakers increasingly accept that compe- tition in the local loop is both possible and desirable But competition is also bringing changes that policymakers are much less knowledgeable about-in the explosion of new technologies, products, and services competing

Page 16: levo~ution and the - documents.worldbank.orgdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/pt/888891468164944771/pdf/454660WP0BOX... · levo~ution and the What the Transformation of Telecommunications

Telecommunications Is Deed, Long Live Networking

with one another to deliver connectivity to the end user (figure 3). New technologies increase arbitrage possibilities for new operators, and they complicate the work of regulators. But above all, they challenge existing operators, which are often slow in I-esponding to new customer demands.

Also changing is the geographic service area in which end users are interested-increasingly not only national but international. International traf- fic is growing by 12.4 percent a year, compared .with 5.9 percent for doinestic calls. Thus, as com- petition in domestic markets Ibecomes the norm, consumers will find operators that can offer packaged services on an international scale in- creasingly attractive. The growing demand for international services helps explain the trend toward global alliances among telecommunica- tions operators (page 17). But this trencl may stern more from the desire of former monopoly players to recreate at the international level the oligarchies to which they are accustomed in their domestic markets than from the underlying nlar- ket forces in the industry.

In an alternative future, transmission capacity and bandwidth might become tradable corn- modities, with a spot market on which capac- ity is lbought and sold in half-hour slices and megabit-per-second tranches. The spot rnarlzet could be associated with a futures market on which contracts would allow operators to hedge futul-e positions. It is difficult to imagine today's mastodon operators, which now cover every- thing from bulk transmission to value added services, in such a world. Instead, the world would segment into wholesalers, which would invest in and sell capacity: retailers, which would be in contact with the final consumer; and traders and brokers, which would inter- mediate supply and demancl for capacity.

important benefits both locally and globally. The \VTO has placed telecommunications at the top of its agenda for multilateral trade lib- eralization (page 20) . As markets open to For- eign participation, ancl as technology creates nenr markets, we can expect to see an entirely new cast of players investing in markets that are new not only technologically but also geographically.

Conclusion

The old monopoly telecommunications sector is fast disappearing. National telecommunica- tions markets are fragmenting into a multiplicity of niche rnarltets at the same time that national trade barriers are falling. Many new operators are emerging, each targeting the segment that best corresponds to its comparative advantage. In this new networlted bit industry, offering a huge range of competing technologies and ser- vices, the future for the incumbent telecommu- nications companies looks increasingly bleak. Over the next decade, as the market shifts From under their feet and as new, more nimble actors emerge, we can expect the dominance of the telecornrnunications operators over their tradi- tional markets to erode spectacularly. Some countries are likely to see their major telecom- munications operators fail, and new players will appear that quickly become household names around the world.

./sines Bond (jhoizd@zuorldba~zk.o~.g) , Dzoisio~z ChieJ Telecornmtrnicatiom and hgon?zatics

Globalization goes beyond telecommunications operators. As the World Trade Organization (WTO) focuses world attention on liberalizing trade in services, policymakers are beginning to realize that opening telecommunications markets to foreign investors and operators has

Page 17: levo~ution and the - documents.worldbank.orgdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/pt/888891468164944771/pdf/454660WP0BOX... · levo~ution and the What the Transformation of Telecommunications

What the Transformation of Telecommunications Markets Means for Regulation

If the telecommunications sector is undergoing fundamental change, s o is the role of the regu- lator. In most countries, telecommunications regulators no longer regulate a static, monopo- l~stic industry that provides essentially a single product, telephone service, but a dynamic, multiproduct, multioperator industry. The tele- com~ni~nications regulator is way ahead of its peers in other utility sectoss in moving from a monopolistic to a competitive market.

Transformation of markets

The transformation of telecommunications markets is occurring in several climensions-in the changing structure of demand, in the con- vergence of services, ancl in the changing struc- ture of the industry. The transformation is driven mainly by technological developments. But com- petitive pressures resulting frorn the globaliza- tion of the world economy and the ideology ancl results of reform policies in the sector are also important forces.

Changing demand structure. Only ten years ago, conventional "fixed" voice telephony dominated the revenues of all telephone companies. Today, unprecedented growth in demand for new services-facsimile, mobile telephony, and Internet-is funclamentally changing the overall structure of demand in the sector. For example, in Thailand recently, 24 percent of all telephones were mobile (fig- ure 1). 'The exponential growth in the number of Internet servers and users, and consequently in the demand for banclwidth to carry graphics- rich data files, is intensifying the dernancl for national and international transmission links (page 27). Convergence of services. Convergence is oc- curring not on1 y between telecommunications

broadcasting, cable television, and the Inter- net, but also within segments of the telecom- munications market. For example, cellular mobile telephony is now a substitute for con- ventional local telephone service for many customers (see figure 1); the distinction be- tween local and long-distance calling or, with the pending introduction of global personal mobile satellite service, between donlestic and international service is becoming less and less relevant; and paging and cellular telephony are now sometimes bundled as a single sel.- vice delivered through the same handset. Changing industry structure. There has been a fundamental shift in the indust~y structure in many countries toward a multioperator en- vironment. Several factors are driving this shift. New operators are entering the market frorn other utility sectors (in the United Kingdom, for example, electric utilities and cable TV companies both provide telephony services). Sewice suppliers are going international as the era of national monopolies passes (figure 2). And the resale of network services is becom- ing an increasingly important business as separating network ownership from service delivery becomes operationally and cornmer- cially viable.

The future of telecommunications regulation

These trends in telecommunications markets mean that regulators will operate in a fast- changing envil-onment characterized by increased complexity, reduced scope for discretionary de- cisions, increasing privatization of some aspects of regulation, and the convergence of regulation of different sectors and of regulation within the sector.

Page 18: levo~ution and the - documents.worldbank.orgdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/pt/888891468164944771/pdf/454660WP0BOX... · levo~ution and the What the Transformation of Telecommunications

16 What the Transformation of Telecommunications Markets Means for Regulation

Philippinsr lhailaad

I l5 venalue w

Gabon

Management of change

In contrast to such utilities as power and wa- ter, telecom~nunications is now clearly a multi- product sector with several alternative service delivery mechanisms that permit competition in senlice provision. But con~petition has not eliminated the fundamental reasons for regu- lation of the sector-the need to allocate the scarce radio spectrum and to protect custom- ers fro111 potential monopoly abuses. Voice te- lephony is still widely regarded as an essential public service, and the sector is still a poten- tial monopoly in which operators could adopt strategic behavior with respect to network in- terconnection, numbering plans, allocation of radio spectrum, and the use of cross-subsidies. Regulators are the gatekeepers of the transfor- mation of the telecommunications market. They have influence or control over pricing, stan- dards, market entry, numbering plans, and in- terconnection arrangements. They influence the speed, conditions, and areas of change, and

they arbitrate conflicts that arise between win- ners and losers in that change. Consequently, regulators often must keep an eye on politi- cally acceptable limits to change (For example, to the structure of cross-subsidies in the sec- tor) while steering a course toward regulatory reform.

Still, the regulatory agenda has changed. The focus has shifted from minimizing the price of subscribing to local telephone service or main- taining cross-subsidy to n~anaging the transi- tion to a new environment. Managing this transition requires addressing multiple issues related to compeLition, entry, pricing, and cross- subsidies:

Determining whether entry in different mar- ket segments should be limited or open and setting the terms of entry-and thus creating rnarltet forces. Adopting processes for the award of licenses to service providers. (These may include bid- ding processes in which the evaluation cri- teria are clear and easily measured, as in price bids, or "beauty contests," in which the bid evaluation criteria are subjective and the se- lection process is less transparent.) Resolving network interconnection issues and managing numbering plans to promote the emergence of a multioperator environment. Authorizing rate rebalancing (whereby prices are moved closer to costs by reducing prices for international and long-distance services and increasing them for local and network access service) in order to reduce economic rents and cross-subsiclies. Applying new approaches to cross-subsidies, such as improvecl targeting of beneficiaries, bidding for minimum subsidies, and the ad- ministration of subsidies in a way that doe.< not favor one operator over another.

Furthermore, the wireless revolution (reflected in the rapid growth of cellular telephony, the increasing significance of wireless local loop systems, and the planned deployment of sev- eral new-generation global personal mobile sat- ellite systems) demands that regulators respond to the increased need to manage radio spec-

Page 19: levo~ution and the - documents.worldbank.orgdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/pt/888891468164944771/pdf/454660WP0BOX... · levo~ution and the What the Transformation of Telecommunications

The World Bank Group

FIGURE 2 GLOBALIZATION THROUGH GLOBAL TElECOM AUIANCES

E-P h p r

WORLD PARTNERS I CONCERT -

United Statsl laia Unisd Sate6 Asia

trum. Typically, this task involves allocating portions of the radio spectrum to different uses, assigning frequencies and authorizing transmis- sion power levels to transmitters at specifiecl locations, maintaining standards to ensure that transmitters make optimum use of the radio spectrum, and implementing measures to con- trol unauthorized use.

Increased complexity and reduced discretion

The transformation of telecommunications markets-the changing structure and mix of regulated companies, the changing competi- tive environments in rnarltet segments, and the increasing importance of transnational issues- has made the job of regulating the sector much more complex. At the same time, it has reduced the scope for discretionary decisions.

Market transformation is reducing the scope for regulators to maintain cross-subsicly, for example, as a result of the convergence of ser- vices within the sector. Traclitionally, the clear segmentation of the market enabled regulators to treat different categories of custo~ners and service providers differently, influencing the p1,ofitability of services and the flow of cross- subsiclies. Thus, mobile telephone service prices were typically unregulated, while fixed telephone service prices were regulatecl. And monopoly international telephone service

prices could be set vely high in order to gen- erate a pool of funds for cross-subsidy.

But the convergence of services-reflected in the increasing substitutability of nob bile and fixed services, the increasing ease with which high-priced international telephone service can be bypassed through private networks, the in- troduction of call-back services, and the pend- ing introduction of global personal mobile satellite services-creates pressures to seduce differentia.1 regulatory treatment ancl to push prices closer to costs. The involvement of the World Tracle Organization (WTO) in setting rules for regulating basic telecommunications services further reduces regulators' scope for discretionary decisions relating to, for example, preventing anticompetitive practices, provid- ing interconnection with a major operator on noncliscriminatory terms, and allocating scarce resources such as radio frequencies and tele- phone numbers.

Privatizing regulation

With the increased complexity, the option of privatizing some aspects of telecommunications regulation is increasingly attractive. Two main approaches are possible. One is to create pri- vate property rights over the radio spectrum, which has been implemented to some extent in the United States and other countries through

Page 20: levo~ution and the - documents.worldbank.orgdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/pt/888891468164944771/pdf/454660WP0BOX... · levo~ution and the What the Transformation of Telecommunications

What the Transformation of Telecommunications Markets Means for Regulation

radio spectrum auctions. Once such property rights are estal~lished the new owners of the spectrum may wish to take an increased role in sublicensing to other users and in policing the use of the spectrum. By establishing prop- erty rights the commercial value of the spec- trum takes on increased importance, and thus provides incentives for more efficient use.

An important extension of this approach, pro- posed by advisers to the government of El Sal- vador in 1996, calls for creating rights over designated commercial radio spectrum bands not just for specific uses, but for any use. This gives owners of designated commercial bands an incentive to assign frequency to the most profitable (or highest-value) use.

Creating property rights thus substitutes a mar- ket process for the government role in assign- ing radio spectrum for specific uses such as broadcasting, cellular telephony, or private tele- co~llmunications networks. The government role could be limited to managing the initial sale of spectrum, ensuring compliance with in- ternational agreements on spectrum use, and ensuring that ownership of the radio spectrum is not monopolized.

The second approach for privatizing regulation is outsourcing. While regulatory authority would remain with a government agency, many func- tions could be contracted out, such as auditing the performance of operators, preparing public consultation documents, or implementing alter- native dispute resolution mechanisms. The multi- operator environment emerging in most countries promises a heavy workload for regulators in ad- judicating billing, numbering plan, and intercon- nection issues. Alternative dispute resolution mechanisms and other forms of outsourcing are important options For reducing that workload as well as the budgetary burden on telecommuni- cations regulators.

Convergence of regulation

Multisector public utility boards have been around for many years in the United States. These utility

boards often have a mandate over telecommuni- cations, natural gas, and electric power supply. Anci in some jurisdictions, communications regu- lators have a mandate over transport or Ihroad- casting as n7ell as telecommunications.

Now, new pressures for convergence in regu- lation are arising from four main sources. First, the overlap between regulation of carriage (tele- communications) and regulation of content (broadcasting) will increase as both telephone companies and cable TV operators begin to provide services previously provided only by the other and as the Internet's capability to deliver video improves.

Second, the substitutability of services across subsectors or market segments, particularly between telecommunications and cable TV, broadcasting, satellite broadcasting, or Internet, also creates pressures for harmonizing regula- tion across communications subsectors.

Third, important issues are emerging in telecorn- rnunications that relate to promoting competi- tion: interconnection arrangements, revenue settlement, numbering plans, number portability, and the like. Although the implementation of procompetition policies in telecornmunic~t' I O ~ S

is sector-specific (or in some cases, specific to network industries) in important ways, the policy itself is essentially competition policy. This pres- sure for regulatory convergence is an outcome not only of the changing technology and mar- ket structures, but also of the increasing role of international agreements on telecommunications regulation. Telecommunications regulatory agen- cies will increasingly become specialized com- petition policy agencies.

Fourth, the high level of insularity or compart- ~iientalization that has been possible at the national and international level as well as the sectoral level is being eroded. Until recently. for example, France could have a completely different regulatory approach than the United Kingdom. But the recent completion of the WTO agreements setting out commitments for regulating basic teleco~nn~unications services

Page 21: levo~ution and the - documents.worldbank.orgdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/pt/888891468164944771/pdf/454660WP0BOX... · levo~ution and the What the Transformation of Telecommunications

The World Bank Group 19

is a step toward international harmonization of regulation in the sector. And in the Euro- pean Union, the application of European competition policy has played a key role in liberalizing basic telecommunications. These recent EU and \VTO initiatives, though not com- prehensive, are important steps in harmoniz- ing national approaches to telecommunications regulation.

Conclusion

Regulation is profoundly changing the telecom- munications sector. But change in the sector is also driving the agenda for regulation. It is hard to know where all this will end. But it is not inconcei\7able that telecommunications regu- latory agencies will eventually disappear, absorbed into multisector antitrust agencies.

Peter Smith (psm ith2@zi~orldbnnk or@, Principal Teleconz~?zz~nicnliol.ls Policy Specialist, Teleconzm u n icatio~zs and I n formatics Diuision

Page 22: levo~ution and the - documents.worldbank.orgdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/pt/888891468164944771/pdf/454660WP0BOX... · levo~ution and the What the Transformation of Telecommunications

Role of the World Trade Organization Carlos A . Prinzo B~zbga

Febl-uary 15, 1997, will be remembered as a landmark date in the history of the multilateral trade system. On that day, sixty-nine govern- ments formalized commitments to liberalize their basic telecommunications services under the General Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS). The resulting Decision on Commit- ments in Basic Telecomlnunications has both symbolic and practical meaning. 'The final act of the Uruguay Round in Marrakech in 1994, giving birth to the World Trade Organization (WTO), was described by many as the begin- ning of a new era in international trade rules. The agreement on basic teleconununications can be characterized as the first major accom- plishment of this new era. Moreover, it will foster the liberalization O F telecommunications, bringing significant benefits for industrial and developing countries alike.

This article reviews the evolution of the ser- vices and telecommunications negotiations, the scope of the new set of multilateral disciplines, and the implications of the agreement for WTO members, particularly developing countries. The basic message is that the agreement is a major accomplishment, but implementing the commitments it contains will pose a significant challenge for many of the developing country LVTO members. But the potential benefits of following through with these commitments are not trivial, and policymakers should maintain the focus on the liberalization agenda, build- ing on the commitments already made.

A clash of worlds

In the early 1980s, when the trade community, under the leadership of the United States, be- gan to discuss the inclusion of services in the

lnultilateral trade regime, there was no con- sensus on the best way to proceed. Develop- ing countries, for example, opposed the negotiations either because they believed that they did not enjoy cornpal-ative advantage in the relevant industries, or because they feared that these negotiations would intrude into other areas, such as foreign direct investment poli- cies and national regulatory regimes. Needless to say, other topics-For example, agriculture and textiles-were much more prominent on the negotiating agenda of developing countries.

For telecommunications, resistance to tracle ne- gotiations also came from major players in the industry. After all, state-owned enterprises were the suppliers of telecomn~unications services in all but a handful of countries, and interna- tional telephony was conducted like a cartel, with transactions closely regulated under rules negotiated under the International Telecommu- nication Union (ITU). Against this background, the idea of using trade negotiations to promote the liberalization of telecommunications was an alien concept to most of this community. It was also perceived as a threat to national regu- lators, and in some countries, it was even por- trayed as a threat to national sovereignty.

Despite the opposition, the services negotia- tions progressed more smoothly than most ana- lysts had predicted at the beginning of the Uruguay Round. The internationalization of services is at the very core of the process of economic globalization. Service industries (for example, telecommunications, transport, finan- cial services) provide critical links among geographically dispersed markets. Efficient, high-quality links are fundamental for trans- national corporations-the most dynamic actors

Page 23: levo~ution and the - documents.worldbank.orgdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/pt/888891468164944771/pdf/454660WP0BOX... · levo~ution and the What the Transformation of Telecommunications

The World Bank Group 21

in globalization-and this critical need explains their strong interest in the establishment of multilateral disciplines in se~vices trade. Pushed by these powerful interests and the growing recognition of the potential benefits of liberal- izing services, the negotiating agenda evolved graduall.~, and by 1993, the basic architecture of the GATS hacl been agreed on.

The GATS in a nutshell1

The GATS comprises the framework agreement (with its twenty-nine articles and eight annexes) as well as the schedules of specific commit- ments and the lists of exemptions to most- favored-nation (MFN) treatment submitted by member countries. It covers four modes of international delive~y of services: cross-border supply (for example, ~nternational telephony), consumption abroad (tourism), commercial presence (provision of services abroad through a branch, agency, or subsidiary), ancl the pres- ence of natural persons (entry and temporary stay of foreign individuals in order to supply a service).

It broadly follows the tradition of its counter- part for trade in goods-the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT)--emphasizing nondiscrimination and imposing limits on the use of quantitative restrictions on trade. But it introduces innovations, covering transactions associated with commercial presence and in- troducing a concept of market access that goes beyond border restrictions (for example, in principle, it proscribes restrictions on the type of organization under which foreign providers can establish commercial presence).

Unconditional MFN treatment is a basic obli- gation of signatories that applies to all services, an obligation that bars a WTO member from treating other members less favorably than any other country. Rut GATS allows MFN exernp- tions as long as the member country identifies them explicitly. The list of exemptions is sup- posed to be time-bound and, in principle, should not last more than ten years. Another basic obligation of members is a commitment

to transparency, which requires governments to publish and make available to the public the laws and regulations that affect trade in services.

Market access and national treatment, in turn, are specific obligations under the GATS. They apply only to the service industries and activi- ties specifically listed by a country in its sched- ule of commitments. These obligations are specified at the level of each of the four modes of supply and subject to the limits made ex- plicit in the offer. The GATS adopts a "positive list" approach with respect to sectoral coverage of service industries-that is, only the industries and activities scheduled in the commitments are subject to the GATS'S specific obligations.

The treatment of telecommunications in the GATS

Telecommunications services are defined in a comprehensive manner for GATS purposes, en- compassing both basic services-those that in- volve simply end-to-end transmission of voice or data-and value aclded services-those that modify the form or content of the messages re- layed through the network^.^ By the end of the Uruguay Round, forty-eight schedules (repre- senting 59 of the 125 governments participating in the negotiations) contained commitments in the area of telecommunications. But almost all of these commitments covered only value added services, reflecting the resistance still facing this novel approach to telecommunications nego- tiations. In short, most of the relevant markets for communications continued to operate out- side multilateral disciplines.

The Uruguay Round accomplished some irn- portant results for the telecommunications sec- tor, however. First, it raised awareness about the potential role of trade negotiations in foster- ing the liberalization of telecommunications. Second, it helped to diminish the gap in understanding between the trade and telecom- munications communities by promoting a dia- logue on their distinct approaches to regulation. Third, it established that access to telecommu-

Page 24: levo~ution and the - documents.worldbank.orgdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/pt/888891468164944771/pdf/454660WP0BOX... · levo~ution and the What the Transformation of Telecommunications

22 Liberalizing Telecomrnunlcations and the Role of the World Trade Organization

nications services was critical for trade in ser- vices and that users were entitled to fair terms of access (Annex on Telecommunications of the GATS).

But the limited progress in effective liberaliza- tion of basic telecommunications led WTO members to agree to continue the negotiations beyond the date of the Round's completion (April 15, 1994). Basic telecon~munications joined maritime transport, financial services, and the movement of natural persons as topics for sectoral negotiations. The Negotiating Group on Basic Telecommunications (NGBT) was created in May 1994, with a deadline of April 30, 1996, for completing the talks.

From the NGBT to the GBT

Participation in the NGBT was voluntary. Ini- tially, fifty-three WTO members decided to par- ticipate in the negotiations, with twenty-four other governments attending the meetings as observers. The attitude of most participating countries about the usefulness of engaging in these negotiations had shifted significantly by then. In part, this simply reflected a better un- derstanding of the potential benefits of liberal- izing telecommunications. More fundamentally, however, it reflected the growing recognition that the industry is facing a paradigm shift. Tech- nological progress is rapidly eroding the sustainability of old practices based on monopo- listic behavior, state control, and protected mar- kets for local providers. Call-back systems, virtual private networks, the Internet, and the growing promise of modern satellite communications are multiplying the opportunities for bypassing tele- communications monopolies. At the same time, the increasing information intensiveness o f transnational corporations and the dramatic re- ductions in the cost of communications create additional incentives for customers to actively explore bypassing alternatives.

In the NGBT, the focus of the debate rapidly progressed from "why to liberalize" to "how to liberalize." Important conceptual progress was achieved as participants recognized that for

telecommunications, unless a procompetitive regulatory framework was also put in place, the value of the market access co~nmitments would be greatly reduced. A draft reference paper describing regulatory disciplines support- ive of market entry was negotiated, and most countries became signatories to this text (par- tially or in its entirety) in the context of addi- tional commitments made in their offers (expanding on their market access and national treatment commitments). This can be charac- terized as the first multilateral effort to deal explicitly with substantive aspects of competi- tion policy. Even though limited to telecom- munications, it was a major achievement and it paves the way for Future multilateral disci- plines and international harmonization.

By April 1996, thirty-four offers (encompassing forty-eight governments, with the European Union's submission counting as one) were on the table. Still, some countries-particularly the United States-were dissatisfied with the qual- ity and coverage of the offers. Moreover, in the final phase of the negotiations, the issue of sat- ellite services-that is, to what extent explicit provision for these services needed to be made in the offers-added "noise" to the negotiations. As a result, no deal was attained by the dead- line of April 30, 1996. Given the progress al- ready achieved, however, there was broad support for continuing the negotiations. Seizing this opportunity, Renato Ruggiero, Director- General of the WTO, suggested that countries should be given a chance to improve on their offers, and February 15, 1997, was established as the new deadline for the negotiations. A new body-the Group on Basic Telecommunications (GBT)-was created to carry on with the nego- tiations, replacing the NGBT, and the rules of participation were changed to make all WTO members fill1 participants.

The negotiations restarted in July 1996, and by the WTO Ministerial Conference in Singapore in December 1996, several countries had al- ready tabled improvecl offers, signaling sup- port for a successful conclusion of the negotiations. Still, some thorny issues contin-

Page 25: levo~ution and the - documents.worldbank.orgdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/pt/888891468164944771/pdf/454660WP0BOX... · levo~ution and the What the Transformation of Telecommunications

The Warld Bank Gruup 23

FIQURL 1 EOUlTRlEl MAKING BASIC TELECOMMUNICATIONS COMMITMENT)

hh *aw L W ~ I W

40Msrtn, l0ngdrtr~8 + . - 1 IalsrtwWal

h a l e

Private Is& eimllit ravip#r

Other tomstre mbiC sarvicdo

MobilemllL rmicea

uecl to loom on the horizon. In particular, lively discussions continued on international services (for example, countries with more liberal re- gimes were concerned that an MFN commit- ment to liberalize international services could give rise to anticompetitive practices by for- eign monopolistic carriers), on satellite services, and on what constituted an adequate "critical mass" for a deal. Other controversial issues included how to avoid discriminatory practices in the allocation of spectrum and how to draw the line between telecommunications and au- diovisual setvices given the growing techno- logical convergence in these areas.

Gradually, however, technical and political so- lutions began to emerge. With respect to inter- national services, the United States unilaterally announced a new pol~cy toward international settlement rates in December 1996, creating a mechanism for addressing the concerns of its own carriers about the distortions of the ac- counting sates system outside the WTO frame- work. This helped deflate opposition to the agreement based on concerns that it could fos- ter anticompetitive practices (for example, by one-way accounting sate bypass). Also help-

ing to pave the way to the final agreement were the adoption of a technologically neutral ap- proach to scheduling (that is, unless otherwise noted, the commitments would cover all trans- mission possibilities including satellite services) and the acceptance of the concepts that fre- quency and spectrum management should not be used to undermine market access commit- ments and that the use of MFN exemptions could temporarily address the differences in treatment of audiovisual services.

In a parallel effort, governments, the WTO, and several other multilateral organizations worked to raise awareness of the importance of the negotiations for developing countries and to help these countries prepare their own offers. The World Bank, for example, through its In- formation for Development (i~goDev) program and in close cooperation with the WTO, spon- sored a project to provide technical assistance to more than twenty developing countries in the final stages of the negotiations.' By early 1997, it became clear that a "critical mass" of offers woulcl be achieved. On February 15, 1997, the telecommunications talks were suc- cessfully concludecl.

Page 26: levo~ution and the - documents.worldbank.orgdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/pt/888891468164944771/pdf/454660WP0BOX... · levo~ution and the What the Transformation of Telecommunications

24 Liberrlhing Tdsoommuniwtions and the Role ofthe Workl Trade Organbadon

naw~ t m w m REVENUES BETWEEN PARTICIPATING AND

The scope of the agreement

Sixty-nine WTO members tabled commitments by February 15, 1997.' These schedules will be- come formally binding by January 1, 1998. Not only were several new offers added to the ones available in April 1996, but thirty-two of the thirty-four original offers were revised, typically leading to more substantive commitments. Com- mitments were made in all basic telecommuni- cations services by both high-income and developing countries (figure 1). Moreover, most participants made commitments either to all or to parts of the reference paper, subscribing to procompetitive regulatory principles (for ex- ample, the establishment of independent regu- lators, the adoption of competitive safeguards, measures to ensure interconnection, transpar- ent and nondiscriminatory practices with respect to licensing, and universal service obligations).

The exact implications of the agreement for a particular country can only be assessed by a careful analysis of its schedule of commitments, including phasing considerations, list of qualifi- cations by activity and mode of delivery, and

eventual recourse to MFN exemptions (nine gov- ernments claimed such exemptions for certain activities). It is fair to say, however, that in con- trast with the GATS'S results in 1994, when most schedules were characterized by status quo com- mitments (that is, governments basically bound themselves not to adopt more restrictive poli- cies), the outcome of the basic telecommunica- t ions negot ia t ions will fos ter significant additional liberalization.' In this sense, the agree- ment proved wrong those analysts who were skeptical of the role of sectoral negotiations in fostering liberalization at the n~ultilateral level.

The markels affected by the agreement repre- sent more than 90 percent of the world market for telecommunications (figure 2). Developing countries account for less than 20 percent of the global revenues from telecommunications services, but they are the fastest-growing mar- kets for these s e l ~ i c e s . Their participation in the WTO process is thus important not only for developmental reasons, but also because these markets are bound to increase their rela- tive importance in global terms. The areas with the weakest telecommunications infrastructure

Page 27: levo~ution and the - documents.worldbank.orgdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/pt/888891468164944771/pdf/454660WP0BOX... · levo~ution and the What the Transformation of Telecommunications

The World Bank Group 25

FIGURE 3 COUNTRIES WITH LOWEST TELEDENSITY WERE LESS ACTIVE IN WTO NEGOTIATIONS

L

per 100 inhabiats

tk b a u d a r k calon denonlnhns, and other i d o W a n shown on *Is msp L npt imply, or ma pan of tbs W o a b3 brq, eny an tho l q a l status of any tsrhry or uy eaJonenrot r r awrptnnce of slcb boundrrier

~ T W - ~ l U l i * l ~ w O ~ h a d r ~ t a ( s r c k k

(such as Sub-Saharan Africa) were those that had participated less actively in the WTO ne- gotiations (figure 3). Assistance to help bring these countries into the system should be a priority for the donor community.

The road ahead

Analyses of the importance of the basic tele- communications agreement tend to cluster

around two extreme positions. Most analysts have been extremely enthusiastic and present the agreement as delivering swift liberalization of participating markets. Others are more sltep- tical, pointing out that the multilateral regime and the regulatory authorities are being over- taken by the velocity of technological change in the industry. For the latter, the agreement plays at best a seconda~y role in this process of change.

Page 28: levo~ution and the - documents.worldbank.orgdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/pt/888891468164944771/pdf/454660WP0BOX... · levo~ution and the What the Transformation of Telecommunications

Liberalizing Telecommunications and the Role of the World Trade Organization

Reality is somewhere in between. It is true that fast technological change has been the main driver of the paradigm shift described above, and it explains to a large extent the changing attitude in the industry on the desirability (in- evitability) of competition. But credible rules relating to market access, constraints on dis- crimination, and a procompetitive regulatory environment play an important part in shap- ing the outcome of this "revolution," particu- larly in influencing the distribution of its benefits.

Private capital is expected to take the lead in funding investments in telecomm~~nications in the developing world. In the early 1990s, 65 percent of the funds used to finance basic wireline telecommunications in the develop- ing world came from internal sources (prof- its), with commercial funds (20 percent) and official sources (15 percent) playing a more limited role. By the end of this clecade, it is estirnatecl that private capital flows will finance a much greater share of the investments in the sector (55 percent), with internal (40 percent) and official sources ( 5 percent) reducing their relative participation.

But private investors will be willing to invest in modernizing the telecommunications infra- structure of cleveloping countries only if they can count on fair and stable rules of the game. Accordingly, developing countries able to sig- nal their commitment to liberalization and to adopt a procompetitive regulatory environment will be in a better position to attract the capital flows required for these investments. WTO commitments can play an important part in this.

Benefits for developing countries are not lim- ited to attracting foreign direct investment. Lib- eralization will also improve local firms' access to efficient telecommunications service provid- ers. This will increase their competitiveness- and thus their ability to explore the dynamism of international trade in information-intensive, products and services. Last but not least, com- petition will improve the price-quality mix of the telecommunications services available to

consumers. The critical remaining issue is the quality of the implementation of the commit- ments. Many developing countries are enter- ing uncharted territory, particularly with respect to procompetitive regulatory disciplines. Those able to face these challenges successfully will be much better positioned to benefit from the "information age."

I This rction relies on Prjrno Braga (1996). For further details on the rationale for liberalizing services and on rhe architecture of the GATS, see UNCTAD and World Rank (1994) and Hwkman (1996)

? Basic services cover voice telephony, relcs, telep~pli. facs~rnile, dara mosmissron, pnvate I d circuit services, fixed and ~nohdr satellite system5 and sercices, cellular relephony, mobile dara xr- vices, paging, and personal communication services. Value added services indude ernail, voice mail, on-line dara processing, on-line database storage and mrieval. and electronic data interchange.

' For furrhrr details on this project, which was executed by rhe

lntemdtional Imtirute of Como~unications, visit the infoDev welxitc at http://n~.n~.n~orldhank.o~html/infodl.

' Antigua and Barbuda. Argentina, Australia. Bangladesh, Belize. Bolivia, Blazil. Brunei Da-lam Bulgaria. Canada. Chile. Cnloln- hi, a t e d'lvoire. Czech Repuhlic, Dominica. Dominican Republic, Ecuatlor, El Salvador. European Communiries and its Me& Stares, Ghana. Grenada. Guaclmla. Hone, Kong. Hungry, Icelad. Indra. Inclonesid. Israel, Jamaica. Japan, b e Rept~blic of I<ol.ea. klala)~s~r. hlauritius, Mexico. Morocco. New &land. No~way, Paltisrdn. P,ipu;~ New Guinea, Peru. Phlllppines, Polantl. Romania. Senegal. Singapore. Srl Lanka. Switzedand. Slovak Republic. Sour11 Afric~, Thailand, Trinidad and Tobago. Tunisia. lurkey, United State>. a d Venc~uela. For a discussion of the ms~~lrs of the GATS in p~omoting s e ~ v i c r ~ liheraliu~~on. we Hoekman and Primo Braga (1996).

References

Hockman, &mad. 19% "Asesing the General Agreement on Trade in Services." In W~ll Manin and L. Alan Winters, etls.. The Uruguay Roirndur~d the Dei.aio/~r~~g Cor~ii/r.ic?s Camhritlge: Carnlwidge Uni- versiry Press.

Hoekrnan. Bernard, and C.I\. I'l.imo Braga. 1%1. "Tmde In SenKes, the GATS and Asia." Asin-Pcfcijic Ecorzoniic Rm'it?u> 2 (Aph.11) 5--20

Primo Braga. C.A. 1996. "The Itnpacr of the Intematlonal~zation of Services on Developing Countries." Finance and &eIopmer~t (1March). 34-37.

UNCTAD 2nd World Bank. 1994. Lihernlizfng I~~ternrrriorwl Tmrrs- actioiis in Xenrica: A Ifandbook. New York: United Nations.

Carlos A. Prim0 Bragn (cbraga&orldbank.or@, Principal Economist, Telecommunications and In for'nzntics Division

Page 29: levo~ution and the - documents.worldbank.orgdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/pt/888891468164944771/pdf/454660WP0BOX... · levo~ution and the What the Transformation of Telecommunications

The Private Sector and the Internet Carlos A. Prinzo Braga and Carsteiz Fink

Advances in telecornrnunications and informatics have transformed the Internet from an acade~liic experiment into a household name in most in- dustrial countries. The number of computers connected to the Internet grew from 535,000 in July 1991 to close to 16 million by January 1997 (figure 11, and it is estimated that the number of Internet users has already exceeded 50 million. Although still concentrated in industrial coun- tries, this "network of networks" is rapidly es- pancling in the developing world. Many now believe that it provicles a window into a future in which access to information will be indepen- dent of geographic location and interactivity in a multimedia environment will be ubiquitous.

This article briefly reviews the history of the Internet and its evolution from an academic experiment into the main application behind the emerging global infor~nation infrastructure. It discusses the role of the private sector in these developments and the regulatory envi- ronment required fol- the Internet to fulfill its promise. It concludes with some lessons for expanding the Internet in developing countries.

The rise of the Internet

The origins of the Internet can be tracecl to the 1960s, when the U.S. Department of Defense clecided to Fund the development of a pacliet- switching data network that would allow net- worked computers of different sizes and types to communicate efficiently. In packet-switch- ing networks, data files are broken into small packages that are sent inclepenclently over the network and then reassembled at the final des- tination. This permits efficient use of commu- nications lines because, unlike circuit-switching. an architecture typically used for voice tele-

phony, it does not require an open, or point- to-point, connection. Packet-switching allows many users to share a circuit, with n o particu- lar connection dedicated for a given commu- nication session. Moreover, i t increases the network's reliability, allowing i t to operate even under catastrophic conditions (for example, amid a nuclear war).

The resulting network, Arpanet, Ibegan opera- tion in 1969, linking four sites. In the 1970s, other government-supported networks emerged in the United States, but access remained re- stricted to the research community connected w ~ t h the Department of Defense ancl other gov- ernment agencies. This changed in 1986 with

FIGURE 1 GROWTH OF THE INTERNET lneractkwrhic) 10 I

14 mmhmet 12

lu .mdu I m m

8 mmi 6 .ah 4

2 I : hl M U 4 - -~rd & U Q W

~ k ~ h d i ~ u q u u t h n l r V M U t m b u h m a d - r r i a k . 8 m W and has 0 Slrect con.oetion la *. k w m L Top-Iwe[danaIn r u m ill.atay hosla by type or aqlr-- lor rxmple, eom kometcmll. .a (datrtioml), and .et

govenmatl. and CUUIUIV d.maLn such as .mk Nnkd Klnoh) a d .de&rmawl. But top*lsvml dDnrsln namw cam be nirleadirgt c h e a m i g i net Ed Iocmled Im IL~. wnlry inllcrSed anighl be elcbr a public or a prlvale i I & U l i ~ . Swn*N.nwd V h d m I~J/www.nw.wml. I

Page 30: levo~ution and the - documents.worldbank.orgdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/pt/888891468164944771/pdf/454660WP0BOX... · levo~ution and the What the Transformation of Telecommunications

The Private Sector and the Internet

the creation of the NSFNet. Subsidized by the U.S. government, the idea of the NSFNet was to provide high-speed backbone services connect- ing regional networks as well as campuses and research centers. The network of networks com- municating through the Internet protocol be- gan to expand rapidly.

In the early 1990s, the management of the NSFNet backbone was subcontracted to private firms, which were allowed to route commer- cial traffic through the Internet. The explosive demand for network service in the 1990s- mainly from the private sector-led to the emergence of several commercial Internet back- bone networks (such as Alternet, PSNet, and SprintLink), and in October 1995, the NSFNet backbone was shut down. US, government subsidies for the Internet have fallen to an in- significant amount, and almost all the costs of the Internet are now borne by its users.

Supporting the explosive growth of the Inter- net and of the demand for Internet services have been the rapidly evolving network archi- tecture and user interfaces. This technology has

benefited from the decline in computing costs relative to transmission costs. On the user side, the growth of the Internet has been promoted by the appearance of powerful programming languages, new network "tools," and user- friendly interfaces. The World Wide Web, a so- phisticated application that allows users to access any kind of digitized information (text, picture, sound, video) and configure it for dis- play with a mouse click, has given multimedia capabilities to the Internet. The growth of the Web has been astounding: between June 1993 and January 1997, the number of Websites leapt from 130 to roughly 200,000. Fostered by the improving multimedia capabilities, commercial use of the Internet overtook research and edu- cational use and has been growing exponen- tially in the 1990s (see figure 1). By January 1997, there were close to 4 million hosts in the .com domain.' The private sector has clearly taken the driver's seat in providing both the Internet's infrastructure and its content in the United States.

Regulation

The Internet has blossomed in a relatively regulation-free environment. Most regulatory activity has concentrated on defining standards for the formats and protocols necessary to operate the network. But as the commercial presence on the Net increases, regulatory is- sues relating to the provision of the network's infrastructure and services become increasingly important. The development of a regulatory framework is critical in three areas: provision of Internet backbone access; Internet service providers (ISPs); and information services.

The Internet backbone servers are the highest- level network servers-those to which ISPs pay connection charges. The basic regulatory options are to provide public support for lbacltbone access to promote connectivity or to leave back- bone service provision to the market. As men- tioned, the original backbone in the United States, NSFNet, was government-funded until rapid growth in networking demand led to the emergence of commercial backbones. A similar

Page 31: levo~ution and the - documents.worldbank.orgdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/pt/888891468164944771/pdf/454660WP0BOX... · levo~ution and the What the Transformation of Telecommunications

The World Bank Group

pattern can be found in otl~er industrial coun- tries. In Germany, for example, the first Internet Ihackbone-UNIDO, for Universirit Dorttnund- n7as run by the university and later replaced by con~mercial backbones.

ISPs provicle Internet services to the end users. In the United States, ISPs are colupeting private firms Jn other countries, the major ISP is the sta~c-owned telecor~munica tior~s operator, of- ten a monopoly. Regulato~y options for ISPs depend on he market str~~cturt. in telecom~lu- nicarions. In many cases, the telecomtnunica- tions operators a!-c well positioned to provide Internet services. But it is worth pointing out that OECD countries with more competitive tele- communications sectors rend to have greater Internet connectivity than countries with a mo- nopoly (figuse 2).

Policyrnakers have to decide whether telecom- munications network operators should be per- mitted to offer information services in direct competition with inclependent information ser- vice providers. As a rule of thumb, if a telecom- munications operator has market power in the transport network. structural or at leasl: account- ing separation ~hou ld be required to avoid anti- competitive cross-subsidization. In other words, the Internet services unit of the operator shoulcl be required to buy access to the transport net- work on an "arm's-length" basis. Another, very sensitive issue is voice telephony over the In- ternet, which may become a serious threat to the traditional circuit-switched networlc.

Appropriability of content

Digitized inforluation can be easily reproclucecl and reclistributed on the Internet, and provicl- ers o f information find it difficult to chal-ge users directly. Most private content providers recover costs indirectly: providing information to potential customers about other goocls and ser- vices. The indirect incentive structure is strong given the low cost of disseminating informa- tion on the Internet relative to the numl~er of users and the bright future prospects of the Internet.

But the conventional remedy for the cost re- covery pr-oblem is intellectual property rights protection. Copyright, for example, protects an author's work-whether a book, a performance, a recorrllng, or a computer program-from un- licensed copying. In principle, traclitional copy- right Iaw applies to tlie Internet environment. But such major industrial economies as the United States and those in the European Lrlion have revised or are now revising their intellec- tual property rights laws to address specific needs of electronic networks. Moreover, the glo-

Page 32: levo~ution and the - documents.worldbank.orgdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/pt/888891468164944771/pdf/454660WP0BOX... · levo~ution and the What the Transformation of Telecommunications

30 The Private Sector and the Internet

bal character of the Internet demands interna- tional legal governance (box l).

An important problem in legal protection for copyright holders on the Internet is enforcement, given the speed and magnitude of data trans- mission. This is an area where digital rights man- agement technologies can be of help. In general, digital rights management technologies are hard- ware and software devices that control access to information and the ability to use and further distribute it. In principle, these "encryption" tech- nologies are attractive because, unlike intellec- tual property rights, they can prol~ide digital protection across national boundaries. Increas- ingly sophisticated digital rights management technologies are becoming available on the World Wide Web. But national security reasons have been invoked to lirnit the dissemination of cryptographic capabilities. The United States has been trying to address the national security is- sue by promoting data encryption standards that can be broken by intelligence agencies and by controlling the export of encryption technology, restrictive measures that may inhibit widespread commercial use of these technologies.

A third way to recover costs is through the sale of advertising space on information pages.

Commercial advertisements first appeared on the Web in 1994. Although this step toward pure commercial use of the Internet initially met with strong resistance from the research and education communities, growth has been rapid, and advertising revenues are estimated to have exceeded US$250 million in 1996.

Internationalization

Although the Internet is still most dominant in the United States, the 1990s have been marked by its rapid internationalization. The share of non-U.S. hosts increased from 20 percent in July 1991 to 36 percent in July 1996. But most non-U.S. hosts stil.1 reside in industrial coun- tries, and in July 1996, roughly 96 percent of all Internet hosts were in OECD countries.

Most developing countries are connected to the Internet-if only through email-though pen- etration is still low (figure 3). In 1996, there was on average only 0.5 Internet host per 10,000 inhabitants in developing countries, compared with 101 in industrial countries. The low penetration is due mainly to the poor in- formation infrastructure in developing coun- tries--the roads and ports that carry and process digitized information. Average teledensity (tele-

Page 33: levo~ution and the - documents.worldbank.orgdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/pt/888891468164944771/pdf/454660WP0BOX... · levo~ution and the What the Transformation of Telecommunications

The World Bank Group

phone lines per person) is thirteen times lower, and average PC density thirty-eight times lower, than in industrial countries.

For developing countries, establishing the right regulatory environment is as critical as it is for industrial countries-though the relevance of the regulatory experience of industrial econo- mies discussed above is open to debate for coun- tries with poor telecommunications networks, low computer penetration, and inefficient, state- owned telecommunications monopolies. But a few developing countries have managed to rap- idly expand Internet connectivity despite weak information infrastructure, such as Brazil, Chile, the Czech Republic, Mexico, Malaysia, and South Africa.

Brazil, for example, successfully adopted a model of public-private partnership to diffuse the Internet, and it has increased Internet connectivity notwithstanding its dominant state- owned telecommunications operator. Recogniz- ing the economic benefits of electronic networking, the Brazilian government supports an Internet backbone open to commercial con- nectivity and traffic while limiting the domi- nant carrier's activity in the direct provision of Internet services to the public. The nurnher of Internet hosts in Brazil (.br domain) grew from 300 in January 1992 to more than 50,000 in July 1996, of which some 20,000 are commer- cial (.com.br domain). By the mid-1990s, Bra- zil had a higher ratio of Internet hosts to PCs than such economies as France, Germany, Hong Kong, and Singapore.

There are, of course, many obstacles to the diffusion of the Internet in developing coun- tries. National laws regarding privacy and in- tellectual property rights protection must be refined. And the predominance of Englisb- language content n1aj7 deter local researchers or local firms that could use the Internet to add value to their goods and services.

promote Internet connectivity at the level of the research and education communities may help jump-start the national information infra- structure. And governments should support community access in public libraries and com- munity centers. But an increasingly important role for governments in fostering the Internet revolution is that in the regulatory arena. Most important here is to promote a competitive en- vironment for Internet service providers, es- tablish adequate rilles of the game for electronic commerce, and ensure effective incentives for the provision of content-essential measures For attracting private investment in the infra- structure and in content generation. Those countries able to attract such investment will be better positioned to benefit from the emerg- ing global information infrastructure.

' This underswta rhe number of commercial hosts. since the .net domain (with more than 1.5 million hosts) and some of the countly domaim alw include commercial hosrs.

Ca~los A. Prinzo Brclga (cbmgn@worldbnnk. org), Principal Economist, and Carsten Fink, Consultant, Telecommunications and InJormatics Division

The critical bottleneck, however, continues to be the weak information infrastructure of de- veloping countries. Government activism to

Page 34: levo~ution and the - documents.worldbank.orgdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/pt/888891468164944771/pdf/454660WP0BOX... · levo~ution and the What the Transformation of Telecommunications

The Information Revolution and the Role of Government A z ~ n ~ o i s e Clottes

New information and cornm~~nications tech- nologies underpin a range of new applications that provide real opportunities for develop~ng countries to skip stages of development and catch up to industrial countries-in trade, gov- ernance, education, business connectivity, health care delivery, and environmental and natural resource management. In the health sec- tor, for example, information and cominunica- tions technologies have created much interest in distance diagnosis, in which health care pro- viders in remote rural areas call on the exper- tise of diagnosticians in the capital city or abroad. While most information technologies in curative health care are still at the experi- rllental stage. a quiet revolution is also taking place in preventive health care in developing countries: medical records are being comput- erized, ancl health care decisions are increas- ingly based on statistical time series, with L I I L I C ~

more targeted and cost-effective results.

For businesses in developing countries. connec- tivity allows access to international information in real time about markets, prices, and product specifications. It also allows provision of ser- vices at a distance, opening up to service pro- viders in developing countries such activities as airline ticketing and the processing of insurance forms and credit card transactions. And as com- munications costs fall, loose international alli- ances of companies, many from developing countries, are formlng and operating globally.

Isolation in poor. remote areas can be addressed cost-effectively using new information and communications technology. In such countries as Indonesia, community infor tn~~ion centers

proviclc access for the poor to networlcs. In many ways emulating for the digital age the role of the post office for poor communities fifty years ago. Wireless technologies increas- rngly allow cost-effective comlnunications for people in rural areas who would be unable to afford conventional telephone system-as pag- ing does in China, for example.

Environmental and natural resource manage- ment are also experiencing real benefits from the new technologies. Teledetection and com- puterized databases make it possible to spot environmental trends, and to implement miti- gation measures, much earlier. New technolo- gies also make it possible to deliver government services much more efficiently. Electronic pay- ment systems, electronic taxation and customs, electronic land titling and registries, and smart cards for social services all enable governments to deliver services more quickly, more cost- effectively, and with greater transparency. Ancl access to inforination at loaf cost is transfornz- ing the relationship between government and the governed around the world, as people be- come more amfare of their choices and illore interested in influencing the clecisions that will shape their future.

To take advantage of the potential for develop- ment offered by information infrastructure, coun- tries must have a nlinimum of infrastructure in place. But a comparison of the infornlation in- frastructure in developing countries with that in industrial countries n~nkes it clear that develop- ing countries are ill equipped, with endowlnents equivalent to only about 10 to 20 percent of industrial countries' (figure 1). Sub-Saharan Africa's endo\ment is about 1 percent of in- dustrial countries'. These low levels of installed

Page 35: levo~ution and the - documents.worldbank.orgdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/pt/888891468164944771/pdf/454660WP0BOX... · levo~ution and the What the Transformation of Telecommunications

The World Bank Group

infrastr~~cture are not the result of lack of de- mand or lack of capacity to pay. Rather, they are a sign that the model of teleconiniunica- tions service delivery based on public sector mo- nopoly providers has not performed well in developing countries ancl has not responded to consun~ers' clemancls.

The news is by no means all bad, though. Many developing countries have undertaken wide- ranging reform of their telecom~iiunlcations sec- tors. Ancl as countries move to a lnoclel where t e lecom~~i~~nica t ions services are delivered by private sector operators in a competitive frame- work, equipment costs are plummeting, en- abling new investors in developing countries to install the most up-to-date equipment for a fraction of the cost of the networks installed only a couple of years ago in industrial coun- tries. I~~vestment is accelerat~ng. The total capi- tal invested annually in ttlecommunications in developing and transition economies has doubled since the start of thc 1990% from USS3O I~illion to USSGO billion, with more than half coming from private investors.

Bottlenecks in the value chain

hlost of the discussion about the informarion revolution relates to what are essentially tech- nical issues, such 21s bandwidth, 11ow wil.eless solutions for the local loop compare with con- ventional wireline, ancl what the Internet's role will be. But the ualtle of infornlation infiastruc- ture for economic agents-in increased pro- ductivity, in a better quality of 11fe tl~rough improved access to information, and in greater co~npetitivc'ness-stems from a whole series of links in a long and colnplex chain. Only a few of the links really depencl on technology (!>ox 1). Other links depend o n laws, o n the regula- tory environment, and o n human capacity to take advantage of the new technology.

Participants in the informat1011 infrastructure value chain can be groupecl inlo five broad categories.

The co~ztetzt creator, who generates the raw material of the inforniation age. Contc:~lr cre-

FIGURE 1 INfOAM#710M ImASTlfUCFmE GAPS [per inhobitad

ators' value added ranges from low, for ba- sic data entry, to very high, for music, video, and electronic newspapers. Trunk tfzlrzsnzission oj' irfirmntion, such as long-clistance ancl international telephony and sateIlite video transmission. Intelsat and other providers of satellite capacity are in this cat- egory, as are such fiber-optic cable systems as Fiber Link Around the Globe (FLAG). /njorma/ion irztertnedic~r-ies, wwh~ch convert, process, store, and broker content. Examples inclucle cable companies, Internet service providers, and movie studios, which often store old films in vast video lil3raries. Loc~ll dish-ibzttion, which carries the signal to the final consunier of information. Ex- amples are the local loop of the telephone network, local cable links, and direct digital TV broadcasters. E17d ztsers, who use the information in spe- cific ways, ranging from entertaininent to education to productive activities.

Closing the physical infrastructure gap is the easi- est hurdle to overcome. Technological solutions may differ bclween rich and poor countries, but not all that much. If the right environment is in placc, private investors will make the appropri- ate technology available to the encl user.

But in most cleveloping countries, government policies, the legal system, ancl the regu la toly

Page 36: levo~ution and the - documents.worldbank.orgdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/pt/888891468164944771/pdf/454660WP0BOX... · levo~ution and the What the Transformation of Telecommunications

The Information Revolution and the Role of Gover nment

framework are simply not information-friendly. For example, technical norms and specifications are not standarclized, and quallty standards vary between industries and between countries. In- tellectual property rights laws and their enforce- ment are weak, which leacls to poor protection for local content creators and to illicit duplica- tion and sale of foreign material. Most impor- tant, telecommunications laws are often biased in favor of public sector monopoly institutions, limiting private investors' willingness to install new equipment. Commitment to liberalizing trade (including trade in services) may be weak or simply unclear (see page 20).

Unclear public policy, antiquated laws, and out- dated regulations can be major hurdles to tak-

ing advantage of information infrastructure for development. Imagine how difficult it might be for a firm to enter the world of Internet- based long-distance commercial services in a country where electronic evidence (such as electronic order forms from customers) is not legally admissible, intellectual property rights laws do not exist, customs and fiscal authori- ties do not recognize exports of services be- cause they are intangible (so value added taxes cannot be deducted), receiving payment from customers by credit card is impossible, and the telecommunications link to the rest of the world is provided by a public sector monopoly that does not know the meaning of customer service.

But if dealing with policy, legal, and segula- tory gaps is a challenge, education and worker skill levels can be an even greater hurdle, of- ten simply inadequate to match the demands of the new economy. Illiteracy rates are high in the developing world. Secondary school enrollment is low, and unless it improves, the education gap is likely to be perpetuated. Com- puter skills are scarce, ancl there is not enough technical and scientific higher education to sat- isfy demand. Vocational and on-the-job train- ing is limited-indeed, sometimes nonexistent.

But here too the news is not all bad. New tech- nology is part of the solution to the problem. The new technologies are leading to two im- portant trends in education and vocational train- ing. First, education, particularly higher and vocational education, is becoming much more cost-effective, as technology improves the de- livery and packaging of information for the stu- dent, and the teacher becomes facilitator and intermediator rather than depository of infor- mation. Second, education is shifting from the nontradable to the tradable sector, as countries come to see it as an important service export. So today it is becoming increasingly possible to buy excellent education from world-class estab- lishments for a fraction of the cost of develop- ing the system from scratch. But it all depends on having an education policy that takes this possibility into account.

Page 37: levo~ution and the - documents.worldbank.orgdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/pt/888891468164944771/pdf/454660WP0BOX... · levo~ution and the What the Transformation of Telecommunications

The World Bank Group 35

Implications for the role of government

Just as the information revolution is changing the global economy, it is also changing the role of government. Increasingly, governments no longer hold a monopoly on information, nor can they compete effectively with the private sector in delivering goods and services, includ- ing public services. These new limits are the basis for the change in the way people think of governments and public authorities, and for much of the rolling back of the public sector worldwide over the past decade.

But what role-if any-do governments have in unleashing the full potential of the informa- tion revolution? The information value chain framework, and the gaps and weaknesses in some of the links of the value chain, provide some important insights into what governments should do. At the same time, it is very clear what they should not do.

At a minimum, governments need to tackle the bottlenecks in telecommunications infrastruc- ture. In most developing countries, this means getting out of the telecommunications business and allowing full private entry in investment and service provision in a competitive frame- work. Telecommunications policies and laws that promote public sector monopolies in ser- vice provision are the biggest obstacles to developing robust, cost-effective telecommu- nications infrastructure.

Next, it means removing from the statute books all the outdated laws and regulations that hinder the development of an information economy. Because it is decentralized, the information economy is not something that laws can d o much to promote, but a small number of ratio- nal laws-for example, to protect property rights-can reduce the risks for private inves- tors and entrepreneurs. And economic regula- tion can reduce the market dominance of large players, such as the incumbent telecommuni- cations operators, and promote competitive behavior.

But what will make the most difference in the new global information economy are the gen- eral education level of the population and the skills of the labor force. Governments must seek new ways to deliver training and skills cost- effectively, relying increasingly on the private sector. Education systems worldwide are sim- ply not u p to the task.

In a nutshell, the best thing governments can d o to promote i~lformation for development is to withdraw from the hardware dimension of information infrastructure and focus o n the soft- ware-laws, regulations, and education.

Fmn~oise Clottes [email protected]), Economist, Telecommunications and Informa Ncs Division

Page 38: levo~ution and the - documents.worldbank.orgdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/pt/888891468164944771/pdf/454660WP0BOX... · levo~ution and the What the Transformation of Telecommunications
Page 39: levo~ution and the - documents.worldbank.orgdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/pt/888891468164944771/pdf/454660WP0BOX... · levo~ution and the What the Transformation of Telecommunications
Page 40: levo~ution and the - documents.worldbank.orgdocuments.worldbank.org/curated/pt/888891468164944771/pdf/454660WP0BOX... · levo~ution and the What the Transformation of Telecommunications